How Institutions Evolve: The Political Economy of Skills in Germany, Britain, The United States, and Japan
How Institutions Evolve: The Political Economy of Skills in Germany, Britain, The United States, and Japan
How Institutions Evolve: The Political Economy of Skills in Germany, Britain, The United States, and Japan
KATHLEEN THELEN
Northwestern University
v
P1: KcS
0521837685pre Thelen 0521837685 June 19, 2004 10:36
A catalog record for this book is available from the British Library.
vi
P1: KcS
0521837685pre Thelen 0521837685 June 19, 2004 10:36
Contents
Preface page xi
ix
P1: KcS
0521837685pre Thelen 0521837685 June 19, 2004 10:36
Contents
Bibliography 297
Index 323
x
P1: JzG/JzK
0521837685c01 Thelen 0521837685 May 31, 2004 17:5
1 Harry Katz and Owen Darbishire make a more nuanced argument about the pace and scope
of common trends (Katz and Darbishire 1999; see also Martin and Ross 1999).
1
P1: JzG/JzK
0521837685c01 Thelen 0521837685 May 31, 2004 17:5
2 The literature on the political economy of advanced capitalism from the 1970s and 1980s
similarly focused on distinctive national models (for example, Hall 1986, Zysman 1983, and
corporatism theorists of the 1970s). The newer literature on “varieties of capitalism” is an
outgrowth of that earlier work, though with some important theoretical innovations. For
an extended discussion, see Thelen (2002b).
3 In fact, all these various categorization schemes also have trouble sorting the same set of
“intermediate” or hard to classify countries, including France and Italy.
2
P1: JzG/JzK
0521837685c01 Thelen 0521837685 May 31, 2004 17:5
3
P1: JzG/JzK
0521837685c01 Thelen 0521837685 May 31, 2004 17:5
forces” (Streeck 2001: 31). He emphasizes how national models are not the
product of a grand design, and “Ex post accommodation . . . seems to have
been at least as important . . . as a priori calculations of the advantages of
compatibility and complementarity under conditions of interdependence”
(Streeck 2001: 31). Unlike Hall and Soskice’s equilibrium-based view of
institutions, Streeck sees these arrangements as inherently less coherent
and therefore also not at all self-equilibrating, which leads to a picture that
is overall less sanguine about the robustness of such systems. At the same
time, however, and for many of the same reasons, this alternative view would
not necessarily see such systems as vulnerable to the kind of “unraveling”
mentioned above in the event of strong perturbations in one realm.
The premise of this book is that in order to understand the likely fu-
ture of the institutions that make up the different “varieties of capitalism”
we need a better sense of where these institutions came from, what has
sustained them, and what are the ways in which they have changed over
time. This is not the first time these systems have experienced strain, and
understanding how they evolved in the past can yield new insights into the
modes and mechanisms of change through which they continue to develop
today. My analysis focuses on the institutions of skill formation because
they constitute a key element in the institutional constellations identified
by all the authors cited above. In fact, one recent strand of scholarship sees
skills and skill formation systems as causally central to the development and
articulation of social policy preferences generally, and thus foundational for
the development and maintenance of different systems of social protection
across the developed democracies (see, especially, Iversen and Soskice 2001;
also Iversen 2003).
I approach the politics of skill formation from two angles, pursuing both
a cross-national and a longitudinal dimension. First, the cross-national com-
ponent of the study traces the origins of different skill formation regimes,
focusing especially on Britain and Germany, and with only slightly less de-
tailed treatments as well of Japan and the United States. This part of the
book asks the questions: Why did different countries pursue such different
trajectories in terms of plant-based training? And: how did the evolution of
training institutions interact with the development of “collateral” organiza-
tions and institutions – especially labor unions and employer associations,
and industrial relations institutions?
One of the most widely cited differences between “coordinated” market
economies (such as Germany and Japan) and “liberal” market economies
(such as the United States and United Kingdom) is that the former
4
P1: JzG/JzK
0521837685c01 Thelen 0521837685 May 31, 2004 17:5
4 Mine is not the first study to draw attention to these particular cases. As mentioned above,
the different literatures on varieties of capitalism tend to focus on the same basic clusters
of countries. Likewise, in the literature on skills in particular, it is not uncommon to draw
a broad distinction between Germany and Japan on one hand (as “high-skill” economies)
and the United States and United Kingdom on the other (as “low-skill” or strongly skill
bifurcated economies) (for example, Ashton and Green 1996; Brown, Green, and Lauder
2001). This convention follows pioneering work by Finegold and Soskice (1988), who draw
a sharp line between “high-skill” and “low-skill” equilibrium countries, though in the mean-
time this somewhat simplified distinction has been superseded by a more differentiated view
that emphasizes the different types and mixes of skills produced within any one country.
This is also why I adopt the somewhat less normatively inflected language of “coordinated”
versus “liberal” training regimes, which are characterized by different mixes of strengths
and weaknesses in skill formation. See the discussion below.
5 Ashton and Green (1996) propose an explanation of these outcomes that is broadly com-
patible with mine. However their historical analysis is very fleeting (five to ten pages per
country, and in each case covering both plant-based and school-based training). Their ex-
planation of these outcomes hinges on the behavior of highly aggregated actors (“the ruling
class,” the “bourgeoisie,” the “aristocracy”), and the conclusions – although not wrong –
are highly simplified. Many of their assertions (for example, the idea that the Handwerk
sector was “undermined” by industrialization or the implication that unions pushed for
skill standardization against employer opposition) are not consistent with the results of the
historical–empirical research presented here (Ashton and Green 1996: 142–3).
5
P1: JzG/JzK
0521837685c01 Thelen 0521837685 May 31, 2004 17:5
6 For example, Acemoglu and Pischke note that low education entry-level workers are more
likely to get training in Germany than in the United States (Acemoglu and Pischke 1999a:
F129).
9
P1: JzG/JzK
0521837685c01 Thelen 0521837685 May 31, 2004 17:5
to compete in these markets. As he puts it: “firms that create only those
skills that they need may well end up with less than they need. Cost- and
profit-consciousness are more part of the problem than of the solution”
(Streeck 1992b: 17). In Streeck’s view, cultural or political constraints that
bend the logic of individual market incentives – in this case encouraging
firms to “over invest” in skills – may turn out “to be more conducive to
economic performance under given technological and market conditions
than others” (Streeck 1992b: vii).
Given this posing of the problem, Germany was long considered a
model of successful vocational training and skill formation for the ad-
vanced industrial countries generally. The comparisons to other countries
were mostly invidious (see, for example, Berg 1994; Oulton and Steedman
1994; Finegold 1993). In one important contribution, for example, David
Finegold and David Soskice examined the institutional bases of Germany’s
“high skill” and the United Kingdom’s “low skill” equilibria (Finegold and
Soskice 1988). In particular, they argued that Britain’s chronic undersupply
of training went back to public good or free rider problems, and the re-
sulting dearth of skills in the economy encouraged firms to pursue product
strategies premised on low skills, which in turn discouraged investment in
skills, and so on. This dynamic provided the backdrop to their analysis of
the inability and/or unwillingness of the British government to take action
to break the cycle (Finegold and Soskice 1988: 25ff).
In the meantime, the literature has begun to paint a somewhat more dif-
ferentiated pattern of strengths and weaknesses (see, for example, Crouch,
Finegold, and Sako 1999; Culpepper 2003; Culpepper and Finegold 1999;
Hall and Soskice 2001; Green and Sakamoto 2001). Thus, for example,
Finegold’s more recent work highlights Germany’s continued high invest-
ment in initial manufacturing skills (apprenticeship) but notes deficits in
the commitment of firms to further training – now arguably more impor-
tant than ever in the context of rapidly changing production technology –
(see Pichler 1993), as well as the overall scarcity of certain high-end
(information technology and engineering) skills (Crouch, Finegold, and
Sako 1999; Atkins 2000). Conversely, the United States, long viewed as a
skills “laggard,” is now getting more credit for producing an abundance
of high-end skills – having become a net exporter of skills in informa-
tion technologies, for example – despite continued worries about the coun-
try’s under-investment in traditional manufacturing skills (Hall and Soskice
2001; Smith 2000). In a way, the emphasis in the political economy litera-
ture has shifted from an effort to identify overall differences in the quantity
10
P1: JzG/JzK
0521837685c01 Thelen 0521837685 May 31, 2004 17:5
Economists on Skills
As a first step in situating this literature and in mapping the empirical cases, it
is useful to summarize briefly the way in which economists have approached
the issue of skill formation. A point of departure for the political economy
literature cited above is training market failures going back to poaching
externalities, a view which for most of the first half of the twentieth cen-
tury was widely accepted among economists (see, for example, Pigou 1912;
Stevens 1996). The crux of the problem was seen to consist of a collective
action dilemma. Specifically, firms that need skills face a choice: whether to
provide their own training (at some cost to themselves), or attempt to secure
skilled labor on the labor market (in effect, to attract workers from other
firms that have invested in training). Since firms are themselves competitors
in labor and product markets, each individual company will be tempted to
poach workers from other firms, thus avoiding the costs associated with skill
formation and in fact making off with the investment of its competitors.
The more firms that choose this strategy, the greater will be the costs to
those firms that do train; they incur both the costs of training itself and the
costs of competing with non-training firms which – free of these costs –
can offer these workers a wage premium. If all firms pursue non-training
strategies, then of course all are worse off since this would diminish the
overall stock of skills on which all rely.
In a widely cited contribution, Gary Becker called into question this pos-
ing of the problem (1964). Becker distinguished between general skills and
specific skills and argued that poaching externalities would not be a prob-
lem in either case. For general skills – defined as those skills that are fully
transportable and hold value to many employers – it is quite true that firms
have no incentive to invest in training. But even if firms do not invest, work-
ers will, or in Becker’s words, “it is the trainees, not the firms who would
bear the cost of general training and profit from the return” (1993: 34).8
7 The available, mostly OECD, data are anyway notorious for their lack of comparability (for
example, OECD 1998: 10–11). For a discussion see also Lynch (1994).
8 Note that this formulation does not address the question of the supply of training, however.
11
P1: JzG/JzK
0521837685c01 Thelen 0521837685 May 31, 2004 17:5
Beyond Becker
In the meantime a number of studies have emerged which take us “be-
yond Becker” (Acemoglu and Pischke 1999a) but also, paradoxically, back
to some of the training–market problems identified by the earlier literature.
This work responds in part to empirical anomalies that point to sources
of under investment in skills that appear not to be captured by the logic
of Becker’s model (Acemoglu and Pischke 1999a; Finegold and Soskice
1988). Most of this more recent scholarship does not take issue directly
with Becker’s analysis of the two ideal-typical models of training markets
characterized by perfect competition (general skills) and non-competitive
labor markets (specific skills), but research has focused on the provision of
training in the intermediate case of imperfectly competitive labor markets
for certain kinds of skills. Specifically, analysts have reacted to two aspects
of Becker’s argument: (1) the sharp distinction he draws between general
and specific skills (Estevez-Abe, Iversen, and Soskice 2001; Stevens 1996;
Stevens 1999),9 and (2) his implicit assumption that the market for general
skills will always be perfectly competitive (Acemoglu and Pischke 1998;
Acemoglu and Pischke 1999a; Acemoglu and Pischke 1999b).
First, Margaret Stevens attacks the problem by questioning Becker’s stark
categorization of skills as either general or specific. She focuses on an inter-
mediate category of skills, what she calls transferable skills.10 Such skills “are
of value to more than one firm, and there is competition between firms to
employ the worker, but competition is not sufficiently fierce that the wage
is driven up to the marginal product” (Stevens 1999: 19). Stevens and others
imply that very many skills fall into some kind of intermediate category.
In a similar vein, Finegold and Soskice note that a given firm may need
a particular mix of skills, and that while each one may be general the mix
9 Although Becker does recognize that most training is neither purely general nor purely
specific (Becker 1993: 40).
10 This seems similar to the category “industry skills” identified by Estevez-Abe, Iversen, and
Soskice (2001).
13
P1: JzG/JzK
0521837685c01 Thelen 0521837685 May 31, 2004 17:5
itself is specific (Finegold and Soskice 1988; Acemoglu and Pischke 1999a:
F124). Moreover, Franz and Soskice (1995) argue that the acquisition of
general and specific skills is complementary, that is, teaching firm-specific
skills reduces the costs of teaching general skills and vice versa.
The introduction of this intermediate category of transferable skills
(portable but not really “general” in Becker’s sense) re-introduces the prob-
lem of poaching externalities since in an imperfectly competitive labor mar-
ket the value of the skill (= wage) will not necessarily be driven up fully to
marginal product, and some of the training accrues to the firm that employs
the skilled worker (Stevens 1999: 20). This situation reduces the employee’s
incentive to acquire skills (since he will not be able to capture the full re-
turn on his training investment in the form of wages), but for the very same
reason, it also increases the employer’s incentive to assume a part of the
costs of training. But this, in turn, raises again the possibility that one firm’s
investment in training might accrue to some other firm – that is, a poach-
ing externality – leading to under investment in skills of this type (Stevens
1999: 27).
Acemoglu and Pischke argue similarly for the possibility of imper-
fect labor market competition and associated implications for training
(Acemoglu and Pischke 1999a: F127). Whereas Stevens and others (for
example, Estevez-Abe, Iversen, and Soskice 2001) attack the Becker the-
sis by drawing out more fine-grained distinctions among types of skills,
however, Acemoglu and Pischke focus instead on the structure of the labor
market. Against Becker’s thesis that firms will never pay for general training,
they note empirical examples (German apprenticeship is one) where firms
do bear a significant fraction of the cost of general training (Acemoglu and
Pischke 1999a: F113–4). By way of explanation they cite labor market im-
perfections that prevent skilled workers from claiming wages equal to their
full marginal productivity and that thus allow employers to earn rents on
their training (Acemoglu and Pischke 1999a: F120; Acemoglu and Pischke
1998: 80).
Acemoglu and Pischke consider various sources of labor market imper-
fections. Institutions or situations that result in low labor turnover, for
example, distort the competitiveness of labor markets, making it possible
for employers to retain a worker after training at a wage lower than marginal
product. One source of low labor turnover is monopsony power exercised
by large firms that may dominate a local economy. Firms in such a situation
could pay a wage above the local rate but still below the marginal produc-
tivity of its trained workers (Acemoglu and Pischke 1998: 80–1). Japanese
14
P1: JzG/JzK
0521837685c01 Thelen 0521837685 May 31, 2004 17:5
Back to Politics
The analytic move made by Acemoglu and Pischke – from the assumption
of perfectly competitive labor markets to the observation that the degree
11 Blinder and Krueger (1996) show that labor turnover in Japan is less than half the U.S.
level. Japanese management policies, including seniority-based wages, company-level so-
cial policy, and reluctance to recruit experienced workers from other firms, contribute to
this outcome.
12 Acemoglu and Pischke also note other sources of labor market imperfections that have
similar effects to low labor turnover and wage compression. These include matching and
search frictions, which make it difficult for workers to quit their jobs and find new ones, and
asymmetric information about how much training workers have (that is, a firm which trains
its workers has an advantage over competitors because it has better information about the
workers’ skill levels) (Acemoglu and Pischke 1999a).
13 Additionally, the typical argument about compression is that this creates incentives for em-
ployers to replace relatively expensive unskilled workers with machines. Together with the
skills argument I am making, this points toward a high-skill, higher technology trajectory
(supporting what Streeck has called “diversified quality production”) (see also Moene and
Wallerstein 1995; Streeck 1991).
15
P1: JzG/JzK
0521837685c01 Thelen 0521837685 May 31, 2004 17:5
of competitiveness in the labor market can vary (with implications for the
incentives facing both firms and trainees) – is crucial to the present anal-
ysis because, as the case studies elaborated below show, training regimes
developed historically in tandem and in interaction with the development
of other labor-market institutions and organizations. In Britain, as we will
see, union structures and collective bargaining institutions developed in
ways that intensified and in some ways distorted competition among em-
ployers in both skilled labor and product markets. By contrast, in Germany
and Japan, developments with respect to union structures and collective
bargaining introduced labor-market imperfections that provided some in-
centives for firms to train while at the same time (re-)introducing collective
action problems associated with poaching.14
The point is that the structure and operation of skilled labor markets
can be significantly influenced by politics, and historically, the interaction
of the development of training regimes and of labor-market institutions
had a profound effect on what kind of skilled labor market employers (and
trainees) faced, as well as the kinds of solutions available for redressing
the particular (different) market failures that emerged in different contexts.
The problems (and solutions) that emerged historically are what lie behind
some of the striking contemporary national differences in training regimes
(Acemoglu and Pischke 1999a: F132).
In terms of outcomes, Peter Hall and David Soskice note that in lib-
eral market economies, the incentives are for young people to acquire skills
that are generally marketable rather than firm- or even industry-specific.
Companies may upgrade this education with some company training but
typically attempt to add only non-transferable (firm-specific) skills whose
full benefit they and only they can recoup (Hall and Soskice 2001). The
U.S. training regime thus does not favor strong firm-based investment in
private sector vocational training. It appears, however, to support very well
the production of a plentiful supply of “high-end” skills – for example, en-
gineering and programming – that thrive in a context that rewards strong
general (especially university) education and where demand for training on
the part of young people is driven by intense competition among firms.
14 Acemoglu and Pischke do not do the historical analysis, but they do stress the complemen-
tarities between training systems and labor market regulations (1999a: F136) and suggest
that “the more frictional and regulated labor markets [in Europe and Japan] may encourage
more firm-sponsored training” (Acemoglu and Pischke 1999b: 567). See also Peter Hall
and David Soskice who discuss institutional complementarities between training systems
and other political–economic institutions (Hall and Soskice 2001).
16