T C E D R G R: Ransaction OST Conomics and Irections For Elational Overnance Esearch
T C E D R G R: Ransaction OST Conomics and Irections For Elational Overnance Esearch
ABSTRACT
Transaction Cost Economics (TCE) has formed the basis of interorganizational governance research for the past thirty years.
This paper summarizes TCE and explores some of its criticisms, namely its restricted solution set and its ignorance of trust-
based behaviors. Some of these concerns are addressed by the relational view of interorganizational governance, although a
more compelling solution appears to be a hybrid of these theories. Suggestions for future research and highlights of
prominent IS research utilizing these theories are included.
Keywords
Transaction cost economics, TCE, relational view, hybrid view, organizational governance, review
INTRODUCTION
The study of organizational governance is also a study of organizational strategy. This paper aims to trace the foundation of
modern governance theory from the explosion of Transaction Cost Economics to the relational view of the firm and the
eventual hybridization of the two approaches.
TRANSACTION COST ECONOMICS (TCE)
This exploration of organizational governance theory begins with Transaction Cost Economics (TCE), which focuses on
organizational transactions as its unit of analysis. Exposed to decades of review and analysis, TCE has been called ―an
empirical success story‖ (Carter & Hodgson, 2006; Williamson, 1999, p. 1059), and has been the subject of multiple review
articles, including Carter & Hodgson (2006), and as a part of a broader review of inter-organizational theories, by Robey, Im
and Wareham (2008). TCE is a lens useful for examining build/buy operational decisions, contracts, and organizational
structure (human asset governance). In general, TCE defines a continuum between regulated hierarchical structure and open,
market-driven behavior, and provides guidance for how a transaction might best be structured based on its internal and
external coordination and control costs. In other words, TCE posits that organizations perform optimally by reducing the
costs of the transactions they engage in, and this, in turn, drives the transaction’s governance mechanism. (See Figure 1.)
Assumptions of TCE
Arguing convincingly that proper theory must account for the behavior of ―human nature as we know it‖, Williamson (1981,
pp., p. 553) bases TCE first on human bounded rationality, and second on ―the assumption that at least some agents are given
to opportunism.‖ Bounded rationality describes the finite ability of humans to access, store, and process information. This
means that contracts must necessarily be incomplete (Williamson, 1981). In general, although the assumption of bounded
rationality seems largely accepted by TCE theorists, the specific consequences of this assumption have been given very little
attention. Opportunism, described as self-interest with guile (Williamson, 1996), moves beyond the traditional economic
definition of self-interest and allows agents to behave deceitfully in a strategic way, by cutting corners, issuing false
promises, and reneging on contracts. One example of opportunism is agency costs, such as when the actions of an employee
or contractor are not in the best interest of the principal due to misaligned incentives. Because of opportunism, TCE posits
that stewardship and good faith behavior cannot universally exist, and accepts that curbing opportunism imposes control
costs. Although not ubiquitous, opportunism is unknowable in its strength or frequency (Ghoshal & Moran, 1996).
Dimensions of TCE
The critical dimensions for describing transactions are (1) uncertainty, (2) frequency, and (3) the degree to which transaction-
specific assets are required (Williamson, 1981).
Uncertainty
Uncertainty refers to any sort of unknown or unknowable variables in a transaction. A common facet of uncertainty,
particularly in IS literature, is technological uncertainty, meaning future changes in technology required for the transaction
are unknown and could significantly alter the cost of the transaction or render it wholly moot (e.g., Choudhury, 1997; Song &
Proceedings of the Southern Association for Information Systems Conference, Atlanta, GA, USA March 25 th-26th, 2011 73
Gregory TCE and Directions for Relational Governance
Montoya-Weiss, 2001). Choudhury (1997) also specifies demand uncertainty, were variability exists in demand, even for
frequent transactions.
More recently, Carson, Madhok and Wu (2006) further classified uncertainty as either volatility or ambiguity. Volatility
refers to the unpredictable rate of change such as a change in market demand or a change in supplier availability (it may be
easier to consider these respectively as demand uncertainty and supply uncertainty). Volatility implies parties in a contract
may need to adapt as the environment changes, and contracts should reflect conditions where renegotiation should be
considered. Ambiguity includes ―(1) lack of clear information, (2) uncertainty about the importance of environmental
variables, (3) uncertainty of cause-effect relationships between variables, and (4) uncertainty about available courses of
action and their potential effects‖ (Carson, et al., 2006, p. 1059). It is because of ambiguity that decision makers may arrive at
different boundedly rational results, which reduces the predictive ability of TCE. This also implies mechanisms that improve
information quality or reduce other forms of uncertainty will likely be cost-effective to the extent they reduce the governance
cost of a transaction or shift it toward a market-based rather than hierarchical solution.
Frequency
Although transaction frequency is considered a dimension of TCE, in his analysis, Williamson (1981) only ever addresses
frequent transactions (although frequency might be in doubt because of uncertainty). There is no discussion or
acknowledgement that optimal one-time transactions may exhibit different characteristics as compared with frequent
transactions.
Asset Specificity
Transaction-specific assets (meaning ―the degree to which transaction-specific investments are required to realize least-cost
supply,‖ (Williamson, 1981, p. 555)) are perhaps the most studied dimension of TCE, and the feature to which Williamson
devotes the most attention. Williamson (1981) defines three types of asset specificity: (1) location specificity, such as when
assets are located near each other to minimize costs, (2) physical asset specificity, where the assets have little value on their
own, but have value only for their use in a transaction, such as specialized manufacturing parts that provide little benefit in
another context, and (3) human asset specificity, meaning learned human skills used in the transaction. Perhaps because of
his focus on the transactional level of analysis, Williamson does not seem to differentiate between transaction-specific, firm-
specific, and industry-specific assets. This is an opportunity for future theorists.
In TCE analysis, the nature of a transaction’s assets is the driving force in determining whether a market or hierarchical
governance should be favored. The more general the asset, the better the firm is served by looking to the market. Conversely,
the greater the specificity of the asset, the more likely internal production under the firm’s hierarchy is the optimal solution.
Transaction Governance
(i.e., efficient boundaries, build/buy)
Hierarchy Market
Proceedings of the Southern Association for Information Systems Conference, Atlanta, GA, USA March 25 th-26th, 2011 74
Gregory TCE and Directions for Relational Governance
Easy
Meterability
Figure 2: TCE Applied to Human Asset Governance; adapted from Williamson (1981)
Easily measured and easily replaced, examples of spot market human assets include custodial and farm workers, and some
professional careers. In a spot market, ―Neither workers nor firms have an efficiency interest in maintaining the association‖
(Williamson, 1981, p. 564). Workers in a primitive team are non-specific, but their output cannot be easily measured on an
individual level, such as with manual freight loading. An obligational market includes employees requiring highly specific
knowledge or skills, such as accountants. Because their specificity makes the employment relationship valuable to both
parties, structures will be in place to prevent either party from terminating the employment relationship arbitrarily. Such
structures may include long vesting periods for retirement or due process termination procedures. Finally, a relational team is
both highly specific and difficult to meter, and, according to Williamson (1981) correspond to the clan organization proposed
by Ouchi (1977). Firms will offer these employees a high level of job security. (Williamson, 1981)
TCE and Information Systems
In a review of governance literature, Robey, et al. (2008) recognized that some studies in the IT field (e.g., Brynjolfsson,
Malone, Gurbaxani, & Kambil, 1994) ―support the hypothesis that increased levels of IT lead to smaller firms" (p. 503),
suggesting that the resulting reduced governance costs allowed firms to take advantage of the benefits of hierarchical
governance (e.g., better information and control) in areas previously relegated to market solutions. Argyres (1999) also
argued for the value of IT for reducing governance and coordination costs, showing a case where the implementation of an
information system enabled social conventions and a complex technical grammar resulting in improved coordination and
reduced governance.
Opposition to TCE
TCE did not emerge without opposition. Along with others, Ghoshal and Moran (1996) cautioned that the assumptions
underlying TCE narrowed its scope so much as to be less useful than claimed. Arguing by analogy, they recognized that
when governance decisions were being made using TCE heuristics as a reference, the solution space was constrained to the
continuum between hierarchy and market, with no accounting for strategic inputs (e.g. innovation, although Williamson
might simply consider such inputs to be externalities of the transaction that provided either a cost or benefit) or options that
had been assumed away, such as franchising, joint ventures. Ghoshal and Moran (1996) argued that although TCE had its
uses, these limiting assumptions crippled the use of TCE as a decision-making tool. "Our primary objective," they said, "... is
to caution against this growing frequency of applying the TCE logic for such normative purposes. (p. 15)"
Ghoshal and Moran continue their critique of TCE by examining its underlying assumptions. Opportunism, according to their
understanding of Williamson, is necessary to predict transactional governance. They argue that this suggests increased
hierarchical governance acts to counter the effects of opportunism. More specifically, Ghoshal and Moran argue that
Williamson intends governance to control opportunism through sanctions, this creates a feedback loop where the controls
designed to hedge against opportunism instead encourage it: "For example, even though sanctions can undoubtedly promote
specific types of behavior and deter others, elements of governance mechanisms such as surveillance and fiat have
consistently been shown to have negative effects on individual attitudes toward the specific behavior that is targeted. (p. 30)"
Proceedings of the Southern Association for Information Systems Conference, Atlanta, GA, USA March 25 th-26th, 2011 75
Gregory TCE and Directions for Relational Governance
They conclude, "The consequence of these negative feelings [engendered by behavioral controls] for both controller and
controlee is a 'pathological spiraling relationship', (p. 25)" and quote Enzle and Anderson (1993, p. 263) "Surveillants come
to distrust their targets as a results of their own surveillance and targets in fact become unmotivated and untrustworthy. The
target is now demonstrably untrustworthy and requires more intensive surveillance, and the increased surveillance further
damages the target. Trust and trustworthiness both deteriorate."
However, this argument is incomplete as it assumes the level of opportunism is knowable and that such knowledge drives
(rather than tangentially affects) the governance determination.
Opportunism is perhaps even more unpredictable than either Williamson or Ghoshal and Moran (1996) acknowledge,
particularly when the companion assumption of bounded rationality is included. Although opportunistic behavior might be
predicted, whether the actor has fully considered the long-term as well as short-term consequences of the opportunistic
behavior is unknowable (in part, due to the assumption of bounded rationality). Thus, its likelihood is similarly unknowable,
and provides a common level of uncertainty to all transactions. This supposition holds even if Hill's argument (1990) that
market participants avoid habitual opportunists is accepted.
Separate from the concerns of opportunism, Williamson (1996, p. 55) undermines his own work when he acknowledges that
―poor management can undo the advantages that accrue to correct alignments, and good management can sometimes
compensate for incorrect alignments.‖ This goes counter to the proposition that TCE predicts the optimal alignment of a
transaction in two ways. First, if costs of ―misalignment‖ can be mitigated through human action, it means the
―misalignment‖ may actually be ―more optimal‖ by deriving similar effects at a lower transaction cost. At the very least, such
a circumstance allows for the possibility of multiple optima, something not considered by TCE. Second—and this is perhaps
the most crucial objection—Williamson’s is acknowledging TCE is missing some crucial factor that accounts for the
behavior of managers.
RELATIONAL VIEW
With clear roots in both Transaction Cost Economics (TCE) and the Resource-Based View (RBV) (Barney, 1991), the
relational view of the firm further explores sources of sustainable competitive advantage. Agreeing with Williamson (1981)
that the typically arm’s-length transactions of markets provide little opportunity for sustained competitive advantage (or more
specifically, what they refer to as ―economic rents‖), Dyer and Singh (1998) proposed that a firm needs to consider not only
the transaction, as TCE does, but the long-term series of transactions a firm may require. Further, they argued that by creating
alliances and investing resources, firms with complementary resources can reduce their per-transaction cost (Dyer & Singh,
1998), similar to how a manufacturer might move resources to fixed costs in order to reduce variable costs. Thus, in addition
to a longitudinal perspective on transactions, the relational view of the firm considers complex inter-firm governance beyond
the dichotomous hierarchy/market framework imposed by TCE, and thus addresses an admitted blind spot of TCE.
The relational view predicts competitive advantages from strategic alliances seem to fall into four categories: ―(1)
investments in relation-specific assets; (2) substantial knowledge exchange, including the exchange of knowledge that results
in joint learning; (3) the combining of complementary, but scarce, resources or capabilities (typically through multiple
functional interfaces), which results in the joint creation of unique new products, services, or technologies; and (4) lower
transaction costs than competitor alliances, owing to more effective governance mechanisms‖ (Dyer & Singh, 1998, p. 662).
Each of these elements presents a way to either reduce uncertainty or increase productivity of specific assets in a transaction
without resorting to the high-cost governance controls suggested by TCE.
Part of the reason for examining relation-specific assets is that TCE only seemed to examine one side of the transaction. As
examples of their perspective, Dyer and Singh (1998) cited several studies showing that a seller’s investment in location-
specific assets provided significant benefit to both parties: the buyer incurred lower supply chain costs. Firms that invested in
other relation-specific assets tended to also see ―greater product differentiation, fewer defects, and faster product
development cycles‖ (Dyer & Singh, 1998, p. 664). Subramani and Venkatraman (2003) found that domain-specific
knowledge arising from relationship-specific intellectual capital investments by suppliers in asymmetric relationships with
powerful retailers was more predictive of governance than investment in specific physical assets, and allowed suppliers
greater input into joint decisions.
HYBRID VIEW
Based on the concepts presented in TCE and the relational view, some researchers proposed that opportunism was minimized
in long-term relationships (as it would be irrational when longitudinal consequences were considered, although this discounts
the core assumption of bounded rationality) so the need for formal contracts—which supposedly added significant cost to the
transaction—could be substituted with trust (e.g., Ghoshal & Moran, 1996; c.f., Poppo & Zenger, 2002). In contrast, Poppo
Proceedings of the Southern Association for Information Systems Conference, Atlanta, GA, USA March 25 th-26th, 2011 76
Gregory TCE and Directions for Relational Governance
and Zenger (2002) argued that well-specified contracts lower risks and promote relational longevity by increasing costs for
violation. Consistent with TCE literature (Williamson, 1991), they also agued that good contracts should include custom
measures for adaptation and dispute resolution, and are a necessary mechanism for limiting the conditions for opportunism.
Their research showed good evidence that trust and contracts functioned as complements, not substitutes, thus holding intact
the TCE structures within the relational view. As an example, two companies would be more likely to make strategic
investments that highlighted their mutual dependence with the intent of perpetuating the relationship indefinitely if a contract
is in place. Such actions would both require and engender trust, and lead to behavior from both parties that further solidified
the relationship. This suggests claims of governance mechanisms as a signal of distrust leading to greater opportunism
(resulting in further distrust and governance in a negative feedback loop, such as argued by Ghoshal & Moran, 1996) are not
strongly supported.
Continuing the stream of hybrid relational/TCE research, Carson, Madhok and Wu (2006) more closely examined the
relationship between contracts, uncertainty, and opportunism, and found relational contracts to be a robust safeguard against
volatility (but not ambiguity), and formal contracts to be a robust safeguard against ambiguity (but not volatility). They,
along with Goo, Kishore, and Rao (2009) found support for Poppo and Zenger’s (2002) determination that trust was
important in constraining opportunism under both forms of contracting, as it facilitated information sharing, harmonious
conflict resolution, and mutual dependence. Thus, both the hierarchical governance proposed by TCE and the preference for
―softer‖ trust-based mechanisms advocated by relational governance are considered by researchers adopting the hybrid view
as compliments rather than as substitutes.
CONCLUSION
Transaction Cost Economics has offered researchers a solid foundation for exploring governance issues, but has perhaps
attempted too much by attempting to be both predictive and prescriptive (although application of a prescriptive theory
necessarily increases its predictive ability). Most notably, the useful assumption of opportunism and the TCE dimension of
asset specificity have been the basis of most governance work for the past thirty years. However, the relational view adds
value to the exploration of interorganizational governance by addressing some of the human issues pointedly ignored by
TCE. More recently researchers have adopted a hybrid view, combining the two approaches. This may prove especially
useful when examining relationships in IS that are recognized as more difficult to contract for, such as agile development
(Wang, Lane, Conboy, & Pikkarainen, 2009). Examining interaction effects and building prescriptive theory regarding the
application of these complementary but opposing views of governance is a promising area for future research.
REFERENCES
1. Argyres, N. S. (1999). The Impact of Information Technology on Coordination: Evidence from the B-2 "Stealth"
Bomber. Organization Science, 10(2).
2. Barney, J. B. (1991). Firm Resources and Sustained Competitive Advantage. Journal of Management, 17(1), 99-120.
3. Brynjolfsson, E., Malone, T. W., Gurbaxani, V., & Kambil, A. (1994). Does Information Technology Lead to Smaller
Firms? Management Science, 40(12), 1628-1644.
4. Carson, S. J., Madhok, A., & Wu, T. (2006). Uncertainty, Opportunism, and Governance: The effects of volatility and
ambiguity on formal and relational contracting. Academy of Management Journal, 49(5).
5. Carter, R., & Hodgson, G. M. (2006). The Impact of Emprical Tests on Transaction Cost Economics on the Debate on
the Nature of the Firm. Strategic Management Journal, 27, 461-476.
6. Choudhury, V. (1997). Strategic Choices in the Development of Interorganizational Information Systems. Information
Systems Research, 8(1).
7. Dyer, J., & Singh, H. (1998). The Relational View: Cooperative Strategy and Sources of Interorganizational Competitive
Advantage. Academy of Management Review, 23(4), 660-679.
8. Enzle, M. E., & Anderson, S. C. (1993). Surveillant Intentions and Intrinsic Motivation. Journal of Personality and
Social Psychology, 64, 257-266.
9. Ghoshal, S., & Moran, P. (1996). Bad for Practice: A critique of the transaction cost theory. Academy of Management
Journal, 21(1), 13-47.
10. Goo, J., Kishore, R., & Roao, H. R. (2009). The Role of Service Level Agreements in Relational Management of
Information Technology Outsourcing: An empirical study. MIS Quarterly, 33(1), 119-145.
11. Hill, C. W. L. (1990). Cooperation, opportunism, and the invisible hand: Implications for transaction cost theory.
Academy of Management Review, 15, 500-513.
12. Ouchi, W. G. (1977). Review of Markets and Hierarchies. Administrative Science Quarterly, 22, 541-544.
13. Poppo, L., & Zenger, T. (2002). Do Formal Contracts and Relational Governance Function as Substitutes or
Compliments? Strategic Management Journal, 23, 707-725.
Proceedings of the Southern Association for Information Systems Conference, Atlanta, GA, USA March 25 th-26th, 2011 77
Gregory TCE and Directions for Relational Governance
14. Robey, D., Im, G., & Wareham, J. D. (2008). Theoretical Foundations of Empirical Research on Interorganizational
Systems: Assessing Past Contributions and Guiding Future Directions. Journal of the Association for Information
Systems, 9(9), 497-518.
15. Song, M., & Montoya-Weiss, M. M. (2001). The Effect of Perceived Technological Uncertainty on Japanese New
Product Development. Academy of Management Journal, 44(1), 61-80.
16. Subramani, M. R., & Venkatraman, N. (2003). Safeguarding Investments in Asymmetrical Interorganizational
Relationships: Theory and evidence. Academy of Management Journal, 46(1), 46-62.
17. Wang, X., Lane, M., Conboy, K., & Pikkarainen, M. (2009). Where agile research goes: starting from a 7-year
retrospective (report on agile research workshop at XP2009). SIGSOFT Softw. Eng. Notes, 34(5), 28–30. doi:
10.1145/1598732.1598755
18. Williamson, O. E. (1981). The Economics of Organization: The transaction cost approach. The American Journal of
Sociology, 87(3), 548-577. doi: 10.1086/227496
19. Williamson, O. E. (1991). Comparative Economic Organization: The analysis of discrete structural alternatives.
Administrative Science Quarterly, 36(2), 269-296.
20. Williamson, O. E. (1996). Economic Organization: The case for candor. Academy of Management Review, 21(1), 48-57.
21. Williamson, O. E. (1999). Strategy Research: Governance and Competence Perspectives. Strategic Management
Journal, 20, 1087-1108.
Proceedings of the Southern Association for Information Systems Conference, Atlanta, GA, USA March 25 th-26th, 2011 78