0% found this document useful (0 votes)
40 views4 pages

Interest Rate Models 19.1 Basic Elements in A Bond Market: T T T U T

The document summarizes key elements of interest rate models, including three classical models - Vasicek, Cox-Ingersoll-Ross (CIR), and Heath-Jarrow-Morton (HJM). [1] The Vasicek and CIR models describe the stochastic process of the short-term interest rate, while HJM models the term structure directly. [2] The CIR model is an improvement over Vasicek since it ensures the short rate never becomes negative. [3] HJM provides greater flexibility than Vasicek and CIR but requires more complex computation.

Uploaded by

owltbig
Copyright
© Attribution Non-Commercial (BY-NC)
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
40 views4 pages

Interest Rate Models 19.1 Basic Elements in A Bond Market: T T T U T

The document summarizes key elements of interest rate models, including three classical models - Vasicek, Cox-Ingersoll-Ross (CIR), and Heath-Jarrow-Morton (HJM). [1] The Vasicek and CIR models describe the stochastic process of the short-term interest rate, while HJM models the term structure directly. [2] The CIR model is an improvement over Vasicek since it ensures the short rate never becomes negative. [3] HJM provides greater flexibility than Vasicek and CIR but requires more complex computation.

Uploaded by

owltbig
Copyright
© Attribution Non-Commercial (BY-NC)
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 4

Lecture 19 Interest Rate Models

19.1 Basic elements in a bond market


R
Consider a market money account B = {Bt } with B0 = 1, Bt = exp( 0t ru du), t ∈ [0, T ], where
the short rate {rt } is assumed to be a stochastic process. The bank account B and related term
structures ({B(t, τ )}, or {Y (t, τ )}, or {f (t, τ )}) in a bond market serve as underlying assets similar
to stocks in a stock market. We will introduce several interest rate models and use them to price
various derivatives defined on the underlying assets. Note that each fixed-income asset or derivative
may have its own maturity time.

Let (Ω, F, P ) be a probability


³R space´equipped with a filtration {Ft }t∈[0,T ] . Assume {rt } is an
T
adapted process with P 0 |rt | dt < ∞ = 1. The filtration {Ft }t∈[0,T ] is usually generated by a
multidimensional Brownian motion (called shocks or factors) as a source of uncertainty. Since our
main purpose is derivative pricing, we assume the existence of a risk neutral measure Q, equivalent
to P following the Girsanov transformation (detail skipped), under which the discounted processes
of all underlying assets are martingales. This will rule out arbitrage opportunities, according to
the (continuous-time) Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing, which we have not presented. For
0 ≤ t < τ ≤ T , three equivalent term structures can be defined as follows:

• Zero-coupon bond: Let B(t, τ ) be the time-t price of a bond with maturity τ (called τ -bond)
and the par value B(τ, τ ) = 1. The risk-neutral valuation principle implies
· µ Z τ ¶¯ ¸
¯
B(t, τ ) = EQ exp − ru du ¯¯ Ft .
t

• Yield Y (t, τ ), defined by

−1
Y (t, τ ) = log B(t, τ ),
τ −t
which follows from

B(t, τ ) exp[Y (t, τ )(τ − t)] = 1,

i.e. Y (t, τ ) is the constant compounding interest rate that brings B(t, τ ) to the par value.

• Forward rate f (t, τ ), defined by


f (t, τ ) = − log B(t, τ ),
∂τ
which follows from
·Z τ ¸
B(t, τ ) exp f (t, u)du = 1,
t

1
i.e. f (t, τ ) is the instantaneous rate locked in at t for risk-free borrowing or lending at τ , with
f (t, t) = rt . Intuitively, f (t, τ ) should be interpreted as the interest rate over the infinitesimal
time interval [τ, τ + ∆τ ] as seen at time t.

To ease the notation, assume 0 ≤ τ ≤ T and consider a European option g(B(τ, T )) with
maturity τ written on a zero-coupon bond with maturity equal to the horizon T . The option g
can be hedged by a dynamic portfolio h = {(h0t , h1t ), t ∈ [0, T ]}, where h0t Bt and h1t B(t, T )
represent the time-t balance of the bank account and the time-t holding value of the zero-coupon
bond respectively. The time-t value of the portfolio is

Vt = h0t Bt + h1t B(t, T ), (19.1)

with the corresponding self-financing condition

dVt = h0t dBt + h1t dB(t, T ). (19.2)

Under certain regularity conditions, the time-t value of the option g is given by
· µ Z τ ¶ ¯ ¸
¯
Vt = EQ exp − ru du g(B(τ, T ))¯¯ Ft , (19.3)
t

which can be calculated in each problem with a specified interest rate model.

19.2 Three classical models

We will present three continuous-time single factor interest rate models in this section, whose
discrete-time versions appeared in Lecture 8. In each model, the SDE represents the risk neutral
dynamics under Q.

19.2.1 Vasicek model

Assume the short rate under Q satisfies the SDE

drt = a(b − rt ) dt + σ dWt (19.4)

with positive constant parameters a, b and σ. Note that X = {Xt } with Xt = rt − b is an Ornstein-
Uhlenbeck (O-U) process satisfying the SDE

dXt = −aXt dt + σ dWt .

Hence X is a Gaussian process, which implies that Q(rt < 0) > 0 for every t ∈ [0, T ] — an
unreasonable behavior in practice. Pricing bond options would be easy due to nice properties of
the O-U process.

2
19.2.2 Cox-Ingersoll-Ross (CIR) model

The short rate process under Q follows


drt = a(b − rt ) dt + σ rt dWt (19.5)

with constant parameters a, b and σ. Suppose r0 = x > 0 and define

Tx,0 = inf{t > 0 : rt = 0}, or Tx,0 = ∞ if rt > 0 ∀ t > 0.

The following proposition shows that the CIR model is an important improvement of the Vasicek
model.

Proposition 19.1 There are three cases based on different ranges of the parameters:

Case 1 If ab ≥ σ 2 /2, then Q(Tx,0 = ∞) = 1 ∀ x > 0.

Case 2 If 0 ≤ ab < σ 2 /2 and a ≥ 0, then Q(Tx,0 < ∞) = 1 ∀ x > 0.

Case 3 If 0 ≤ ab < σ 2 /2 and a < 0, then 0 < Q(Tx,0 < ∞) < 1 ∀ x > 0.

Proposition 19.1 provides us with a guideline for setting the parameters a, b, σ. {rt } in (19.5) is an
example of Feller’s square-root diffusions which enjoy great popularity in financial economics. It is
a Markov process with a closed-form transition density: the conditional density of ru given rt for
t < u is a scaled version of non-central χ2 distribution. Prices of the zero-coupon bond and some
bond options under a CIR model can be obtained with explicit expressions.

19.2.3 Heath-Jarrow-Morton (HJM) model

The Vasicek and CIR models, although very simple, do not model term structures directly.
When market term structure data {B(t, τ ), τ ∈ [t, T ]} are observed at time t, they are inconsistent
with the output generated by these two short rate models. In contrast, HJM proposes a general
mechanism that models term structures directly and takes observed term structures as inputs.

df (t, τ ) = α(t, τ ) dt + σ(t, τ ) dWt (19.6)

given the initial term structure f (0, τ ) = g(τ ), τ ∈ [0, T ], where α(·), σ(·) satisfy the HJM drift
condition
Z τ
α(t, τ ) = σ(t, τ ) σ(t, u) du (19.7)
t

3
to avoid arbitrage.

The integral form of (19.6)


Z t Z t
f (t, τ ) = g(τ ) + α(u, τ ) du + σ(u, τ ) dWu , (19.8)
0 0

along with f (t, t) = rt , will give us


Z t Z t
rt = f (0, t) + α(u, t) du + σ(u, t) dWu . (19.9)
0 0

Note that in a general HJM model, the drift coefficient α(t, τ ) and volatility coefficient σ(t, τ ) are
not just functions of “current state” f (t, τ ), they also involve the history {f (u, τ ), 0 < u < t}. For
fixed τ , the process {f (t, τ ), 0 ≤ t ≤ τ } is non-Markovian. Therefore, the computation required
for the HJM model is extremely complicated, as a price to pay for greater modeling flexibility than
the Vasicek and CIR models.

Multi-factor versions of Vasicek, CIR and HJM are available that further improve the results
in empirical studies.

You might also like