Trusts and The Origins of Antitrust Legislation
Trusts and The Origins of Antitrust Legislation
Trusts and The Origins of Antitrust Legislation
2013
Recommended Citation
Wayne D. Collins, Trusts and the Origins of Antitrust Legislation, 81 Fordham L. Rev. 2279 (2013).
Available at: http://ir.lawnet.fordham.edu/flr/vol81/iss5/7
This Symposium is brought to you for free and open access by FLASH: The Fordham Law Archive of Scholarship and History. It has been accepted for
inclusion in Fordham Law Review by an authorized editor of FLASH: The Fordham Law Archive of Scholarship and History. For more information,
please contact [email protected].
TRUSTS AND THE ORIGINS OF
ANTITRUST LEGISLATION
Wayne D. Collins*
Between 1888 and 1890, thirteen states and the federal government
enacted antitrust legislation criminalizing combinations among competitors
intended to control prices in the marketplace. These laws were a reaction
to the increasing formation of horizontal combinations, large and small,
throughout the economy in the wake of dramatically changing economic
conditions since the Civil War. Through most of this period, combinations
struggled to find structures that would enable them to operate effectively.
Simple combinations of independent firms, although neither criminal nor
tortious, were often undermined because state common law refused to
enforce the contractual arrangements that would prevent members from
deviating from the rules that would give a combination the power to control
price. Nor could early combinations avail themselves of a unitary
ownership structure, since state corporation law restricted the corporate
form in ways that made it largely unworkable as a combination structure.
In the early 1880s, however, some combinations, beginning with
Standard Oil, adopted a new form of organization, the trust proper, which
had the command and control attributes of a corporation without being
subject to the restrictions of state corporation law. Shortly thereafter, some
states, notably New Jersey, liberalized their corporation laws, making
corporations suitable as a vehicle for housing a business combination.
States and the federal government responded with legislation that adopted
the common law prohibitions against combinations in restraint of trade,
extended these prohibitions to combinations organized as trusts proper and
holding companies, and criminalized violations in order to enable
government challenges. Despite these extensions of the law, early
enforcement was virtually nonexistent, even against most combinations that
had achieved widespread public notoriety. After the turn of the last
century, however, the new laws set the stage for an aggressive enforcement
policy following a massive horizontal consolidation movement that began in
1895.
* Partner, Shearman & Sterling LLP; Adjunct Professor of Law, New York University
School of Law. My colleagues Vittorio Cottafavi and John Mellyn, as well as David Merkin
in the Shearman & Sterling LLP law library, have been extraordinarily tenacious and
successful in locating many of the sources and economic data used in this Article. I am in
their debt, although they bear no responsibility for any errors in the final product.
2279
2280 FORDHAM LAW REVIEW [Vol. 81
TABLE OF CONTENTS
INTRODUCTION ........................................................................................ 2280
I. A CHANGING ECONOMY: ECONOMIC CONDITIONS PRIOR TO 1890 ... 2281
II. THE “TRUST” MOVEMENT ................................................................. 2288
III. FORMS OF COMBINATION AND PRE-ANTITRUST REGULATION ........ 2292
Simple Combinations .............................................................. 2293
A.
Pools ....................................................................................... 2307
B.
Corporations........................................................................... 2309
C.
Trusts ...................................................................................... 2315
D.
E.
Holding Corporations and the Liberalization of
Incorporation Laws............................................................... 2329
IV. THE LEGISLATIVE RESPONSE ........................................................... 2334
A. State Antitrust Legislation ...................................................... 2335
B. Federal Antitrust Legislation .................................................. 2339
V. SOME CONCLUDING OBSERVATIONS................................................. 2342
INTRODUCTION
For much of antitrust history, conventional wisdom has held that the
Sherman Act was passed because of overwhelming popular agitation for
federal legislation to restore a balance in the marketplace between “big
business,” on the one hand, and consumers, farmers, and small businesses,
on the other. When we examine the actual conditions of the time, the state
and federal legislative responses to calls for antitrust regulation, and how
these new statutes were enforced immediately after their enactment, it
becomes apparent that large firms as such were not a target. In both the
years preceding the passage of the Sherman Act in 1890, as well as the
immediate years following its enactment, there was not a single identifiable
case brought under the common law or the new state and federal antitrust
laws that challenged an organically grown firm simply because it was big,
even if it displaced—as many large firms did—smaller competitors.
Rather, the focus was on the combinations of competitors, whether large or
small, that were able to raise the prices at which they sold their output (or
lower the prices at which they purchased their inputs) to an extent regarded
as injurious to the public interest. Regardless of their technical legal form,
these combinations came at the time to be called “trusts.” This Article
examines the economic conditions that gave rise to a pervasive number of
these so-called trusts, the various legal structures in which these
combinations were housed, and the laws in effect prior to the enactment of
state and federal antitrust legislation that attempted to regulate them.
Part I surveys the macroeconomic conditions in the United States in the
two decades prior to the passage of the Sherman Act. The years between
1870 and 1890 were a period of enormous economic growth brought about
by fundamental changes in transportation, communications, population
2013] THE ORIGINS OF ANTITRUST LEGISLATION 2281
farmers with food, clothing, and farming inputs. With a few exceptions,
most notably the railroads and some large textile mills, firms were
organized as sole proprietorships or partnerships with a single location
producing a limited line of labor-intensive goods and services.1 For the
most part, the lack of a reliable, inexpensive, high-speed transportation
network confined a firm’s operation to the local area and correspondingly
limited demand for the firm’s product.2 When a business sold in distant
markets, it did so through commissioned merchants or agents that handled
the business of multiple firms.3 No cadre of professional managers existed;
rather, the owners personally managed the business and supervised the
firm’s few employees.4 Nor was there the financial incentive or
wherewithal to create large firms. Production technologies yielding
significant economies of scale either did not exist or were overshadowed by
the high costs of broader geographic distribution.5 Markets for raising
investment capital had yet to emerge, and investment resources were
limited largely to what a family or a small group of partners were willing to
invest.6
Beginning in the 1870s, however, fundamental changes in transportation,
communications, population growth, production technology, business
organization, and finance led to rapid economic growth and a shift from a
predominately agrarian economy to an industrial one. This shift started
before the Civil War, but it was particularly pronounced for several decades
beginning in 1870.
A rapidly expanding transportation network and declining real freight
rates made it increasingly possible and economical to reliably ship products
over long distances for distribution and sale. This, in turn, enlarged the
effective geographic area a single firm could serve from its local vicinity to
regional or even national markets. After connecting the coasts in 1869 by
linking the tracks of the Union Pacific Railroad Company and the Central
Pacific Railroad Company at Promontory Point, Utah, the railroads
increased their track mileage by a factor of three from 52,922 miles in 1870
to 166,703 miles by 1890.7 But this was hardly the whole story. Since
1. See JEREMY ATACK & PETER PASSELL, A NEW ECONOMIC VIEW OF AMERICAN
HISTORY 191–93 (2d ed. 1994); CHRISTOPHER J. SCHMITZ, THE GROWTH OF BIG BUSINESS IN
THE UNITED STATES AND WESTERN EUROPE, 1850–1939, at 31 (1993).
2. See SIDNEY RATNER, JAMES H. SOLTOW & RICHARD SYLLA, THE EVOLUTION OF THE
AMERICAN ECONOMY 183–84 (1979).
3. See GLENN PORTER & HAROLD C. LIVESAY, MERCHANTS AND MANUFACTURERS 15–
17 (1971); Alfred D. Chandler, Jr., The Role of Business in the United States: A Historical
Survey, 98 DÆDALUS, WINTER 1969, at 26.
4. See GLENN PORTER, THE RISE OF BIG BUSINESS, 1860–1910, at 11–12 (1973).
5. See ALFRED D. CHANDLER, JR., THE VISIBLE HAND: THE MANAGERIAL REVOLUTION
IN AMERICAN BUSINESS 49 (1977); SCHMITZ, supra note 1, at 54–55.
6. See PORTER, supra note 4, at 8; SCHMITZ, supra note 1, at 44.
7. U.S. BUREAU OF CENSUS, HISTORICAL STATISTICS OF THE UNITED STATES, EARLIEST
TIMES TO THE PRESENT: MILLENNIAL EDITION 4-916 ser. Df874 (2006) [hereinafter
HISTORICAL STATISTICS]. The underlying data for most of the statistics cited in this Article
come from Historical Statistics, which is widely regarded as collecting the best time series
statistics available. Even so, given the problems of systematic data collection as we go back
2013] THE ORIGINS OF ANTITRUST LEGISLATION 2283
railroads did not have to follow meandering rivers, they could, in many
cases, cut effective travel distances for bulk transportation by large margins.
A trip from New York to Philadelphia could take a week to ten days by
road in 1800, while the same trip took less than a day by rail in the late
1850s.8 Railroads also were not subject to the vicissitudes of rivers
freezing over or roads made impassable by rain or snow and could reliably
deliver passengers and freight in all but the most extreme weather. Freight
rates also dropped precipitously. Nominal freight rates averaged $0.15 per
ton/mile by road in the 1830s, $0.04 per ton/mile by rail in 1850, and
$0.015 per ton/mile by rail by 1880.9
Growing alongside the railroads was an equally expanding
communications network. The broadening communications system not
only permitted the railroads to manage their train traffic but also allowed
suppliers to better understand and respond to current market conditions in
distant markets.10 Samuel F.B. Morse built the first electromagnetic
telegraph demonstration line in 1844, connecting Washington and
Baltimore.11 By the beginning of the Civil War, the telegraph network was
essentially nationwide; by 1870, multiplexing allowed multiple telegraph
messages to be sent simultaneously over the same line.12 For the most part,
telegraph companies built their lines on the railroad rights-of-way, and most
communications occurred between railroad stations.13 The early telegraph
companies, however, were plagued by bankrupting competition between
parallel lines and incompatible technologies and coordination problems
when messages were transmitted over the interconnecting lines of different
operators, so that, by the mid-1850s, they had largely consolidated into six
major companies.14 In 1857, these six companies, in what became known
as the “Treaty of the Six Nations,” divided the eastern half of the United
States among themselves into six disjoint exclusive regions and then
in time, the early statistics in this Article (say, those for years prior to 1900) generally should
only be considered indicative and not exact. The notes in Historical Statistics provide the
underlying source of each data series.
8. SCHMITZ, supra note 1, at 11.
9. HISTORICAL STATISTICS, supra note 7, at 4-781 ser. Df17 & Df21. For more on the
development of railroads during this period, see ATACK & PASSELL, supra note 1, at 427‒56;
ROBERT FOGEL, RAILROADS AND AMERICAN ECONOMIC GROWTH: ESSAYS IN ECONOMETRIC
HISTORY (1964); JOHN F. STOVER, AMERICAN RAILROADS (2d ed. 1997); ALBERT FISHLOW,
AMERICAN RAILROADS AND THE TRANSFORMATION OF THE ANTE-BELLUM ECONOMY (1965);
Albert Fishlow, Productivity and Technological Change in the Railroad Sector, 1840–1910,
in OUTPUT, EMPLOYMENT, AND PRODUCTIVITY IN THE UNITED STATES AFTER 1800 (Dorothy
S. Brady ed., 1966), available at http://www.nber.org/chapters/c1578.pdf.
10. See Alexander James Field, The Magnetic Telegraph, Price and Quantity Data, and
the New Management of Capital, 52 J. ECON. HIST. 401, 411 (1992).
11. DAVID HOCHFELDER, THE TELEGRAPH IN AMERICA, 1832–1920, at 2 (2012).
12. Id. at 2–3, 42–43.
13. See CHRISTOPHER H. STERLING, PHYLLIS W. BERNT & MARTIN B.H. WEISS, SHAPING
AMERICAN TELECOMMUNICATIONS: A HISTORY OF TECHNOLOGY, POLICY, AND ECONOMICS
41–42 (2006); ROBERT LUTHER THOMPSON, WIRING A CONTINENT: THE HISTORY OF THE
TELEGRAPH INDUSTRY IN THE UNITED STATES, 1832–1866, at 203–16 (1947).
14. THOMPSON, supra note 13, at 187–202.
2284 FORDHAM LAW REVIEW [Vol. 81
during this period was from fossil fuels, almost entirely coal.25 The
discovery of abundant new coal sources, new mining methods, the
emergence of railroad networks that could provide cheap and reliable
transportation, and the development of new, more efficient coal energy
technologies both reduced the real cost of energy and freed energy-
consuming businesses to locate away from rivers (which provided
hydropower) and closer to other factors of production (including labor and
transportation). Moreover, since hydropower could be subject to
interruptions caused by limited waterfall, ice, and other weather-related
conditions, firms demanding a steady, reliable source of power often
switched to coal energy technologies even when hydropower was
available.26
New innovations in production technology, such as the Bessemer process
of steelmaking, new distillation methods in petroleum refining, and
Hungarian reduction techniques in flour milling, lowered average
production costs and created substantial economies of scale.27 At the same
time, new economies of integration led to vertical growth within the chain
of manufacturing and distribution, especially in industries where new
product developments found no existing system for their distribution or
after-sales support or where new process developments or economies of
scale overwhelmed the existing distribution system with increased
production rates.28 Some industries also vertically integrated into raw
materials to ensure the inputs necessary for large-scale production.29
Finally, apart from economies from new technologies and vertical
30. See Jeremy Atack, Economies of Scale and Efficiency Gains in the Rise of the
Factory in America, 1820–1900, in QUANTITY & QUIDDITY: ESSAYS IN U.S. ECONOMIC
HISTORY 286 (Peter Kilby ed., 1987); Kenneth L. Sokoloff, Productivity Growth in
Manufacturing During Early Industrialization: Evidence from the American Northeast,
1820–1860, in LONG-TERM FACTORS IN AMERICAN ECONOMIC GROWTH 679 (Stanley L.
Engerman & Robert E. Gallman eds., 1986).
31. See Atack, supra note 30.
32. HISTORICAL STATISTICS, supra note 7, at 3-24 to -25 ser. Ca9 (data originally
reported in 1996 dollars).
33. See id. at 4-680 ser. Dd687 (data originally reported in 1958 constant dollars).
Unfortunately, the data series for this period does not include depreciation or the real net
value of assets. Throughout this Article, real dollars refer to 2005 dollars. When the data
was originally reported in constant dollars other than 2005 dollars, I converted to 2005
dollars by multiplying the reported data by the ratio of the GDP deflator for 2005 to the GDP
deflator for the constant dollar year of the reported data:
2013] THE ORIGINS OF ANTITRUST LEGISLATION 2287
used Frickey index, grew by over 50 percent and had a compound average
growth rate of 4.4 percent.34 By 1885, the United States had replaced Great
Britain as the world’s largest manufacturing nation, accounting for
29 percent of the world’s industrial production.35
Agricultural production also soared, aided by the development of the
western lands and an efficient transportation network, new mechanized
technologies, and driven by a rapidly expanding population.36 With the
increasing cultivation of land in the West, the number of farms increased by
71.6 percent from 2.7 million in 1870 to 4.6 million in 1890,37 while the
amount of land in farms increased by 52.8 percent from 407.7 million acres
to 623.2 million acres.38 During this period, agricultural production
increased 70.8 percent, for a compound average growth rate of
2.9 percent.39 During the same period, the agricultural labor force increased
from 6.8 million to 10 million, for a compound average growth rate of
1.9 percent.40 This suggests that labor productivity grew at about
1.0 percent per year, which was probably due largely to increased
mechanization. The total capital stock used in agriculture increased from
$218 billion to $379 billion, for a compound average growth rate of
2.8 percent.41 Land employed in agriculture increased at about the same
rate, but machinery and equipment grew from $0.6 billion to $1.3 billion,
for a compound average growth rate of 3.9 percent, again consistent with
the idea that increased mechanization significantly increased farm labor
productivity.42
Conversion Ratio
Year GDP Deflator (to 2005 dollars)
1929 10.593 9.4402
1958 18.157 5.5075
1996 83.154 1.2026
2005 100 1
The relevant GDP deflators are reported in U.S. DEPT. OF COMMERCE, BUREAU OF ECONOMIC
ANALYSIS tbl.1.1.4 (Price Indexes for Gross Domestic Product, with 2005=100), available at
www.bea.gov/itable/. For example, to convert $100 in constant 1958 dollars to 2005 dollars,
multiply $100 by the conversion ratio of 5.5075 to yield $550.75.
34. See HISTORICAL STATISTICS, supra note 7, at 4-652 ser. Dd497. Historical Statistics
uses the data series developed in EDWIN FRICKEY, PRODUCTION IN THE UNITED STATES, 1860–
1914, at 54 (1947).
35. W.W. ROSTOW, THE WORLD ECONOMY: HISTORY & PROSPECT 52 (1978).
36. For a review of the post–Civil War agricultural technologies, see RATNER ET AL.,
supra note 2, at 264–65 (1979).
37. HISTORICAL STATISTICS, supra note 7, at 4-43 ser. Da16.
38. Id. ser. Da17.
39. See id. at 4-204 ser. Da1117.
40. See id. at 2-110 ser. Ba817. Historical Statistics uses the data series developed in
Stanley Lebergott, Labor Force and Employment, 1800–1960, in OUTPUT, EMPLOYMENT,
AND PRODUCTIVITY IN THE UNITED STATES AFTER 1800, supra note 9, at 117, available at
http://www.nber.org/chapters/c1567.pdf.
41. See JOHN W. KENDRICK, PRODUCTIVITY TRENDS IN THE UNITED STATES 367 tbl.B-III
(1961), available at http://www.nber.org/books/kend61-1.
42. See id.
2288 FORDHAM LAW REVIEW [Vol. 81
CAGR
Indicator 1870–1890
Real GDP 4.5%
Real GDP per capita 2.2%
Population 2.5%
Manufacturing output 5.2%
Agricultural output 2.9%
Real net capital stock 4.7%
Real net capital stock per laborer 1.8%
Output per unit of labor 1.8%
Output per unit of capital 1.2%
43. See HISTORICAL STATISTICS, supra note 7, at 3-24 to -25 ser. Ca9 (data originally
reported in 1996 dollars).
44. See id. at ser. Ca11 (data originally reported in 1996 dollars).
45. SIMON KUZNETS, CAPITAL IN THE AMERICAN ECONOMY: ITS FORMATION AND
FINANCING 64 tbl.3 (1961) (data originally reported in 1929 constant dollars).
46. Id.
47. KENDRICK, supra note 41, at 332 tbl.A-XXI.
48. HISTORICAL STATISTICS, supra note 7, at 3-182 to -183 ser. Cc113.
2013] THE ORIGINS OF ANTITRUST LEGISLATION 2289
price decline was due to the tight monetary policy that the United States
followed, at least until 1879, as part of the return to the gold standard from
the “greenback” standard after the Civil War.49 In the Long Depression
from 1873 to 1879, this caused an asset price deflation even as unit
production was increasing. Between 1873 and 1878, nominal GDP
declined 2.5 percent while real GDP increased 17.9 percent.50 After 1879,
when specie payments resumed, the price deflator exhibited a much slower,
but still downward, trend until around 1896.
But at least some of the price decline during the period was due to
rapidly expanding aggregate output, which exceeded the rate of population
and export growth, coupled with broadening geographic markets that
brought more firms into competition with one another. David A. Wells, a
prominent popular economist at the time, believed that the primary cause of
declining prices was overproduction and underemployment, both caused by
technological advances.52 Moreover, where an increasingly large
investment was necessary to build minimum efficient scale factories, it was
in the interest of profit-maximizing firms to continue to produce as long as
price exceeded variable costs, even if the firm could not cover its fixed
49. See MILTON FRIEDMAN & ANNA JACOBSON SCHWARTZ, A MONETARY HISTORY OF
THE UNITED STATES, 1867–1960, at 15–88 (1963).
50. See HISTORICAL STATISTICS, supra note 7, at 3-24 ser. Ca13 (price deflator with
1996 =100); id. ser. Ca10 (nominal GDP); id. ser. Ca9 (real GDP).
51. Id. ser. Ca13 (data originally reported with 1996 = 100).
52. See David A. Wells, The Economic Disturbances Since 1873 (pts. 1–5), 31 POPULAR
SCI. MONTHLY 289, 433, 577, 768 (1887), 32 POPULAR SCI. MONTHLY 1 (1887). Other
contemporary analyses, while acknowledging the popular strength of Well’s argument, more
properly identified the problem. See, e.g., MORETON FREWEN, THE ECONOMIC CRISIS 165–94
(1888) (responding to Well’s argument).
2290 FORDHAM LAW REVIEW [Vol. 81
53. See PORTER, supra note 4, at 10–11; see also Chandler, supra note 3, at 28 (noting
the expense of shutting down a factory and observing that from the mid-1870s to the mid-
1890s the supply of goods outstripped the demand and prices fell sharply). This is the well-
known “empty core” problem. See LESTER G. TELSER, ECONOMIC THEORY AND THE CORE
41–87 (1978). See generally Abagail McWilliams & Kristen Keith, The Genesis of the
Trusts: Rationalization in Empty Core Markets, 12 INT’L J. INDUS. ORG. 245 (1994).
54. Later, in some contexts “destructive” competition came to mean primary or
secondary line price discrimination designed to competitively disadvantage rivals if not drive
them out of business. This is the sense in which the Industrial Commission used the term at
the turn of the century. See, e.g., 19 U.S. INDUS. COMM’N, FINAL REPORT OF THE INDUSTRIAL
COMMISSION 660–62 (1902) (supplemental statement of Thomas W. Phillips).
55. PAUL L. VOGT, THE SUGAR REFINING INDUSTRY IN THE UNITED STATES 9–11 (1908)
(number of refineries); see also HISTORICAL STATISTICS, supra note 7, at 4-627 ser. Dd369
(refined sugar production).
56. VOGT, supra note 55, at 17.
57. See HISTORICAL STATISTICS, supra note 7, at 4-627 ser. Dd369.
58. VOGT, supra note 55, at 18.
59. Id.
60. For more on the sugar industry in the late nineteenth century, see generally ALFRED
S. EICHNER, THE EMERGENCE OF OLIGOPOLY: SUGAR REFINING AS A CASE STUDY (1978);
VOGT, supra note 55; David Genesove & Wallace P. Mullin, Testing Static Oligopoly
Models: Conduct and Cost in the Sugar Industry, 1890–1914, 29 RAND J. ECON. 355, 368
(1998); John E. Searles, American Sugar, in ONE HUNDRED YEARS OF AMERICAN COMMERCE
257 (Chauncey M. Depew ed., 1895); Richard Zerbe, The American Sugar Refinery
Company, 1887–1914: The Story of a Monopoly, 12 J.L. & ECON. 339 (1969).
2013] THE ORIGINS OF ANTITRUST LEGISLATION 2291
63. Economies of scale were probably not a reason to combine, at least in “loose”
combinations where member firms remained separate albeit collaborating entities. For the
most part, economies of scale occur at the plant or factory level. SCHMITZ, supra note 1, at
57. Since loose combinations did not integrate the facilities of their members, there probably
were little or no economies of scale to be gained.
64. NEW YORK 1889 REPORT, supra note 61, at 6.
65. See 19 U.S. INDUS. COMM’N, supra note 54, at 604. For a modern analysis drawing
the same conclusion, see LAMOREAUX, supra note 29, at 87.
2013] THE ORIGINS OF ANTITRUST LEGISLATION 2293
A. Simple Combinations
The simplest form of combination is an agreement among firms that
remain otherwise legally independent of one another. These agreements
tend to have simple terms, such as not selling below a certain price,
producing above a certain level, or allocating customers or sales territories
to particular participating firms. To allow the agreement to be more
flexible and enable the participating firms to respond to changing market
conditions, sometimes the contracting members would form an
unincorporated association and use its governance mechanism to centrally
fix prices and perhaps allocate sales quantities or customers among the
members.66 The idea behind these simple combinations is that if the
contracting members adhere to the agreement, they will make more profits
than they would in the absence of the agreement. Each member, however,
remains individually responsible for operating its own business and the
profits it earns are the profits generated by that business (that is, it does not
share in the profits of other combination members). We recognize these
arrangements today as garden-variety horizontal cartels.
A significant problem that contractual combinations face is cheating on
the combination’s rules. Each participating firm has an incentive to breach
its agreement by secretly shaving prices, increasing production above the
agreement’s allocation limits, or making sales to customers that have been
allocated to other members. After all, if everyone else in the combination
follows the rules, a firm that breaches the agreement can undercut its
competitors and sell more output at less than the combination’s price (but
still at higher prices than would exist with unregulated competition) and
make much higher profits than it could if it followed the rules. Since all
participants face similar incentives, this can make the combination very
unstable.67
This incentive incompatibility is the well-known prisoner’s dilemma
problem for cartels.68 The obvious solution to the cheating problem is to
they propose to follow. Even if the rules are followed, since different rules can have
different profit consequences for the members individually, reaching agreement on the rules
can be a major hurdle in cartel formation. For more on problems of cartel formation, see, for
example, MICHAEL D. WHINSTON, LECTURES ON ANTITRUST ECONOMICS 20–26 (2006). See
generally George J. Stigler, A Theory of Oligopoly, 72 J. POL. ECON. 44 (1964).
69. Contracts are not the only cartel enforcement mechanism. Another possibility is
preagreed reaction strategies by the conforming cartel members to punish members that
breach the cartel rules. See, e.g., Robert H. Porter, Optimal Cartel Trigger Price Strategies,
29 J. ECON. THEORY 313 (1983).
70. See, e.g., Palmer v. Stebbins, 20 Mass. (3 Pick.) 188, 188 (1825); Diamond Match
Co. v. Roeber, 13 N.E. 419, 420 (N.Y. 1887); De Witt Wire-Cloth Co. v. N.J. Wire-Cloth
Co., 14 N.Y.S. 277, 278 (C.P. 1891).
71. See, e.g., Cent. Ohio Salt Co. v. Guthrie, 35 Ohio St. 666, 668 (1880).
72. Y.B. 2 Hen. 5, fol. 5, Pasch, pl. 26 (1414) (Eng.).
2013] THE ORIGINS OF ANTITRUST LEGISLATION 2295
the defendant broke his covenant, the plaintiff sued on assumpsit.78 Edward
Coke, then chief justice of the Court of King’s Bench, held that the
restrictive covenant was valid, since the restrictions were reasonable in light
of the circumstances and limited “for a time certain, and in a place
certain.”79
The most detailed and influential analysis of the relaxed rule appeared
almost a century later in the celebrated 1711 case of Mitchel v. Reynolds.80
Mitchel leased a bakehouse from Reynolds in a parish of London for five
years, and Reynolds agreed that if he worked anywhere in that parish as a
baker during that time he would pay the plaintiff £50 and posted a bond to
secure his promise.81 When Mitchel sued Reynolds to collect on the bond
for breach of his covenant, Reynolds, in defense, pleaded that, since he had
served his apprenticeship as a baker and had been admitted to the guild, no
private person could lawfully prevent him from working at that trade and
that he should not be required to pay the £50.82 Chief Justice Parker
disagreed and ordered that the debt on the bond should be paid.83 To
Parker, a covenant not to compete was reasonable and therefore enforceable
as a matter of contract law, since it restricted the business opportunities of
the covenantor no more than necessary to achieve the legitimate business
objective of ensuring that Mitchel obtained the benefit of his bargain.84 On
the other hand, Parker opined, if the restraint prohibited Reynolds from
competing throughout England, the restraint would have been unlawful
since it reached beyond areas in which Mitchel had a legitimate need for
protection.85
Courts quickly construed Mitchell to apply different rules depending on
whether the challenged restraint was general or partial. General restraints
of trade, that is, restraints that prohibited the covenantor from competing
anywhere in the jurisdiction at any time, were always void and
unenforceable since they both deprived the public of the restricted party’s
industry as well as prevented him from pursuing his occupation and
supporting himself and his family.86 Partial restraints of trade, which were
limited in time and place and so provided the covenantor some opportunity
to work, were presumptively illegal, but the presumption could be rebutted
where the party seeking to enforce the restriction (or collect damages for a
78. Id. Assumpsit is a form of action for the recovery of damages for the
nonperformance of a simple contract (that is, a contract not under seal or of record). See
1 JOSEPH CHITTY, A TREATISE ON PLEADING 111 (5th ed. 1831).
79. Id. at 1013.
80. (1711) 24 Eng. Rep. 347 (K.B.).
81. Id. at 347.
82. Id.
83. Id. at 348.
84. Id.
85. Id.
86. See, e.g., Or. Steam. Navigation Co. v. Winsor, 87 U.S. (20 Wall.) 64, 68 (1873);
Alger v. Thacher, 36 Mass. (19 Pick.) 51, 53–54 (1837) (also noting that general restraints
can “prevent competition and enhance prices” and “expose the public to all the evils of
monopoly”); Lange v. Werk, 2 Ohio St. 520, 532 (1853).
2013] THE ORIGINS OF ANTITRUST LEGISLATION 2297
91. See, e.g., Cook v. Johnson, 47 Conn. 175, 178 (1879); Bowser v. Bliss, 7 Blackf.
344, 346 (Ind. 1845); Guerand v. Dandelet, 32 Md. 561, 567 (1870); Webster v. Buss,
61 N.H. 40, 40 (1881); French, 14 A. at 871.
92. See, e.g., Wiley v. Baumgardner, 97 Ind. 66, 68 (1884); Bishop v. Palmer, 16 N.E.
299, 303–04 (Mass. 1888).
93. See, e.g., More v. Bonnet, 40 Cal. 251 (1870); Wright v. Ryder, 36 Cal. 342, 359
(1868); Taylor v. Blanchard, 95 Mass. (13 Allen) 370, 374–75 (1866); State v. Neb.
Distilling Co., 46 N.W. 155, 160 (Neb. 1890); Dunlop v. Gregory, 10 N.Y. 241, 244–45
(1851) (dictum); Lange, 2 Ohio St. at 530. The idea was that a noncompetition covenant
deprived a state’s citizens of the restricted party’s productive endeavors as would a covenant
that covered the entire county which drove the restricted party to another state. Taylor,
95 Mass. at 374–75.
94. See, e.g., Or. Steam Navigation, 87 U.S. at 64 (upholding noncompetition restraint
that covered California and other areas); Morse Twist Drill & Mach. Co. v. Morse, 103
Mass. 73 (1869) (upholding unlimited territorial restriction); Beal v. Chase, 31 Mich. 490
(1875) (upholding a noncompetition covenant in connection with the sale of a printing
business that covered the entire state); Bailey v. Collins, 59 N.H. 459 (1879); Diamond
Match, 13 N.E. at 421–23 (upholding a covenant in connection with the sale of a New York
match factory not to compete in the sale of friction matches anywhere within the United
States except Nevada and Montana); Herreshoff, 19 A. at 713 (holding noncompetition
covenant in connection with employment not void simply because it covered the entire
state). Some courts were also willing to view the territorial restriction as divisible, so if a
contract named a smaller area that was reasonable and a larger area that was overly broad
(e.g., “the City of Jacksonville, or anywhere in the United States”), the court would enforce
the restriction as to the smaller area but not the larger one. See, e.g., Wiley, 97 Ind. at 69
(1884) (noting rule); Peltz v. Eichele, 62 Mo. 171, 173 (1876) (reducing covered territory
from “any other place” to St. Louis); Lange, 2 Ohio St. at 531 (reducing covered territory
from the United States to one county).
95. See, e.g., Gibbs v. Consolidated Gas Co., 130 U.S. 396, 409 (1889) (“The question is
whether, under the particular circumstances of the case and the nature of the particular
contract involved in it, the contract is or is not unreasonable.”); W. Wooden-Ware Ass’n,
47 N.W. at 604; Herreshoff, 19 A. at 713; Leslie, 18 N.E. at 365–66; Diamond Match,
13 N.E. at 421. In England, the House of Lords eliminated the distinction in 1894.
Nordenfelt v. Maxim Nordenfelt Guns & Ammunition Co., [1894] 1 A.C. 535.
96. See, e.g., Beal, 31 Mich. at 523 (Christiancy, J.) (“[W]here such a contract is the
result of fair bargaining, the reasonable presumption is, that each party, in view of all the
circumstances which were within his own intimate knowledge, was able to see how the
bargain was to result to his advantage, and that the party resigning the business did not do so
2013] THE ORIGINS OF ANTITRUST LEGISLATION 2299
The idea was that the beneficiary would have to pay the restricted party
more consideration as the restriction became broader, and that a beneficiary
therefore would not seek a restrictive covenant that was broader than his
legitimate interest.97 So by the 1890s, the case results were heavily
weighted toward enforcing ancillary restraints negotiated by the parties, at
least in the typical situation of the sale of a business.
But it is important to keep in mind that the litigants in these cases were
almost always the contracting parties, not the state or injured third parties.
An action on the condition of a bond, assumpsit, or specific performance
could only be brought by a party with an enforceable contractual right. The
existence of an enforceable obligation necessitated a valid contract, which
in turn required mutuality of consideration. The early courts did not
recognize executory obligations on the part of the covenantee to be legally
sufficient consideration. Consequently, the purchase of a business and the
employment for pay were two of the few types of nonexecutory
consideration that could support the covenantee’s side of the bargain for a
noncompetitive covenant from the other party.98 In these cases, a decision
not to enforce a restrictive covenant would have relieved the restricted party
from an obligation that it had freely accepted at the time the contract was
entered or would otherwise work a significant injustice to an essentially
innocent party.99
Enforcing a noncompetition covenant in connection with the sale of a
business or an employment contract also was unlikely to threaten the public
interest by reducing competition, raising prices, or reducing market output.
The buyer replaced the seller in the operation of the business, and the
employer continued to work in the town training apprentices, with the
graduating apprentices moving elsewhere to work. In these cases, although
the effect on the public interest remained part of the reasonableness test,
there was no reason for courts to take competitive effects (as we understand
them today) into the analysis. There was the rare case where an agreement
could adversely affect competition, but in these cases the courts could rely
on the public interest leg of the test to find the contract unenforceable. For
example, a company could buy up all of its competitors, bind each one of
them to a noncompetition covenant, and (at least temporarily) become the
only seller in the marketplace allowing it to raise prices. This was the
situation in Richardson v. Buhl,100 where the Michigan Supreme Court
refused to enforce a noncompetition covenant in connection with the sale of
a business, since the purchase and the covenant were part of a broader
without being fully satisfied that he was receiving full equivalent, which would be more
advantageous to him than the property and the business sold.”).
97. See id. at 522–23.
98. Occasionally, a case would arise when the covenantee would simply pay the
restricted party not to compete. See, e.g., Leslie, 18 N.E. at 364 (where a new competitor
allegedly engaged in predatory conduct in order to coerce a payment in return for exiting
business from the incumbent steamship company).
99. See, e.g., Manchester & L.R.R. v. Concord R.R., 20 A. 383 (N.H. 1890).
100. 43 N.W. 1102 (Mich. 1889).
2300 FORDHAM LAW REVIEW [Vol. 81
scheme to monopolize the U.S. market for matches by purchasing the assets
of most match manufacturing companies in the country.101 Courts also
opposed ancillary restraints that indirectly imposed restrictions on third
parties.102 As a general rule, courts held that public policy favored
competition because competition tended to provide consumers with the
lowest possible prices, and opposed monopolies, which tended to raise
prices.103
Courts began to see more contracts that could substantially affect
competition once the courts accepted reciprocal executory commitments as
valid consideration for the purposes of mutuality in the eighteenth century.
This created the possibility of contracts consisting of reciprocal
noncompetition covenants: the commitment of A not to compete with B
could be the requisite consideration for B’s commitment not to compete
with A and vice versa. These reciprocal noncompetition commitments,
which did not promote capital mobility or labor training, made the
elimination of competition the primary, if not only, purpose of the contract
between the parties. To distinguish them from restraints ancillary to
business sales or employment relationships, some courts called
arrangements involving these reciprocal, noncompetition covenants
combinations or conspiracies in restraint of trade, although many courts
drew no distinction and continued to call these restraints simply contracts in
restraint of trade. However denominated, the distinguishing factor was that
these restraints were nonancilliary in the sense that they did not promote
the sale of a business, the hiring of employees, or any other primary
business purpose; rather, their primary purpose was to eliminate
competition among the convenantors.
When confronted with nonancilliary reciprocal noncompetition covenants
that threatened to raise prices and reduce output, courts generally refused to
enforce them. By 1890, most courts in the United States agreed that, when
the challenged restraints encompassed all or materially all of the
competitors in a trading area and completely determined the members’
manner of trade, the restraints were void as contrary to public policy and
hence unenforceable. Courts often reached this result after finding that the
purpose of the combination was to artificially enhance prices, often through
limiting supply either by reducing their own production or sales or by
contracting with third parties not to sell into the area.104 Then, as today,
courts were reluctant to engage explicitly in a balancing analysis under the
reasonableness test for a restraint of trade, so they almost always decided
cases at the corners: they found these types of restraints unenforceable
because they were general restraints of trade105 or because the restraint was
not ancillary to any legitimate business purpose and deprived the public of
the benefits of competition.106 On the other hand, courts typically upheld
restraints that were partial, involved less than all of the sellers in the market,
had a legitimate business purpose, and did not restrict third parties from
competing with the contracting parties.107
In addition to analyzing noncompetition agreements among combinations
under a reasonableness test for restraints of trade, many courts also
characterized the ability of a combination to raise prices or restrict market
104. See, e.g., Anderson, 12 S.W. at 670 (finding void a combination to eliminate all
competition and pool profits between two rival steamboat companies on the Kentucky river);
India Bagging Ass’n v. B. Kock & Co., 14 La. Ann. 168 (1859) (summarily finding
unenforceable an agreement whereby eight firms agreed for a period of three months not to
sell their holdings of India bagging without the consent of the majority); Pittsburgh Carbon
Co. v. McMillin, 23 N.E. 530 (N.Y. 1890) (combination of nine carbon companies that
consolidated their management and control of their respective businesses in a trustee); Arnot
v. Pittston & Elmira Coal Co., 68 N.Y. 558 (1876) (holding that a contract providing that
P&E would purchase up to a fixed amount of coal per month from its competitor and that the
competitor would not sell coal into the Elmira market was in furtherance of a corner by P&E
designed to create artificially high prices in the Elmira market and hence illegal); Stanton v.
Allen, 5 Denio 434 (N.Y. Sup. Ct. 1848) (finding void for public policy a pooling agreement
among all transportation lines on the Erie and Oswego canals).
105. See, e.g., W. Union Tel. Co. v. Am. Union Tel. Co., 65 Ga. 161, 163 (1880) (“Such
contracts are not favored by the law; they are against the public policy, because they tend to
create monopolies, and are in general restraint of trade.”); Cent. Ohio Salt, 25 Ohio St. at
672–73 (refusing to enforce a voluntary association agreement among salt manufacturers in a
large trading area where the association could regulate member production, and all produced
salt, when packed in barrels, became the property of the association to be sold only at retail
and at fixed prices); see also Skrainka v. Scharringhausen, 8 Mo. App. 522, 525 (Ct. App.
1880) (characterizing restraints held void and unenforceable in Craft, Morris Coal, Arnot,
and Stanton as “restraints in the general sense”).
106. See, e.g., Craft v. McConoughy, 79 Ill. 346 (1875) (finding illegal an agreement to
form a secret partnership of all grain dealers in the town and surrounding area to pool profits
in the sale of grain in Rochelle, Illinois); Morris Run Coal Co. v. Barclay Coal Co., 68 Pa.
173 (1871) (finding illegal an association agreement among five coal companies to allocate
coal regions that they controlled and to sell coal only in amounts and at prices set by the
association).
107. See, e.g., People’s Gaslight & Coke Co. v. Chi. Gaslight & Coke Co., 20 Ill. App.
473 (1886) (noting actual competition from other sellers and enforcing mutual
noncompetition covenants between two gas companies), rev’d on other grounds, 13 N.E.
169 (1887) (finding restraints, although partial, prejudicial to the public interest and hence
unenforceable given the public nature of the services involved and also finding
noncompetition covenants outside of the authority of the corporate charters of the
contracting parties); Hubbard v. Miller, 27 Mich. 15, 20–21 (1873) (holding that a partial
restraint is “not specially injurious to the public” where “every other person except the
[covenantor] is still at liberty to engage in the same business within the same limits”); see
also Chappel v. Brockway, 21 Wend. 157, 163 (N.Y. Sup. Ct. 1839) (finding no monopoly
where the noncompetition covenant “only secures the plaintiff in the exclusive enjoyment of
his business as against a single individual, while all the world beside are left at full liberty to
enter upon the same enterprise”).
2302 FORDHAM LAW REVIEW [Vol. 81
108. See, e.g., W. Union Tel. Co., 65 Ga. at 162–63 (finding that agreements “entered into
to cripple and prevent competition, and that they thereby enable the plaintiff in error to fix its
tariff of rates at a maximum . . . are not favored by the law; they are against the public
policy, because they tend to create monopolies, and are in general restraint of trade”); Craft,
79 Ill. at 349 (characterizing a combination of all of the grain merchants in a town to fix
prices and pool profits as an illegal attempt “to control and monopolize the entire grain trade
of the town and surrounding country”); Richardson v. Buhl, 43 N.W. 1102 (Mich. 1889)
(finding that the purpose of the Diamond Match Company was to monopolize the
manufacture and sale of friction matches in the United States and holding that contracts in
furtherance of this scheme were void and unenforceable); Arnot, 68 N.Y. at 567–69 (holding
that where a defendant’s purpose was to obtain control over the sale of all anthracite coal in
the Elmira market in order to raise prices, and where the plaintiff had knowledge of this
purpose, a contract between the plaintiff and defendant that prevented the plaintiff from
selling coal in Elmira was void and unenforceable); Cent. Ohio Salt, 35 Ohio St. at 672
(finding that the “clear tendency” of an agreement among essentially all of the territory’s salt
manufacturers to fix prices and control production through an association was “to establish a
monopoly, and to destroy competition in trade, and for that reason, on grounds of public
policy” refusing to enforce the agreement); see also State v. Neb. Distilling Co., 46 N.W.
155, 161 (Neb. 1890) (finding that the purpose of the Whiskey Trust was “to control prices,
prevent production, and create a monopoly of the most offensive character”).
109. See, e.g., W. Union Tel. Co., 65 Ga. at 162–63 (holding void and unenforceable
contracts providing Western Union the exclusive right to erect telegraph lines along the
rights of way of the contracting railroads); FREDERICK H. COOKE, THE LAW OF TRADE AND
LABOR COMBINATIONS 94–95 (1898) (“Within a comparatively recent period, the conception
of a monopoly has been extended from a right created by government to a condition
produced by the acts of mere individuals; thus, where, within a given area, all sales of a
given article are made by a single individual or set of individuals.” (footnote omitted)).
110. See, e.g., Raymond v. Leavitt, 9 N.W. 525, 526 (Mich. 1881). Originally,
forestalling was the buying or selling of foodstuffs and other necessities of life outside of an
officially established fair or other marketplace and then reselling them in the market,
presumably at higher prices; regrating was a form of arbitrage: the buying of necessities in
one fair and reselling them in the same area; engrossing was a form of forward contract: the
buying of crops in the field with the intent to resell them once harvested. See 5 & 6 Edw. 6,
c. 14 (1552) (Eng.), reprinted in 5 Stat. 377 (1763) (Eng.) (defining terms). Higher prices,
while often incidental to these practices, were not the harm the English statutes sought to
prevent. Rather, in the medieval period when these laws emerged, local authorities such as
manors, cities, and guilds had legally enforceable prerogative grants or customary rights to
organize local markets, set conditions of trade, and collect taxes on goods sold. Forestalling,
regrating, and engrossing almost surely were declared crimes more to protect the rights of
market organizers than to protect consumers from monopoly pricing. Later economic and
political changes made these crimes obsolete, and by the early 1700s they had largely fallen
into disuse and many of the statutes were repealed. Even so, some later English courts held
that these practices violated the common law if not statutory law. See R v. Waddington,
(1800) 102 Eng. Rep. 56 (K.B.) 65; Rex v. Rusby, (1799) 170 Eng. Rep. 241.
2013] THE ORIGINS OF ANTITRUST LEGISLATION 2303
indictable common law crimes under state law,111 the idea that cornering
the market to increase prices above reasonable levels was against public
policy and that the implementing restraints should not be enforceable
retained traction.
Overall, by the time of the passage of the Sherman Act in 1890, the
common law governing contracts, combinations, and conspiracies in
restraint of trade in the United States was reasonably uniform in
application, if not in principle.112 Restrictive covenants that were freely
negotiated, ancillary to a legitimate business purpose, and did not threaten
higher prices, reduced output, and other “evils of monopoly”113 were
generally enforced, while those that restricted enough competitors to enable
a contracting party or combination to harm the public interest by raising
prices or reducing output were almost always held to be void as contrary to
public policy. But there are four aspects of the late nineteenth century
common law worthy of note.
First, for ancillary restraints in nonexecutory agreements (such as in the
sale of a business), there was a tendency for courts to view, if not legally
presume, freely negotiated restraints as reasonable and enforceable,
regardless of how they constrained the contracting parties, in the absence of
a showing that the effects of the restraints went beyond the parties and
materially harmed the public interest.114 A reading of the cases at the time
111. In 1844, Parliament passed legislation reaffirming the repeal of all statutes
prohibiting forestalling, regrating, and engrossing and declaring that these activities were not
to be found criminal at common law. 7 & 8 Vict., c. 24 (1844) (U.K.). The old notions of
these crimes did not entirely disappear in the United States. See Taggart v. City of Detroit,
38 N.W. 714, 718 (Mich. 1888) (noting that the charter of the City of Detroit always had the
authority to prevent forestalling and regrating and that the city always had ordinances on
these practices with respect to the city-operated public market to ensure that consumers
could always deal directly with farmers and not through middlemen); NEW YORK 1889
REPORT, supra note 61, at 7 (suggesting that forestalling, regrating, and engrossing were still
indictable as common law misdemeanors in New York State). For more on forestalling,
regrating, and engrossing, especially as it relates to antitrust law, see Edward A. Adler,
Monopolizing at Common Law and Under Section Two of the Sherman Act, 31 HARV. L.
REV. 246, 251–63 (1917); Wendell Herbruck, Forestalling, Regrating and Engrossing,
27 MICH. L. REV. 365 (1929).
112. See Tex. & Pac. Ry. Co. v. S. Pac. Ry. Co., 6 So. 888, 891 (La. 1889) (“We have
been at great pains, and have devoted long and tedious labor, to examine all the authorities,
consisting mainly of decisions rendered on the point by courts of last resort in this country,
which were submitted to us by counsel in the case, and we reach the conclusion that
American jurisprudence has firmly settled the doctrine that all contracts which have a
palpable tendency to stifle competition, either in the market value of commodities or in the
carriage or transportation of such commodities, are contrary to public policy, and are
therefore incapable of conferring upon the parties thereto any rights which a court of justice
can recognize or enforce.”).
113. See, e.g., Alger v. Thacher, 36 Mass. (19 Pick.) 51, 54 (1837); see also Bishop v.
Palmer, 16 N.E. 299, 304 (Mass. 1888) (citing Alger, 36 Mass at 54); Newell v. Meyendorff,
23 P. 333, 334 (Mont. 1890) (quoting Alger, 36 Mass. at 54).
114. See Leslie v. Lorillard. 18 N.E. 363, 366 (N.Y. 1888) (“[C]ourts should refrain from
the exercise of their equitable powers in interfering with and restraining the conduct of the
affairs of individuals or of corporations, unless their conduct, in some tangible form,
threatens the welfare of the public.”).
2304 FORDHAM LAW REVIEW [Vol. 81
indicates that the burden of proving harm to the public interest from an
ancillary restraint was a heavy one. Significantly, however, no such
presumption appears in combination cases for reciprocal, nonancilliary
noncompetition restraints. If anything, just the opposite was true.115
Second, harm to the public interest almost always meant significant harm
to competition reflected through increased prices and reduced output. The
judicial analysis of a restraint’s effect on prices and output, however, was
not particularly sophisticated. Courts depended on rather rudimentary
notions of competitive constraint. If, for example, the court found that there
was sufficient actual rivalry between the combination and independent third
parties to ensure price competition so that the combination could increase
prices, the restraint did not threaten the public interest and hence was
enforceable. Even if actual competition from third parties was not present,
if the court found that barriers to entry were low, and the challenged
restraints did not affect third parties, the court could uphold the
combination on the ground that a new entry would occur to protect the
public if the combination raised prices above reasonably remunerative
levels.116 Conversely, where the combination comprised most, if not all, of
the competitors in the market, barriers to entry were high, and prices were
fixed at levels not reflecting a competitive market, courts tended to find the
restraints contrary to the public interest and unenforceable. 117
Third, and somewhat relatedly, courts did not regard all price increases
and output reductions as necessarily contrary to the public interest. As
discussed in the beginning of this section, there was significant concern in
115. See, e.g., Cleveland, C., C. & I. Ry. Co. v. Closser, 26 N.E. 159, 163 (Ind. 1890)
(observing that the justification for a horizontal price-fixing combination “must be upon an
affirmative showing, and one so full, complete, and clear as to remove the presumption (to
which its existence of itself gives rise) that it was formed to do mischief to the public by
repressing fair competition”). England did adopt the presumption that a freely negotiated
horizontal combination was reasonable. See Mogul Steamship Co. v. McGregor, [1892] 1
A.C. 25.
116. See, e.g., Goodman v. Henderson, 58 Ga. 567, 570 (1877) (“It was argued that it
tended to a monopoly, as the contracting parties were the only active parties engaged in
purchasing such hides; but any others, we suggest, could engage, if they wished, and, if
prices warranted, they certainly would do so.”); Leslie, 18 N.E. at 366 (finding a
noncompetition clause enforceable where it restricted only the covenantee and did not
exclude other competition); Diamond Match Co. v. Roeber, 13 N.E. 419, 422 (N.Y. 1887)
(“To the extent that the contract prevents the vendor from carrying on the particular trade, it
deprives the community of any benefit it might derive from his entering into competition.
But the business is open to all others, and there is little danger that the public will suffer
harm from lack of persons to engage in a profitable industry. Such contracts do not create
monopolies. They confer no special or exclusive privilege.”). The Northern District of Ohio
applied similar reasoning when it rejected an application for removal of the defendant to
stand trial in the District of Massachusetts in a Sherman Act challenge to the Whiskey Trust,
finding that the indictment was insufficient, as it did not allege that the Whiskey Trust
exerted any control over production or prices of the 25 percent of distilleries in the country
that it did not own. In re Corning, 51 F. 205, 210–11 (N.D. Ohio 1892).
117. See, e.g., Anderson v. Jett, 12 S.W. 670 (Ky. 1889); Cent. Ohio Salt Co. v. Guthrie,
35 Ohio St. 666 (1880); Craft v. McConoughy, 79 Ill. 346 (1875); Morris Run Coal Co. v.
Barclay Coal Co., 68 Pa. 173 (1871); India Bagging Ass’n v. B. Kock & Co., 14 La. Ann.
168 (1859); Stanton v. Allen, 5 Denio 434 (N.Y. Sup. Ct. 1848).
2013] THE ORIGINS OF ANTITRUST LEGISLATION 2305
the years prior to the passage of the Sherman Act about “ruinous,”
“destructive,” or “excessive” competition, that is, competition that reduced
prices to a level at which many producers in the market could not cover
their costs or at least could not earn a fair or reasonable profit on their
business. Some courts observed that restraints designed to eliminate
excessive competition and stabilize prices at a “reasonable” level among
competitors served a legitimate public purpose and supported the
reasonableness of a restrictive combination.118 While many of these same
118. See, e.g., Cleveland, 26 N.E. at 163 (assuming without deciding that there is a
defense for a horizontal price-fixing combination, “it can only be so where it is affirmatively
shown that its object was to prevent ruinous competition, and that it does not establish
unreasonable rates, unjust discriminations, or oppressive regulations”); Sayre v. Louisville
Union Benevolent Ass’n, 62 Ky. (1 Duv.) 143, 147 (1863) (“The public interest does not, we
believe, forbid carriers from guarding themselves against undue competition, reducing
freights below the standard of fair compensation; and we should hesitate to condemn an
agreement between carriers not to carry goods for less than a certain, reasonable price.”);
Cent. Shade-Roller Co. v. Cushman, 9 N.E. 629, 631 (Mass. 1887) (overruling a demurrer to
enforce an agreement among three competing patentee-manufacturers to combine their
patents and charge a uniform fixed price where the purpose of the arrangement was allegedly
“to prevent the injurious effects, both to producers and consumers, of fluctuating prices
caused by undue competition”); Skrainka v. Scharringhausen, 8 Mo. App. 522, 523–24, 527
(Ct. App. 1880) (finding an agreement of twenty-three stone quarry operators in a district of
St. Louis that did not embrace all competitors in St. Louis and was limited in time to be a
partial restraint of trade and reasonable, where its purpose was to “secure a fair,
proportionate sale of the produce of all quarries at uniform prices and living rates” and did
not apparently tend “to deprive men of employment, unduly raise prices, cause a monopoly,
or put an end to competition”); Manchester & L.R.R. v. Concord R.R., 20 A. 383, 384 (N.H.
1890) (observing that “the lessons of experience, as well as the deductions of reason, amply
demonstrate that the public interest is not subserved by competition which reduces the rate of
transportation below the standard of fair compensation”); see also Beal v. Chase, 31 Mich.
490, 521 (1875) (Christiancy, J.) (“The public is quite as much interested in the prosperity of
its citizens in their various avocations as it can possibly be in their competition. The latter
may bring low prices to purchasers, but may also bring them so low that capital becomes
unprofitable and business men fail, to the general injury of the community.”); Leslie, 18 N.E.
at 366 (“I do not think that competition is invariably a public benefaction, for it may be
carried on to such a degree as to become a general evil.”); ELISHA GREENHOOD, THE
DOCTRINE OF PUBLIC POLICY IN THE LAW OF CONTRACTS 683 (1886) (stating that the
elimination of ruinous competition is a legitimate purpose of a restraint); 2 VICTOR
MORAWETZ, A TREATISE ON THE LAW OF PRIVATE CORPORATIONS § 1131, at 1096–97 (2d ed.
1886) (same with respect to competing railroads). Interestingly, Chief Judge Parker in
Mitchel v. Reynolds arguably recognized destructive competition as legitimate grounds for a
noncompetition covenant, at least when connected to the sale of a business. Mitchel v.
Reynolds, (1711) 24 Eng. Rep. 347 (K.B.) 350 (finding as the fourth grounds for upholding
the restraint “to prevent a town from being overstocked with any particular trade”); accord
Holmes v. Martin, 10 Ga. 503 (1851). For an early American view, see Palmer v. Stebbins,
20 Mass. (3 Pick.) 188, 192 (1825) (“I am rather inclined to believe, that in this country at
least, more evil than good is to be apprehended from encouraging competition among rival
tradesmen or men engaged in commercial concerns.”). The court qualified its view in
Palmer, which involved a contract providing for the exit of a rival boatman and an exclusive
dealing covenant, by supposing that the beneficiary of the restrictive covenants would not
enter into so many contracts as to obtain a monopoly. Id.; see also NEW YORK 1889 REPORT,
supra note 61, at 5 (“Such contests [from excessive competition] often result in wounds
which it takes long years to heal, and from them the public not only receive no real benefit,
but positive injury rather, for sooner or later the public are expected to make good the losses
which such ruinous policies entail.”).
2306 FORDHAM LAW REVIEW [Vol. 81
119. See, e.g., Cleveland, 26 N.E. at 163; Sayre, 62 Ky. at 146–47; Cent. Shade-Roller
Co., 9 N.E. at 631 (suggesting in dictum that if the purpose of the combination was to
“unduly raise the price” above a fair level to the public detriment the combination would not
be enforceable); see also Skrainka, 8 Mo. App. at 523–24, 527 (noting that restraint did not
“unduly raise prices, cause a monopoly, or put an end to competition”).
120. See United States v. Addyston Pipe & Steel Co., 85 F. 271, 279 (6th Cir. 1898),
aff’d, 175 U.S. 211 (1899); In re Greene, 52 F. 104, 111 (C.C.S.D. Ohio 1892). For a
contemporary review of the case law concluding that unlawful restraints of trade were
generally not indictable at common law, see Arthur M. Allen, Criminal Conspiracies in
Restraint of Trade at Common Law, 23 HARV. L. REV. 531 (1909). But cf. Raymond v.
Leavitt, 9 N.W. 525, 526 (Mich. 1881) (noting that forestalling and engrossing were
indictable misdemeanors under early English common law).
121. See Act of Dec. 10, 1828, § 8(6) (originally codified at 2 N.Y. REV. STAT. 689, 691–
92 (1829)); see also Act of Mar. 9, 1885, ch. 240, § 138 (originally codified at MINN. STAT.
§ 6423(6) (1894)); An Act Concerning Crimes and Punishments, ch. 28, § 110, 1861 Nev.
Stat. 79 (originally codified at NEV. GEN. STAT. § 4660 (1885)); An Act for the Punishment
of Crimes (originally codified at N.J. REV. STAT. 256, 275, § 61 (1847), and recodified at
N.J. REV. STAT. 121, 185, § 191 (1874)); Penal Code § 225(6) (1877) (originally codified at
N.D. REV. CODE § 7037(6) (1895)); OKLA. STAT. ch. 25, § 2071(5) (1890)); Act of Feb. 17,
1877 (originally codified at S.D. COMPILED LAWS § 6425(5) (1887)); Tenn. Code
§§ 4789(7), 4825(6) (1858); Penal Code § 84 (originally codified at UTAH COMPILED LAWS
§ 1914(5) (1876)). Mississippi enacted a similar statute in 1892. See Act of Apr. 2, 1892
(originally codified at MISS. CODE ANN. § 1006 (1892)).
122. For cases brought under the New York statute, see, for example, Leonard v. Poole,
21 N.E. 707 (N.Y. 1889); Stanton v. Allen, 5 Denio 434 (N.Y. Sup. Ct. 1848); Hooker &
2013] THE ORIGINS OF ANTITRUST LEGISLATION 2307
B. Pools
A special type of contractual combination is a pool. In a pool, as in a
simple combination, the contracting parties retain ownership of their
properties and other assets and merely agree to abide by the rules laid down
by the pool contract in conducting their respective business affairs. What
makes pools unique is that they aggregate some common attributes related
to production, typically profits or output, and then reallocate the common
factor to the pool members in agreed proportions, independently of what
any individual firm may have actually contributed. In the late nineteenth
century, pools were used extensively by the railroads and other businesses,
some national and some local, including cordage, anthracite coal,
meatpacking, cast iron pipe, steel rails, whiskey, sandpaper, wallpaper, and
bagging.125
The Michigan Salt Association provides an excellent example of a pool’s
operation.126 In 1860, salt production began in the extensive brine fields
Woodward v. Vandewater, 4 Denio 349 (N.Y. Sup. Ct. 1847); People v. Fisher, 14 Wend. 9
(N.Y. Sup. Ct. 1835); see also Morris Run Coal Co. v. Barclay Coal Co., 68 Pa. 173 (1871)
(holding that a contract entered into in New York, between Pennsylvania coal companies,
that violates the New York statute will not be enforced by Pennsylvania courts). In
interpreting the New York statute, New York courts looked to the common law. See N.Y.
STATE BAR ASS’N, REPORT OF THE SPECIAL COMMITTEE TO STUDY THE NEW YORK ANTITRUST
LAWS 3a (1957).
123. See Cent. Shade-Roller Co. v. Cushman, 9 N.E. 629, 631 (Mass. 1887); see also
Raymond v. Leavitt, 9 N.W. 525, 526 (Mich. 1881) (noting the sensitivity of the common
law to restraints on wheat and other “indispensable” articles).
124. See, e.g., Chi. Gaslight & Coke Co. v. People’s Gaslight & Coke Co., 13 N.E. 169,
175 (Ill. 1887); W. Va. Transp. Co. v. Ohio River Pipe Line Co., 22 W. Va. 600, 620 (1883).
125. A number of early pooling agreements are reprinted in INDUSTRIAL COMBINATIONS
AND TRUSTS, supra note 66, at 4–10 (agreement between distillers); id. at 10–12 (agreement
between envelope manufacturers).
126. A detailed analysis of the operation of the Michigan salt pool is contained in J.W.
Jenks, The Michigan Salt Association, 3 POL. SCI. Q. 78 (1888).
2308 FORDHAM LAW REVIEW [Vol. 81
around Saginaw.127 Salt production involves pumping the brine out of the
ground and refining it into purified product. Capital costs of a production
facility were relatively small, making entry easy. Operating costs were also
small, since the primary variable cost was energy, which most salt-well
operators obtained from burning sawdust and other waste products from the
Michigan sawmills.128 Production was limited only by the capacity to
pump and refine, since the brine was virtually inexhaustible in the
underground brine fields. As a result of these conditions, over time
competition among salt-well operators became intense and prices fell to
levels around marginal costs, making it difficult for producers to make a
meaningful profit or perhaps even cover their fixed costs. To deal with this
situation—a paradigmatic case of what was viewed at the time as excessive
competition—in 1876, the Michigan producers organized the Michigan Salt
Association.129 Under the Association’s bylaws, shares in the association
could be held only by member salt manufacturers, with one share issued for
each barrel of the member’s average daily production.130 Upon becoming a
member, each manufacturer was required to contract to sell its entire
production to the Association, which would then be responsible for selling
it.131 Members received profits from the Association’s sales as dividends
on their shares. This pooling of sales mitigated each member’s incentive to
increase production and increased the incentive to cooperate with other
members to reduce production in order to increase the market price.
Pools suffer from the same incentive compatibility problems as simple
agreements: each individual member has an incentive to cheat on the pool’s
rules by producing extra product and selling outside of the pool while
taking advantage of the higher prices that the pool created. The apparent
advantage of a pool is that cheating is easier to detect, since individual
members have ostensibly less independence. Even so, the collective effect
of several cheaters caused many pools to disintegrate.132 But, as in the case
of simple combinations designed to restrict output and raise prices, courts
were hostile and almost always found pooling agreements void and
unenforceable as contracts or combinations restraining trade under the
common law.133 Indeed, pools were found by some courts to be even more
C. Corporations
Nor was the corporation generally available as a vehicle in which to
organize combinations. A corporation is an artificial legal person created
by the state distinct from the persons who own or operate it. As an artificial
person, a corporation has only the powers and attributes that the state
confers on it, either expressly in the corporation’s charter or incidental to
the corporation’s express powers.135 In creating corporations, states
typically permitted them to hold property, sue and be sued, adopt rules for
their internal governance, exist independently of the persons that created it,
and, in many states by the mid-nineteenth century, limited the liability of
shareholders to the corporation’s creditors.136 Corporations, with
ownership interests that are readily divisible, transferable, and expandable
and an existence that is defined by a charter without regard to the lives of
the shareholders, are especially attractive vehicles for businesses that
require large amounts of investment capital and pay returns over long
periods of time. Individuals and even partnerships typically could not
muster the resources to engage in many capital intensive enterprises,
particularly in transportation and finance. Unless the state found some
other private vehicle to undertake the activity, it would be forced into
providing the service itself. Private corporations provided the vehicle.
Private corporations could raise the required capital in private markets,
assume the business risks of the endeavor, and relieve state and local
governments from the need for providing financing and operating the
enterprise. To aid private corporations in their public endeavors, states
often included in the early corporation charters such benefits as a favorable
tax status or exemption from taxation altogether, exclusivity rights to shield
the corporation from competition, and particularly in the case of public
Dec. Reprint 517 (Super. Ct. 1884) (pooling agreement among Cincinnati tobacco
warehousemen) (full report in 23 Am. L. Reg. (N.S.) 648 (1884)); McBirney & Johnston
White Lead Co. v. Consol. Lead Co., 9 WKLY. CINCINNATI L. BULL. 258 (Super. Ct. 1883);
Morris Run Coal Co. v. Barclay Coal Co., 68 Pa. 173, 175–78 (1871) (pooling agreement
among five coal companies).
134. See, e.g., Anderson, 12 S.W. at 671.
135. The seminal expression is in Trustees of Dartmouth College v. Woodward, 17 U.S.
(4 Wheat.) 518, 636 (1819) (“A corporation is an artificial being, invisible, intangible, and
existing only in contemplation of law. Being the mere creature of law, it possesses only
those properties which the charter of its creation confers upon it, either expressly, or as
incidental to its very existence.”); accord Horn Silver Mining Co. v. New York, 43 U.S. 305,
312 (1892) (“A corporation being the mere creature of the legislature, its rights, privileges,
and powers are dependent solely upon the terms of its charter.”).
136. See Phillip I. Blumberg, Limited Liability and Corporate Groups, 11 J. CORP. L. 573,
592–94 (1986).
2310 FORDHAM LAW REVIEW [Vol. 81
137. See, e.g., Hugh L. Sowards & James S. Mofsky, Factors Affecting the Development
of Corporation Law, 23 U. MIAMI L. REV. 476, 480–81 (1969); see also EDWIN MERRICK
DODD, AMERICAN BUSINESS CORPORATIONS UNTIL 1860, at 44 (1954).
138. See, e.g., Sowards & Mofsky, supra note 137, at 480–81; see also DODD, supra note
137, at 202–41 (1954).
139. See J. WILLARD HURST, THE LEGITIMACY OF THE BUSINESS CORPORATION IN THE LAW
OF THE UNITED STATES, 1780–1970, at 30–47 (1970).
140. See JOHN W. CADMAN, JR., THE CORPORATION IN NEW JERSEY: BUSINESS AND
POLITICS, 1791–1875, at 6–7 (1949) (recounting the New Jersey experience); DODD, supra
note 137, at 196.
141. See HURST, supra note 139, at 15, 17–18; SEAVOY, THE ORIGINS OF THE AMERICAN
BUSINESS CORPORATION, 1784–1855, at 47–48, 73–74 (1982).
142. See Leslie v. Lorillard, 18 N.E. 363, 365 (N.Y. 1888) (“In the granting of charters
the legislature is presumed to have had in view the public interest, and public policy is (as
the interest of stockholders ought to be) concerned in the restriction of corporations within
chartered limits, and a departure therefrom is only deemed excusable when it cannot result in
prejudice to the public or to the stockholders.”).
2013] THE ORIGINS OF ANTITRUST LEGISLATION 2311
eminent domain and the authority to set toll rates.143 With the increasing
use of the power loom in the early nineteenth century, some states, notably
Massachusetts, began granting charters to manufacturing corporations to
enable the creation of capital-intensive factories, presumably to increase the
wealth and employment in local economies.144
Gradually, states began to recognize that, by making corporate vehicles
more freely available and eliminating any special powers, corporations
would lose any advantages associated with their scarcity and positions of
privilege. States first began granting increasing numbers of special
corporation charters, taking care not to include in these charters provisions
that would confer monopoly privileges. To this end, states often chartered
multiple corporations to build competing gas lines or other public works in
a given city or chartered multiple railroads to build competing lines.145
Courts also construed these charters narrowly and refused to find monopoly
rights by implication.146
Once the demand for special charters began to overwhelm state
legislatures, some states started to dispense with the need for individually
enacted charters and instead made corporate charters with standardized
powers and limitations automatically available upon request.147
Corporations created in this manner are known as “general corporations”
and are created pursuant to a general corporation law. In 1811, New York
143. See, e.g., Bonaparte v. Camden & A. R. Co., 3 F. Cas. 821 (C.C.D.N.J. 1830)
(No. 1617) (upholding eminent domain powers of railroad corporation); Chesapeake & O.
Canal Co. v. Key, 5 F. Cas. 563 (C.C.D.D.C. 1829) (No. 2649) (upholding eminent domain
power granted to canal corporation); State v. Town of Hampton, 2 N.H. 22 (1819)
(upholding eminent domain powers granted to a turnpike corporation).
144. For more on the power loom, see 1 VICTOR S. CLARK, HISTORY OF MANUFACTURES
IN THE UNITED STATES 428–30 (1916); CAROLINE F. WARE, THE EARLY NEW ENGLAND
COTTON MANUFACTURE: A STUDY IN INDUSTRIAL BEGINNINGS 63–64 (1931). For more on
the history of Massachusetts manufacturing in the wake of the mechanization of the textile
industry, see E. Merrick Dodd, The Evolution of Limited Liability in American Industry:
Massachusetts, 61 HARV. L. REV. 1351, 1355‒56 (1948).
145. See, e.g., Chic. Gaslight & Coke Co. v. People’s Gaslight & Coke Co., 13 N.E. 169,
174 (Ill. 1887) (noting that the Illinois state legislature specially chartered two gas
companies to supply gas to Chicago in order to end a monopoly). But cf. The Slaughter-
House Cases, 83 U.S. (16 Wall.) 36 (1872) (upholding a twenty-five-year monopoly grant by
the Louisiana legislature for slaughter-houses as a valid exercise of the state’s police power).
146. See, e.g., Proprietors of Charles River Bridge v. Proprietors of Warren Bridge,
36 U.S. (11 Pet.) 420, 548–49 (1837) (construing the corporate charter for Charles River
Bridge to not preclude construction of Warren Bridge over the Charles River); see also
People ex rel. Peabody v. Chi. Gas Trust Co., 22 N.E. 798, 804 (Ill. 1889) (noting the Illinois
policy after 1870 of not granting exclusive privileges to corporations of any kind).
147. The burden on the legislature could be substantial. Larcom reports that between
1885 and 1897, when Delaware adopted a constitutional provision prohibiting special
incorporation, acts authorizing special incorporations and those granting divorces accounted
for roughly half of the laws passed by the Delaware legislature. RUSSELL CARPENTER
LARCOM, THE DELAWARE CORPORATION 7 (1937). Political influence in obtaining special
incorporation and the powers and privileges granted also appeared to be a problem. See
CADMAN, supra note 140, at 10–11; LARCOM, supra, at 5–7 (1937); Henry N. Butler,
Nineteenth-Century Jurisdictional Competition in the Granting of Corporate Privileges,
14 J. LEGAL STUD. 129, 141 (1985).
2312 FORDHAM LAW REVIEW [Vol. 81
passed the first general corporation law, although it was limited to certain
types of manufacturing (principally in textile, glass, metal, and paint
industries) and imposed a maximum capitalization of $100,000.148 In 1837,
Connecticut dispensed with the purpose limitations when it passed a general
incorporation statute enabling anyone to form a corporation for any “lawful
business.”149 By 1875, twenty-five of the then thirty-seven states had
adopted constitutional provisions either prohibiting special charters
altogether or granting them with only rare exceptions.150 By the end of
1890, thirty-four of the then forty-four states had adopted similar
constitutional provisions.151
The emerging general corporation laws, however, did not satisfy the
needs of most large multistate business combinations. The original idea of
a general corporation was limited: general corporations were conceived not
as massive business enterprises but rather as local “incorporated
partnerships.”152 Corporations formed under these laws were typically
subject to low capitalization limitations. New York had one of the highest
maximum capitalization limits, but it was only $2 million in 1875 and
$5 million in 1881.153 Many states limited the duration of corporate
148. Act of Mar. 22, 1811, ch. 67, 1811 N.Y. Laws 151; see Slee v. Bloom, 19 Johns.
456, 457 (N.Y. 1822). See generally W.C. Kessler, A Statistical Study of the New York
General Incorporation Act of 1811, 48 J. POL. ECON. 877 (1940); Ronald E. Seavoy, Laws
To Encourage Manufacturing: New York Policy and the 1811 General Incorporation
Statute, 46 BUS. HIST. REV. 85 (1972).
149. Act of June 10, 1837, ch. 63, 1837 Conn. Pub. Acts 49, § 2.
150. See Liggett Co. v. Lee, 288 U.S. 517, 550 n.5 (1932) (Brandeis, J., dissenting)
(collecting provisions); LARCOM, supra note 147, at 3 n.7 (listing adoptions of state
constitutional provision by year). New York, in its Constitution of 1846, appears to be the
first state to adopt a constitutional provision requiring incorporation under the general laws
and prohibiting special incorporation except under limited circumstances. See N.Y. CONST.
of 1846, art. VIII, § 1. The constitutions of Maine and Maryland also permitted special
incorporation when the objects of incorporation could not be obtained through general
incorporation. See LARCOM, supra note 147, at 3 n.7.
151. Liggett, 288 U.S. at 550 n.5; LARCOM, supra note 147, at 3 n.7. For more on the
development of general incorporation laws, see, for example, JOSEPH STANCLIFFE DAVIS,
ESSAYS IN THE EARLIER HISTORY OF AMERICAN CORPORATIONS (1917); HURST, supra note
139; SEAVOY, supra note 141; Butler, supra note 147, at 154–56; E. Merrick Dodd, Jr.,
Statutory Developments in Business Corporation Law, 1886–1936, 50 HARV. L. REV. 27, 28
(1936); Oscar Handlin & Mary F. Handlin, Origins of the American Business Corporation,
5 J. ECON. HIST. 1 (1945); Charles M. Yablon, The Historical Race Competition for
Corporate Charters and the Rise and Decline of New Jersey: 1880–1910, 32 J. CORP. L. 323
(2007).
152. See Slee, 19 Johns. at 473 (“The object and intention of the legislature in authorizing
the association of individuals for manufacturing purposes, was, in effect, to facilitate the
formation of partnerships, without the risks ordinarily attending them, and to encourage
internal manufactures.”).
153. Act of May 18, 1881, ch. 295, § 11, 1881 N.Y. Laws 400, 400 (increasing maximum
to $5 million); General Business Corporation Act of June 21, 1875, ch. 611, § 11, 1875 N.Y.
Laws 755, 758 (increasing maximum to $2 million); Liggett, 288 U.S. at 550–54 & nn.5–26
(reviewing state capitalization limitations).
2013] THE ORIGINS OF ANTITRUST LEGISLATION 2313
existence to periods of twenty to fifty years.154 Many states also limited the
indebtedness of a corporation to an amount not to exceed the corporation’s
capital stock or, in some states, even a lower amount.155 To ensure that
corporations were not undercapitalized, the “trust fund” doctrine denied
shareholders limited liability by making them personally responsible for the
acts of the corporation in cases of insolvency to the extent that they had
failed to pay the full value for their shares, and some states imposed double
liability on shareholders until the corporation was fully capitalized.156
States retained the power to revoke the charter of a corporation that the state
created if the corporation operated in violation of state law or beyond the
scope of its charter.
Moreover, until the late nineteenth century, corporations were effectively
unable to conduct any substantial operations outside of their state of
incorporation.157 Businesses for the most part were local and, when
incorporated, states expected their corporations to operate within their
jurisdictions. Some states simply did not permit their corporations to
conduct out-of-state operations, and those that did often imposed
restrictions on how much business could be conducted in a foreign state.158
The Supreme Court spoke to the ability of states to regulate corporations
operating within their jurisdiction in 1839 in the landmark case of Bank of
Augusta v. Earle.159 Chief Justice Roger Taney observed that a corporation
“can have no legal existence out of the boundaries of the sovereignty by
which it is created,”160 and, assuming that its charter permits so, it may
operate in another state but only with the authorization of the host state.161
The Court also rejected the argument that a corporation was entitled to the
protections of the Privileges and Immunities Clause of Article IV of the
Constitution162 as the corporation’s incorporators would themselves be.163
In 1851, in the equally significant case of Cooley v. Board of Wardens,164
the Supreme Court reaffirmed that states had broad discretion in regulating
businesses within their jurisdiction, so long as the regulated conduct was so
local in nature as to admit diverse treatment and not impinge on interstate
154. In 1903, twenty-two of the then forty-five states limited corporate existence to
periods of twenty to fifty years, although some states permitted renewals. See REPORT OF THE
COMM. ON CORP. LAWS OF MASS. 162–64 (1903) [hereinafter MASS. CORP. REPORT].
155. See id. at 165–67.
156. 1 CHARLES FISK BEACH, JR., COMMENTARIES ON THE LAW OF PRIVATE CORPORATIONS
§ 116 (1891).
157. See, e.g., MASS. CORP. REPORT, supra note 154, at 18 (noting that the operation of
foreign corporations in Massachusetts was “not general” until after 1893 or so).
158. In 1865, for example, New Jersey amended its general incorporation law to permit
its corporations to operate in part out of the state, but required that “a majority of the persons
associated in the organization of such company shall be citizens and residents of this state.”
Act of Mar. 16, 1865, 1865 N.J. Laws 354, ch. 201, § 1.
159. 38 U.S. (13 Pet.) 519 (1839).
160. Id. at 588.
161. Id. at 588–89.
162. U.S. CONST. art. IV, § 2, cl. 1.
163. Bank of Augusta, 38 U.S. at 586–87.
164. 53 U.S. (12 How.) 299 (1851).
2314 FORDHAM LAW REVIEW [Vol. 81
rather than voting securities, states could hold the acquisition contract void
and unenforceable if the state determined that the acquisition was made in
furtherance of a scheme of monopolization.172 While a corporation might
be useful as a vehicle for a local combination, all state general corporation
laws restricted the operation of a corporation to “lawful purposes” and a
corporation used to coordinate a combination was subject to attack as
operating ultra vires.173 The general rule was that a corporate purpose that
had the effect of creating a monopoly of the type void under common law
was equally void under state corporation law.174 Moreover, another form
was required to accommodate the demands for a business vehicle capable of
combining and managing large multistate business operations.
D. Trusts
The necessary legal innovation for large multistate combinations came in
1879 with the creation of the original Standard Oil Trust, which was
rewritten in 1882.175 The creation of the Standard Oil Trust is usually
regarded as the beginning of the trust movement.
Trusts are creations of the law of equity that separate the legal and
beneficial interests in a group of assets. The basic notion is that one or
more trustees hold the legal title to the trust property (the trust “res”) for the
benefit of one or more beneficiaries. As a matter of property law, the
trustees have the full legal authority to deal with third parties with respect to
the trust res, but at the same time have a fiduciary obligation to exercise a
high standard of care and selflessness in managing the res for the benefit of
the beneficiaries. The interests of the beneficiaries can be defined at the
trust’s creation, and the trustees’ duty to act as directed in the trust
instrument—or, in the absence of explicit direction, in the best interests of
the beneficiaries—are enforceable in courts of equity. Applied to the world
of business, the trust, like a corporation, is a vehicle in which a large
number of individuals can aggregate their resources in order to create and
manage a large enterprise, with the trustees acting much like the directors of
172. See, e.g., W. Wooden-Ware Ass’n v. Starkey, 47 N.W. 604 (Mich. 1890) (voiding an
asset purchase contract, where the contract contained a covenant restricting seller from
reentering wooden-ware business for five years in any one of seven states); Richardson v.
Buhl, 43 N.W. 1102 (Mich. 1889) (voiding a contract to acquire a friction match plant where
the defendant’s Diamond Match Company had been organized for the purpose of acquiring
all such plants in the United States).
173. See, e.g., Peabody, 22 N.E. at 798, 802–03 (describing a general corporation
organized to hold and sell the capital stock of gas or electric companies operating in Chicago
or elsewhere in Illinois and in fact holding a majority of the stock of all four Chicago
operating gas companies).
174. Id. at 803 (“If contracts and grants, whose tendency is to create monopolies are void
at common law, then where a corporation is organized under a general statute, a provision in
the declaration of its corporate purposes, the necessary effect of which is the creation of a
monopoly, will also be void.”).
175. The 1879 and 1882 trust agreements are reprinted in INDUSTRIAL COMBINATIONS
AND TRUSTS, supra note 66, at 14–27. The 1882 trust agreement is also reprinted in State ex
rel. Att’y Gen. v. Standard Oil Co., 30 N.E. 279, 281–84 (Ohio 1892).
2316 FORDHAM LAW REVIEW [Vol. 81
a corporation. But since a trust was not technically a corporation, it did not
require a state grant to exist, was not subject to the state regulation of
corporations, and was not prohibited from holding stock in multiple
corporations in multiple states.
The 1882 Standard Oil Trust, which became the model for other trusts,
illustrates the formation and operation of a trust.176 The 1882 agreement
was joined by all of the stockholders and members of fourteen corporations
and limited partnerships, the controlling stockholders and members of an
additional twenty-six corporations and limited partnerships, and forty-six
individuals, all of whom would be the beneficiaries of the trust. The trust
agreement contemplated that separate corporations would be organized
initially in Ohio, New York, Pennsylvania, and New Jersey. Each trust
beneficiary would transfer its assets to the Standard Oil Company in the
state in which the assets were located, and in return the beneficiary received
stock of the recipient Standard Oil Company equal at par to the appraised
value of the transferred assets. The beneficiaries would then deliver the
stock they received in the constituent corporations to a board of trustees to
be held in trust, and in turn the beneficiary would receive one “Standard Oil
Trust” certificate for every $100 of stock it contributed. Dividends paid on
the constituent Standard Oil Company stock would be received by the
trustees—the legal owners of the stock—who in turn would pay dividends
on the trust certificates. The nine-member board of trustees (each member
to be elected for a staggered three-year term by a majority of votes
representing the outstanding trust certificates) was given full power to vote
the stock of the various Standard Oil Companies in its discretion and
thereby control the operations of these companies. The trust was to
terminate twenty-one years after the death of the last survivor of the original
nine trustees, unless dissolved beforehand by a specified supermajority vote
of the outstanding trust certificates.177 When the Standard Oil Trust was
formally dissolved in 1892, there were some 972,500 trust certificates
176. The details of the 1882 Standard Oil Trust first became public as the result of a New
York State Senate investigation. See REPORT OF THE COMMITTEE ON GENERAL LAWS ON THE
INVESTIGATION RELATIVE TO TRUSTS, S. 111-50, at 8–10 (N.Y. 1888) [hereinafter NEW YORK
1888 REPORT]. As a result, it is common to see 1882 as the year in which the trust
movement started even though there was an earlier trust agreement in 1879. The history of
the Standard Oil Trust is examined in detail in IDA M. TARBELL, THE HISTORY OF THE
STANDARD OIL COMPANY (1904). For other treatments of the Standard Oil Trust, see, for
example, Standard Oil Co. of N.J. v. United States, 221 U.S. 1 (1911); State ex rel. Att’y
Gen., 30 N.E. at 279; INVESTIGATION OF CERTAIN TRUSTS: REPORT IN RELATION TO THE
SUGAR TRUST AND STANDARD OIL TRUST, H.R. REP. NO. 50-3112 (1888); GILBERT HOLLAND
MONTAGUE, THE RISE AND PROGRESS OF THE STANDARD OIL COMPANY (1903); Elizabeth
Granitz & Benjamin Klein, Monopolization by “Raising Rivals’ Costs”: The Standard Oil
Case, 39 J.L. & ECON. 1 (1996); John S. McGee, Predatory Price Cutting: The Standard Oil
(N.J.) Case, 1 J.L. & ECON. 137 (1958).
177. The drafters clearly had the rule against perpetuities in mind when drafting the trust
agreement.
2013] THE ORIGINS OF ANTITRUST LEGISLATION 2317
178. For the number of outstanding certificates upon dissolution, see U.S. Trust Co. v.
Heye, 181 A.D. 544, 583 (N.Y. App. Div. 1918) (Dowling, J., dissenting), aff’d as modified,
120 N.E. 645 (N.Y. 1918).
179. See Norbert Heinsheimer, The Legal Status of Trusts, 2 COLUM. L. TIMES 51, 53–54
(1888) (describing the typical legal structure of trusts proper).
180. The amount of authorized capital is reported in Luther Conant, Jr., Industrial
Consolidations in the United States, 53 PUBLICATIONS AM. STAT. ASS’N 1, 2–3 (1901).
Seager and Gulick provide a description of the operations of the major trusts organized in the
1880s. See HENRY R. SEAGER & CHARLES A. GULICK, JR., TRUST AND CORPORATION
PROBLEMS (1929).
181. See NEW YORK 1888 REPORT, supra note 176, at 6–7.
182. For a description, see JOHN MOODY, THE TRUTH ABOUT THE TRUSTS 54–55 (1904).
183. For a description of the formation and operation of the National Lead Trust, see
Nat’l Lead Co. v. S.E. Grote Paint Store Co., 80 Mo. App. 247, 250–51 (Ct. App. 1899);
Unckles v. Colgate, 72 Hun 119, 119–23 (N.Y. Sup. Ct. 1893) (reprinting National Lead
Trust agreement).
184. A description of the formation and operation of the Whiskey Trust is found in State
v. Neb. Distilling Co., 46 N.W. 155, 156–59 (Neb. 1890). The trust deed is reprinted in
INDUSTRIAL COMBINATIONS AND TRUSTS, supra note 66, at 36–42. For contemporary
accounts of the Whiskey Trust, see 1 U.S. INDUS. COMM’N, PRELIMINARY REPORT ON TRUSTS
AND INDUSTRIAL COMBINATIONS 74–93, 813–48 (1900); Jeremiah W. Jenks, The
Development of the Whiskey Trust, 4 POL. SCI. Q. 296 (1889). For a modern economic
analysis, see Karen Clay & Werner Troesken, Further Tests of Static Oligopoly Models:
Whiskey, 1882–1898, 51 J. INDUS. ECON. 151 (2003); Karen Clay & Werner Troesken,
Strategic Behavior in Whiskey Distilling, 1887–1895, 62 J. ECON. HIST. 999 (2002); Werner
Troesken, Exclusive Dealing and the Whiskey Trust, 1890–1895, 58 J. ECON. HIST. 755
(1998).
185. The trust deed of The Sugar Refineries Company, dated as of August 16, 1887, is set
forth in People v. N. River Sugar Refining Co., 24 N.E. 834 (N.Y. 1890). For a description
of the trust, see NEW YORK 1888 REPORT, supra note 176, at 5–6; U.S. INDUS. COMM’N,
supra note 184, at 59–74.
2318 FORDHAM LAW REVIEW [Vol. 81
The deed of the Sugar Trust set forth its five purposes, which were not
atypical of the public positioning of the major trusts:
(1) To promote economy of administration and to reduce the cost of
refining, thus enabling the price of sugar to be kept as low as is consistent
with reasonable profit. (2) To give each refinery the benefit of all
appliances and processes known or used by others, and useful to improve
the quality and diminish the cost of refined sugar. (3) To furnish
protection against unlawful combinations of labor. (4) To protect against
inducements to lower the standard of refined sugars. (5) Generally to
promote the interests of the parties hereto in all lawful and suitable
ways.186
A variety of more minor consolidations were also created in the late 1880s,
including the Southern Cotton Oil Company, the National Cordage
Company, the American Biscuit and Manufacturing Company, and the
American Tobacco Company.187
The trust proper solved one of the most serious problems undermining
consolidations in the form of simple agreements or pools: enforceability.
As discussed, combinations designed to raise prices and reduce output face
an incentive compatibility problem. The members of the combination each
have a profit-maximizing incentive to cheat on the combination by shaving
prices or increasing output, even though they will all make more profits if
they abide by the combination’s pricing and output rules. Since the
common law did not enforce contracts to implement these simple
combinations and pools, they were often plagued by cheating problems.
Trusts proper did not have this problem, since they did not rely on the
restrictive contracts with legally independent firms as the means of
controlling price and output. Rather, trusts proper relied on control through
ownership. Although their constituent corporations may have been legally
separate corporations or other entities, the trusts proper controlled the
voting rights that elected the governing bodies of these entities. While
technically, as a shareholder, a trust could not command its constituent
corporations to raise their prices, reduce their production, or cease
operation, the trust could ensure that each constituent corporation’s
directors—which the trust elected and which often were the trustees of the
186. People v. N. River Sugar Refining Co., 121 N.Y. 582, 586 (N.Y. 1890).
187. See Conant, supra note 180, at 2–3. While each of these “trusts” was a consolidation
of some form since they issued certificates at the holding company level, I have not
confirmed that they were all organized as trusts proper. Some of them were organized as
corporations, such as the American Tobacco Company, while others may have been
unincorporated associations. There are also common references at the time to a variety of
other trusts, such as the Preservers Trust, the Envelope Trust, the Salt Trust, the Oil-Cloth
Trust, the Paving-Pitch Trust, the School-Slate Trust, the Chicago Gas Trust, the St. Louis
Gas Trust, the New York Meat Trust, and the Paper-Bag Trust. While some of these,
including the Preserver’s Trust, were in fact trusts proper, most of them were likely to have
been simple combinations. The Preservers’ Trust agreement is reprinted in Bishop v. Am.
Preservers Co., 41 N.E. 765, 768–71 (Ill. 1895).
2013] THE ORIGINS OF ANTITRUST LEGISLATION 2319
188. When the Whiskey Trust acquired control of the Nebraska Distilling Co, for
example, the trust replaced the Nebraska company’s board with three Whiskey Trust trustees
and two former shareholders. See, e.g., Neb. Distilling Co., 46 N.W. at 157.
189. ATACK & PASSELL, supra note 1, at 483.
190. 2 VICTOR S. CLARK, HISTORY OF MANUFACTURES IN THE UNITED STATES, 1860–1893,
at 520–21 (1929).
191. WHITNEY EASTMAN, THE HISTORY OF THE LINSEED OIL INDUSTRY IN THE UNITED
STATES 31 (1968).
192. EICHNER, supra note 60, at 114–15.
2320 FORDHAM LAW REVIEW [Vol. 81
195. See WILLIAM W. COOK, A TREATISE ON STOCK AND STOCKHOLDERS AND GENERAL
CORPORATION LAW §§ 21–22, at 28–30 (2d ed. 1889); ARTHUR L. HELLIWELL, A TREATISE
ON STOCK AND STOCKHOLDERS §§ 145‒56, at 243‒79 (1904).
196. NEW YORK 1888 REPORT, supra note 176, at 5–6.
197. See N. River Sugar, 24 N.E. at 838.
198. Neb. Distilling Co., 46 N.W. at 157.
199. See EDWARD SHERWOOD MEADE, TRUST FINANCE 295 (1903).
200. Stimson, in an article in the first volume of the Harvard Law Review, collected a
number of arguments that states might use against the trust device and urged the states to
prosecute vigorously these enterprises. Frederick J. Stimson, “Trusts,” 1 HARV. L. REV. 132
(1887); see also William F. Dana, “Monopoly” Under the National Antitrust Act, 7 HARV. L.
REV. 338, 348–49 (1894) (collecting citations of state prosecutions).
2322 FORDHAM LAW REVIEW [Vol. 81
201. See, e.g., Whittenton Mills v. Upton, 76 Mass. (10 Gray) 582 (1858) (declaring void
a longstanding putative partnership between a corporation and an individual as outside the
powers of the corporation); N. River Sugar, 24 N.E. at 841 (affirming the revocation of a
corporate charter where the corporation violated its charter and failed to perform its
corporate duties by joining and subordinating its interest to the Sugar Trust and closing its
facilities pursuant to the trust’s instruction); Mallory v. Hananer Oil Works, 8 S.W. 396, 399
(Tenn. 1888) (holding that it was unlawful for Hananer, a Tennessee corporation, to become
a member of a partnership with three other Memphis-based corporations, independently of
whether the partnership constituted an illegal combination to fix prices and control
production of cottonseed oil in Memphis). See generally HELLIWELL, supra note 195, § 375,
at 703‒05.
202. See, e.g., Neb. Distilling Co., 46 N.W. at 161.
203. See Ward v. Farwell, 97 Ill. 593, 607 (1881) (“So, every private corporation, in
accepting its charter, impliedly undertakes and agrees, upon condition of forfeiture, that it
will exercise the rights and privileges conferred upon it in furtherance of the objects and
purposes of its creation, and not otherwise, and that it will so manage and conduct its affairs
that it shall not become dangerous or hazardous to the safety or well being of the State or
community in and with which it transacts its business.”). A writ of quo warranto is an order
to the corporation to show by what authority it has exercised some power or performed some
action. For a discussion of the history of the quo warranto writ and its contemporary usage
in the late nineteenth century, see, for example, JAMES L. HIGH, A TREATISE ON
EXTRAORDINARY LEGAL REMEDIES, EMBRACING MANDAMUS, QUO WARRANTO AND
PROHIBITION §§ 647–77a (2d ed. 1884); 5 SEYMOUR D. THOMPSON, COMMENTARIES ON THE
LAW OF PRIVATE CORPORATIONS ch. 157 (1895).
2013] THE ORIGINS OF ANTITRUST LEGISLATION 2323
211. The deed is reprinted in People v. N. River Sugar Refining Co., 121 N.Y. 582, 585–
95 (1890).
212. People v. N. River Sugar Refining Co., 24 N.E. 834, 837 (N.Y. 1890).
213. Id.
214. Id. at 837–38.
215. Id. at 838.
216. Id. There is no record of what Searles did with the trust certificates. Id.
217. People v. N. River Sugar Refining Co., 121 N.Y. 582, 599 (N.Y. 1890).
218. N. River Sugar, 24 N.E. at 835.
219. Id.
220. Id. at 839.
2013] THE ORIGINS OF ANTITRUST LEGISLATION 2325
sign the trust deed, it acquiesced to participating in the trust, though the
actions of its original management, by registering the stock transfers,
seating a new replacement board of Sugar Refineries designees, and paying
its earning to the new stockholders of record.221
It remained for the court to determine whether this membership was
illegal under New York corporation law and, if so, whether this worked to
the public injury so as to make revocation of its charter an appropriate
remedy. The court considered both questions together.222 As a matter of
state corporation law, North River had abandoned its responsibilities as a
corporate body to make decisions solely in its own interests.223 Its “real”
stockholders had been separated from their voting rights given to them by
the state, its directors served at the sufferance of the Sugar Trust’s board, it
had no discretion to declare dividends and retain earnings, and its property
could be mortgaged for interests other than its own.224 At the direction of
the Trust, North River ceased to do business for the purpose of lessening
market supply.225 Most egregious to the court, however, was North River’s
participation in the creation of a trust that circumvented New York’s
regulations of large the aggregation of capital through the state’s
corporation laws.226 The court concluded that it was unnecessary to
determine whether the Sugar Trust was an unlawful combination in restraint
of trade or monopoly.227 It was enough that North River abandoned its
corporate responsibilities imposed on it by law, much less that it evaded
state supervision of capital aggregations by forming an unsupervised trust
or partnership.228 The court affirmed the judgment of dissolution.229
Nebraska’s suit to revoke the charter of the Nebraska Distilling Company
proceeded on a somewhat different theory.230 In 1887, NDC became part of
the Distillers and Cattle Feeders Trust, better known as the Whiskey
Trust.231 The stockholders of NDC, whose assets the trust assessed at
$100,000, exchanged their stock in return for trust certificates valued at par
at $285,700 (yet another example of stock watering), whereupon NDC
221. Id.
222. Id.
223. Id. at 839–40.
224. Id. at 840.
225. Id.
226. Id.
227. Id. at 841.
228. Similarly, in its action to declare the American Cotton Oil Trust illegal and enjoin it
from doing business in the state, the Louisiana attorney general alleged, among other things,
that the trust operated as if it were a corporation but was not incorporated in the state nor was
it subject to state corporate law regulation. In its opinion, the court noted that the absence of
proper regulation could harm persons who purchased Cotton Oil Trust certificates and those
who deal with it and become its creditors. The court found the allegations sufficient to state
a cause of action that the trust was operating in the state illegally, overruled the demurrer,
and ordered the case to proceed to trial. State v. Am. Cotton Oil Trust, 1 RY. & CORP. L.J.
509, 510–11 (La. Civ. Dist. Ct. 1887).
229. N. River Sugar, 24 N.E. at 839.
230. State v. Neb. Distilling Co., 46 N.W. 155 (Neb. 1890).
231. Id. at 156.
2326 FORDHAM LAW REVIEW [Vol. 81
issued new stock to the trustees, who in turn installed a new board of
directors for the company.232 The Whiskey Trust, which was started after
the failure of a series of pools, was formed for the purpose of reducing the
industry production of alcohol, spirits, and liquor.233 The trust’s method of
controlling production was simple: it centralized production in the most
efficient plants and mothballed the rest.234 By 1890, of the roughly 90 to
110 distilleries located north and west of the Ohio River, 75 to 80 had
become members of the trust.235 Of these, the trust kept fourteen in
operation.236
Within a few months after joining the trust, the NDC plant was closed.237
The plant stayed shuttered but apparently operational until January 1890.238
At that time, the NDC’s shareholders (that is, the trustees of the Whiskey
Trust) voted to liquidate NDC’s plant and equipment and surrender NDC’s
corporate charter to the state of Nebraska.239 It is likely that the trustees
were concerned about the possibility of a quo warranto proceeding, which
could result not only in the revocation of NDC’s charter but also in the
appointment of a receiver for its assets and possibly the reopening of
production. The trustees authorized NDC’s president to convey without
restriction the plant’s equipment to Weston Arnold, a trust operative, who
five days later assigned his interest in all but two cookers and a mash pump
to George Woolsey, one of NDC’s original stockholders and later a trust-
appointed officer of NDC.240 Woolsey, who wished to use the plant for the
manufacture of cereals, agreed with Arnold not to use any part of the
equipment for distilling purposes for a period of roughly twenty years and
to include a restrictive covenant to the same effect for the benefit of Arnold
in the event Woolsey ever sold the plant to someone else.241 In making
these assignments, the Whiskey Trust sought to dissolve NDC before a quo
warranto proceeding could revoke its charter and to ensure that NDC’s
plant would not resume production.242 In addition, the reservation of the
two cookers and mash pump by Arnold was designed to destroy the plant’s
usefulness as a distillery regardless of what Woolsey did with the other
equipment.243
The scheme did not work. Within days after the assignment to Woolsey
the state initiated its action.244 Although NDC’s charter stated that it was
organized for the purpose of the manufacture and sale of alcohol, spirits,
and other liquors, the court did not cite the NDC’s takeover by the trust or
the failure of NDC to stay in business as the grounds for revoking the
charter (probably because the attorney general was really after the
equipment, which was already out of NDC’s hands, before it could be
rendered useless for distilling purposes). Rather, the court noted that the
general corporation statute under which NDC had been organized restricted
the operations of Nebraska corporations to those with a lawful purpose; acts
done in furtherance of an unlawful purpose were unauthorized and in excess
of the corporation's powers, and therefore illegal and void. The court found
that NDC’s purpose in originally joining the Whiskey Trust was to suppress
competition and create a monopoly, and that all contracts and conveyances
in furtherance of this purpose—including the conveyance of the equipment
to Arnold and Woolsey—were null and void.245 Since the equipment was
within the jurisdiction of the court, the court could take control of it and
dispose of it as the ends of justice required. Moreover, NDC’s
unauthorized contracts and conveyances also provided the grounds for the
court annulling NDC’s corporate franchise.246
The quo warranto actions by New York, California, Nebraska, and Ohio
against their respective state corporations for participating in a trust proper,
and the action by Louisiana to enjoin the Cotton Oil Trust from operating in
the state for lack of incorporation, are often regarded as the first antitrust
actions against the trusts. While harm to customers and suppliers and the
tendency to monopoly may have been a consideration in bringing the
actions, and certainly were noted when the states argued that participation
in the trusts were not only ultra vires but also against the public interest,
competition concerns were probably secondary at best. In the New York
and Nebraska actions, the quo warranto actions were brought against
corporations whose facilities were closed down by the controlling trust,247
while Louisiana directly challenged the operation of the Cotton Oil Trust,
which had shut down two mills in the state.248 At least in New York and
perhaps in the other states as well, the closure of a plant and the
concomitant loss of employment appear to be the determinative factor. It is
worth noting that the base of the Sugar Trust was in New York, yet the only
quo warranto proceeding that the state brought was against a constituent
corporation whose facilities were closed almost immediately upon joining
the trust. For many years, New York left the Sugar Trust unmolested,
although the Sugar Trust was one of the most notorious combinations in the
country, controlling 85 percent of the refining capacity on the East Coast,
and probably the most significant combination operating in New York,
since it controlled all of the sugar refineries in the state.249 Nor did New
250. See id. at 4 (investigating the Sugar Trust, the Milk Trust, the Rubber Trust, the
Cotton Seed Oil Trust, the Envelope Trust, the Elevator Trust, the Oil Cloth Trust, the
Standard Oil Trust, the Butchers’ Trust, the Glass Trust, and the Furniture Trust); NEW YORK
1889 REPORT, supra note 61, at 3 (investigating the Copper Trust, the Sugar Trust, the Jute
Bagging Trust, the Milk Trust, the Elevator Trust, and the Wholesale Grocers’ Trust). As
the reports noted, many of these “trusts” were almost surely in the form of simple
agreements and not trusts proper.
251. NEW YORK 1888 REPORT, supra note 176, at 7.
252. See ARTHUR H. DEAN, WILLIAM NELSON CROMWELL, 1854–1948, AN AMERICAN
PIONEER IN CORPORATION, COMPARATIVE AND INTERNATIONAL LAW 99 (1957).
253. Id.
254. See State v. Neb. Distilling Co., 46 N.W. 155, 157–58 (Neb. 1890).
2013] THE ORIGINS OF ANTITRUST LEGISLATION 2329
255. The bulk of New Jersey revenues had come historically from railroad taxes. In
1884, New Jersey extended its tax reach to other corporations. See generally CHRISTOPHER
GRANDY, NEW JERSEY AND THE FISCAL ORIGINS OF MODERN AMERICAN CORPORATION LAW
(1993); Charles W. McCurdy, The Knight Sugar Decision of 1895 and the Modernization of
American Corporation Law, 1869–1903, 53 BUS. HIST. REV. 304, 317 (1979).
256. For an account of the various machinations of the New Jersey legislature during this
time, see Harold Stoke, Economic Influences upon the Corporation Laws of New Jersey,
38 J. POL. ECON. 551 (1930). For further background, see also GRANDY, supra note 255, at
39–45; Christopher Grandy, New Jersey Corporate Chartermongering, 1875–1929, 49 J.
ECON. HIST. 677 (1989); Edward Q. Keasbey, New Jersey and the Great Corporations,
13 HARV. L. REV. 198 (1899); Lincoln Steffans, New Jersey: A Traitor State, 24
MCCLURE’S MAG. 649, 650 (1905). New Jersey had substantially liberalized its general
incorporation act once before in 1875, although there was no significant increase in the
number of incorporations in the state until the second liberalization in 1889. See CADMAN,
supra note 140, at 155–60; GEORGE H. EVANS, JR., BUSINESS INCORPORATIONS IN THE UNITED
STATES, 1800–1943, app. A, at 125–32 (1948) (New Jersey general incorporation statistics);
Keasbey, supra, at 205–07; Melvin I. Urofsky, Proposed Federal Incorporation in the
Progressive Era, 26 AM. J. LEGAL HIST. 160, 163–64 (1982). See generally JAMES B. DILL,
THE STATUTORY AND CASE LAW APPLICABLE TO PRIVATE COMPANIES UNDER THE GENERAL
CORPORATION ACT OF NEW JERSEY AND CORPORATE PRECEDENTS (3d ed. 1901).
257. Act of Apr. 4, 1888, ch. 269, 1888 N.J. Laws 385–86 (authorizing New Jersey and
other corporations operating in the state, and so authorized by their law of incorporation, to
own and hold stock and bonds of corporations chartered in other states).
258. Act of Mar. 10, 1892, ch. 56, § 1, 1892 N.J. Laws 90.
259. Act of Mar. 14, 1893, ch. 171, § 1, 1983 N.J. Laws 301; see Act of Mar. 8, 1893,
ch. 67, § 1, 1893 N.J. Laws 121 (consolidation or merger).
260. See Act of Apr. 21, 1896, ch. 185, 1896 N.J. Laws 277.
2330 FORDHAM LAW REVIEW [Vol. 81
261. See Joel Seligman, A Brief History of Delaware’s General Corporation Law of 1899,
1 DEL. J. CORP. L. 249, 266 (1976).
262. Act of May 18, 1892, ch. 688, 1892 N.Y. Laws 1834.
263. Act of May 17, 1895, ch. 138, 1895 Conn. Pub. Acts 514–15.
264. Act of June 26, 1895, ch. 261, 1895 Pa. Laws 369–70.
265. Act of Mar. 10, 1899, ch. 273, 21 Del. Laws 445 (1899). Delaware essentially
copied the New Jersey Revised Statute of 1896, although Delaware’s fees were lower. See
LARCOM, supra note 147, at 14–15, 17–25; Little Delaware Makes a Bid for the
Organization of Trusts, 33 AM. L. REV. 408, 419 (1899). In 1913, the New Jersey state
legislature, with the guidance and encouragement of Governor Woodrow Wilson, reformed
the general corporation law through the so-called “Seven Sisters” acts. See Acts of Feb. 19,
1913, chs. 13–19, 1913 N.J. Laws 25–33. Apparently stung by Theodore Roosevelt’s
attacks in the 1912 presidential election on Wilson’s failure to do anything about New Jersey
as a haven for trusts, Wilson sought and obtained state legislation that eliminated most of the
attractive features of the New Jersey general corporation statute. See ARTHUR S. LINK,
WILSON: THE NEW FREEDOM 32–34 (1956). Two years later, Delaware adopted a new
General Corporation Law and became the state of choice for new incorporation. See
LARCOM, supra note 147, at 9–10, 155. In 1917, the New Jersey legislature reversed course,
largely to stem the loss of revenue in franchise fees, and substantially weakened or repealed
the Seven Sisters Acts. See Act of Mar. 28, 1917, ch. 195, 1917 N.J. Laws 566. By then,
however, it was already too late, since Delaware already replaced New Jersey as the state of
choice for large corporations.
2013] THE ORIGINS OF ANTITRUST LEGISLATION 2331
In 1876, the Supreme Court began to pull back from its earlier
suggestions that states could discriminate arbitrarily against foreign
corporations, or at least discriminate against the sale of goods by foreign
corporations in the course of interstate commerce. In Welton v. Missouri,266
the Court used the Commerce Clause to invalidate a discriminatory
licensing fee imposed on traveling wholesale salesmen, known as
“drummers,” representing out-of-state manufacturers but not on those
representing in-state manufacturers.267 Welton, an agent of the Singer
Sewing Machine Company who was indicted and convicted for failing to
obtain the requisite license to sell goods produced out of state, claimed that
the license fee constituted a tax on the sale of goods in interstate commerce
and therefore an unconstitutional restraint.268 The Court, despite a history
of sustaining state taxes on the in-state sales activities of foreign
corporations, agreed.269 A decade later, in Robbins v. Shelby County Taxing
District,270 the Court held that even nondiscriminatory drummer license
fees are invalid if they impede interstate commerce.271 While Welton and
Robbins paved the way for the expansion of firms such as Singer and
McCormick that used demonstration agents who required no local facilities
to market their products, Cooley and Paul continued to permit states
complete freedom to regulate foreign corporations producing out-of-state
goods or services that required local manufacturing, warehouses, sales, or
272. Paul v. Virginia, 75 U.S. (8 Wall.) 168, 183–85 (1868); Cooley v. Bd. of Wardens,
53 U.S. (12 How.) 299, 321 (1851).
273. See, e.g., Horn Silver Mining Co. v. New York, 143 U.S. 305, 313–15 (1892)
(noting the absolute right to exclude foreign corporations from intrastate business activities);
Pembina Consol. Silver Mining & Milling Co. v. Pennsylvania, 125 U.S. 181, 189–90
(1888) (upholding a discriminatory tax on in-state offices of foreign corporations); Cooper
Mfg. Co. v. Ferguson, 113 U.S. 727 (1885).
274. 118 U.S. 394 (1886).
275. See Morton J. Horowitz, Santa Clara Revisited: The Development of Corporate
Theory, 88 W. VA. L. REV. 173, 173 (1985).
276. See ELIOT JONES, THE TRUST PROBLEM IN THE UNITED STATES 40 (1921). Within a
few years after the passage of the Sherman Act, other significant enterprises, including the
American Sugar Refining Company (1891), the National Lead Company (1891), the General
Electric Company (1892), the United States Rubber Company (1892), the National Wall
Paper Company (1892), the United States Leather Company (1893), and the American
Malting Company (1897), reorganized into corporations. Id.; GLENN D. BABCOCK, HISTORY
OF THE UNITED STATES RUBBER COMPANY (1966); ARTHUR STONE DEWING, CORPORATE
PROMOTIONS AND REORGANIZATIONS 19–20 (1914) (formation of the United States Leather
Company); CLIFFORD DYER HOLLEY, THE LEAD AND ZINC PIGMENTS 24–25 (1909)
(formation of the National Lead Company); MOODY, supra note 182, at 248 (formation of
the General Electric Company).
2013] THE ORIGINS OF ANTITRUST LEGISLATION 2333
Iowa Act of April 16, 1888, ch. 84, 1888 Iowa Acts 124
Maine Act of March 7, 1889, ch. 266, 1889 Me. Laws 235
Kansas Act of March 9, 1889, ch. 257, 1889 Kan. Sess. Laws 389
North Carolina Act of March 11, 1889, ch. 374, 1889 N.C. Sess. Laws 372
Nebraska Act of March 29, 1889, ch. 69, 1889 Neb. Laws 516
Texas Act of March 30, 1889, ch. 117, 1889 Tex. Gen. Laws 141
Tennessee Act of April 6, 1889, ch. 250, 1889 Tenn. Acts 475
Missouri Act of May 18, 1889, 1889 Mo. Laws 96
Michigan Act of July 1, 1889, no. 225, 1889 Mich. Pub. Acts 331
Mississippi Act of February 22, 1890, ch. 36, 1890 Miss. Laws 55
North Dakota Act of March 3, 1890, ch. 174, 1890 N.D. Laws 503
South Dakota Act of March 7, 1890, ch. 154, 1890 S.D. Sess. Laws 323
Kentucky Act of May 20, 1890, ch. 1621, 1890 Ky. Acts 143
Federal Act of July 2, 1890, ch. 674, 26 Stat. 209 (1890)
As discussed, state courts in the United States applied the common law to
find void and unenforceable the agreements underlying combinations of
competitors organized for the purpose of raising prices and limiting
production. Although some of the fine points vary, each of the thirteen
state antitrust statutes contains a broad prohibition against combinations
designed to raise price or reduce production. Although some courts raised
the possibility that combinations could regulate prices and output to the
extent necessary to control excessive competition, I could find no reported
court decisions that enforced a combination implementing agreements on
this ground. North Carolina, however, appears to have recognized this
defense by prohibiting only price increases “beyond the price that would be
fixed by the natural demand for or the supply of” the products in
question.296 Six state statutes—Kansas, North Carolina, Tennessee,
Mississippi, Texas, and South Dakota—explicitly prohibited collective
activity to reduce prices (presumably of inputs),297 although many statutes
had catch-all provisions prohibiting the restriction of “full and free
competition” or something to a similar effect that might be used to reach
collective monopsony pricing.298 The North Carolina and Tennessee
296. Act of Mar. 11, 1889, ch. 374, § 2, 1889 N.C. Sess. Laws 372, 373.
297. Act of Mar. 9, 1889, ch. 257, § 1, 1889 Kan. Sess. Laws 389; Act of February 22,
1890, ch. 36, § 1, 1890 Miss. Laws 55; Act of Mar. 11, 1889, ch. 374, § 2; Act of Mar. 7,
1890, ch. 154, § 1, 1890 S.D. Sess. Laws 323 (farm and agricultural products); Act of Apr. 6,
1889, ch. 250, § 1, 1889 Tenn. Acts 475; Act of Mar. 30, 1889, ch. 117, § 1, 1889 Tex. Gen.
Laws 141.
298. Act of Mar. 9, 1889, ch. 257, § 1 (“full and free competition”); Act of July 1, 1889,
no. 225, § 1, 1889 Mich. Pub. Acts 331 (“free competition”); Act of Feb. 22, 1890, ch. 36,
§ 1, 1890 Miss. Laws 55 (“free and unrestricted competition”); Act of Mar. 7, 1890, ch. 154,
2013] THE ORIGINS OF ANTITRUST LEGISLATION 2337
§ 1 (“free, fair and full competition”); Act of Mar. 30, 1889, ch. 117, § 1 (“free and
unrestricted competition”).
299. Act of Mar. 11, 1889, ch. 374, § 5.
300. Act of Apr. 6, 1889, ch. 250, § 1.
301. Act of Mar. 9, 1889, ch. 257, § 2; Act of May 20, 1890, ch. 1621, § 2, 1890 Ky. Acts
143; Act of Mar. 7, 1889, ch. 266, § 1, 1889 Me. Laws 235; Act of May 18, 1889, § 2, 1889
Mo. Laws 96; Act of Mar. 3, 1890, ch. 174, § 2, 1890 N.D. Laws 503, 504; see also Act of
Feb. 22, 1890, ch. 36, § 1 (defining combinations as trusts but not explicitly the issuance of
trust certificates or the subordination to trust management); Act of Mar. 11, 1889, ch. 374,
§ 3 (same); Act of Mar. 30, 1889, ch. 117, § 1 (same).
302. Act of Mar. 7, 1889, ch. 266, § 4; Act of May 18, 1889, § 6.
303. See State ex rel. Att’y Gen. v. Simmons Hardware Co., 18 S.W. 1125, 1127 (Mo.
1892). The experience under the statute is recounted in Steven L. Piott, Missouri and
Monopoly? The 1890s As an Experiment in Law Enforcement, 74 MO. HIST. REV. 21 (1979).
304. Act of Mar. 9, 1889, ch. 257, § 3; Act of Mar. 29, 1889, ch. 69, § 6, 1889 Neb. Laws
516, 519.
305. Act of May 20, 1890, ch. 1621, § 3; Act of May 18, 1889, § 3; Act of Mar. 3, 1890,
ch. 174, § 3.
306. Act of Mar. 7, 1890, ch. 154, § 1, 1890 S.D. Sess. Laws 323.
2338 FORDHAM LAW REVIEW [Vol. 81
Texas, and Mississippi each provided for a maximum term of ten years.307
Iowa, Maine, and Tennessee did not provide for imprisonment.
On criminal fines, Michigan and Tennessee appear on the low end.
Depending on the section violated, Michigan provided for a criminal fine
range of $50 to $300 or $500 and imprisonment of not more than six
months to one year.308 Tennessee provided for a criminal fine of not less
than $250 for the first offense and not less than $500 for subsequent
offenses, together in both cases with a $50 tax to be paid to the state
attorney general as costs.309 Kansas, Nebraska, and South Dakota provided
for a maximum criminal fine of $1,000.310 Iowa, Texas, Missouri
(individual only), Mississippi, North Dakota (individual only), and
Kentucky provided a maximum fine of $5,000,311 while Maine
(organizational only) and North Carolina had maximum fines of $10,000.312
In addition, Missouri and North Dakota provided for organizational fines of
between 1 percent and 20 percent of the corporation’s capital stock or the
amount invested otherwise.313 Interestingly, in addition to a criminal fine,
Mississippi also provided for a forfeiture of $50 for each day of a violation
to be paid into the state treasury to the credit of the common school fund.314
Nebraska, Texas, Tennessee, Michigan, Mississippi, North Dakota, and
Kentucky all provided for the revocation of the charter through a quo
warranto proceeding of any domestic corporation that violated their
antitrust laws,315 although the other states undoubtedly had this option
under their respective corporation laws.
Most states simply ordered their respective attorney general and
subordinate state attorneys to enforce the law. Some states, however,
clearly were concerned about incentives to enforce the law. Missouri
incentivized its attorney general and prosecuting attorneys by entitling them
to one-fifth of any fine collected if prosecuting alone or one-fourth if
prosecuting together.316 Similarly, Tennessee provided that the attorney
general would receive 50 percent of any fine as well as a taxed fee of
307. Act of Feb. 22, 1890, ch. 36, § 2, 1890 Miss. Laws 55, 56; Act of Mar. 11, 1889, ch.
374, § 3; Act of Mar. 30, 1889, ch. 117, § 6, 1889 Tex. Gen. Laws 141, 142.
308. Act of July 1, 1889, no. 225, §§ 1, 3, 1889 Mich. Pub. Acts 331, 332.
309. Act of Apr. 6, 1889, ch. 250, § 2, 1889 Tenn. Acts 475.
310. Act of Mar. 9, 1889, ch. 257, § 3, 1889 Kan. Sess. Laws 389, 390; Act of Mar. 29,
1889, ch. 69, § 6, 1889 Neb. Laws 516, 519; Act of Mar. 7, 1890, ch. 154, § 1.
311. Act of Apr. 16, 1888, ch. 84, § 2, 1888 Iowa Acts 124; Act of May 20, 1890, ch.
1621, § 3, 1890 Ky. Acts 143, 144; Act of Feb. 22, 1890, ch. 36, § 2; Act of May 18, 1889,
§ 3; Act of Mar. 3, 1890, ch. 174, § 3, 1890 N.D. Laws 503, 504; Act of Mar. 30, 1889,
ch. 117, § 6.
312. Act of Mar. 7, 1889, ch. 266, § 3, 1889 Me. Laws 235, 236; Act of Mar. 11, 1889,
ch. 374, § 3.
313. Act of May 18, 1889, § 3; Act of Mar. 3, 1890, ch. 174, § 3.
314. Act of Feb. 22, 1890, ch. 36, § 7, 1890 Miss. Laws 55, 57.
315. Act of May 20, 1890, ch. 1621, § 5; Act of July 1, 1889, no. 225, § 5, 1889 Mich.
Pub. Acts 331, 333; Act of Feb. 22, 1890, ch. 36, § 10; Act of Mar. 29, 1889, ch. 69, § 5; Act
of Mar. 3, 1890, ch. 174, §§ 6–7; Act of Apr. 6, 1889, ch. 250, § 4, 1889 Tenn. Acts 475,
476; Act of Mar. 30, 1889, ch. 117, § 3.
316. Act of May 18, 1889, § 8.
2013] THE ORIGINS OF ANTITRUST LEGISLATION 2339
$50.317 Kansas provided that county attorneys that fail to prosecute and
officials with knowledge of a violation who fail to come forward and notify
the county attorney were subject to fines between $100 and $500 and
forfeiture of office.318
Surprisingly, only Nebraska and Kansas provided for a private right of
action by persons injured as a result of a violation of the state’s antitrust
law. Nebraska provided for the recovery of the “full amount of damages
sustained” plus a reasonable attorney’s fee.319 Kansas provided for a
private right of action to recover the full purchase price paid by the plaintiff
to any illegal combination.320 Missouri and Kentucky provided that a
purchaser from an illegal combination was not liable for the purchase price
and could interpose the illegality of the combination as a defense in a
failure to pay contract action but it does not explicitly provide for a private
right of action to recover a purchase price that had already been paid.321
South Dakota permitted “any person” to file a complaint for any violation
of its antitrust law and instructed its courts to proceed with the case “the
same as though the State’s Attorney had made the complaint.”322 The
language of the statute is ambiguous as to whether it applied to criminal
complaints as well as petitions for injunctive relief.
imprisonment not exceeding one year, on the lower end of the state
imprisonment statutes.332 The criminal provisions of the Sherman Act were
enforceable by the U.S. Attorney General and the U.S. district attorneys.333
The Sherman Act also provided the federal circuit courts with
jurisdiction in equity to prevent and restrain violations of the Act and
authorized the Attorney General and the district attorneys to bring
proceedings to enjoin on-going and imminent violations.334 Moreover, the
Sherman Act provided the United States with a remedy of forfeiture, so that
property owned under any illegal contract or by any illegal combination that
was in the course of being transported in interstate or foreign commerce
could be condemned and forfeited to the United States.335
Finally, and unlike the state antitrust statutes, the Sherman Act provides
persons injured by an antitrust violation in their business or property with a
private right of action to recover treble damages (three times actual
damages) plus reasonable attorney’s fees.336 The legislative history of the
treble damage remedy is sparse, although it appears that the remedy was to
be available not only to customers who purchased goods or services from a
combination member at fixed prices but also to competitors who may have
been driven out of business by a combination’s efforts to control the
market.337 On multiple damages, the legislative path was convoluted.
Sherman originally introduced a bill providing that customer could sue for
double the amount of actual damages resulting from increased prices
charged pursuant to an illegal combination.338 When the bill was reported
by the Senate Finance Committee, which Sherman chaired, the bill had
been amended to provide, as did the Nebraska and Kansas antitrust statutes,
that purchasers could recover the full consideration paid for any goods or
merchandise purchased from a combination member at an increased
332. Id.
333. Id. § 4.
334. Id. The United States circuit courts were established by the Judiciary Act of 1789.
ch. 20, § 4, 1 Stat. 73. The U.S. circuit courts had original jurisdiction over civil actions
based on diversity jurisdiction and over most federal crimes and appellate jurisdiction over
U.S. district courts. Id. §§ 11, 22. The Judiciary Act of 1891 transferred appellate
jurisdiction to the newly created U.S. circuit courts of appeals, which are now known as the
U.S. courts of appeals. ch. 517, §§ 2, 4, 26 Stat. 826. In 1912, the Judicial Code of 1911
abolished the circuit courts and transferred their remaining original jurisdiction to the U.S.
district courts. Pub. L. No. 61-475, §§ 289–292, 36 Stat. 1087, 1167.
335. Sherman Act § 6. The United States has only rarely sought forfeiture and then
mostly in consent decrees rather than litigated relief. See, e.g., United States v. Steinhardt
Mgmt. Co., No. 94 Civ 9044, 1995 WL 322772 (S.D.N.Y. May 5, 1995) (consent decree);
United States v. Certain Property Owned by Salomon Bros., No. 92 Civ. 3700, 1992 WL
295221 (S.D.N.Y. Sept. 14, 1992) (consent decree providing for a $27.5 million asset
forfeiture to settle in part a charge that Salomon Bros. cornered the market for certain two-
year Treasury notes); see also United States v. Addyston Pipe & Steel Co., 85 F. 271, 301
(6th Cir. 1898) (denying as a matter of law a petition in equity for forfeiture and holding that
forfeiture actions must be tried at law before a jury), aff’d on other grounds, 175 U.S. 211
(1899).
336. Sherman Act § 7.
337. See 21 CONG. REC. 2569 (1890) (statement of Sen. Sherman).
338. S. 3445, 50th Cong. (as introduced, Aug. 14, 1888).
2342 FORDHAM LAW REVIEW [Vol. 81
price.339 The full Senate amended the bill, retaining the committee’s
purchaser cause of action to recover the full consideration and adding a new
cause of action for actual damages for firms that were compelled to join or
sell out to a combination or were forced out of business.340 When the 50th
Congress ended without further action on the bill and the 51st Congress
convened, Sherman reintroduced the bill as reported earlier by the Senate
Finance Committee, retaining the purchaser cause of action for the full
purchase price but eliminating the competitor cause of action that the full
Senate had introduced.341 When the Finance Committee reported the bill, it
returned to Sherman’s original idea of double damages, but the language of
the amendment appeared to broaden the private action to include all injured
persons and not just purchasers.342 After being reported to, and debated and
amended by, the Senate,343 double damages and the broadened cause of
action remained in the bill through the floor debate. Unexpectedly, and
undoubtedly to Sherman’s dismay, the bill was referred to the Senate
Judiciary Committee, which rewrote the bill in its entirety in six days. The
Judiciary Committee increased the recovery to treble damages,344 where it
remained through enactment. No doubt the multiple damages were
provided not only to compensate victims, but also as an inducement to bring
what were likely to be expensive and risky law suits,345 as well as a further
deterrent to committing violations in the first instance.346 Even so, both
critics and supporters voiced skepticism that, given the difficulties and
expense of proving a violation, especially against a well-financed
adversary, there would be much private enforcement of the Sherman Act.347
339. S. 3445, 50th Cong. § 2 (as reported by the S. Comm. on Finance, Sept. 11, 1888).
340. S. 3445, 50th Cong. § 3 (as amended by the Senate, Jan. 25, 1889); see 20 CONG.
REC. 1167 (1889) (motion by Sen. Hoar to add competitor cause of action).
341. S. 1, 51st Cong. § 2 (as introduced, Dec. 4, 1889).
342. S. 1, 51st Cong. § 2 (as reported by the S. Comm. on Finance, Jan. 14, 1890); see
21 CONG. REC. 1767–68 (1890) (statement of Sen. George).
343. See S. 1, 51st Cong. § 2 (as amended by the Senate, Mar. 26, 1889) (retaining double
damages).
344. S. 1, 51st Cong. § 7 (as reported by the S. Comm. on the Judiciary, Apr. 2, 1890).
345. See 21 CONG. REC. 2569 (1890) (statement of Sen. Sherman) (expressing concern
that even double damages is “too small” to induce private enforcement).
346. See 21 CONG. REC. 3146–47 (1890) (statement of Sen. Hoar) (characterizing treble
damages as a “penalty”).
347. See 21 CONG. REC. 1768 (1890) (remarks of Sen. George) (“I do not hesitate to say
that few, if any, of such suits will ever be instituted and not one will ever be successful.”); id.
at 2569 (1890) (statement of Sen. Sherman); id. at 2615 (1890) (statement of Sen. Coke).
2013] THE ORIGINS OF ANTITRUST LEGISLATION 2343
and inflicting other “evils of monopoly,” the only recourse under the law
was to hope that the combination fell apart because enough of its members
cheated on the combination’s rules. The new antitrust legislation changed
this. State and federal prosecutors now had the ability to challenge
combinations directly.
Curiously, however, only two states and the federal government passed
statutes that provided injured private parties—a customer, for example, that
purchased products or services from a combination member at a
supracompetitively fixed price or a competitor that was excluded from the
marketplace by a combination’s exclusive dealing restraints—with a private
cause of action against the combination. One would think that more states
would have concluded that private parties were entitled to redress and
vindication for their injuries or even that private parties could deter
violations and advance the public interest by adding another means of
enforcing the law to supplement limited state enforcement resources. It
remains a mystery why more states did not create a private cause of action,
although certainly one possibility is that the states saw some combinations
as furthering the state’s economic interest and so wanted to maintain
exclusivity over which combinations would be challenged under state law.
In any event, early enforcement of the antitrust statutes was sparse at
best. In the electronic case databases, only a handful of cases appear
through the end of 1893 under the various state statutes and the Sherman
Act. Nor does there appear to be any significant number of material
unreported cases, since there is little mention of additional cases in the
treatises or the newspapers of the day. What reported decisions there are,
however, all pertain to the legality of horizontal combinations.
The electronic case databases contain only four cases under the thirteen
state antitrust laws, all brought by the state. The most interesting of these is
State ex rel. Attorney General v. Simmons Hardware Co.348 The Missouri
attorney general brought an action against the Simmons Hardware
Company alleging (1) that Simmons was a member of a trust organized
with other corporations to regulate the price of hardware in violation of the
Missouri antitrust law and (2) that the Simmons managing officers failed to
respond to the letter of inquiry sent by the secretary of state under the state
antitrust law to confirm that the company was not a member of an illegal
trust.349 On appeal, the Missouri Supreme Court declared the letter of
inquiry provisions of the Missouri antitrust statute unconstitutional as
compelling self-incrimination, since as the law was structured an
affirmative response would subject the responding officers (as well as the
corporation) to criminal penalties, a negative response would subject them
to prosecution for perjury, and a failure to respond would result in the
immediate revocation of the corporation’s charter.350 The remaining cases
involved two decisions in Kansas holding that the selling of insurance was
“trade” and so covered by the Kansas antitrust statute,351 and a decision in
Texas holding that insurance is not “commence” and therefore not covered
by the Texas antitrust act.352
The records of federal prosecutions are more complete.353 Only seven
cases—four bills in equity and three criminal cases—were brought by the
United States during the two and a half years that President Harrison
remained in office after the passage of the Sherman Act.354 All seven cases
were brought by U.S. district attorneys in the field with only mild
encouragement from William H.H. Miller, Harrison’s Attorney General.
Even so, some of the targets were substantial: the Sugar Trust,355 the
Whiskey Trust,356 the Cash Register Trust,357 a major railroad trust in the
Midwest,358 and a large lumber trust in the Northwest.359 The government
also obtained a temporary injunction against the labor unions and union
the prospect of criminal indictments, reallocate the power to revoke the charters of violating
corporations from the secretary of state to a court of competent jurisdiction, and require
affirmative proof in court of a state antitrust violation. Act of Apr. 2, 1891, 1891 Mo. Laws
186 (Apr. 2, 1891) (repealing chapter 128). The law was revised once again in 1885. Act of
Apr. 11, 1895, 1895 Mo. Laws 237. For the early saga of the Missouri antitrust law, see
Piott, supra note 303, at 21.
351. State v. Phipps, 31 P. 1097 (Kan. 1893) (affirming the convictions of two insurance
agents for violating laws prohibiting unlawful trusts and combinations in restraint of trade);
In re Pinkney, 27 P. 179, 180–81 (Kan. 1891).
352. Queen Ins. Co. v. State, 24 S.W. 397, 404 (Tex. 1893).
353. For a complete list of Department of Justice prosecutions under the Sherman Act
through 1911, see GOV’T PRINTING OFFICE, SHERMAN ANTITRUST LAW WITH AMENDMENTS
(1911).
354. For a review of antitrust enforcement during Harrison’s tenure as president, see
HOMER CUMMINGS & CARL MCFARLAND, FEDERAL JUSTICE: CHAPTERS IN THE HISTORY OF
JUSTICE AND THE FEDERAL EXECUTIVE 317–21 (1937); William Letwin, The First Decade of
the Sherman Act: Early Administration, 68 YALE L.J. 464, 468–76 (1959).
355. No. 38 (C.C.E.D. Pa. filed Mar. 4, 1892), dismissed, 60 F. 306 (C.C.E.D. Pa.), aff’d,
60 F. 934 (3d Cir. 1894), aff’d, United States v. E.C. Knight Co., 156 U.S. 1 (1895).
356. United States v. Greenhut, No. 461 (D. Mass. filed Feb. 23, 1892), indictment
dismissed, 50 F. 469 (D. Mass. 1892). There were three associated cases where the
government sought removal of out-of-state defendants to Boston to answer the indictment.
In each case, the petition for removal was denied. See In re Greene, 52 F. 104 (C.C.S.D.
Ohio 1892); In re Terrell, 51 F. 213 (C.C.S.D.N.Y. 1892); In re Corning, 51 F. 205 (N.D.
Ohio 1892).
357. United States v. Patterson, No. 1215 (C.C.D. Mass. filed July 2 and Oct. 5, 1892),
indictment dismissed in part, 55 F. 605 (C.C.D. Mass. 1893), nolle prosequi, (C.C.D. Mass.
Nov. 10, 1894), reprinted in DECREES AND JUDGMENTS IN FEDERAL ANTI-TRUST CASES, JULY
2, 1890–JANUARY 1, 1918, at 680 (Roger Shale ed., 1918).
358. United States v. Trans-Mo. Freight Ass’n, No. 6799 (C.C.D. Kan. filed Jan. 6, 1892),
dismissed, 53 F. 440 (C.C.D. Kan. 1892), aff’d, 58 F. 58 (8th Cir. 1893), complaint
reinstated and combination enjoined, 166 U.S. 290, combination dissolved and enjoined,
(C.C.D. Kan. June 7, 1897), reprinted in DECREES AND JUDGMENTS IN FEDERAL ANTI-TRUST
CASES, supra note 357, at 6.
359. United States v. Nelson, No. 1408 (C.C.D. Minn. filed Jan. 20, 1892), dismissed,
52 F. 646 (D. Minn. 1892).
2346 FORDHAM LAW REVIEW [Vol. 81
Why was the number of Department of Justice actions so low in the early
years? One factor was certainly the limitation on subject matter jurisdiction
imposed by the contemporary judicial interpretation of the Commerce
Clause, especially after the Supreme Court’s decision in United States v.
E.C. Knight Co.364 But this fails to explain why prosecutors did not attempt
a more artful pleading of restraints on interstate commerce in more cases
given the large number of combinations operating across state lines.
Another factor may have been the perceived limitations on applying the
prohibitions of the Sherman Act in an ex post facto manner, which
concerned the court in In re Greene.365 Here, too, one would think that
aggressive prosecutors would bring more cases to try to find ways to plead
around the problem and establish more favorable precedent, even if in the
end they were unsuccessful.
360. United States v. Workingmen’s Amalgamated Council of New Orleans, No. 12143
(C.C.E.D. La. filed Nov. 10, 1892), injunction entered, 54 F. 994 (C.C.E.D. La. 1893), aff’d,
57 F. 85 (5th Cir. 1893).
361. United States v. Jellico Mountain Coal & Coke Co., No. 2820 (M.D. Tenn. filed Oct.
13, 1890), declared illegal, 46 F. 432 (C.C.M.D. Tenn. 1891), enjoined, (C.C.M.D. Tenn.
June 17, 1891), reprinted in DECREES AND JUDGMENTS IN FEDERAL ANTI-TRUST CASES, supra
note 357, at 1.
362. Trans-Mo. 166 U.S. 290.
363. These statistics were compiled largely from COMMERCE CLEARING HOUSE, INC., THE
FEDERAL ANTITRUST LAWS WITH SUMMARY OF CASES INSTITUTED BY THE UNITED STATES
1890–1951 (1952).
364. 156 U.S. 1 (1895); see In re Greene, 52 F. 104, 112–13 (C.C.S.D. Ohio 1892).
365. See In re Greene, 52 F. at 112.
2013] THE ORIGINS OF ANTITRUST LEGISLATION 2347
366. See COMMERCE CLEARING HOUSE, supra note 363; Richard A. Posner, A Statistical
Study of Antitrust Enforcement, 13 J.L. & ECON. 365, 366 (1970).
367. See Letwin, supra note 354, at 466–68 (describing the “poverty” of the Department
of Justice in resources and manpower in the 1890s). See generally 1893 ATT’Y GEN. ANN.
REP.; 1892 ATT’Y GEN. ANN. REP.; 1891 ATT’Y GEN. ANN. REP.
368. Letwin, supra note 354, at 466.
368. Id.
369. Id. at 467. For a criticism of the fee system by former a attorney general, see
CUMMINGS & MCFARLAND, supra note 354, at 493 (“However, by far the greatest evil which
beset the administration of federal justice in the nineteenth century was the fee system for
the compensation for local federal officers.”). The fee system was abolished in 1896. Id. at
494.
370. On the public perceptions of the trusts at the time, see LOUIS GALAMBOS, THE PUBLIC
IMAGE OF BIG BUSINESS IN AMERICA, 1880–1940, at 47–78 (1975).
371. Of course, another possibility was that the Department of Justice and the district
attorneys simply shirked their responsibilities. See Mr. Edmunds on Trusts, N.Y. TIMES,
Nov. 25, 1892, available at http://query.nytimes.com/mem/archive-free/pdf?res=F00C15
2348 FORDHAM LAW REVIEW [Vol. 81
This all changed by the beginning of the next decade. Beginning with
the Panic of 1893, the country entered into its most severe economic
depression to that date.372 Marked by violent strikes and unemployment
rates that exceeded 10 percent in at least five years,373 the decade saw an
enormous number of business failures. These same pressures brought a
further round of combinations. In the aftermath of the depression, over
1800 firms were absorbed into horizontal consolidations of at least five
competing firms.374 This merger wave produced such giants as U.S. Steel,
American Tobacco, International Harvester, Du Pont, Corn Products,
Anaconda Copper, and American Smelting and Refining.375 Antitrust
enforcement, which became funded in 1903, responded with a new vigor,
but that is another story.