038840eo PDF
038840eo PDF
038840eo PDF
In'this series:
1. The peopling of ancient Egypt and the deciphering of Meroitic script
2. The African slave trade from thefifteenthto the nineteenth century
The african slave trade
from the fifteenth
to the nineteenth
century
Reports and papers of the meeting of experts
organized by Unesco at Port-au-Prince, Haiti,
31 January to 4 February 1978
wnesoo
The designations employed and the presentation of material throughout the publication
do not imply the expression of any opinion whatsoever on the part of Unesco concerning
the legal status of any country, territory, city or area or of its authorities, or concerning
the delimitation of its frontiers or boundaries.
I S B N 92-3-101672-5
French edition: 92-3-201672-9
© Unesco 1979
Printed in France
Preface
This second volume in the series 'The General History of Africa: Studies and
Documents' presents the working documents, a summary report of discus-
sions, and supplementary papers submitted at the Meeting of Experts on the
African Slave Trade which was organized by Unesco at Port-au-Prince, Haiti,
from 31 January to 4 February 1978.
The purpose of the meeting, which was recommended by the Interna-
tional Scientific Committee for the Drafting of a General History of Africa,
was to elicit the authorized views of specialists on the various aspects of the
slave trade mentioned in several volumes of the General History of Africa.
Over and above its immediate results, it also aimed at identifying new lines of
research on this subject, since despite the numerous studies and publications
that have already been produced, there remain several questions that have
not yet been satisfactorily answered.
Discussions centred on the following topics: scale and effects of the
slave trade; ideological positions with regard to the problem; abolition of
the slave trade, especially in the Indian Ocean; new lines of research.
The authors are responsible for the choice and the presentation of the
facts contained in this book, and for the opinions expressed therein, which
are not necessarily those of Unesco and do not commit the Organization.
Contents
Introduction 9
The slave trade within Africa and between Africa and the Middle East
^ T h e slave trade within the African continent, Mbaye Gueye 150
The slave trade and the population drain from Black Africa to North
Africa and the Middle East, / . B. Kake 164
Population movements between East Africa, the H o r n of Africa and the
neighbouring countries, Bethwell A. Ogot 175
Appendixes
Appendix 1 : List of participants 233
Appendix 2 : Opening speech of the Secretary of State for Education,
Haiti 236
Appendix 3 : Opening speech of the Director-General of Unesco 239
M a i n lines of debate
The task here was to use the most recent work in order to establish statistics
about the population uprooted from Africa by the traffic in slaves, in particular
with a view to providing receiving countries with statistical data about the
origin and numerical strength of the people of African extraction.
The figures given and the methods adopted to arrive at these estimates
vary from one school of thought to another. The meeting was required to
compare the various procedures followed, to m a k e a critical appraisal of them
and to suggest a method likely to produce better results. It would undoubtedly
be desirable to attempt to take stock of the methods used to evaluate the h u m a n
losses sustained by Africa as a result of the slave trade (particularly losses
suffered at the time of man-hunts o n the African continent and deaths in the
ports of embarkation and on the slave ships).
The experts were requested to examine the repercussions of the slave trade
both in Africa and in the receiving countries, and also in those countries which
organized the slave trade. The aim was to assess not only the numerical impor-
tance of the population forcibly removed from Africa, but also the impact of
this deportation on the demographic development of the African continent.
The impact of the slave trade on political and social structures, o n cul-
tural life and on economic development in Africa, which has not been studied
in any depth, was to be discussed thoroughly in order that conclusions could
be reached which s u m up the question and suggest fresh lines of research.
10 Introduction
A great deal of research has been carried out on what led to the abolition of
the slave trade and the stages through which it passed. The participants were
requested to review the issue.
In particular, they were invited to evaluate the role played by slaves'
uprisings in the abolition process itself, and the participation of slaves in
national liberation movements, especially in North and South America and the
Caribbean.
Special emphasis was to be placed on the Indian Ocean routes, which
have been less thoroughly studied than those across the Atlantic.
Introduction 11
The experts were requested to bring together under this heading all the recom-
mendations concerning the pursuit of research into the slave trade which arose
out of the discussions. In particular, they were to : (a) list the sources of archives
still to be published; (b) suggest forms and directions which further research
might take; and (c) put foward suggestions o n ways of setting u p a system
for the exchange of information, researchers and teachers and, when appro-
priate, students, between universities in the region (Caribbean and the Ameri-
cas) and Africa.
Working papers
The working papers are grouped in four sections in Part I of this book. The
first section contains contributions by S. U . A b r a m o v a and Michèle Duchet
on ideological and political aspects of the slave trade. In the second section,
Joseph E . Inikori deals with the effects of the slave trade on the Atlantic econ-
omies; José Luciano Franco examines the slave trade in the Caribbean and
Latin America; Oruno D . Lara discusses Negro resistance to slavery and
F . Latour da Veiga Pinto, assisted by Antonio Carreira, examines the effects
of Portugal's participation in the slave trade o n Portuguese society and the
country's socio-economic development.
The third and fourth sections deal with the slave trade within Africa
itself and in other parts of the world. M b a y e Gueye shows h o w European
participation in the slave trade caused it to swell to huge proportions and
discusses the subsequent effects on the internal slave trade. I. B . K a k e points
out that the peoples of North Africa and the Middle East had been transfer-
ring black populations to their territories long before Europeans began trading
in slaves and shows h o w this population drain developed from thefifteenthto
the end of the nineteenth century. Population movements between East Africa,
the Horn of Africa and the neighbouring countries are examined by Bethwell
A . Ogot, and Hubert Gerbeau discusses research to be undertaken on the slave
trade in the Indian Ocean.
Part I ends with the summary report of the meeting of experts and recom-
mendations for future action.
Part II of the book contains additional papers which participants were
asked to submit, describing research on the slave trade being carried out in
various countries. These papers contain mainly bibliographical data, details of
12 Introduction
S. U . Abramova
after the Christian Reconquest the influx of slaves virtually ceased. The market-
ing of black slaves was probably thefirstprofitable 'outcome' of the costly
African expeditions.
O n e often reads that Portuguese rulers, and a m o n g them Prince Henry,
k n o w n as 'the Navigator', the organizer of Portuguese expeditions to Africa,
sanctioned the import of Africans ostensibly to convert them to Christianity.
It is true that slaves were baptized, but nevertheless sold.
At that time the Church took quite a different line with regard to Africans.
Pope Nicholas V issued a special bull granting the King of Portugal, Alphonso
V , the right to seize lands and enslave heathens in regions discovered by that
time in Africa, and in those that would be discovered. Moreover, the Catholic
clergy, for instance, in the Congo, daily compromised itself and the Church
by indulging openly in the slave trade.4
In the early sixteenth century, the Spanish established a huge colonial
empire in the West Indies and America. In the process of seizing new lands
they massacred nearly all of the native Indian population. T o obtain cheap
manpower they began to bring African slaves, w h o had proved their worth
in Europe as capable and handy workers, to the N e w World.
By exporting Africans to America the Spanish were not trying to save
what was left of the Indians. They were eager to preserve their colonies where
there was no manpower to work the mines and plantations. In 1510, the first
large group of African slaves, 250 in all, was brought to the Hispaniola gold
mines. After that, the Spanish Government regularly concluded asiento with
other countries for the right to sell African slaves in Spain's American colonies.
In the second half of the sixteenth century, Portugal began to lose its
monopoly in Africa, and Spain in the N e w World. The development of capi-
talism in Europe prompted an active colonial policy. Holland, Great Britain
and then France began conquests in America, Asia and Africa, where they
built up their colonial empires.
Having considerably squeezed out Portugal, these countries settled on
Africa's western coast where they built forts and established settlements. In
the West Indies, Holland seized Curaçao and Aruba; Great Britain, Barbados
and Jamaica; France, Guadeloupe, Martinique and, in the late seventeenth
century, Santo Domingo, etc. Brazil, Cayenne, Surinam, N e w Amsterdam
(New York) and Virginia were a m o n g the colonies that emerged in America
at the time.
By the mid-seventeenth century, the main colonies where African labour
was soon to be employed were founded. Following the essential organizational
period in the colonies the development of plantation economies began. T h e
rapid development of the West Indies and the American colonies would have
been impossible in that period without the mass employment of cheap m a n -
power.
18 S. U. Abramova
has survived to our day. 7 It has, however, been refuted by the history of the
European colonies in America.
After exterminating the American Indians, the British and the French
began to employ white slaves to work their plantations. At that time political
prisoners and criminals were exiled to the West Indies. The system of inden-
tured servants was also widespread. In Europe, particularly in London and
Bristol, people were kidnapped and sold into slavery to the N e w World. 8
In the 1640s, when sugar-cane was introduced on a wide scale in the
West Indies, and crop areas were extended, the number of white slaves fell
short of the demand for manpower. Beginning with the late seventeenth cen-
tury the import of African slaves into the colonies of the N e w World rose
sharply.
Thus the reason for replacing white slaves by Africans had nothing to
do with the hot climate. A t that time Europe simply could not supply the
colonies with a sufficient amount of cheap manpower. A s admitted by all
contemporaries, without the enslavement of Africans the colonies of the N e w
World could not have continued to exist. O n e of the documents of the Royal
African C o m p a n y , founded in 1672, reads: "The slaves are sent to all His
Majesty's American Plantations which cannot subsist without them.' 9
In the second half of the seventeenth century, the slave trade became
notorious as one of the most profitable branches of trade, and each European
country, provided it had the opportunity, sought to snatch a profitable share
of the slave trade for itself. Great Britain, Holland and France were the leading
slave-trading powers of the time. F r o m the late seventeenth century, the British
North American colonies, the future United States of America, also sent slave
ships to the American coast. Even D e n m a r k and Sweden built several forts
on the western coast of Africa with the aim of taking part in the slave
trade.
In the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries, the slave trade was considered
as respectable as any other branch of trade. Tradesmen from different countries
boasted of their successes in trading in 'live merchandise'. Pages upon pages of
old books arefilledwith inventories showing the number of slaves exported
from Africa and the number of those w h o managed to reach the N e w World
alive.10 These data are only approximate—there were no precise statistics—yet
they are sufficient evidence of the importance of the slave trade and its scope
in the eighteenth century.
Robert Bisset's The History of the Negro Slave Trade in its Connection
with the Commerce and Prosperity of the West Indies and the Wealth of the
British Empire}1 one of the most serious works on the subject written by an
advocate of the slave trade in the years of struggle for its abolition, w h e n both
abolitionists and their opponents spared neither words nor emotions in publi-
cizing their economic, political and religious views on the subject, gives the
20 S. U. Abramova
precise standpoint on this question: the flourishing and wealth of the metro-
politan country depend on the size of the slave trade, the import of slaves to the
plantations.
In Capital, Karl M a r x quotes a prominent historian, a specialist of the
colonial period: 'It is the agriculture of the West Indies, which has been for
centuries prolific of fabulous wealth, which has engulfed millions of the African
race.'12 A n d that was exactly the way things stood. The American colonies,
the slave trade and the 'triangular' trade were a major factor in the primary
accumulation of capital and had a substantial impact on the economic devel-
opment of the metropolitan countries, but the fabulous wealth of the West
Indies and of the American planters was created by the hands of Africans,
scores of thousands of w h o m perished in the conditions of plantation slavery.
In distinction to several present-day historians this was well understood by
contemporaries.
T o quote a British historian, at the opening of the eigtheenth century :
the African slave trade was the foundation on which colonial industry and the colonial
commerce of European countries rested. It dominated the relations between the
countries of Western Europe and their colonies; it was one of the most important
factors in the warsthe of the century; it played a considerable role in the domestic
affairs of the nations involved in it.13
O n e has only to recall the asiento. Being well aware of the profits that would
c o m e pouring in from the delivery of slaves to the Spanish colonies and from
the goods that were smuggled during those voyages, European countries vied
to obtain this contract. According to the Treaty of Utrecht (1713) following the
war for the Spanish inheritance, Great Britain, as the victor, succeeded to the
asiento previously held by France and gained several additional privileges
into the bargain.14 According to contemporaries, obtaining the asiento was a
huge victory for British diplomacy.
In the eighteenth century, the interests of European society were closely
linked with the slave trade, which had a great impact on the growth of Euro-
pean ports and promoted the emergence of manufacturers processing raw
materials cultivated by Africans. In 1796, during debates held in the British
Parliament on the question of abolishing the slave trade, Tarleton and Y o u n g ,
members of the House of C o m m o n s , w h o represented the interests of ship-
builders and slave-traders, claimed that the abolition of the slave trade would
ruin London, Liverpool, Bristol and Glasgow. 15
The manufacturers of Nantes maintained in all competence :
The slave trade is the basis of all our navigations. It brings manpower to till the land
of our islands. In exchange the islands give us an abundance of sugar, coffee, cotton
and indigo which are used in domestic and foreign trade.16
Ideological, doctrinal, religious and political 21
aspects of the African slave trade
Certainly, these cities continued to thrive after the slave trade was abolished,
but the words of British Parliamentarians and Nantes manufacturers testify
once again to their awareness of the economic significance of the slave trade :
it provided work for thousands of craftsmen and sailors; m a n y hundreds of
people were employed in the textile mills and factories of London, Bristol,
Glasgow, Manchester, Nantes, Roanne, etc., working on raw materials from
West Indian and American plantations : products of sugar-cane, tobacco, cot-
ton, etc.
Undoubtedly, the greatest profits from the slave trade went to both
Americas. N o one denies the fact that for several centuries Brazil was actually
integrally linked with Africa and that the greatest number of slaves were
imported into Brazil. But less is written of the significance of the African slave
trade for the United States of America, or of the fact that 'it was the sale of
Africans in the N e w World—the slave trade—that laid thefinancialfoundation
of the United States'.17 Nevertheless, history has preserved the testimony of
contemporaries o n the importance of the slave trade for the United States
economy: w h e n the Declaration of Independence was put u p for discussion
at the Continental Congress the article denouncing the slave trade was exempted
from the text.18
In the eighteenth century the export of slaves increased yearly. According
to the (exaggerated) data of contemporaries, in the 1780s, when the movement
for the abolition of the slave trade began to develop in Europe and America,
100,000 Africans were exported yearly.
Viewing the events of those years from the present time one can single out the
following reasons for the abolition of the slave trade in the early nineteenth
century: the development of capitalist relations in European countries and
America in general; changes in Great Britain's economic policy—the result of
the breaking off of its Continental colonies; the impact of the French Revo-
lution with its ideas of liberation; the revolution of African slaves in Santo
D o m i n g o ; the growing number of slave uprisings in the West Indian colonies
as the result of the revolutionary events in France and Santo D o m i n g o ; the
upsurge of the abolitionist movement in nearly all the European countries.
The struggle to abolish the slave trade continued for several decades.
It acquired, to use present-day terminology, an international character and
was accompanied by sharp polemics between the abolitionists and their oppo-
nents, in the course of which there appeared m a n y books, brochures and p a m -
phlets depicting, often with pro and con exaggerations, the main ideological,
political, economic and religious views of that time on the slave trade.
22 S. U. Abramova
economies of the south of the United States of America, Great Britain and in
part France would be undermined; that incomes from mines in Brazil, C u b a
and other countries would fall, losses would be suffered by the shipbuilding
and textile industries, the makers offirearmsand other craftsmen, leaving
m a n y people without work.
Its protagonists admitted that the slave trade was a brutal affair but
that this brutality was not something peculiar to that trade alone. In conclu-
sion, facts would be adduced showing the brutal treatment of sailors in the
British Navy, or the cruellest European laws.
The advocates of the slave trade, like the abolitionists, said m u c h about
the Africans' awful life in their homeland, claiming that the slave trade had
nothing to d o with that side of the question : Africa had always been rent by
internecine warfare, slave raids, etc. Idyllic pictures would be given of life
in the N e w World plantations with the following conclusion: in the N e w
World Africans were m u c h better off than at h o m e , as for the state of slavery,
they were used to that in Africa. The defenders of the slave trade categorically
refuted the abolitionists' arguments o n the freedom-loving nature of Africans
and explained frequent uprisings on the slave ships only because of brutal
treatment.
The advocates categorically claimed that enslavement of Africans and
the slave trade were sanctioned by the Bible. They alluded to N o a h ' s damnation
of H a m and his progeny as evidence of the fact that Africans were predestined
to be slaves. Nevertheless, there was no single opinion on the slave trade a m o n g
the clergy, and especially so in Great Britain. The Bishop of London, for
instance, reminded people that the Bible wrote of slavery in general and not
with regard to Africans, and that it did not mention the slave trade or the
export of Africans to the N e w World. 2 1 At that time these doubts did not become
widespread. But in the nineteenth century, w h e n the question of abolishing
slavery in the British West Indies was put u p for discussion in Great Britain,
even the most rabid protagonists of slavery refrained from quoting the Bible.
A t that time m a n y books were published explaining that the Bible did not
sanction the enslavement of Africans.
T h e Quakers were a m o n g those w h o came out against the slave trade.
In the late seventeenth century the American Quakers voiced slogans to abolish
it. In Great Britain, the Quakers submitted a petition for the abolition of the
slave trade in 1783, and in the nineteenth century they were thefirstto d e m a n d
the abolition of slavery in the West Indian colonies.
Beginning of racism
In those years it was widely claimed that Africans in general were intellectually
inferior to Europeans, that Negroes, using the expression of those days, stood
24 S. U. Abramova
closer in the line of development to apes than to h u m a n beings. This was the
beginning of racism in regard to Africans.
W e shall not dwell here on racism in general, its origin, or h o w it was
and is manifested in different epochs and a m o n g different peoples. This report
deals in brief with the times when racialism in regard to Africans began to
assume the form of theory.
In the works of Azurara, Cadamosto and Pacheco Pereira, Portuguese
sailors w h o m a d e voyages to Africa before the beginning of the transatlantic
slave trade, no racist views are expressed. W h e n Europeansfirstcame into
contact with the Negro race, Africans were not looked upon as inferior beings.
They could not be regarded as the Europeans' equal partners because priority
belonged to those w h o were stronger. But if the newly discovered lands had
been inhabited by non-black people having the same level of development as
the Africans encountered there, relations between the Europeans and the local
population would have developed in m u c h the same way. A t that time the
stress was not on racial but religious intolerance. A n d historians are well
aware that religious intolerance was displayed not only with regard to Africans
and not only in those times.
After the extermination of the Indians in the French and British West
Indies, white slaves were brought there to work alongside Africans (see above).
In the writings of those years w e do notfindany racial pronouncements against
African slaves. White and black slaves worked shoulder to shoulder on the
plantations and were subject to equally brutal treatment.
In the late seventeenth and early eighteenth centuries m a n y works were
published by slave-traders and clerks employed in the numerous African trade
companies. A m o n g these authors one finds Barbot, Snelgrave, Bosman,
Phillips et al.22 Serving first as guidebooks (with the exception of Phillips'
book in which he openly pities African slaves), informing slave-traders of the
most profitable slave markets and means of delivering slaves with the least
possible losses to the N e w World, they were written in a business language.
Books written at the time by slave-traders contained no racialist views.
Discourse on the alleged inferiority of Africans as compared with Euro-
peans took place not a m o n g slave-traders but in quite different quarters.
In 1781, the work of P. Camper, a Dutch physician and naturalist and a
well-known scientist of his time,23 appeared. Employing in his studies of skele-
tons of h u m a n beings and apes the facial angle, a measure he introduced,
Camper concluded that the facial angle of Africans came nearer to that of
apes rather than of Europeans. C a m p e r merely stated his conclusions, but his
followers, including C . White, 24 used the distinctions between skeletons oi
people belonging to different races and apes to claim that Europeans were in
general superior to Africans not only physically but also intellectually. The prota-
gonists of the slave trade were quick to m a k e use of this conclusion.
Ideological, doctrinal, religious and political 25
aspects of the African slave trade
Neither before the beginning of the slave trade nor while it was conducted
freely and legally did any doubt arise as to the Africans' inferiority to Euro-
peans. But w h e n it became necessary to prove the need for its continuation,
economic and religious arguments lacking sufficient conviction were augmented
by racialist theory. All the basic racialist provisions against Africans were
put forth during the struggle for abolition. F r o m its very beginning racialism
had a purely auxiliary character. It was needed to legalize the continuation
of the slave trade and sanction slavery in the American colonies, as well as
to prove that Africans, owing to the inferiority of their race, were fated to be
slaves of the superior Europeans.
The slave trade and racism engendered by it turned the concept of 'slave'
from a social distinction into a racial one. Racism is the most odious heritage
of the slave-trade epoch.
In the early nineteenth century two of the biggest slave-trading powers
abolished the slave trade: Great Britain in 1807 and the United States of
America in 1808.
The year 1808 ushered in the third and last period in the history of the slave
trade, that of illegal export of slaves from Africa. The official abolition of the
slave trade in Great Britain and the United States did not reduce the number
of slaves coming from Africa. In the early nineteenth century, the labour of
slaves in N e w World plantations and mines was just as profitable and enabled
planters and manufacturers to receive high profits. The retention of slavery
in the N e w World after the slave trade was abolished predetermined the large-
scale development of the illegal slave trade, for not a single slave-trading coun-
try was ready to substitute hired labour for the work of slaves.
These factors determined the attitude of different States to the slave
trade in the nineteenth century. O f the big slave-trading countries Great
Britain was the only one that found it more profitable to struggle against the
slave trade than to take part in it. B y that time its main colonial interests had
switched from the West Indies to the East Indies. Besides, British industry
called for increasing amounts of raw materials and n e w markets, and in this
respect its interests became concentrated on Africa. Great Britain headed an
international campaign to abolish the export of slaves from Africa. This allowed
her to preserve till today the reputation of an allegedly disinterested champion
of Africans' freedom. Foreseeing the emergence of its future colonies in Africa,
Great Britain found it highly profitable to pose as a liberator in the eyes of
Africans.
Undoubtedly the anti-slave blockage played a substantial role in curbing
the export of slaves. Moreover, the first African scientists and public leaders
26 S. U. Abramova
Historiography
A century has gone by since the abolition of the Atlantic European Slave
Trade. 28 The international situation has changed as well as the place of African
countries a m o n g other States: former colonies have become independent. A
genuine history of the African peoples is in preparation : The General History
of Africa, thefirstvolumes of which will soon be published under Unesco
auspices. It stands to reason that the slave-trade problem, incorporating numer-
ous complex and often contradictory points, has become in recent years a
subject of particular interest to historians in different countries.
T h e history of the slave trade is n o w depicted in different ways and
sometimes receives a new interpretation (Boahen, Curtin, Duignan, Clendensen
et a/.). a7 It is clear that the historiography of the slave trade is a separate,
highly important and interesting theme.
T h e history of the slave trade is n o w studied by African historians,
and a m o n g them Boahen, Ajayi et al.,3* and this is particularly interesting.
African scholars are able to m a k e a m u c h better evaluation of the scale of the
Atlantic slave trade and its consequences in Africa than European historians.
Undoubtedly some questions have to be revised. It is utterly wrong to
assert, for instance, that Africans themselves are to blame for the development
of the slave trade or to speak of equal co-operation between European and
African slave traders, just as it is absolutely incorrect to exaggerate, as has
been done in the last few years, the role of the Arab slave trade in East Africa
while diminishing the role and consequences of the Atlantic trade.
A point for consideration : for m a n y years historians adopted the figures
of Africa's losses from the slave trade given by Dunbar and adduced by
28 S. U. Abramova
Notes
Michèle Duchet
The problems of trading and dealing in black slaves, and slavery as such, can
clearly not be dissociated: the various anti-slavery movements indeed also
denounced the inhumanity of the traffic in h u m a n beings that drained ever-
increasing numbers of blacks from Africa over to America and the West
Indies. T h e petition submitted to the French National Assembly in 1790 by
the A m i s des Noirs (Friends of the Black People) refers to both ' the slave
trade and slavery ', and this is true of most of the works quoted,2 if only because
the initial step towards stamping out slavery was to put an end to the slave
trade. But experience has proved that it was perfectly possible to abolish one
without doing away with the other, whence the persistent resurgence of slavery.
They can therefore be seen as two distinct forms of h u m a n exploitation which
are probably closely linked but must not be confused. Indeed, they never were
in the minds of those w h o fought either to preserve or abolish them. I shall
try to explain w h y this was, and review the arguments put forward and the
interests at stake.
It would be impossible here to relate the whole history of the slave trade3
but a few relevant facts must be recalled. T h e Spaniards were thefirstto take
black slaves across to the N e w World at the beginning of thefifteenthcentury.
But it was particularly from the seventeenth century onwards, with the devel-
opment of the great plantations—especially in Brazil—and the sugar economy,
that the slave trade really reached its zenith. It is estimated today that some 9
to 12 million Africans were embarked on the slave ships in the period from the
fifteenth to the end of the eighteenth century, the yearly average being 60,000.
The mortality rate on these vessels was high, but the profit to be m a d e was such
(300 per cent) that this traffic was a significant factor in that era of capital
accumulation which preceded the Industrial Revolution. T h e slave trade was
profitable for two reasons: not only was this triangular traffic a source of
rapid enrichment for those w h o were involved in it, but it also brought pros-
perity to the colonies with the steady flow of labour it provided. For the first
of these two reasons, countries to which a particular colony did not even belong
could be seen to invest in the slave trade there, as did the Dutch in Brazil.4
For the second reason, companies were founded with the backing of the various
32 Michèle Ducket
mother countries and vied with foreign nations for the monopoly of the trade :
the French Compagnie du Sénégal et de Guinée was an example. The combina-
tion of these two factors meant that the whole of Europe was involved in this
abominable traffic, deriving enormous profit from it. Having thus attained
world-wide proportions, the slave trade overstepped the boundaries of the slave
economy as such; true, it was the keystone to that economy, but it developed
as an independent form of commerce, one of m a n y , and a particularly lucrative
one. It had its o w n trading stations and trade routes in Africa itself, involved
in the buying and selling of a n e w kind of merchandise, the black slave. A
whole set of practices grew up around it, both on land and at sea, designed to
keep the cargo alive, the value of the shipment being carefully assessed in
terms of the price it would fetch at the auction sales.8 T h e fact that people
had become accustomed to such high rates of profit, and the very existence of
the 'system' explain up to a point w h y the slave trade has subsisted to this day.
For the abolition of slavery did not by any means imply the abolition
of the slave trade. Slavery was abolished by Great Britain in 1807, Brazil in
1836, France in 1848, Argentina in 1853 and the United States in 1865, to give
only a few examples. But the slave trade continued to exist to satisfy the demand
for labour in certain countries, and subsequently the demand for 'forced
labour', the modern brand of slavery. Furthermore, in some places, 'a fusion
of the two forms of slave trade, the Atlantic and the Arabized trade', had
occurred; Moorish traders took their slaves to the Niger delta or the Upper
Sangha basin and sold them to European traders.8 With the slowing d o w n of
slave traffic to America, the older routes were revived and the caravans simply
changed direction without the trade itself being affected.7
Thus it was that shiploads of slaves continued to pour into the Dutch
colonies until as late as 1862, and into Brazil until 1887. Thus it was that m e n
like Savorgnan de Brazza and later Monseigneur Augouard had reason to
report numerous cases of transactions in h u m a n lives in the Oubangui region
at the end of the nineteenth century.8 A n d thus it is that to this day, the United
Nations still receives reports attesting to the continued existence of slavery
and the slave trade in the Arab countries. A n d yet from thefifteenthto the
twentieth century, there has been no dearth of protests, decrees and laws on
the subject, which ought to have succeeded in eradicating such practices,
whilst the countries of Africa, with their accession to independence, were at
last freeing themselves from the fear of servitude, forced migration and exile.
This calls for a re-examination of history, an investigation of anti-slavery
'opinion': O f what did it consist? W h o spoke out against the slave trade and
slavery? W h a t did they say? W h a t were their arguments and what reasons
did they give? W h y this struggle? W a s it purely a matter of defending the cause
of black slaves, or was there some other underlying cause ? W h a t part did the
black people themselves play in that struggle ? These are all questions that can
Reactions to the problem 33
of the slave trade
only be answered by ignoring details of facts and events and going in each
case to the heart of the matter : the overall conjuncture, constraints, official
attitudes, the issues at stake, ideologies. I shall therefore deal separately with
two distinct periods, divided in terms of the prevailing 'conjuncture':
F r o m thefifteenthto the end of the eighteenth century. This was the age of
slavery as an institution and the economic system to which it was linked.
The 'abolitionist' trend was very slow to develop, and only reached its
peak with the independence of the American colonies.
In the nineteenth and twentieth centuries, there was a strong anti-slavery
movement and it had w o n the legal battle, but 'forced labour' and the
slave trade gained m o m e n t u m in defiance of h u m a n rights. The fact that
they were carried o n clandestinely meant that the anti-slavery cause
became a humanitarian battle.
evidence of any concern in the matter, and when in 1557 the Jesuit Manuel de
Nobrega requested permission to buy more slaves, the Order blamed Miguel
Garcia, w h o had dared to protest against it.12 The fact that the clergy in the
Spanish and Portuguese colonies owned thousands of slaves was regarded as
proof of the so-called legitimacy of the slave trade by the Council of the Indies.
In addition it was imperative not to let the slave trade fall into the hands of
'heretic' nations. With a clear conscience, Catholics and Protestants vied with
each other to secure the market for themselves. Thus it was that the problem of
the slave trade came to the fore in a case which took place in 1685, w h e n a
G e r m a n Protestant, Balthazar C o y m a n s , upon request for a concession, met
with the reply from the Spanish theologians Molina, Sanchez and Sandoval,
w h o had been consulted on the matter, that there was nothing to be said
against trading in slaves if it served the true Faith, but that the souls of the
blacks were in grave danger of being contaminated by a voyage on board a
heretic vessel ! 1 3
It m a y be said, however, that Protestants and Catholics shared the same
evangelical ideal and that the image of the faithful servant subject to divine
law and the authority of a kindly master was enough to reassure a Christian
conscience. But there still remained the problem of persecution of the indi-
vidual—in Africa, on board the slave ships, at the slave markets—in short,
within the actual framework of the whole slave system. The deliberately sus-
tained myth of m e n taken as slaves and then sold to dealers by the Africans
themselves, the alleged care taken by slave traders to look after their shipments
of slaves, was all cast in doubt when it came to the third stage of proceedings,
the slave markets, whose iniquities could not be disguised. The rest transpired
through accounts by missionaries and travellers. In 1571, a theologian from
Seville, T o m a s de Mercado, showed just h o w far the slave trade was contrary
to proper commercial practice and humanitarian principles. Although he
acknowledged the fact that slavery and the sale of African slaves by the Africans
themselves did exist, he spoke out against the way traders would foment inter-
necine conflicts as a means of capturing prisoners. H e described conditions
on board the ships and protested against the alarming mortality rate. His
protest was all the more significant in that it was aimed at the slave trade and
not simply slavery as such. Other theologians14 were to express similar views,
challenging the 'good faith' of the traders to w h o m the prisoners were handed
over, and w h o would undiscriminatingly carry off m e n , w o m e n and children.
Christian tradition, as w e k n o w , holds that any business transaction must be
legitimate, and proscribes fraud or excessive profit; the black slave trade was
therefore inadmissible, even if one of its functions was to supply the plantations
with slaves w h o would ultimately become Christians. Traders whose consciences
were not clear were therefore urged by Mercado to speak to their confessors!16
It would be pointless to deny the fact that the theologians' standpoint
Reactions to the problem 35
of the slave trade
had the advantage of keeping the system fundamentally intact (the plantation
and mission economy, and the tacit approval of the local clergy) and only
attacking traders and company agents whose lucrative ventures could deserv-
edly cause an outcry. Nevertheless, by drawing attention, through the very
arguments they put forward, to the fact that the system depended entirely on
a form of commerce which consisted in trading in h u m a n lives, and in which
slaves of both sexes and of all ages exchanged hands in lots as though they
were commodities and not h u m a n beings belonging to the same ethnic group
or family, a form of commerce in which people were treated on the slave-ships
as no animal would ever have been treated, those w h o raised these questions
sowed the seeds of doubt in m a n y a mind : could one take delivery of these
slaves without another thought for the inhumanity of the whole process ?
The Protestants had inherited the same 'dualistic'16 tradition as the
Catholics, accepting the existence of slavery but not the fact of reducing a
m a n to slavery by unjust and violent means. They believed even more firmly
than the Catholics that in a world fraught with sin, slavery was a means of
redemption for those w h o m G o d had reduced to that state. They, too, proposed
to spread the W o r d to the servile masses, but their far more rigorous doctrine
dictated other means of achieving this end. They did their utmost to improve
master-slave relations, preaching charity and moderation to the former and
submission and respect to the latter. Richard Baxter would say to the slaves :
reverence that providence of G o d which calleth you to a servant's life, and murmur
not at your labour or your low condition, but know your mercies, and be thankful
for them. 17
This ideology of the 'good slave' and the 'good master' was based not only
on a theological precept (the proper exercise of 'servitude'), but was also in
keeping with the moral standards of everyday life, so typically Protestant; in
keeping, too, with the ideal of Christian brotherhood.
At any rate, far from being opposed to the slave trade, the Protestants
saw in it a means to serve the cause of evangelization ; and it must not be
forgotten that in the Protestant world the success of commercial undertakings
was evidence of divine approval, and that when it came to deciding w h o was
to blame, to put all the onus on the greedy, ruthless dealer rather than the
planter, was positively unthinkable. W e shall see, moreover, that the concept
of sin plays a decisive role in religious ideology. Let m e simply say at this
juncture that whereas for the Catholics, the wicked trader was more to blame
than the master w h o owned the slaves, Protestant ethics required that the master
be held responsible for the slaves w h o m G o d had bestowed on him for their
mutual benefit.
36 Michèle Ducket
Sects
traders and dealers prevented her from feeling the burden of those black peoples
coming to die on her plantations. A land of exile and frustration, she had
nothing to offer her slaves other than slavery. Thus the abolitionists were
constantly confronted with the eternal logic of the system. At the beginning
of the eighteenth century, the Anglican Church's only answer to the expansion
of the slave trade was a great campaign to 'christianize' slaves, thereby
shelving the issue, as it were, and resigning itself to making Christians of those
of w h o m it could not m a k e free m e n .
economy, and these theories were hardly an incitement to use black labour.
But in a world in which the law of profit prevailed, the economic argument
carried most weight, overriding humanitarian considerations and offering in
exchange for 'compassion' a distinctly worldly reward, i.e. better yields. W e
might ask to what extent this form of anti-slavery was compatible with a code
of ethics and h o w far it was instrumental in preparing for the changes that
would inevitably come about.
In France, the realism of the Physiocrats was just as ambiguous ; it was
chiefly an answer to the actual crisis in the slave system, put into words by its
administrators.31 S o m e of them were reformists, like Pierre Poivre w h o in 1766
urged the H e de France settlers to treat their slaves with 'humanity' and not to
lose sight of the fact that they were ' m e n like themselves'. In exchange, the
slave would 'serve his master joyfully and faithfully'.32 Others condemned the
evils of the slave 'system' from the economic standpoint; at all stages of the
process there were losses, because of the increased difficulty of carrying on the
trade and therefore the higher selling price, because of the overworking of
badly cultivated land, the excessively high mortality rate, militia expenses,
time wasted, and because of the insecurity, indeed the hostility, of the slaves :
'The slave is lazy because it is his only enjoyment in life, and his only way of
recapturing a part of himself robbed wholesale by his master. 'S3
There were others w h o believed in gradual emancipation, so that over
a period of twenty years the slave masses would become free workers. L'His-
toire des Deux Indes, written in 1780, reflected such a project proposed by
Bessner, the governor of Guiana. But Raynal's work gave prominence to the
ideas of the economists, set out between 1765 and 1775 in the Ephémérides du
Citoyen: w h y not let Africa itself produce the commodities that America n o w
supplied? W h y not resettle the black slaves in Africa, where they would be
free? Admittedly this solution would entail keeping on the slave trade, but
it would do away with slavery which was detrimental to the economy of the
plantations.34 Humanitarianism thus upheld the theories of the Physiocrats,
and the poet Saint-Lambert, on publishing Ziméo in the economists' journal,
wrote to Dupont de Nemours : ' It is an act of charity for you to take u p the
cause of these poor Negroes; I have always pitied them greatly . . .'.35
Pity, humanitarianism, philanthropy—these three words aptly s u m u p
the reactions of the eighteenth-century philosophers to the problem of slavery
and the slave trade. But with Buffon, Voltaire and Bernardin de Saint-Pierre,38
the emphasis was on moral condemnation. Helvétius' critique was consistent
with the views of the Physiocrats, but was more political : one must be careful
not to destroy the principle of self-interest which motivates m e n , and seen in
that light slavery is a mistake as well as a crime.37 A horror of the 'system' was
the subject of most attacks, and in Voltaire's Candide, the Negro of Surinam
w h o was mutilated in compliance with the Black Code on runaway slaves,
40 Michèle Ducket
was a sort of symbol of all the sufferings the black m a n was m a d e to endure,
and with impunity, for the law condoned slavery and all the hardships that went
with it. In most cases, their accusations were by the same token an extension
of their denunciation of the bloodthirsty, barbaric practices of so-called 'civi-
lized' peoples, of the pervading spirit of intolerance which corrupted all their
undertakings, of vain conquests and futile voyages.38 T h e cause of the black
slaves gave rise to a sense of helplessness reflected fairly accurately in this
quotation from Helvétius : 39 ' Let us avert our gaze from such a baneful sight,
which is so shameful and abhorrent to mankind. '
It is as though the very universality of enlightened philosophical thought
deterred it from undertaking a 'charitable action' at a time when a radical
change in mankind and society was imminent, from serving a cause which was
not sufficiently in the interests of progress, as was, for example, the case of
Calas, a victim of religious intolerance.
There is a well-known chapter in Montesquieu's Esprit des Lois, in which
he questions what 'right w e had to m a k e the Negroes slaves' and in which
there is this sentence, showing h o w injustice (in the strongest meaning of that
which is unlawful) follows injustice: ' T h e peoples of Europe, having extermi-
nated those of America, had to reduce the peoples of Africa to slavery, in
order to use them to clear all that land for cultivation.'40
'Might is right' is the only law here. This was clearly stated, but the
' point of law' was not dealt with, for the fact that there was nothing in religious
texts debarred a 'jurist' from giving a straightforward opinion.41 It was not
until 1780, in the Histoire des Deux Indes, a 'philosophical and political'
history, that the principle of freedom was defended against any ' reasons of
state'. Freedom is 'the ownership of one's body and the possession of one's
mind'. T h e government does not have the right to sell slaves, the trader did
not have the right to buy them, and no one has the right to sell himself.42
Thus politics and ethics must join together to bring freedom to enslaved
peoples, even before the other nations have shaken off their o w n chains. T h e
idea of a 'one and indivisible' freedom emerges here from the crucible of the
Enlightenment, and turns all causes into one great cause. Because of the uni-
versal nature of its principles, 'practice' outweighs theory, the defence of the
'rights of m a n ' is in itself an instrument of progress and justice, whether that
m a n be a 'savage' or a 'civilized' being, whether black, mulatto or white, and
whatever his nationality or religion m a y be.
But the Histoire des Deux Indes went m u c h further than that humani-
tarian protest. It emphasized the Negroes' o w n revolt and the ' maroon ' p h e n o m -
enon, the significance of which has often been underestimated in the history
of slavery.
A thorough study of texts and documents on slavery shows that the
fear of slaves becoming maroons was a predominant factor in Europe's 'guilty
Reactions to the problem 41
of the slave trade
freedom to the Negroes. In 1802, Napoleon was to restore the slave trade and
slavery in the French colonies. In America, where the whole economy depended
on slave labour and slave traffic, the question was raised of h o w to reconcile
the founding of a new nation with an institution which implied non-citizenship.
In 1787, the Northwest Ordinance prohibited slavery in a third of the territory,
and there were m a n y separate instances of manumission in some of the states.
But of the thirteen states, eight were to maintain slavery. After Independence,
abolitionist literature abounded, refuting the racist arguments. 'Christian and
humanitarian motives combine with the principles of liberal ideology' to prove
that the new nation could not act against the very precepts on which it was
founded.49 But most of them trusted in democracy to bring about the gradual
decline of the institution.
The principles which are the basis of the Government of the United States will uner-
ringly lead to the extinction of slavery throughout the empire, as soon as it is compat-
ible with public security and the welfare of the slaves themselves.60
But there was still no question of slaves being integrated into the American
nation, w e have the example of T h o m a s Jefferson accepting the emancipation
of the Negroes but proposing to dispatch them to Sierra Leone B 1 or even to
Santo D o m i n g o . The English philanthropist, T h o m a s Clarkson, had written
a pamphlet which was republished in Philadelphia in 1788. Written for the
British public for the sole purpose of condemning the slave trade, it also pro-
posed a means whereby the Americans could 'carry on the Transatlantic trade
while ethicizing it'.62 The blacks would be sent back to Africa, and thenceforth
there would no longer be a slave trade, but a trade in the products of their
labour. It is of some significance that at this decisive point in its history, the
United States had only economic, if humanitarian, solutions to offer, and that
no mention was m a d e of slavery in its Constitution. A s Elise Marienstras so
aptly puts it: 'Recognized in theory as a m e m b e r of the h u m a n species, the
American Negro was granted none of the prerogatives universally attributed
to mankind by current ideology.'63
A s w e k n o w , it was Great Britain w h o , with the loss of her American
colonies, was thefirstto launch an abolitionist campaign, in 1787. The London
Anti-Slavery Society (Wilberforce, Clarkson, Pitt, Grainville, Fox and Burke)
prompted the founding of the French Society in 1788 (Condorcet, Brissot,
Lafayette, Mirabeau, a number oí fermiers-généraux (tax-farmers) and adminis-
trators and a few merchants). The main target was the slave trade; but here
again, economic and humanitarian motives were inextricably linked: Great
Britain wanted to put an end to a form of trade which brought wealth to the
Americans, and the French saw the abolition of the slave trade as a means to
stamp out slavery. In the documents of the Société des Amis des Noirs—
Reactions to the problem 43
of the slave trade
After being a vast reservoir of slaves, Africa was to become the battleground
for European imperialism. Each country carved out its o w n stronghold, and the
old trading stations were often used as a launching ground for prosperous
settlements. Colonization was an excuse for every possible form of intervention:
military expeditions bought slaves from local traders to use them as 'volun-
teers'; w h e n villages were taken, their inhabitants were also captured, and
shown little mercy. A n d w h e n the need arose, African labour continued to be
exported, especially to the United States and Brazil. T h e nationality of the
44 Michèle Ducket
the entry of 'slave' captives and caravans into the Sudan, the slave-traders
promptly declared that the 'captives' were 'free, wage-earning' porters.60
The facts were there : but h o w to put a stop to the slave trade and slavery
w h e n there were 'contracts', 'salaries' and an apparent lack of constraint?
M o r e than ever, to preserve the rights of individuals, it was the slave trade
which had to be attacked. Even if there were no coercion, deportation with
no chance of return constituted in effect a state of slavery, since the 'contrac-
tual ' labourer was at the mercy of his employers. H e was alienated, hence he
was no longer 'free'; slavery had wrested him from his h o m e , m a d e him an
exile, a captive. In West Africa, the decree of 1905 was aimed at 'any person
w h o has entered into an agreement whose object is to deprive a third person
of his liberty'.61 It is clear enough from the terms of the decree that the legis-
lator's words should, by looking beyond the actual facts of the case, be taken
to m e a n the intention of the guilty party to reduce a m a n to slavery, even if
that man's status was not that of a slave. A n d yet the traffic continued, espe-
cially in the more remote parts of the globe, and only changes in the economic
situationfinallybrought about its extinction.
There was, of course, no lack of humanitarian protests, but the colonial
system was not concerned about slavery save in the case of'household' slaves,
and so it was easy to denounce traditional practices in Africa which had been
the basis of the Atlantic slave trade. A s for the export of labour for the purpose
of 'depriving a third person of his liberty', it was far too useful to be prohib-
ited, as was illustrated only too well when, in 1947, the inspector of the Angolan
Colonial Service, w h o was a m e m b e r of the Portuguese Parliament, submitted
a report on 'forced labour' in Angola, 62 only to be given a seven-year prison
sentence for his courage.
A s for the 'missions', it is extremely difficult to assess their role. Their
c o m m o n ideology was to spread the Gospel, but charity often prompted them
to m a k e 'humanitarian' gestures, and the fact that they were settled perma-
nently in the colonies facilitated their action.63 A s far as the R o m a n Catholic
Church was concerned, Pope Gregory X V I had condemned the slave trade as
being an 'inhuman . . . commercium' in 1838, and Leo XIII denounced slavery
in 1888, instructing Monseigneur Lavigerie to oppose its establishment in the
French colonies. But on the whole, churches and missions supported coloniza-
tion, preferring to focus their attacks on slave trading in the Muslim countries,
thereby killing two birds with one stone. T h e Protestant missionary Fowel
Buxton 64 led an expedition into the interior in an attempt to sap the very
foundations of the slave trade (around 1840) but the discovery at this time of a
route to the Sudan by a Turkish captain oponed up n e w trade outlets, and some
60,000 slaves fell victim to the new trade. A s in the earlier period, opposition
to the slave trade and slavery came chiefly from religious sects, particularly
the Evangelicals. O n e of the most fervent activists was Sir T h o m a s Fowel
46 Michèle Ducket
The discovery of gold and silver in America, the extirpation, enslavement and entomb-
ment in mines of the aboriginal population . . . the turning of Africa into a warren for
the commercial hunting of black-skins, signalized the rosy dawn of the era of capitalist
production. These idyllic proceedings are the chief momenta of primitive accumulation
. . . slavery . . . is the sole natural basis of colonial wealth.67
Liverpool waxed fat on the slave-trade. This was its method of primitive accumulation.
A n d , even to the present day, Liverpool 'respectability' is the Pindar of the slave-trade
which . . . has coincided with that spirit of bold advent which has characterized the
trade of Liverpool and rapidly carried it to its present state of prosperity; has occa-
sioned vast employment for shipping and sailors, and greatly augmented the demand
for the manufactures of the country.68
T h e profit derived from the slave trade itself is compounded by the profit
m a d e out of menial labour: merchants, slave-traders and planters share the
gains of a system which pushes h u m a n exploitation to limits hitherto u n k n o w n .
Reactions to the problem 47
of the slave trade
Treated as a mere commodity, bought, sold and exchanged, the slave still
provides the labour power needed for the production of colonial wealth.
Whereas the wage-earner sells his labour 'freely' (even if that freedom is
illusory), it is 'the labour-power itself which is sold' (by a third party) with the
body of the slave. Hence:
'The horrors of overwork, that product of civilization, serve to augment
the barbarity of slavery and bondage', 89 and the slave trade, prompt to supply
needs, makes it unnecessary to ensure that the individual slave survives. Only
his productivity counts. Slavery sanctions the slave trade, but the slave trade
sanctions slavery: this is the logic of the system which fostered the transition
to industrial capitalism. This, in turn, was to throw men-as-commodities on
to the market, perpetuating the trade in h u m a nfleshand the overwork resulting
from it. Although he denounces the atrocities of the slavery system, M a r x
demonstrates the vanity of humanitarian idealism70 which depicts the revolt
of the slave as a triumph of a certain concept of mankind. 'The rebellious
negroes of Haiti and the fugitive negroes of all the colonies' wanted to free
themselves, not mankind, and theirfightbecomes an example for all w h o are
exploited.71 N o r is it possible to humanize an inhuman system; one must expose
its economic causes and the social relationships brought about by the cir-
cumstances of the quest for profit and by overwork; 72 the struggle against
menial work must be harnessed to the struggle against the exploitation of free
workers, and to the struggle against capital.
However, at the international level, liberalism had a useful role in carrying
on the combat against the wrongs of the system, until such time as the peoples
were able to throw off the colonialist yoke for themselves. But the problem lay
in knowing whether it was the abolition of slavery and the slave trade in the
strict sense they werefightingfor, or whether that included all forms of slavery
and the trade in h u m a n beings stemming from the exploitation of the African
labourers. A n International Labour Office report published in Geneva in 1953
rightly recalls that even though the slave trade and slavery had been condemned
by conferences and conventions throughout the nineteenth century, there had
never been any mention of 'forced labour as an institution distinct from
slavery'. Hence the existence of some confusion both in terminology and in
people's minds. T h e 1890 Brussels anti-slavery conference condemned the
Arab-centred slave trade, the 1885 Berlin conference prohibited slavery and
the traffic in h u m a n beings. Article 22 of the League of Nations Covenant
(1920) mentions together 'the prohibition of abuses such as the slave trade'
and the prevention of compulsory service in certain mandated territories.
The Temporary Slavery Commission placed slavery on a par with 'similar
forms of servitude'. It provided for compulsory repatriation in the event of
work involving the removal of a labourer from his usual place of residence,
thereby defining forced labour unequivocally as a form of servitude w h e n the
48 Michèle Dachet
Notes
1. Certain original English texts being unobtainable, a free English translation has been
given.
2. La Revolution Française et l'Abolition de l'Esclavage, Textes et Documents, Vol. VIII,
Part 2, Paris, E D H I S , 1968. See Clarkson's Essai sur l'Esclavage et le Commerce
de l'Espèce Humaine, Falconbridge's Tableau de la Traite, etc.
3. Data taken from P . D . Curtin, The Atlantic Slave Trade, 1969; See also H . Deschamps,
Histoire de la Traite des Noirs et l'Antiquité à nos Jours, Paris, Fayard, 1971.
4. See Celso Furtado, La Formation Économique du Brésil, de l'Époque Coloniale aux
Temps Modernes, The Hague, M o u t o n , 1972. T h e Dutch were also to seize the
monopoly of the slave trade in the Spanish territories.
5. These practices are described in the ships' logs, and in some accounts by travellers.
6. Pierre Kalck, Histoire de la République Centrafricaine des Origines Préhistoriques à
nos Jours, Vol. I, p. 140, note 276.
7. According to some historians, it was because of the reconversion of the Atlantic slave
trade that the Saharan trade grew to unprecedented proportions. See J. Suret-
Canale, L'Afrique Noire, Vol. I, p. 162 (Ed. Sociales).
8. P . Kalck, op. cit., p. 139-40.
9. Histoire Philosophique et Politique des Établissements des Européens dans les Deux
Indes, IV, 20, A b b é Raynal, É d . de Neuchatel, 1783.
10. Quoted in P . Larroque, De l'Esclavage chez les Nations Chrétiennes, p. 31-2, Paris,
1864.
11. Francisco de Vittoria, Francisco Suarez; but these sixteenth-century documents, like
those of Paul III or Pius V , relate to the Indians.
12. Serafim Leite, Historia da Companhia de Jesus, II, p. 347 et seq.
13. G . Scelle, La Traite Négrière . . ., I, p. 708-11.
14. Bartolomé de Albornoz, T o m a s Sanchez; see David Brion Davis, The Problem of
Slavery in Western Culture, p. 189-90, Cornell University Press, 1966.
15. Summa de Tratos, y Contratos . . ., Chap. 20, Seville, 1587.
16. David Brion Davis, op. cit., p. 198. M y analysis is very close to that of D . B . Davis
in his remarkable work.
17. Quoted in Davis, op. cit., p. 204. Baxter was an English Protestant w h o had been sent
out to Barbados. Appalled by the evils he saw in the colonies, he wrote a ' S u m m
of Practical Theology and Cases of Conscience'.
18. Davis, op. cit., p. 294.
Reactions to the problem 51
of the slave trade
19. ibid., Chap. 10. See Elbert Russell, The History of Quakerism, N e w York, 1942, on
all these points.
20. 1769, I X . Letter from D r Benjamin Rush to Barbeu-Dubourg.
21. Vol. VIII, p. 235.
22. Davis, op. cit., p. 213.
23. Quoted by Davis, op. cit., p. 338.
24. The title of his pamphlet is significant: Trade Preferred before Religion . . ., London,
1695.
25. Davis, op. cit., p. 345.
26. Hoxie N . Fairchild, Religious Trends in English Poetry, I. Protestantism and the Cult
of Sentiment, N e w York, 1939-49.
27. Inquiry Concerning Virtue or Merit, translated into French by Diderot in 1745 : ' . . . the
eternal wisdom governing this universe has linked the personal interest of G o d ' s
creature to the overall good of his system, so that he cannot pass one by without
stepping aside from the other, or fail in his duty to his fellow-men without doing
harm to himself.'
28. His System of Moral Philosophy dates from 1755. Sloane was the author of a History
of Jamaica, Atkins had published an account of a Voyage to Guinea and Brazil. . .,
London, 1735, in which he depicted the atrocities of the slave trade.
29. System of Moral Philosophy, II, p. 202 et seq.
30. The Theory of Moral Sentiments, 1759; An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the
Wealth of Nations, 1776.
31. See Michèle Duchet, 'L'Idéologie Coloniale, la Critique du Système Esclavagiste',
Anthropologie et Histoire au Siècle des Lumières, Paris, 1971, I. 3.
32. ibid., Discours quoted, p. 148-9.
33. Dupont de Nemours, Ephémérides du Citoyen, VI, p. 216 et seq., 1771.
34. Histoire . . . des Deux Indes, V , p. 266, E d . Neuchatel, 1708.
35. Ephémérides du Citoyen, VI, p. 180-1, 1771.
36. See Duchet, op. cit., 'L'Anthropologie de Buffon', p. 278-9; 'L'Anthropologie de
Voltaire, p. 318-21. Racial prejudice in fact prevented Voltaire from going any
further.
37. De l'Homme, Section V I , Chap. I.
38. Essai sur les Moeurs, Chap. C X L I X , 1756.
39. De l'Esprit, I, Chap. 3.
40. Book X V , Chap. 5, 1748.
41. Hence the use of irony which permitted an indirect attack, but had the drawback of
being understood only by the initiated. Even in the eighteenth century, several
noteworthy misconceptions confirm the 'aristocratic' nature of this form of argu-
ment which came to be interpreted as a justification of slavery.
42. Vol. V , p. 275, et seq.
43. See Duchet, op. cit., p. 142-3 and 155-6. These 'colonies' subsisted; they are n o w the
Boni, from the n a m e of their leader, Bonnie.
44. Instructions of 30 November 1771.
45. Vol. VI.
46. Vol. V , p. 288.
47. E . D . Seeber, ' H u m a n i s m , Humanitism and Humanitarianism', Modern Language
Notes, X L I X , 1934. B y the same author, see Anti-slavery Opinion in France during
the Second Half of the Eighteenth Century, Baltimore, The Johns Hopkins Press,
1937.
48. Histoire des Deux Indes, Vol. V , p. 288.
52 Michèle Ducket
49. O n all these questions, see E . Marienstras, Les Mythes Fondateurs de la Nation Améri-
caine, p. 209 et seq., Paris, Maspéro, 1976.
50. Z . Swift, ' A n Oration on Domestic Slavery', 1791, quoted by Marienstras, op. cit.,
p. 257.
51. Where the English had founded a settlement of free Negroes w h o had fought during
the W a r of Independence.
52. Marienstras, op. cit., p. 267.
53. ibid., p. 275.
54. Petion, Discours sur la Traite des Noirs, op. cit., Part I, p. 1.
55. ibid., Part II, p. 2. (Frossard, Observations sur l'Abolition de la Traite des Nègres,
1793.)
56. ibid., p. 26-27.
57. See Celso Furtado, La Formation Économique du Brésil, de l'Époque Coloniale aux
Temps Modernes, p. 101 et seq., Paris and T h e Hague, M o u t o n , 1972. Furtado
points out that between 1827 and 1830, the slave trade increased, since the agree-
ment with England was due to c o m e to an end at that date. There was a further
increase prior to the ceasing of the trade in 1851-52. Between 1800 and 1860,
approximately 300,000 slaves were imported into the United States, most of them
clandestinely since the slave trade had been abolished since 1808 (p. 102, note 33).
58. See J. Duffy, Portugal in Africa, Harmondsworth, Penguin, 1962.
59. Comprising the leaders of the Aborigines Protective Society and the British and Foreign
Anti-slavery Society. T h e missionary, Charles Swan, published The Slavery of
Today, in L o n d o n in 1909.
60. J. Suret-Canale, op. cit., Il, p. 87.
61. ibid. The 1831 law applied only to sea traffic. It was thefirstdecree in Africa to prohibit
any kind of slave trade. But it was, of course, concerned only with the former
territories of French West Africa.
62. James Duffy, op. cit., p. 185. Henrique Galvao estimated that 2 million Africans had
been 'expatriated' in this way.
63. There is, of course, a good deal of controversy on the subject. Suggested reading:
Rev. Joseph Bouchard, L'Église en Afrique Noire, Paris, 1958; G . Goyau, La France
Missionnaire . . ., 2 vols., Paris, 1948; R . Cornevin, Histoire de l'Afrique, 2 vols.,
Paris, Payot, 1966.
64. Cornevin, op. cit., p. 456.
65. The African Slave and its Remedy, 1840. Quoted in M . Merle, L'Anticolonialisme
Européen de Las Casas à Marx, p. 221, Paris, Colin, 1969.
66. La Restauration de la Traite des Noirs au Natal, 1877. See also Esclavage et Colonisa-
tion, selected texts by V . Schoelcher, by E . Tersen. Preface by A i m é Césaire, Paris,
PUF, 1948.
67. Karl M a r x , Capital, p. 1212, E d . L a Pléiade, I.
68. Karl M a r x , Capital, Vol. I, p. 759, N e w York, International Publishers. The end of
the sentence is a quotation from Aikin, A Description of the Country from Thirty
to Forty Miles round Manchester, London, 1795.
62. ibid.
70. See in M a r x and Engels, German Ideology, London, Lawrence & Wishart, 1942, the
harsh criticism of the 'liberal' and individualist thesis of M a x Stirmer, author of
Der Einziger und sein Eigetum.
71. ibid.
72. O n the specific forms of profit within the slavery system, there are analyses more
precise than those of M a r x . For lines of research, see the 'Letter on Slavery',
R eactions to the problem 53
of the slave trade
Bibliography
Historical works
General works
C U R T I N , P . D . The Image of Africa; British Ideas and Action (1780-1850). Madison, Wis.,
University of Wisconsin Press, 1964.
D A V I S , D . B . The Problem of Slavery in Western Culture. N e w York, Cornell University
Press, 1966.
D U C H E T , M . Anthropologie et Histoire au Siècle des Lumières. Paris, Masporo, 1971.
F A I R C H I L D , H . N . Religious Trends in English Poetry. 3 vols. N e w York, Columbia Univer-
sity Press, 1939-49.
M A R I E N S T R A S , E . Les Mythes Fondateurs de la Nation Américaine. Paris, Masporo, 1976.
S E E B E R , E . D . Anti-slavery Opinion in France during the Second Half of the Eighteenth
Century. Baltimore, M d , The Johns Hopkins Press, 1937.
54 Michèle Duchet
Official documents
A w A D , M o h a m e d . Report on Slavery. N e w York, United Nations, 1967.
ILO Reports: 1953, Report of the A d H o c Committee on Forced Labour (Studies and
Reports, N e w Series N o . 38); 1929 Report, 'Forced Labour—Preliminary Report and
Questionnaire'.
T h e Atlantic slave trade
The slave trade and the
Atlantic economies, 1451-1870 *
Joseph E . Inikori
This article deals deals with all the regions of Africa directly affected by the
external slave trade from that continent across the Sahara, the Atlantic ocean,
the R e d Sea and the Indian Ocean. Other territories included are South and
North America, the West Indies and all Europe bordering on the Atlantic,
including those European countries affected by the activities of the Atlantic
countries. In some ways this definition of the scope of this paper is arbitrary.
It excludes some of the slave-receiving economies of the period, in particular,
those of the Middle East.2 O n the other hand, the economies included were not
all affected to the same degree by the slave trade; indeed, some were only
indirectly affected. However, the coverage of the territories mentioned makes
it possible to analyse in one broad sweep the effects of the slave trade on all the
economies most significantly affected.
The slave trade and slavery is a subject on which a great deal has already
been said and written, starting from the eighteenth century and continuing to
the present day. 3
But the existing studies have failed to fit the slave trade as a causal factor,
positive or negative, into a process analysis of economic development in the
major countries or territories that participated in it. This is what this article
tries to do. For that purpose the external slave trade from Africa is viewed as
a form of international trade whose effects on the countries or regions involved
in it, directly or indirectly, are analysed in economic terms. T h e paper is based
essentially on development as opposed to growth analysis. T h e distinction
between these two concepts is not always observed by writers. M o d e r n economic
growth is usually defined in terms of a sustained annual increase in income per
head of the entire population in a given economy, over a long period of time,
while economic development relates to the transformation of an economy from
a customary, subsistence, rural and regional stage, to a rational, commercial,
urban a n d national stage, with appropriate institutions for the efficient mobility
of factors. Often the transformation includes a major structural shift in the
economy, from primarily agricultural to primarily industrial. In the context of
Rostovian analysis, development belongs to the 'pre-condition' and 'take-off'
stages, while growth belongs to the post-take-off stages. T h e main question
The slave trade 57
and the Atlantic economies 1451-1870
which this article tries to tackle, therefore, is the extent to which the movements
of the various economies under review were accelerated or retarded by the
slave trade in those crucial stages of development. The analysis draws on the
concept of dynamic gains from international trade as opposed to the static gains
of classical analysis.*
Gulf, India and the islands on the Indian Ocean, no aggregate estimates of the
total numbers involved have been m a d e , F r o m the information available,* w e
m a y not be exaggerating if w e put the totalfiguresfor the whole of our period
at some 2 million.
Thus, the external slave trade from Africa south of the Sahara between
thefifteenthand nineteenth centuries, involved the export of not less than
19 million people.
system. Its function was limited to the acquisition and sale of slave labour. O n
the whole, of all the territories under review, only the north-eastern states of
North America performed economic functions closely resembling those per-
formed by Western Europe in the Atlantic system.
The character of functions performed by a given territory in the Atlantic
system was a crucial factor explaining the type of developmental effect which
the system produced in that territory. Trade, finance, shipping, manufacturing,
and commercial foodstuff production in medium-sized freehold farms tended
to produce m u c h greater positive developmental effects than plantation agri-
culture. However, the character of the functions does not fully explain the
differing developmental effects. It is significant that the territories which were
engaged mostly in plantation agriculture were also those in which 'foreign
factors of production' were most largely employed, using this concept in
Jonathan Levin's sense.10 A s a consequence, a very large proportion of the total
income produced in the Atlantic sectors of these economies was remitted
abroad. This was particularly so for the West Indian islands. This, together
with the character of the functions performed, left little or no room for a self-
sustained internal development to accompany the growth of activities in pro-
duction for an international market. In the Latin American territories the
operation of some internal factors, partly connected with the character of the
European colonists and the institutions they brought with them, further reduced
the overall positive effects of the Atlantic system for the internal development
of those economies. For these various reasons, the positive developmental
effects of the Atlantic system were largely concentrated in Western Europe and
North America.
The buying and shipping of slaves to the Americas formed one of the
most important functions fulfilled by Western Europe in the Atlantic system.
This proved to be a very demanding task, requiring considerable mercantile
skills, highly sophisticatedfinancialarrangements, refinements in shipbuilding
technology, and production of new types of goods demanded by the slave-
producing regions of tropical Africa. The creative response of the economies
of Atlantic Europe to the requirements of this function formed an important
part of the development process in those economies. Unfortunately, a detailed
study of the character of this response and an assessment of its place in the
process of economic development in Western Europe is only just receiving the
attention of scholars employing the analytical tools of development economics.
Thefirstof such studies, which has been m a d e on the British economy for the
period 1750-1807, 11 shows that during this period of about sixty years w h e n
Great Britain dominated the buying and shipping of slaves to the Americas, the
peculiar requirements of this function stimulated important developments in
key sectors and regions of the British economy. T h e slave merchants were
constantly exposed to considerable risks and so their regular and growing
60 Joseph E. Inikori
participated in the period 1451-1870. It will be shown later that thus pheno-
menal expansion of world trade was due largely to the availability of African
slave labour in the Americas. But for the m o m e n t w e have to establish the
relationship between this growth of world trade and the economic development
of Western Europe and North America.
Between the late Middle Ages and thefirsthalf of the seventeenth century
some very important internal developments occurred in West European econ-
omies, which were due to changes in some internal factors, such as population,
leading to the growth of intra-European trade, particularly in raw wool, woollen
products, metal products and silver, as well as inter-regional trade within the
individual West European countries. These early developments stimulated in
the different West European countries differing institutional changes, political,
social and economic. Particularly in Great Britain and Holland, the changes
which occurred at this time created
a hospitable environment for the evolution of a body of property rights which pro-
moted institutional arrangements, leading to fee-simple absolute ownership in land,
free labour, the protection of privately owned goods, patent laws and other encourage-
ments to ownership of intellectual property, and a host of institutional arrangements
to reduce market imperfection in product and capital markets.18
The main contribution of the Atlantic system to these early developments was
in the supply of bullion which greatly promoted the growth of exchange in
all Western Europe, thereby giving afillipto the expansion of the market
sector of West European economies. Besides this contribution, m u c h of West
European development at this early stage depended on European resources.
The 'hospitable environment' created by these early developments are very
important in explaining the responsiveness of West European economies to
the external stimuli emanating from the growth of world trade from the second
half of the seventeenth century onwards.
But, it is one thing to say that these early internal developments m a d e
West European economies responsive to external stimuli arising from the
growth of the Atlantic system. It is quite another thing to say that from these
early developments the institutional arrangements that evolved in Western
Europe between the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries, and that great
structural transformation called the Industrial Revolution which occurred in
Great Britain during this period, were inevitable. T h e explanation for those
developments is to be found in the n e w problems and possibilities created by
the growth of world trade in the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries : the new
problems of regularly carrying large quantities of goods over very long distances
across turbulent seas ; of processing and distributing large quantities of products
imported from distant places ; of accommodation in a trade system stretching
The slave trade 63
and the Atlantic economies 1451-1870
to every part of the globe; the opportunities offered for developing n e w indus-
tries based on raw materials previously scarce and expensive, or wholly unavail-
able, such as sugar, tobacco, cotton, etc., and for developing n e w products in
response to n e w demands and tastes; the economies of scale associated with
production for a greatly extended world market—these and m a n y other factors
stimulated the institutional developments and the radical structural shifts
which occurred in western Europe at that time. They were all produced by the
growth of world trade in this period. T h e technical developments and the tech-
nological innovations of the period were all called forth and m a d e economic
by the practical problems of production for an extended world market. It is
the verdict of a British economic historian that
Colonial trade introduced to English industry the quite new possibility of exporting
in great quantities manufactures other than woollen goods, to markets where there
was no question of the exchange of manufactures for other manufactures. . . . The
process of industrialization in England from the second quarter of the eighteenth
century was to an important extent a response to colonial demands for nails, axes,
firearms, buckets, coaches, clocks, saddles, handkerchiefs, buttons, cordage and a
thousand other things.19
The eighteenth century can be truly called the Atlantic stage of European economic
development. Foreign trade, and especially trade with the Americas, was the most
dynamic sector of the whole economy (for instance, French colonial trade increased
tenfold between 1716 and 1787), and furthermore the demand from overseas was
stimulating the growth of a wide range of industries as well as increased specialization
and division of labour. Owing to the superiority of sea transport over land transport,
the eighteenth-century European economy was organized around a number of big
seaports, the most prosperous being those with the largest share in the growing colo-
nial trade, such as Bordeaux or Nantes; each of these had, not only its own industries,
but also its industrial hinterland in the river base of which it was the outlet.2a
'Americanization' of trade and industry was the most pronounced for countries which
64 Joseph E. Inikori
owned a colonial empire (such as Great Britain, France, Holland and Spain), its
influence extended also farther to the east, to countries which had no colonies but
were able to send goods to America as re-exports from the colonial powers, especially
through Cadiz; so German linens, cutlery, and hardware reached the West Indian
and Spanish American markets.23
For North America in the colonial period, it has been s h o w n that the propor-
tion of total economic activity devoted to production for overseas markets
was relatively large at the beginning of the eighteenth century, being about
one-fifth of total output, and that though that proportion declined over
the century, it still remained about one-sixth in 1768-72. 24 This w a s m a d e u p
of shipping and other commercial services sold by the north-eastern colonies
to the West Indian islands and southern Europe, export of foodstuffs, horses
and lumber from the middle and north-eastern colonies to the West Indies and
southern Europe, and the export of tobacco, rice and other minor crops from
the southern colonies to Great Britain and other European countries. F r o m
this analysis of the colonial economy of North America, it is concluded :
While overseas trade and market activity m a y not have comprised the major portion
of all colonial economic activity, the importance of the market was that of improving
resource allocation.... W e argue that while subsistence agriculture provided an impor-
tant base to colonial incomes and was a substantial part of average per capita income,
changes in incomes and improvements in welfare came largely through overseas
trade and other market activities. Not only did improvements in productivity occur
primarily through market activity, but the pattern of settlement and production was
determined by market forces. This pattern changed slowly and unevenly, spreading
from the waterways and distribution centres along the Atlantic seaboard into the
interior.25
For the period, 1790-1860, Professor D . C . North has s h o w n that the export
of raw cotton from the southern states was the most crucial factor in the growth
and development of the United States economy. A s the southern states con-
centrated all their resources on the production of raw cotton for export, they
had to buy their foodstuffs from the producers in the west, and this stimulated
the settlement of the west and its specialization in foodstuff production. Also,
the south had to depend on the north-east for its transportation,financialand
other commercial services. Incomes earned from the production of cotton for
export and spent on western food and north-eastern services, provided the
base for the growth of import substitution industries in the north-east. A n d so
the north-east graduated from exporting southern cotton and supplying the
south and west with imported foreign manufactures, to the domestic production
of those goods for consumers in the south and west, as well as in the north-east
itself, using southern cotton as part of the inputs for the n e w industries. It w a s
The slave trade 65
and the Atlantic economies 1451-1870
Apart from the foregoing arguments, it has been shown that in the decade
before the civil war southern slave farms produced 28 per cent more output
per unit of input than southern free farms, and 40 per cent more than family-
66 Joseph E. Inikori
based northern farms.30 W h e n this superior efficiency of slave labour over free
labour is added to the very m u c h higher labour costs that would have prevailed
in the absence of slave labour, it can be easily seen w h y production costs, even
in the areas where it was possible to obtain some additional wage or indentured
labour at a high price, would have been terribly high in the absence of slave
labour. A s Ralph Davis has shown, the phenomenal expansion of European
consumption of products imported from the Americas depended largely on
the very low levels to which their prices dropped in the course of the seventeenth
and eighteenth centuries.81 European demand for products from the Americas
was therefore highly price elastic, so that a manifold increase in the prices of
those products in the absence of slave labour would have greatly reduced their
consumption in Europe and therefore the volume of trade based on them.
Hence, taking into account the large areas in the Americas where no production
at all would have taken place without slave labour, and the greatly reduced level
of production and sale in areas where some wage or indentured labour would
have been forthcoming at a high price, the conclusion can be drawn that the
growth of world trade between 1500 and 1870 was due very largely to the avail-
ability of African slave labour supplied through the slave trade. It is important
to stress that even the growth of trade between West European countries at
this time depended greatly on the re-export of American products from one
European country to another, and the export of European goods from one
European country to another for onward trans-shipment to the Americas.
Before these developments, autarchic practices by various West European
nations in their efforts to encourage h o m e industries militated against the
growth of intra-European trade.32 Even the greatly enlarged trade with the
East Indies during this period still depended largely on the Atlantic system,
for a large proportion of the oriental goods was re-exported to Africa and the
Americas.
This question has just begun to receive the attention of scholars.33 O n e recent
attempt in thisfieldis based on a static model derived from the classical theory
of international trade. T h e costs and benefits of the slave trade for
Africa were computed on the basis of the difference between as estimated total
amount of goods that would have been produced (at the subsistence level of
production) in Africa by the estimated number of all slaves that were exported
and the total value of import goods received in exchange for the slaves. If the
former exceeds the latter than the material welfare of Africans deteriorated as
a result of the slave trade; but if the latter exceeds the former, then the material
welfare of Africans improved as a result of the slave trade.34 Apart from the
conceptual weaknesses of this model, it has no power to determine the dynamic
The slave trade 67
and the Atlantic economies 1451-1870
gains or losses that m a y be associated with the slave trade. A s John H . Williams
points out:
the relation of international trade to the development of new resources and productive
forces is a more significant part of the explanation of the present status of nations, of
incomes, prices, well-being, than is the cross-section value analysis of the classical
economists, with its assumption of given quanta of productive factors, already
existent and employed [with fixed technology and fixed market and productive
organization].85
It is sometimes said that the slave trade brought from the Americas to Africa
n e w food crops, such as manioc, sweet potato, maize, groundnuts and some
others.38 If w e leave aside the controversy over the American origin of these
crops, and accept that as a fact, the argument that those crops c a m e to Africa
because of the slave trade cannot be sustained on any ground, since these crops
are said to have been introduced into West Africa 'by Portuguese traders
early in the sixteenth century',87 a period during which Portuguese slave trade
in West Africa was far less important, in volume and value, than Portuguese
trade in West African products, such as gold, pepper and so on. 8 8
Another way of relating the slave trade positively to African economic
development m a y be through the investment of profits m a d e in the trade by
African dealers. It is possible that after the effective abolition of the external
slave trade late in the nineteenth century, profits earlier accumulated from it
by some African dealers m a y have flowed into the development of trade in
African products, such as palm oil, then in demand. This could be regarded as
a positive contribution by the slave trade to African economic development.
But during the 400 years or so of the slave trade before its abolition, profits
from that trade added nothing in terms of capital formation to the production
capacity of African economies. 89 D u k e Ephraim, one of the greatest Efik
traders of pre-colonial times, 'peopled the vast agricultural area of A k p a b u y o
to the east of Calabar with slaves purchased from the profits of his trade, not
so m u c h to produce oil or even food, but to strengthen the power of his house
or ward. 'n In general, this was h o w slave-trade profits were employed in the
Cross River region of present-day Nigeria. It would seem, therefore, that the
economic conditions associated with the slave trade provided no d e m a n d
incentives for capital formation to take place. Hence economic development in
Africa was not stimulated by the slave trade. Indeed, it can be argued that
institutions and habits inimical to economic development, which developed and
became hardened during over 400 years of slave trade, became, in later years,
great obstacles to economic transformation in Africa.
If it is so difficult to isolate any positive contribution by the slave trade
to African economic development, two other propositions remain to be exam-
68 Joseph E. Inikori
ined. First, w e propose to show that the slave trade had an ascertainable direct
negative impact on the economic development processes in Africa; secondly,
that, while it lasted, it prevented the growth and development of 'normal'
international trade between Africa and the rest of the world.
The first direct negative impact was its retardative or contractionary
effects on African population during a period of over 400 years. This is an
issue on which historians hold differing views.41 With regard to Africa south
of the Equator, there seems to be a general consensus of opinion a m o n g them
that external slave trade led to an outright depopulation in the Congo-Angola
region, broadly defined. A s for West Africa, there is disagreement as to whether
it led to an outright depopulation, but what no one seems to contend is that,
at best, the population there was stationary during the period of the external
slave trade—that is, the rate of population growth was equal to the rate of
population loss due to that trade.
O n e general weakness of the existing studies of the subject is that popu-
lation movements in Africa have been related only to the Atlantic slave trade.
A proper understanding of African demographic processes in the period 1451—
1870 requires an assessment of population losses due to the external slave trade
in all its branches. Also, even in the Atlantic trade, only the numbers of slaves
actually exported are considered, w h e n it is k n o w n that the processes leading
to the export of those numbers—the wars, raids and other methods of slave
gathering ; the long march to the coast ; the ' warehousing ' of slaves on the coast
awaiting shipment; the long keeping of slaves in ship holds before the vessels
actually departed the African coast with their full cargoes—involved population
losses that probably have been far in excess of the numbers actually exported.
The most serious weakness, however, is that no effort has been m a d e to assess,
albeit roughly, the additional population the slaves exported would have
produced in Africa had they been left there.
It is difficult to m a k e such an estimate. In thefirstplace, no data exist
on birth rates and survival rates in Africa at this time. Even if they existed the
data would not have reflected the effects of the slave trade on birth and survival
rates through its retardative effects on economic growth and the high incidence
of war. O n the other hand, the Africans exported were all people in their prime
of life so that the rate of reproduction a m o n g them should have been higher
than that of the rest of society left behind.
O n e way of getting round the problem would have been to employ the
reproduction rates a m o n g the Africans received in the slave-importing territories
of the Americas. But this, again, poses problems. O f all the slave-receiving
territories in the Americas it was only in the United States that the imported
Africans achieved some rate of net natural increase during m u c h of our period.
In the other territories, the effect of a lengthy journey from Africa by sea,
strange disease environment, the harsh conditions of plantation slavery,
The slave traac 69
and the Atlantic economies 1451-1870
particularly on the sugar-cane plantations, etc., actually led to rates of net natu-
ral decrease a m o n g the slave populations. Since rates of net natural decrease
did not operate in the African territories from which people were exported,42 the
only usable rate is that a m o n g the Africans in North America. For this terri-
tory, Professor Curtin's calculations show that about 430,000 Africans imported,
largely between 1700 and 1810, produced a black population of about 4.5
million by 1863.«
Before this rate of reproduction can be refined to provide a rough approxi-
mation of the numbers that would have been reproduced in Africa by the people
exported, some qualifications are necessary. T h e North American imports
were concentrated in the second half of the eighteenth century so that it actually
took the 430,000 imported Africans very m u c h less than a century to produce
a population of 4.5 million by 1863. B y the time a large number of Africans
began to arrive in North America in the second half of the eighteenth century,
the first million people to leave Africa as a result of the external slave trade
in all its sectors had done so for more than 100 years. O n the other hand, the
harsh conditions of slavery, its psychological effects on the fecundity of female
slaves and the strange disease environment still reduced to some extent the
rate of reproduction a m o n g the imported Africans in the United States.
O n the other side of the coin, it m a y be argued that the mortality rate
in tropical Africa during our period was higher than that of North America
during the same period. If this was the case, then the survival rate a m o n g the
children of Africans in North America, from about the second generation
onward, would be higher than that in Africa. In addition the slaves in North
America did receive some modern medical attention, however minimal the
effect m a y have been on their health. Another consideration is the fact that
the population of Afro-Americans in 1863 was produced with the input of
some white fathers. It has been shown that the proportion of mulattos in the
total slave population of the United States of America in 1860 was 10.4 per
cent.44
W h e n these two sets of opposing factors are matched it is not easy to
decide the direction of the net result. T o be conservative let us assume that,
notwithstanding all the points m a d e above, the reproduction rates which
prevailed a m o n g the Africans imported into North America were higher than
the rates that would have prevailed a m o n g the 19 million Africans exported
had they been left in Africa. Let us even assume that, w h e n all the facts stated
earlier have been considered, only 50 per cent of the North American rates
would have prevailed in Africa. Applying this rate to the 19 million earlier
estimated, the result is that had those Africans not been exported they would
have produced an additional population of at least about 99,420,000 in Africa
by about 1870. This calculation does not take into account the fact that the
large number of Africans w h o were exported several years before North
70 Joseph E. Inikori
that would have led to internal colonization, taming the forests, and greater
population concentration. Internal colonization would have led to interregional
differentiation of economic functions arising from climatic differences, diffe-
rential natural-resource endowments, and differing population densities. T h e
taming of the forests and greater population concentration would have led
to a reduction in distribution costs by lowering costs of transportation. All
this would have stimulated interregional trade and therefore the growth of
production for the market and all the institutional developments associated
with that growth. But because the ratio of population to land remained
extremely low, population remained largely dispersed, the forests remained
untamed, extensive, rather than intensive, cultivation was encouraged, and
subsistence production and local self-sufficiency remained the rule. Because
land was never a scarce resource no market for land developed and agriculture
generally remained uncommercialized. The land-tenure system which became
hardened under the conditions produced by the slave trade is one of those
institutions inimical to the growth of capitalism which took root in Africa as
a result of the external slave trade. In most of Africa, this system if often talked
about as if it were something inherently African, without it being realized that
the persistence of the system has its history in the slave trade, which prevented
the growth of demand for land that would have m a d e it a scarce and, therefore,
marketable resource. The present development of a market for urban land in
m a n y African countries, following the pressure of population in the urban
centres, shows clearly w h y a land market (urban and agricultural) failed to
develop in m u c h of Africa m a n y years ago. In the absence of a large population,
the existence of a very great and growing external demand for African products
that were land-intensive in production would gradually have reduced land to
a scarce and marketable resource and hence led to the commercialization of
agriculture and the whole rural economy. This was what the export of raw
wool and wollen cloths did for British land tenure and agriculture in the six-
teenth century and after; what the export of foodstuffs to the West Indies did
for the agriculture of the middle and northern colonies of North America in
the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries; and what the export of cocoa is
doing for the western State of Nigeria.45 But, as w e shall show later, the oppor-
tunity cost of the slave trade m a d e impossible the growth of such an external
demand during the period of that trade. D r Hopkins suggests that, in the
absence of population growth, technical innovation would have encouraged
the growth of market activities by reducing production costs.46 This is rather
a case of putting the cart before the horse since, historically, the growth of
market activities preceded technical innovation. This is to say that, historically,
technical innovation was not an autonomous variable, having always been
stimulated by demand pressures, although in its turn, it later stimulated the
growth of market activities.
72 Joseph E. Inikori
The other direct negative effect of the external slave trade on African
economic development is associated with the general socio-economic and socio-
political conditions created by the trade. Every economic activity has a w a y
of creating such conditions which not only help to sustain its earlier levels but
provide it with further m o m e n t u m . This is the major idea behind Professor
Rostow's 'take-off' analysis. That self-reinforcing process was crucial in
sustaining the slave trade. The socio-economic and socio-political forces created
by the slave trade in Africa which sustained it for several centuries, operated
in the form of increased warfare based on the use of firearms and horses sup-
plied by the European and Arab slave-merchants, the emergence of professional
slave-raiders or man-hunters, the gearing of political, social and economic
institutions to the needs of slave acquisition and marketing and so on. T h e
incentives behind all these innovative activities were the increased variety of
European and Oriental products available to those with slaves to sell.
The mechanism of this self-sustaining process is well elaborated by m a n y
writers on the slave trade. The account by Leo Africanus shows that the king
of Bornu (Borno) at the beginning of the sixteenth century sold slaves to
Barbary merchants and received horses for use in his cavalry in return. With
these horses the king carried out his annual slave-raiding expeditions.47 T h e
horses m a y also have been used to acquire territorial fiefs through which
tribute slaves were obtained. In fact, the important slave market of K u k a is
said to have been supplied with slaves captured in government raids in the
surrounding non-Muslim territories south, west and south-west of Bornu
(Borno), and with tribute slaves paid by vassal princes w h o , in order to dis-
charge this obligation, carried on continuous warfare against their non-
Muslim neighbours.48
In the Atlantic sector, firearms took the place of horses, and the prolifer-
ation of firearms in the coastal and forest states was an important part of the
self-reinforcing mechanism. The firearms gave steam to imperial ventures aimed
at controlling the sources of slave supply. The conflict between these nascent
empires over the control of slave supply on the one hand, and the need for
self-defence against their activities by their victims or potential victims on the
other hand, created a slave-gun circle. This is w h y it does not m a k e m u c h
sense to talk of these wars as being politically motivated, for beneath what
one m a y describe as a political motive lay what was primarily economic. This
is not to say that all the wars of the slave-trade period were caused by the con-
ditions created by the trade, nor that some non-economic motives were not
also present in wars that were largely due to the slave trade. But it does m e a n
that the self-reinforcing conditions created by the trade were responsible for
m u c h of the wars of the period. A s one writer puts it :
The two-way pressures of the ocean trade—European demand for captives and African
The slave trade 73
and the Atlantic economies 1451-1870
The opportunity for gaining durable material wealth from the slave trade obviously
encouraged rulers to expand their possessions and increase the number of people
over w h o m they ruled. Such expansion often took place by warfare which initially
provided prisoners of war, a ready source of slaves, and subsequently provided new
subjects on w h o m taxes could be levied in the form of m e n . By expanding hisfiefthe
ruler also acquired a position of being thefinalarbiter in judicial matters. This position
brought the ruler export slaves through a manipulation of the judicial processes. Thus,
for various reasons, the gains to be derived from the slave trade provided one of the
sharpest incentives to imperial expansion in Central Africa.60
W e have been greatly disappointed in our trade. Ever since the Fanteens went to
engage Elmena no thinking m a n that knew the coast could have expected otherwise;
all the trading paths were stopped; nothing going forward but thieving and panyar-
ring; had the said Fanteens become conquerors it's certain w e should for our o w n
parts have got eight hundred or one thousand slaves at pretty easy terms; but as they
came back repulsed and were even forced to run away, w e have suffered to be sure
considerably, for I credited the headmen pretty largely to secure their interest on their
return that I might have the preference of what slaves they took in the war. 5 1
General S h a m p o o is encamped at the head of the River Vutta [Volta] with 20 thousand
m e n ready to engage D a h o m e e King of W h y d a h ; the said king has an army equal to
the other's, encamped within two miles of each other. O n the success of the former w e
have a large interest depending and until that battle is decided in some shape or
another there are no trade to be expected. Y o u n g in the Africa I a m loading him with
a proper assortment of goods and to dispatch him with all expedition for Little Popo
to attend the result of the Battle.52
74 Joseph E. Inikori
These are not isolated cases, for similar references can be found in the works
of other writers on the subject.83
Historians have always tried to relate the socio-political and socio-eco-
nomic conditions created in Africa by the slave trade to political processes,
particularly those connected with theriseand decline of States, kingdoms and
empires. W h a t has been neglected is an analysis that will explicitly relate those
conditions to the process of economic development in Africa. In the matter
of State formation, for instance, if the slave trade gave rise to some larger and
more powerful States, one would like to k n o w whether such States directed
or took part in economic activities likely to bring about economic development;
whether they m a d e conscious efforts to provide peaceful conditions under which
private enterprise could have helped to bring about economic development;
or,finally,whether they consciously m a d e any efforts to evolve or encourage
the evolution of institutional arrangements essential for economic development.
If the answers to all these questions are negative, one would like to k n o w w h y .
It is well k n o w n that during the period of the slave trade not only did the
States whose rise m a y be associated with that trade fail to do any of the things
specified above, but even others, like the kingdom of Benin failed to d o so.
The explanation is simple. T h e former remained largely slave-trading States
and so had n o political or economic incentives to develop other resources,
or to encourage private enterprise to d o so by providing peaceful conditions,
while the other States also became largely involved in the slave trade, or in
defending themselves against the activities of slave-trading States. O n the
other hand, the requirements of the slave trade were such that they could not
stimulate any infrastructural developments in the slave-trading States. For
instance, the fact that the slaves transported themselves along bush paths
eliminated any possible pressure to build good roads and to encourage artisans
to build 'the wheel' to facilitate the flow of trade".
F r o m the point of view of the private sector, the chaotic conditions which
the slave trade created and which helped to sustain its m o m e n t u m for several
centuries raised transaction costs enormously and so retarded the growth of
market activities. A n y reading of the European company records bears this
out. In a letter to the Royal African C o m p a n y in Great Britain, an official of
the company resident on the African Coast wrote :
at best the Waterside Kings, and Great Cabbasheers (so called) are but poor great
rogues, for when they do not disturb the traders, and are not at war with one another
for a livelihood combine and lay their heads together to contrive how to abuse and
cheat your honours and the Dutch West India Company. 6 1
Obviously, the slave trade was not a gentleman's trade, and what the Europeans
say about the African dealers, the former also say about each other, for the
same writer quoted above had cause to say :
The slave trade 75
and the Atlantic economies J451-1870
Were I to characterize the Dutch as I by experience have found them to be, I should
give the same character of them, as I have herein given of the Natives of this country,
for I have often seriously considered with myself whether they or the Natives here
were of the most villanous, falsest temper and could never come to a resolution
thereon.65
N o doubt the Dutch and the Africans had m u c h the same thing to say about
the British.
W h a t is more, the wars and raids of the slave trade encouraged the
location of settlements
in good defensive positions and their location in relation to natural obstacles makes
settlements inaccessible at the cost of ease of communications or even good building
sites [and good agricultural land].68
The ground of this country is as fertile as any ground in the West Indies, taking places
according as they lye nearer or farther from the sea, but the natives are such scothful
sordid wretches, and so given to stealing from one another rather than labour that
little or nothing is made of it . . .6a
slave trade became increasingly unprofitable due to long credits and bad
debts in the West Indies, the company m a d e some frantic efforts to develop
trade in African products, not only with the coastal States but also with States
in the far interior. In March 1722 the company wrote to its officials on the
coast:
W e have already in divers letters acquainted you with our thoughts concerning the
carrying on of our trade, and as the negroe branch of it grows every day less and less
profitable it is from the article of the home returns we see our chief advantage must
arise.64
be worked up there into assortments proper for the West Indies and as you have
encouragement or profit by that branch of trade your honours slaving vessels will be
capable of taking on board such quantities as you shall please to direct from hence to
be wrought up at Whydah. 6 5
Thus, from the available records, it is clear that not only were the European
merchants aware of the possibilities of developing trade with Africa in the
products of the African soil, but also they m a d e some efforts to develop such
trade. However, they all tended to see the trade in African products as subor-
dinate to the slave trade, which they were unwilling to give u p in favour of
devoting full attention to the development of trade in the products of the soil.
Hence, the zeal and enthusiasm with which late-nineteenth- and twentieth-
century European merchants encouraged the development of trade in the
products of the African soil throuth trial and error were completely lacking
in the slave-trade period.
The explanation for the European merchants' attitude is that the devel-
opment of trade in products of the African soil would have been a slow process
compared with the development of trade in commodities produced in the A m -
ericas with African slave labour, and such development would have required a
mass withdrawal of factors from the exploitation of the American resources
and the shipping and marketing of the output. In other words, the exploitation
78 Joseph E. Inikori
of the American resources was making a very heavy demand on the same pro-
duction factors that were needed for the development of African resources.
But as long as African slave labour was available, production factors from
Europe could be more profitably employed in the exploitation of American
resources than in the development of trade in the products of the African soil.
This was so because the employment of African slaves by European
planters to produce tropical products in Africa on the scale that prevailed in
the Americas would have been very costly in terms of resistance by African
governments, the ease with which the slaves employed in Africa could escape
from their white masters (possibly with the connivance of African governments),
and, most seriously, in terms of mortality a m o n g whites in Africa at a time
when tropical medicine was u n k n o w n to Europeans. The most likely method
would have been through co-operation between the European merchants and
African rulers to encourage African peoples to cultivate the crops in demand,
as was done in the late nineteenth and twentieth centuries. But this method
would definitely have been slow in producing a trade on the scale then pre-
vailing in commodities being produced in the Americas with African slave
labour.
In this circumstance, so long as African slave labour was available, the
Americas remained far more attractive to European production factors. T h e
buying and shipping of the slaves to the Americas, the exploitation of the
American resources, and the shipping and marketing of the American c o m -
modities internationally, absorbed so m a n y production factors from Europe
and Africa that little or nothing was left for the development of trade in the
products of the African soil. That development was further hampered by the
unsettled conditions which attended the acquisition of captives for sale as
slaves.
But the important point is that the advantages of the Americas depended
very largely on African slave labour. If there had been no slave trade from Africa
to the Americas, the advantage would have been on the side of encouraging
Africans to produce a wide range of commodities in Africa for an international
market. F r o m the evidence before us, it is clear that this is what would have
happened. But the conditions which prevailed under the slave trade m a d e that
trade more profitable both to a majority of the European merchants and to
the African rulers and entrepreneurs whose talents would have been required
for the production and marketing of these commodities in Africa. Conse-
quently, African products imported into Europe during the slave-trade period
remained those which required very little entrepreneurship and little or no
capital investment to produce—ivory, g u m , palm oil, redwood, etc.—being
all commodities that were either hunted or gathered from wild trees.
S o m e European governments fully realized that the development of
international trade in the products of the African soil would mean a mass
The slave trade 79
and the Atlantic economies 1451-1870
That the introducing of culture and Industry amongst the Negroes was contrary to
the known established policy of this trade. That there was no saying where this might
stop and that it might extend to tobacco, sugar & every other commodity which w e
now take from our colonies, and thereby the Africans w h o n o w support themselves
by war would become planters & their slaves be employed in the culture of these
articles in Africa which they are now employed in in America. That our possessions in
America were firmly secured to us, whereas those in Africa were more open to the
invasions of an enemy, and besides that in Africa w e were only tenants in the soil
which w e held at the good will of the natives.68
The members of the company's committee were therefore ordered to ask their
officials on the coast to put an end to this type of activity. Thus, in order to
ensure that Africa provided a regular supply of slaves required for the exploi-
tation of American resources, the British Government through the Board of
Trade had to discourage the development of African economies. In a letter
to the British Treasury in April 1812, aboutfiveyears after the slave trade had
been abolished in Great Britain, the Committee of the C o m p a n y of Merchants
Trading to Africa s u m m e d u p the whole matter thus :
It is a lamentable but certain fact, that Africa has hitherto been sacrificed to our West
India colonies. Her commerce has been confined to a trade which seemed to preclude
all advancement in civilization. Her cultivators have been sold to labour on lands not
their own, while all endeavours to promote cultivation and improvement in agriculture
have been discouraged by the Government of this country, lest her products should
interfere with those of our more favoured colonies.69
Conclusion
Notes
the papers are of particular interest: Roger Anstey, 'Capitalism and Slavery—A
Critique'; John Hargreaves, 'Synopsis of a Critique of Eric Williams' Capitalism
and Slavery'; C . Duncan Rise, 'Critique of the Eric Williams Thesis: " T h e Anti-
Slavery Interest and the Sugar Duties, 1841-1853' "; Christopher Fyfe, ' A Historio-
graphical Survey of the Transatlantic Slave Trade from West Africa'. The latter is
a useful survey of the literature and the type of study available on the slave trade.
Also to be noted are, Roger T . Anstey, 'Capitalism and Slavery: A Critique',
Econ. Hist. Rev., Vol. X X I , 1968, p. 307-20; Roger T . Anstey, The Atlantic Slave
Trade and British Abolition, 1760-1810, London, Macmillan, 1975.
S o m e of the literature on the private profitability of the slave trade antedated
Eric Williams' book: James Wallace, A General and Descriptive History of the
Ancient and Present State of the Town of Liverpool, Liverpool, R . Phillips, 1795;
G o m e r Williams, History of the Liverpool Privateers and Letters of Marque with
an Account of the Liverpool Slave Trade, London, W . Heinemann, 1897; S. Dumbell,
'The Profits of the Guinea Trade', Economic History (Supplement to Economic
Journal), Vol. II, January 1931. But since the publication of Eric Williams' book
the literature on this aspect of the slave trade has grown enormously. S o m e of the
more important works include: F . E . Hyde, B . B . Parkinson and S. Marriner,
'The Nature and Profitability of the Liverpool Slave Trade', Econ. Hist. Rev.,
Vol. V , N o . 3, 1953; K . G . Davies, 'Essays in Bibliography and Criticism X L I V .
Empire and Capital, Econ. Hist. Rev., 2nd Ser., Vol. XII, 1960-61, p. 105-10;
R . B . Sheridan, 'The Wealth of Jamaica in the Eighteenth Century', Econ. Hist.
Rev., 2nd Ser., Vol. XVIII, August 1965; Robert Paul T h o m a s , 'The Sugar Colonies
of the Old Empire: Profit or loss for Great Britain?', Econ. Hist. Rev., 2nd Ser.,
Vol. X X I , April 1968; R . B . Sheridan, 'The Wealth of Jamaica in the Eighteenth
Century: A Rejoinder', Econ. Hist. Rev., 2nd Ser., Vol. X X I , April 1968¡Stanley
L . Engerman, 'The Slave Trade and British Capital Formation in the Eighteenth
Century : C o m m e n t on the Williams Thesis ', The Business History Review, Vol. X L V I ,
N o . 4, Winter 1972, p. 430-3; Roger T . Anstey, ' T h e Volume and Profitability
of the British Slave Trade, 1761-1807', in Stanley L . Engerman and Eugene D .
Genovese (eds.), Race and Slavery in the Western Hemisphere : Quantitative Studies,
Princeton University Press, 1975; David Richardson, 'Profitability in the Bristol-
Liverpool Slave Trade' (paper read at the VIth International Congress of Economic
History, Copenhagen, 19-23 August 1974).
See Stanley L . Engerman, ' The Effects of Slavery upon the Southern Eco-
n o m y : A Review of the Recent Debate', Explorations in Entrepreneurial History,
Vol. 4, 1967; R . W . Fogel and S. L . Engerman, Time on the Cross : The Economics
of American Negro Slavery, London, Wildwood House, 1974; Stanley L . Engerman,
' C o m m e n t s on the Study of Race and Slavery', in Engerman and Genovese (eds.),
Race and Slavery, p. 495-526.
K . O n w u k a Dike, Trade and Politics in the Niger Delta, 1830-1885 : An
Introduction to the Economic and Political History of Nigeria, Oxford University
Press, 1956; A . Akinjogbin, Dahomey and its Neighbours, 1708-1818, Cambridge
University Press, 1967; K . Y . Daaku, Trade and Politics on the Gold Coast 1600-
1720, Oxford University Press, 1970; Walter Rodney, A History of the Upper Guinea
Coast 1545-1800, Oxford University Press, 1970; A . J. H . Latham, Old Calabar
1600-1891 : The Impact of the International Economy upon a Traditional Society,
Oxford, Clarendon Press, 1973; M . D . Kilson, ' West African Society and the Atlan-
tic Slave Trade, 1441-1865', in N . I. Huggins, M . Kilson and D . M . Fox (eds.),
Key Issues in the Afro-American Experience, Vol. I, N e w York, 1971 ; David Bir-
mingham, Trade and Conflict in Angola : The Mbundu and their Neighbours under
82 Joseph E. Inikori
the Influence of the Portuguese, 1483-1790, Oxford University Press, 1966; Phyllis
Martin, The External Trade of the Loango Coast 1576-1860, Oxford Clarendon
Press 1972; Edward A . Alpers, Ivory and Slaves in East Central Africa : Changing
Patterns of International Trade to the Later Nineteenth Century, London, Heine-
m a n n , 1975.
4. See John H . Williams, "The Theory of International Trade Reconsidered', in Lord
Keynes, Joan Robinson, et al. (eds.), Readings in the Theory of International Trade,
p . 253-71, London, 1950, where this distinction is clearly m a d e .
5. P . D . Curtin, The Atlantic Slave Trade : A Census, Madison, Wis., University of
Wisconsin Press, 1969.
6. J. E . Inikori, 'Measuring the Atlantic Slave Trade: A n Assessment of Curtin and
Anstey', Journal of African History, Vol. XVII, N o . 2 (1976); D . Eltis, ' T h e Direc-
tion and Fluctuation of the Trans-Atlantic Slave Trade 1 8 2 1 ^ 3 : A Revision of the
1845 Parliamentary Paper' (paper presented at the Mathematical Social Science
Board Seminar on the Economics of the Slave Trade, Colby College, Waterville,
Maine, 20-22 August 1975); Roger Anstey, The Atlantic Slave Trade and British
Abolition 1760-1810, London, Macmillan, 1975.
7. Ralph A . Austen, ' A Census of the Trans-Saharan Slave Trade, or approximating the
uncountable' (paper presented at the Mathematical Social Science Board Seminar
on the Economics of the Slave Trade, Colby College, Waterville, Maine, 20-22
August 1975).
8. This view was expressed by some of the participants at the Colby College Seminar.
9. C . S . Nicholls, The Swahili Coast : Politics, Diplomacy and Trade on the East African
Littoral 1798-1856, London, Allen & U n w i n 1971.
10. Jonathan Levin emphasized the proportion of total income from export production,
which is remitted abroad by'migrated factors' of production, as one of the important
determinants of the magnitude of the contribution of export production to internal
development processes in export economies. Consequently, he applied the term,
'foreign factors of production', only to those factors which remit their income
abroad. Conversely, he applied the term, 'domestic factors of production', to
' those factors which spend their income within the economy in which it is earned,
for consumation, investment, imports, or any other purpose'. See Jonathan V . Levin,
' T h e Export Economies', in James D . Theberge (ed.), The Economics of Trade and
Development, p . 17-18. N e w York, London, Wiley, 1968. In the case of Latin
America, remittances (especially bullion remittances) to imperial governments in
Europe form parts of factors' remittance abroad.
11. J. E . Inikori, 'English Trade to Guinea: A Study in the Impact of Foreign Trade on
the English Economy, 1750-1807'. (Ph.D. thesis, University of Ibadan, 1973.)
12. In some aspects, the credit requirements of the British slave trade are similar to those
required today by the trading of capital goods internationally.
13. Inikori, 'English trade to Guinea', op. cit., Chap. VII.
14. Inikori, 'English Trade to Guinea', op. cit., p . 234-41; J. E . Inikori, 'Measuring the
Atlantic Slave Trade'.
15. Inikori, 'English Trade to Guinea', op. cit., Chap. IV.
16. See Inikori, 'English Trade to Guinea', op. cit., Chap. IV, for more details.
17. Simone Berbain, 'Études sur la Traite des Noirs au Golfe du Guinée: L e Comptoir
Français de Juda (Ouidah) au XVIII e Siècle', Mémoires de l'Institut Français
d'Afrique Noire, N o . 3, 1942, p . 85-6; Gaston Martin, Nantes au XVIIIe Siècle :
l'Ere des Négriers, 1714-1774, Paris, 1931; Pierre M . Boulle, 'Slave Trade, C o m -
mercial Organisation and Industrial Growth in Eighteenth Century Nantes',
Revue Française d'Histoire d'Outre-Mer, Vol. L I X , N o . 214, 1st quarter, 1972.
The slave trade 83
and the Atlantic economies 1451-1870
18. Douglas C . North and Robert Paul T h o m a s , The Rise of the Western World: A New
Economic History, p. 18. Cambridge University Press, 1973.
19. Ralph Davis, 'English Foreign Trade, 1700-1774', Economic History Review, 2nd ser.,
Vol. X V , 1962, p. 290.
20. Phyllis Deane and W . A . Cole, British Economic Growth, 1688-1959, 2nd ed. Table 2,
p. 6, Cambridge University Press, 1967.
21. Ralph Davis, The Rise of the English Shipping Industry in the Seventeenth and Eighteenth
Centuries, p. 393, L o n d o n , Macmillan, 1962.
22. François Crouzet, ' W a r s , Blockade, and Economic Change in Europe, 1792-1815',
Journal of Economic History, Vol. X X I V , N o . 4, December 1964, p. 568.
23. Crouzet, op. cit., p. 569.
24. James F . Shepherd and Gray M . Walton, Shipping, Maritime Trade, and the Economic
Development of Colonial North America, p. 44, Cambridge, Cambridge University
Press, 1972.
25. Shepherd and Walton, op. cit., p. 25.
26. D . C . North, The Economic Growth of the United States, 1700-1860, Englewood Cliffs,
N . J . , Prentice-Hall, 1961.
27. Henry A . G e m e r y and Jan S. Hogendorn, ' T h e Atlantic Slave Trade: A Tentative
Economic Model', Journal of African History, Vol. X V , N o . 2, 1974, p. 229, quoting
C . Padro, Jr, The Colonial Background of Modern Brazil, p. 19, Berkeley, Calif.,
University of California Press, 1967.
28. K . G . Davies, 'Empire and Capital', p. 107.
29. G e m e r y and Hogendorn, op. cit., p. 229-31. For some other aspects of the slave-labour
issue, see Robert P . T h o m a s and Richard N . Bean, ' T h e Adoption of Slave Labour
in British America' (paper presented to the Mathematical Social Science Board
Seminar at Colby College, Waterville, Maine, 20-22 August 1975.
30. Robert W . Fogel and Stanley L . Engerman, Time on the Cross: The Economics of
American Negro Slavery, p. 192, London, Wildwood House, 1974.
31. Ralph Davis, A Commercial Revolution, English Overseas Trade in the Seventeenth
and Eighteenth Centuries, p. 10, London, Historical Association, 1967. Professor
Davis shows that the large reduction in the prices of the products brought them
within the reach of more consumers and m a d e them 'near-necessities rather than
luxuries '.
32. For the points m a d e here, See W . E . Minchinton (ed.), The Growth of English Overseas
Trade in the 17th and 18th centuries, London, Methuen, 1969, Chapters 2 and 3 by
Ralph Davis on English foreign trade, 1660-1774, and Chapter 5, by H . E . S. Fisher,
on Anglo-Portuguese Trade, 1700-70. See also Allan Christelow, 'Great Britain
and the Trades from Cadiz and Lisbon to Spanish America and Brazil, 1759-
1783', Hispanic American History Review, Vol. X X V I I I , N o . 1, February, 1948,
Part 2; and Jean O . McLachlan, Trade and Peace with Old Spain 1667-1750, C a m -
bridge, Cambridge University Press, 1940.
33. Walter Rodney, How Europe Underdeveloped Africa, p. 103-12, L o n d o n and D a r
es Salaam, Bogle-L'Ouverture Publications, 1972; Henry A . G e m e r y and Jan
S. Hogendorn, ' T h e Economic Costs of West African Participation in the Atlantic
Slave Trade: A Preliminary Sampling for the Eighteenth Century' (paper presented
to the Mathematical Social Science Board Seminar at Colby College, Waterville,
Maine, 20-22 August 1975); H . A . Gemery and J. S. Hogendorn, 'Technological
Change, Slavery, and the Slave Trade', forthcoming in C . J. D e w e y and A . G .
Hopkins (eds.), Studies in the Economic History of India and Africa, L o n d o n ,
Athlone Press, in press; A . G . Hopkins, An Economic History of West Africa,
L o n d o n , L o n g m a n , 1973.
84 Joseph E. Inikori
34. Gemery and Hogendorn, 'The Economic Costs of West African Participation in the
Atlantic Slave Trade'.
35. Williams, op. cit., p. 255.
36. Gemery and Hogendorn, 'Technological Change, Slavery, and the Slave Trade'.
37. ibid.
38. John W . Blake, European Beginnings in West Africa, 1454-1578, p. 23, London, Long-
m a n , 1937.
39. It is said that the plantation economy of Zanzibar and P e m b a developed in the 1820s
following restrictions imposed by the British on the slave trade of the Swahili
coast. Thereafter profits from the slave trade contributed to the expansion of those
plantations: Nicholls, The Swahili Coast, p. 203.
40. A . J. H . Latham, 'Currency, Credit and Capitalism on the Cross River in the Pre-
Colonial Era', Journal of African History, Vol. XII, N o . 4, 1971, p. 604.
41. J. D . Fage, 'Slavery and the Slave Trade in the Context of West African History',
Journal of African History, Vol. X , N o . 3, 1969; Peter Morton-Williams, ' T h e O y o
Yoruba and the Atlantic Trade, 1670-1830', Journal of the Historical Society of
Nigeria, Vol. Ill, N o . 1, December 1964; Michael M a s o n , 'Population Density and
"Slave Raiding"—the Case of the Middle Belt of Nigeria', Journal of African
History, Vol. X , N o . 4, 1969; M . B . Gleave and R . M . Prothero, 'Population
Density and "Slave Raiding"—A C o m m e n t ' , Journal of African History, Vol. XII,
N o . 2, 1971; Roger T . Anstey, The Atlantic Slave Trade, p. 58-88.
42. If that had been the case those territories could not have sustained the slave trade for
over 400 years.
43. P . D . Curtin, 'The Slave Trade and the Atlantic Basin: Intercontinental Perspectives',
in N . I. Huggins, M . Kilson and D . M . F o x (eds.), Key Issues in the Afro-American
Experience, p. 39-53, Vol. I, N e w York, 1971.
44. Fogel and Engerman, Time on the Cross, p. 132. The factor of slave breeding is dis-
missed by the authors as an erroneous idea disseminated by the anti-slavery m o v e -
ment. In fact, they argue that if slave-breeding methods were adopted by the slave-
holders the effects on reproduction rates would have been negative due to the
psychological effects they would have had on the female slaves. See Fogel and
Engerman, op. cit., p. 78-86.
45. Sara S. Berry, Cocoa, Custom, and Socio-Economic Change in Rural Western Nigeria,
Oxford, Clarendon Press, 1975.
46. Hopkins, op. cit., p. 77.
47. Allan G . B . Fisher and Humphrey J. Fisher, Slavery and Muslim Society in Africa:
The Institution in Saharan and Sudanic Africa and the Trans-Saharan Trade, p. 59,
London, C . Hurst, 1970.
48. Fisher and Fisher, op. cit., p. 160.
49. Basil Davidson, 'Slaves or Captives? S o m e Notes on Fantasy and Fact', in Huggins,
Kilson and F o x (eds.), op. cit., p. 69.
50. J. R . Gray and D . Birmingham, ' S o m e Economic and Political Consequences of Trade
in Central and Eastern Africa in the Pre-Colonial Period', in J. R . Gray and D . Bir-
m i n g h a m (eds.), Pre-Colonial African Trade : Essays on Trade in Central and Eastern
Africa before 1900, p. 18-19, London, 1970.
51. C.103/130: 'Captain George Hamilton to T h o m a s Hall', A n n a m a b o e , 3 August 1740.
52. ibid., 24 December 1738.
53. K . Y . D a a k u cites two cases among British slave-merchants in 1689 and 1706, respec-
tively: K . Y . D a a k u , Trade and Politics, op. cit., p. 30.
54. C . 113/274 Part 4, folios 275-6. The letter is undated, but it should be early eighteenth
century.
The slave trade 85
and the Atlantic economies 1451-1870
A large amount of the materials relating to the slave trade which are available in
European archives has recently been listed a m o n g other materials for African history
in foreign archives in two parallel sets of series, one of which deals with only West
Africa, as follows :
Patricia Carson, Materials far West African History in the Archives of Belgium and
Holland, London, 1962.
Patricia Carson, Materials for West African History in French Archives, London, 1968.
Noel Matthews, Materials for West African History in the Archives of the United
Kingdom, London, 1973.
A . F . C . Ryder, Materials for West African History in Portuguese Archives, London,
1965.
A very large proportion of the unpublished archival materials relating to the slave
trade will be found listed in the above booklets and it is unnecessary to duplicate them
here. But these booklets do not list all the materials relating to the slave trade that m a y
be found in European archives. For example, the list for United Kingdom archives
does not contain the very important British Parliamentary Papers, in particular, the
'Accounts and Papers' in the British M u s e u m which contain a large amount of mat-
erials relating to the slave trade; the important Tarleton Papers in the Liverpool
Record Office, and the Records of the Heywoods Bank of Liverpool, in Barclays Bank,
Heywoods Branch, are also not included. Lloyds Corporation Archives in London
also contain some materials relating to the slave trade and are not included in the list
by Matthews. The Chancery Masters' Exhibits in the London Public Record Office,
mentioned by Matthews, include a very large amount of materials relating to the
slave trade, but because of the way those records are described it has not been easy
to detect which of them relate to the slave trade. S o m e of those not mentioned by
Matthews are :
C . 109/401: 'Accounts of Five Slave Voyages by Samual Sandys & C o . of Liverpool,
1771-1772 '.
C.114/1-3 and C.114/154-8: 'Records of T h o m a s L u m l e y & C o . , of London, Guinea
Merchants and Dealers in East India Goods, 1801-1807 '.
C.103/130-3: 'Papers of T h o m a s Hall & C o . , of London, Slave Merchants, 1730-
1743'.
Recently, some of the records of the Royal African C o m p a n y of Great Britain have
been discovered a m o n g the Chancery Masters' Exhibits (C. 113/261-95). These have
been described by David P . Henige, ' T w o Sources For the History of the Guinea
The slave trade 87
and the Atlantic economies 1451-1870
cultural groups. It was for this reason that the slave trade developed along the
coasts of Guinea.
The colonizers of the Caribbean islands repeatedly asked the King of
Spain to have more African slaves dispatched to them, and he granted Gouve-
not, Governor of Bresa, a licence to import 4,000 Negro slaves from the coasts
of Guinea into the West Indies. The latter sold this licence to the Genoese,
w h o in turn sold a part of their rights to Portuguese and other traders.
Between 1512 and 1763, some 60,000 African slaves entered C u b a law-
fully. M a n y more were smuggled into the country. The increase in the slave
population was concomitant with the development of the cultivation of sugar,
for which hundreds of workers were needed on the agricultural side, and also
to a lesser extent with the exploitation of the copper mines in the eastern part
of Cuba, administered by an agent of the G e r m a n firm Weiser. Slaves were
provided by the Spanish monarch himself for this purpose.
This characteristic period in the history of the African slave trade with the
Caribbean colonies began on 12 February 1528, when the King of Spain
granted Enrique Ehinger and Jerónimo Sayler, agents of the G e r m a n bankers,
the Welsers, w h o , with the Fuggers, controlled Spanishfinance,thefirstasiento
or licence to introduce African slaves into his American possessions.
T o deal with matters relating to the asientos, a special board, the Junta
de Negros, was set up in Spain, in the Casa de la Contratación in Seville; it
concerned itself with the trade in African slaves and with ensuring full c o m -
pliance with the terms of the asientos.
In fact, thefirst' licence to navigate in the region of our West Indies and
to bring Negro slaves thereto' was granted to Pedro G ó m e z Reynel, for a
period of nine years beginning on 1 M a y 1595. However, under the Royal
Decree signed at Valladolid on 11 March 1601, this concession was withdrawn
from him and awarded instead to the Portuguese Juan Rodríguez Coutiño,
merchant and Governor of Loango. The first stipulation was that Rodriguez
Coutiño should transport 38,250 slaves from Africa to the Caribbean, sailing
with them from the city of Seville, Lisbon, the Canary Islands, Cape Verde,
Sao T o m é , Angola and Säo Jorge de Mina.
However, several years before the monopoly of the slave trade was
formally granted, by asiento, to G ó m e z Reynel, and more particularly from
3 October 1562 to 15 December 1585, the King of Spain authorized various of
his subjects to trade in slaves—for instance, Diego de Ayllon (1562) and Diego
Pérez Negron (1563)—while on 20 November 1571 it was agreed that Juan
Hernández de Espinosa should take 300 African slaves to Havana. Certain
Spanish towns also profited from the slave trade : thus, for instance, the town
90 José Luciano Franco
leasing of a public revenue and to become, as was soon to be the case, treaties
between countries.
The history of British trade in West Africa prior to the establishment of
the C o m p a n y of Royal Adventurers in 1660 is briefly as follows: up to 1630
or 1640 it remained very restricted in volume and had n o connection with trade
in the West Indies or the American continent. Between 1562 and 1569, het
British slave trade was started by John Hawkins. In 1562, aboard his ship
Jesus, he carried off a consignment of slaves from the shores of Africa which
he exchanged for gold, sugar and hides with the Spanish colonists in Santo
Domingo.
Hawkins had shown wisdom and cunning in starting his interloper's
trade in the Caribbean, but he had not reckoned with the Casa de Contratación
in Seville, which would not allow the slightest infiltration in the Spanish trade
monopoly, and promptly seized in Cadiz the two ships that Hawkins was
naïve enough to send to that port to sell some of the hides exchanged for Negro
slaves in Santo Domingo. The king of Spain, Philip II, refused to accede to
the Englishman's repeated requests and was sharply called to account by Queen
Elizabeth of England.
After Hawkins' failure, English trade in West Africa dwindled. With the
defeat of the Invincible A r m a d a in 1588 and the decline of the House of Austria,
Queen Elizabeth was that same year able to grant thirty-five London merchants
the privilege of slave-trading on the African coast from Senegal to the River
G a m b i a ; these promptly set about turning the island of Tortuga in the Carib-
bean into the favourite haunt of slave-traders, rescatadores ('receivers' of
slaves) and pirates.
With the occupation of Jamaica, the British—who during thefirsthalf
of the seventeenth century had given up the slave trade—decided to renew
it with greater intensity. O n 18 December 1661, the C o m p a n y of Royal Adven-
turers obtained the exclusive right to engage in and organize the slave trade
from Cape Blanc to the Cape of G o o d H o p e . Queens, royal princesses, dukes
and peers were included a m o n g the shareholders in this undertaking. T h e
king himself seized the opportunity of acquiring an interest in so profitable a
business. However, the war against the Dutch reduced the profits and caused
that band of high-born adventurers to wind up their business, the company
being replaced in 1672 by the Royal African C o m p a n y . In nine years alone,
from 1680 to 1689, the latter company sent 259 ships to African shores and
transported 46,396 slaves to the American colonies.
At the end of the sixteenth century, the French had not yet realized the
full economic importance for them of the trade practised by the Portuguese
and the Dutch in Africa, and it was only under Cardinal Richelieu that they
began to enter the slave trade on a small scale.
Richelieu gave his approval to the plans of the traders and merchant
92 José Luciano Franco
with the Caribbean islands, especially with Cuba. A n d , under the Peace Treaty
signed in Madrid on 27 March 1713 and ratified by one of the articles of the
Treaty of Utrecht, the monopoly of the slave trade passed into British hands
for the next thirty years.
In 1715, Richard O'Farrill of Irish origin, from the island of Montserrat,
arrived in Cuba as the representative of the South Sea C o m p a n y of London and
established slave depots in Havana and Santiago de Cuba, thereby giving great
impetus to the African slave trade; the majority of slaves were imported into
Mexico, but the traffic was almost at a standstill before the second half of the
eighteenth century.
The Spanish ports had protested that they were being excluded from the
colonial trade (a monopoly exercised by the Casa de Contractación in Seville)
while a foreign country had the right to flood the Caribbean and Latin Ameri-
can colonies with slaves.
The outbreak of war between England and Spain in 1740 provided a
convenient excuse for abolishing the privilege hitherto enjoyed by the English
slave-dealers. T o continue the legitimate business of importing slaves, conducted
until then by O'Farrill and the English concessionaires, some Cuban and Span-
ish capitalists founded the Real Compañía de Comercio de La Habana which,
in addition to supplying Cuban sugar-cane planters with new slaves, held the
monopoly to operate all the foreign trade of the Greater Antilles.
A series of asientos were granted until September 1779 when the last
monopoly in the history of the slave trade was abolished. T o remedy as far as
possible the shortage of labour, the slave-dealers of Cuba, Santo Domingo and
Puerto Rico were granted, by Royal Decree of 25 January 1780, the right to
obtain slaves from the French colonies in the Caribbean. However, as the
demand for slave labour went on increasing, under Royal Decree of 28 February
1789, slave trading was m a d e free in Cuba, Santo D o m i n g o and Puerto Rico,
and this was subsequently extended by Royal Decree of 24 November 1791, to
the slave-dealers of Santa Fé, Buenos Aires and Caracas. In Cuba, these provi-
sions by which the Spanish Government met the demands of the sugar-cane
planters and slave-dealers gave an extraordinary impetus to the slave trade.
The phenomenal increase in the Cuban slave population at the end of the eigh-
teenth century is closely linked with the establishment of a sugar-cane planta-
tion economy. Hundreds of slaves were needed for the cultivation of sugar
cane and the production of sugar, and as exports increased so the productive
labour became intensified, bringing about a higher death rate a m o n g the
slaves, speeding up wastage, and necessitating a faster replacement of the
Africans thus destroyed.
The slave trade in the Caribbean 95
and Latin America
Rise and fall of slave trading and slavery in the nineteenth century
British dominions, and in 1808 this prohibition was extended to the importa-
tion of slaves.
Internationally, the African slave traffic in the Caribbean islands and in
Latin America was partly disrupted by the Treaty of Paris of 30 M a y 1814,
which subsequently led in Vienna, to the famous Declaration of 8 February
1815. In September 1817, a treaty was signed by the representatives of the
London and Madrid Governments abolishing the slave traffic; this was limited
in scope owing to the exigencies of the time but was later amplified by the
treaty of 28 June 1835 under which Spanish subjects were forbidden to engage
in that unlawful business. Brazil was also to sign similar agreements.
However, in spite of the above-mentioned international treaties and
agreements and of innumerable laws passed by the metropolitan countries
concerned, the illegal traffic in slaves reached considerable proportions. Faced
with the abolitionist campaign carried out by progressive groups in Great
Britain and France and the measures taken to suppress the trade, the slave-
trading oligarchy in C u b a and the plantation owners in the Caribbean and
slave-owning parts of America retorted by mounting a vicious campaign
describing the French ' revolutionaries ' in the blackest and most sinister terms
and accusing the English of perfidy and selfishness. With the consent and
support of the colonial governments and the complicity of the reactionary
forces in Europe and America, they organized an illegal slave traffic, thus
disregarding the various international treaties and agreements.
Karl M a r x , commenting on a session of the House of Lords in London
on 17 June 1858 when the Bishop of Oxford raised the question of the slave
trade, in an article entitled 'The British Government and the Slave Trade' and
published by the New York Daily Tribune on 23 July of the same year, m a d e
some important observations with regard to C u b a and the illegal traffic in
slaves. H e said that the Bishop of Oxford and Lord Brougham denounced
Spain as being the focal point of that nefarious traffic, and called upon the
British Government to compel that country by every means in its power to
pursue a political course consonant with existing treaties. Already in 1814 a
general treaty had been drawn u p between Great Britain and Spain under
which trading in slaves was categorically condemned by the latter. In 1817 a
special treaty had been concluded whereby Spain undertook to abolish in 1820,
in respect of its subjects, the right to engage in the slave trade, and by way of
compensation for the losses these might sustain through the application of
the treaty, was paid an indemnity of £400,000 sterling. Spain had pocketed the
m o n e y but the obligations had not been fulfilled. In 1835 another treaty had
been concluded under which Spain solemnly undertook to promulgate a penal
law of sufficient severity to m a k e it impossible for its subjects to continue
engaging in the traffic. But that law had not been adopted until over ten years
later; moreover, by a strange fatality, its most important clause—for which
The slave trade in the Caribbean 97
and Latin America
Great Britain had fought hard—had been left out, namely, the one which
placed the slave traffic and piracy on the same footing. In short, nothing
whatever had been done except that the Captain-General of Cuba, the Minister
of the Interior, the royal camarilla and, if rumour were to be believed, even the
royal family, had imposed a special tax on slave-traders and sold licences to
deal in h u m a nfleshand blood at so m a n y doubloons a h e a d . . . . Lord Malmes-
bury himself had stated that it would be possible to cover the seas between the
Spanish and C u b a n coasts with the number of documents uselessly exchanged
between the two governments.
In Cuba, before the second half of the nineteenth century, the develop-
ment achieved by the colonial economy sounded the death knell for the slave
regime. F r o m 1860 onwards, the h u m a n commodity could no longer be pro-
vided cheaply by the slave traffic. Governmental pressure on the latter was
intensified in compliance with British demands. T o induce the Spanish colonial
authorities to allow the clandestine entry of Africans, recourse had to be had
to the expensive procedure of bribery which raised the price of the commodity.
O n the sea, the relentless vigilance of the British ships gave no respite. O n e only
out of everyfiveconsignments organized managed to reach Cuban shores. T h e
traffic no longer provided a solution to the sugar-cane planters' difficulties.
The Anglo-North American Treaty of 7 April 1862 for the suppression of the
slave trade dealt thefinalblow to the clandestine slave traffic. A n d the opening
of Cuba's struggle for independence on 12 October 1868, with the massive
participation of the Africans and their Creole descendants, heralded the end
of slavery within ten years. A s far as our research enables us to say, the last
African slaves from Angola transported through the Spanish colony of Fer-
nando Po, arrived in C u b a in 1873.
Documentary sources
España. Guía de Fuentes para la Historia de Africa Subsahariana. Paris, Unesco and the
International Archives Council, 1971.
Bibliography
A B R A M O V A , S. L'Histoire de la Traite des Esclaves sur le Haut Littoral de la Guinée. Moscow,
1966. (From the second half of thefifteenthto the beginning of the nineteenth century.)
B E L T R A N , Gonzalo Aguirre. La Población Negra de Mexico. Mexico, D . F . , 1946.
B O N I L L A , Raúl Cepero. Azúcar y Abolición. Havana, 1960.
CuRTiN, P . D . The Atlantic Slave Trade. Madison, Wis., University of Wisconsin Press, 1969.
D A V I E S , K . G . The Royal African Company. London, L o n g m a n , Grion & C o . , 1957.
D E S C H A M P S , Hubert. Histoire de la Traite des Noirs de rAntiquité à nos Jours. Paris, Fayard,
1971.
D Í A Z Y S O L E R , Luis M . Historia de la Esclavitud Negra en Puerto Rico. 1493-1890. Madrid,
n.d.
D U C A S S E , André. Les Négriers ou le Trafic des Esclaves. Paris, Hachette, 1948.
F R A N C O , José Luciano. Afroamérica. Havana, 1961.
. Comercio Clandestino de Esclavos Negros en el Siglo XIX. Havana, 1971. (Historical
series N o . 21. Academy of Sciences.)
. Las Minas de Santiago del Prado y la Rebelión de los Cobreros. 1530-1800. Havana,
1975.
. Los Palenques de los Negros Cimarrones. Havana, 1971.
. La Presencia Negra en el Nuevo Mundo. Havana, 1968.
F R A N C O , José Luciano; P A C H E C O , Francisco; L E R I V E R A N D , Julio. Facetas del Esclavo
Africano en América Latina. Introducción al Cultura Africana en América Latina. Paris,
Unesco, 1970.
H E R S K O V I T S , Melville J. Social History of the Negro. Clark University, 1935. (Handbook
of Social Psychology.)
K I N G , James Ferguson. Evolution of the Free Slave Trade Principle in Spanish Colonial
Administration. The Hispanic American Historical Review. D u r h a m , February 1942.
L A C R O I X , Louis. Les Derniers Négriers. Paris, A m i o t - D u m o z , 1952.
L E R I V E R E N D , Julio. Historia Económica de Cuba. Havana, 1963.
100 José Luciano Franco
Oruno D . Lara
In order to study the Atlantic slave trade and the slave system one must first
review a number of problems and order them according to the way they link
up. Before such research is undertaken a preliminary remark is called for:
central to this vast set of problems is their c o m m o n denominator—which
should be studied in the general History of Africa—the Negro. Captured in the
course of wars or raids, dragged on foot, stocked and then embarked on slave
ships, an African was treated as a piece of merchandise before being sold into
slavery on the American plantations. This h u m a n merchandise has been written
about in two connections : (a) in connection with the slave trade, from the time
it seized the African in Africa u p to the time it sold him in America; and (b)
in connection with the slave system in which the African was forced to work
under a colonial regime.
At the beginning of any survey of the slave trade, mention must also be
m a d e of the historical links between sugar, monoculture and Negroes. These
three elements in combination remain a constant of the slave system and colo-
nial society. The slave trade is approached by historians in two ways, according
to their geographic and social environment. In the first case, the heritage of
colonial history weighs heavily, the mother country and the colony being
regarded as forming a whole. With this approach, interest is centred on Europe,
and the various questions are considered separately instead of being seen as a
whole in relation to the different government policies. For example, the French
West Indies are regarded as appendages of France in French history and there
is no link with the other West Indies or with the American mainland. They are
studied, casually, in connection with the economic history of a port such as
Marseilles, Bordeaux, Nantes or Saint-Malo where an attempt is m a d e to
follow the fortunes of natives of these towns after they went out to the Indies.
Adopting this approach, the Negro workers m a y be totally disregarded and
only the colonists studied.1 O r again the study m a y be centred on the slaves,
but without seeing the dynamics of the system and wondering, after summing
up a whole series of case histories, whether the fate of the slaves was not
102 Oruno D. Lara
iar with the history of the Caribbean. Anyone w h o is willing to refer to the
sources will see that the whole history of the slave trade and slavery is a sequence
of revolts. Seen in this light, marginal elements6 such as the M a r o o n Negroes
assume decisive importance. Studying them makes it possible to clarify the
economic and social aspects of the slave system. Centring the problem on the
M a r o o n Negroes and the slave revolts ' has the advantage of allowing one to
deal with the whole question of the method of slave exploitation without
getting involved in the intricacies of sectoral analysis.
This is the procedure adopted here. T h e history of Africa and
the black Americas extends from thefifteenthto the nineteenth century along
m a n y lines of emphasis—extrema, as the mathematicians would say—which
have economic, political, sociological and cultural aspects. A t a time when
several African and American countries are freeing themselves from colonial
tutelage, it is necessary to go back to origins, to the beginning of a process of
revolts extending over several centuries. It is impossible to understand the
liberation movements in various African countries without going back to the
violent revolts which broke out sometimes as soon as the Europeans arrived
in Africa.8
Approaching the problem from the standpoint of the Negro, in opposi-
tion to the slave system, the protagonist in a long process starting in the fifteenth
century and continuing up to our o w n time, is tantamount to founding a n e w
historical anthropology.
T h e basic records
Thefirstessential step is to go methodically through the tremendous volume
of scattered documents recording the main feature of the revolts in English,
Spanish, Portuguese, French, Dutch, Italian, Danish, Latin, etc. S o m e record
offices appear to have more material than others: the Public Record Office,
London; the Archives Nationales, Paris; and Torre do T o m b o , Lisbon. Other
centres, less well k n o w n to research workers, hold additional material which
must be consulted: the Rigsarkivet, Copenhagen; Algemeen Rijksarchief, T h e
Hague; and Det Kongelige Bibliotek, Copenhagen. It is also important, of
course, and often advantageous to consult records in provincial towns, overseas
territories and the Vatican Archives in order to obtain different viewpoints
and see the problem more clearly.
S o m e archives sources that have not been used and which afford different
approaches to the problem are listed in the Appendix (p. 115).
Research to be undertaken
It would be desirable to undertake a research programme centred on different
topics.
104 Or uno D. Lara
The Jaga problem comes under this head, or what I have called 'the long
transit of the Jaga, from Africa to the N e w World'. The Jaga broke in upon a
foursome already at loggerheads: Portugal, Congo, N d o n g o and Sao T o m é .
They were very cruel warriors enjoying political, religious and military sup-
eriority. Operating from kilombos, or stockades, they invaded the K o n g o and
laid waste the country when D o n Alvaro I (1568-87) came to the throne. H e
was obliged to abandon his capital, Säo Salvador, and take refuge on an
island in the Zaire. Their invasion disorganized the Portuguese slave trade.
The Jaga invasion should be considered in conjunction with an invasion
of Sumbas and that of the M a n e of Sierra Leone at the end of the sixteenth
century and the beginning of the seventeenth. In Guinea, a very belligerent
people, the Bijagos, w h o inhabited the Rio Grande islands, also inflicted great
destruction and took m a n y captives at the same period. Slave revolts have been
mentioned as taking place in the Cape Verde region, at Cacheu, in the seven-
teenth century (1661).
Diogo G o m e s relates in De Prima Inventione Guinée that the Portuguese
were stopped from pursuing the slave trade in the vicinity of Cape Verde and
the Guinea islands by the m e n of Besagichi, w h o greeted them with poisoned
arrows. S o m e caravels were burned. This happened towards the beginning
when the system was getting started, in the middle of thefifteenthcentury.
The Jaga invasion, in which the K w a n g o was crossed in 1568 and the
Congo invaded, was also connected with migrations which completely changed
the African interior and upset the balance of power on the Atlantic seaboard :
(a) migration of the Imbangala, w h o set out from Luanda to found the Kasanje
Kingdom in Angola at the end of the sixteenth century ; (b) Luba migration
from the old Songai empire ; (c) Lunda migration, which followed closely that
of the Imbangala; and (d) Pende migration from the coast eastwards into the
interior in Angola, under pressure from the Portuguese occupying the Luanda
salt-marshes, which were worked by the Pende, and the Imbangala and Jaga
invasions.
The following points might be mentioned:
These migrations were spread over the sixteenth century, starting at the
end of thefifteenthand continuing into the seventeenth, that is, a period which
brought the inhabitants of the African seaboard into contact with the European
slave-traders.
They were not mass migrations in which a whole people was displaced,
but military expeditions with specific targets to be destroyed. W h e n the Jaga
arrived to the west of the K w a n g o , they lived on a war-footing in their fortified
camps or kilombos between brief and effective raids. M e n and w o m e n fought
side by side, newborn babies apparently being put to death so as not to hamper
Negro resistance to slavery and the Atlantic 105
slave trade from Africa to Black America
the progress of the expedition. According to Batteil, the youngest and finest-
looking prisoners were m a d e to go through the ordeal of being used as targets.
The object of these invasions, whether or not they brought to a close
an earlier phase of migration, was to conquer and destroy the coastal kingdoms
which owed allegiance to the Europeans.
W h e n the Dutch took possession of Luanda in August 1641, they became
the allies of the Jaga, w h o cleverly exploited the conflict within the European
camp between the Portuguese and the pirates.
Four lines of research are therefore strongly advocated: (a) the Jaga
problem ('an African reaction to the slave trade'); (b) internal migrations—
origins and movements—causes. S o m e migrations had their origins in the
Sudanese—Moslem conflicts of the ninth and tenth centuries ; (c) related inva-
sions—Mane, S u m b a , Imbangala; and (d) recording oral traditions and c o m -
paring them with any written sources.
Afinalcomment: the Jaga problem is connected with that of the Angolese
of Sao T o m é , w h o apparently had the same origin, and also that of the kilombos
of colonial Brazil.9 The study of the Jaga kilombo, as described by Cavazzi,
with its seven sections carefully oriented and with several Nganga to run it,
helps us to understand the structure of its Brazilian counterpart, whichh as
similar features.
After Cape Verde and Bijagos, the Portuguese tried to occupy Sao T o m é c.
1470-86. The island of Fernando Po, the largest, which was already inhabited
at that time by Bubis Negroes, triumphantly resisted the Portuguese invaders.
' F o r m o s a ' remained theoretically under Portuguese sovereignty right until
1777, which, as the population of Sao T o m é increased, enabled the colonists
to draw on fresh supplies of slaves. Under a treaty between Spain and Portugal
ratified on 11 March 1778, Spain was granted rights over Fernando P o and
A n o - B o m and entitled to engage freely in the slave trade along the African
coast from Cape Formoso at the mouth of the Niger as far as Cape L o p o
Gonçalves, south of the G a b o n estuary, in exchange for Catarina Island and
the Sacramento colony in South America, which came under Portuguese rule.
It was not until 1858, however, that Spanish sovereignty was established firmly
by an expedition led by C o m m a n d e r Carlos Chacon.
Through the development of the sugar industry in Sao T o m é in the
sixteenth century, at the instigation of the Jewish element in the population,
the island had a considerable export trade with ramifications in the Mediter-
ranean and Europe. A s early as 1574, there were sixty engenhos producing
over 150,000 arrobas of sugar. During the years 1575-80, the production had
increased to 200,000 arrobas. By the end of the century it had reached 300,000
106 Oruno D. Lara
was a serious threat to the inhabitants of the city since, feeling that events
were likely to be precipitated, he mentioned in a letter the possibility of the
colony as a whole embarking with the forces at its disposal. It is not k n o w n
what turn the situation took after thisfirstinsurrection, which lasted more
than a year.
In 1574 the Angolese Negroes, w h o had then taken refuge in the matos
(forests) in the south of the island, in the present Pico de C a b u m b ê , came out
of their kilombos and fell upon the engenhos, pillaging and burning them. They
next m a d e for the city of Povoaçoa, where they were repulsed by firearms.
However, they occupied the whole island and Negroes employed in the engenhos
joined them. They had their headquarters on the mountain in the centre of the
island, the Pic de M o c a m b o .
The terrified inhabitants found themselves faced with an enemy enjoying
the protection of a hostile natural environment enabling it to launch surprise
attacks and then withdraw into the forest whose unexplored paths m a d e retreat
easy. T h e canefieldsand the engenhos, which were so vulnerable, had to be
defended, so a long guerra de mato had to be waged, a war of attrition which
adversely affected the prosperity of the island.
For years, the Negroes in revolt held the maquis all around the h o m e -
steads, 'at a distance of three leagues around the town', and from time to time
they attacked a roça (village) and lit a fewfireswhich devastated a district, caused
a disturbance in the town and frightened the colonists still more. W h e n Father
Baltazar Antonio visited the island in 1577, the war was still going on, if it
can be called a war with an elusive enemy moving through the woods and on
the mountain and attacking when and where it willed. H e noted that : ' os mais
dos moradores della sao pretos, porque os broncos sao poucos [most of the
residents are black; there are few whites]'. T h e exodus had already begun.
Father Diogo de Costa, w h o reached Sao T o m é in June 1584 after a four
months' voyage from Lisbon, sailed with 'ten quintals of powder and harque-
buses to arm some 70 to 80 soldiers '. Little indeed to defend the population
against those Angolese devils ! 12 So it is not surprising under the circumstances
that in 1595-96 the Angolese succeeded in taking the city under the leadership
of the legendary chieftain A m a d o r , w h o assumed the title of King of the Island.
The Portuguese, with their backs against the wall, managed to capture him
by means of a ruse and mete out retribution. The Angolese then left the city
for their kilombos in the forests, whence they continued to threaten the terror-
stricken colonists.
T o explain the economic decline which began at the end of the sixteenth
century, it is customary to refer to the sugar-cane disease13 and the promising
start of Brazilian development. However, there are other internal factors pecu-
liar to the island of Sao T o m é which must not be overlooked, such as the disor-
ganization and permanent political instability.14 Governors, bishops, commis-
108 Or uno D. Lara
sioners of audit and judges had been quarreling about land and possessions
since the time of the last donee, Joäo de Melo (sentenced in 1522). W h a t is
more, from 1567 on, foreign pirates, mainly French, then Dutch, began to
harass (apoquentar) Portuguese shipping. At the end of the century the first
Dutch attacks struck a hard blow at the island's trade. In 1599, a Dutch
squadron attacked and plundered the city of Sao T o m é . In 1641, the Dutch
took possession of the island and destroyed more than sixty engenhos de
acucara Their squadron then ruled the whole of the west coast of Africa, where
the Sao T o m é merchants traded, and m a d e things very difficult for them.
It was in this situation of internal disorder and disturbances due to
foreign competition that the insurrection of the Angolese developed. A number
of documents discovered by chance in the course of research at Torre do T o m b o
in the boxes of uncatalogued archives throw light on the tumultuous events
which attented these Negro revolts.
For instance, it would appear that 1616 marked the end of one insurrec-
tion and 1617 the beginning of another. Negro maquis existed at a distance
of three leagues from the city throughout the century. The year 1693 witnessed
a dramatic episode referred to as 'the rape of the Sabine w o m e n ' . Wives of
moradores were carried off by the Angolese, w h o attacked the engenhos. A
foray {entrada) organized by the planters to recover their wives was unsuccess-
ful. Most of the w o m e n carried off into the woods and taken into the quilombos
were coloured, if the traditional story is to be believed.
The eighteenth century began with a violent uprising of the Negro
maquis in 1709 and it is mentioned in the documents that the Mina Negroes
actively participated. Whenever the privateers attacked the homesteads, the
Negroes took advantage of the situation and attacked too. In 1709, the Angolese
went into action during the invasion of French privateers and unchained slaves
from Mina. Garrison mutinies in 1734 and 1736 also favoured these slave
revolts.
The Angolese, w h o were still a constant worry to the population, obtained
letters patent giving them a certain autonomy. Their chieftain and his represen-
tatives were respected. W h e n Mateus Sampaio climbed to the top of the Pico
de Säo T o m é in 1880 the island began to be 'rediscovered'. F r o m 1884 on,
the Angolese started abandoning their difficult existence in the kilombos.
Anthropometric studies were carried out in 1950 and 1954 by the Anthropo-
biological Mission of Angola and the Ethno-sociological Brigade of Säo T o m é
respectively.
In 1895, the Angolese formed a community of 2,000 people spread over
the area extending from Vila de Santa Cruz to Vila das Neves on the west coast
of the island.
Negro resistance to slavery and the Atlantic 109
slave trade from Africa to Black America
M a n y revolts broke out on board the slave-ships which transported all these
unwilling workers from Africa to America. F e w voyages were completed
without the Negroes in the hold attempting, sometimes desperately, to get
free. M a n y of them preferred death to captivity and the sources record m a n y
cases of suicide, achieved by a variety of means, after unsuccessful attempts to
escape. A study of the revolts on board the slave-ships remains to be m a d e ,
chiefly on the basis of the considerable volume of British records, in particular,
the log books or slave-trade ships' journals and the tales and letters written
by slavers. T h e greater part of these sources is at present lying dormant in
London, in the National Maritime M u s e u m , the British Library, the Public
Record Office, and in Bristol, Liverpool, Oxford and Edinburgh. The important
place occupied by Great Britain from the time of thefirstvoyages undertaken
by Francis Drake and John Hawkins in the reign of Elizabeth I,16 but more
especially from 1713 on, after the Treaty of Utrecht and the Asiento, which
gave that country the possibility of providing Hispanic America with an annual
supply of African workers, explains the great wealth of material to be found
in the British records.
In Dutch, French, Portuguese, Danish and American records, too, docu-
ments are to be found concerning voyages of slave-ships across the Atlantic,
which sometimes came to a tragic end as a result of the Negroes in the hold
breaking their chains andfightingfuriously for their freedom.17
The first k n o w n landing of slaves from Africa on Brazilian soil took
place in 1552, although the documents lead one to suspect that there had been
earlier ones. S o m e thirty years later, in 1580, after the founding of Loanda
in 1575 and just before the rise of the sugar industry, there were at least 10,000
Africans in Brazil. O f course this represents far less than the 4,000 slaves
imported annually to Pernambuco fifty years later. Before the time of the
bandeiras (1590-1625), that of the entradas was a period during which fugitive
Negroes, few and far between, were captured in the course of 'reconnaissance
expeditions to the interior or along the coast by the Nordeste colonists'. T h e
Negroes were already mixing with the Indian tribes pursued by colonists in
search of labour, despite the famous 'law on the freedom of the indigenous
inhabitants of Brazil' (1570), which they had amended and revised.
The Negro revolts were a great nuisance to the Governor of Pernambuco,
Diogo de Meneses, for in a letter to the king dated 23 August 1608 he requested
that aldeas be organized in the capital near the sugar-mills. In this w a y the
Negroes, w h o were so expensive and revolted against their masters, could be
advantageously replaced by Indians.
110 Oruno D. Lara
The resistance of the Negroes in Haiti during the French occupation, from
the second half of the sixteenth century up to the W a r of Toussaint
Louverture (1790-1803), which enabled Haiti to overthrow the colonial
regime.
Negroes w h o ran away from the Surinam plantations had been taking refuge
in the virgin forest and organizing themselves with the help of the Indians since
the middle of the seventeenth century. Under the governorship of Sommelsdijk,
the Dutch m a d e several attempts to wipe out bands of Maroons.
The number of rebel slaves was constantly growing, it rose from 6,000
in 1725-30 to 8,000 by the end of the century. The Dutch were obliged to
conclude a peace treaty with the Negro rebel chiefs, as were the British in
Jamaica, w h o were vanquished in the field. In 1760, Governor Crommelin
set about renewing the peace offers to the Maroons along Djuka Creek. O n
22 M a y 1761, peace was concluded with the Djuka, then in October Major
Meyer confirmed the official peace with the two most important Djuka chief-
tains : Arabi and P a m o . A year later, on 18 September 1762, the Saramaccaners
signed a peace under the same conditions. In 1767, the Becu-Musinga group,
w h o were Matwari Negroes, led by the chieftain Musinga, concluded a separate
peace with the Dutch and remained on board the Saramacca. They secured
free passage along the Vanica Creek for their products.
Afro-American insurrections
disturbances in 1810, 1819, 1831, 1834-35, 1851, 1856 and 1860. The Negroes
revolted in Florida in 1820 (Talbot Island) and in 1856 (Jacksonville). Other
revolts occurred in Alabama, in 1837, and Mississippi, in 1835.
Louisiana was also the scene of frequent insurrections. There was one
in 1804, in N e w Orleans, two in 1805 and nearly 500 Negroes marched on
N e w Orleans in 1811. There were revolts on the sugar-cane plantations in 1829,
1835, 1837, 1840, 1841, 1842 and 1856. Tennessee, Kentucky and Texas had
their share in 1831, 1856 and 1857.
All this is a far cry from the submissive 'Uncle T o m ' so readily imagined
by American authors.
Conclusion
In recent years some progress has been m a d e in historical research as a result
of the studies of a number of African, West Indian and Afro-American research
workers, w h o have tried to analyse slave society in depth. If such studies are
to be continued and if these links between Africa and America and these
sources are to be taken fully into account, group pluridisciplinary research
will have to be envisaged.
The aim should be to build up an historical anthropology bringing in
history, geography, sociology, economics and ethnology. A study of the slave
trade and of slavery as it relates to Negro resistance is essential to the under-
standing of the economic, political and ideological implications of the slave
trade for Africa and its effect on societies and powers. Incidentally it enables
one to measure the demographic implications for the African continent and
to evaluate all that the economies based on slavery gained from the slave
trade.
Notes
1. Charles Frostin, in a recent thesis, ' L e Sentiment d'Autonomisme des Colons de Saint-
Domingue, XVII e -XVIII e Siècles ', goes so far as to maintain that the Negro slaves
accepted their condition and that only the white colonists revolted against the royal
power in Santo D o m i n g o .
2. cf. Gabriel Debien, Les Esclaves aux Antilles Françaises, C h a p . X X , Fort-de-France,
Société d'Histoire de la Guadeloupe, Basse-Terre et la Société d'Histoire de la
Martinique, 1974.
3. cf. P . D . Curtin, The Atlantic Slave Trade, Madison, Wis., University of Wisconsin
Press, 1969.
4. W e are indebted to Fernand Braudel for the term ' geohistory'.
5. cf. for example, Gilberto Freyre, Casa Grande e Senzala, Rio de Janeiro, 1943. (Coleçao
Documentos Brasileños N o . 36, 36a), in which it is maintained that the slaves were
better fed than the whites and that they enjoyed their work.
6. Marginal because they refused to h o w to the constraints of the method of slave
exploitation.
114 Oruno D. Lara
Denmark1
France
Archives Nationales, Paris. A . N . Fonds Marine: Série B 2 (2.4, 234, 283); Série B 3
(235, 251, 315, 330); Série 4 JJ, Journaux de bord A/Voyages en Amérique 20,
21, 22, 27, 28, 29, 30, 31, 34, 37, 38,43, 4 4 ; B/Voyages sur les côtes occidentales
d'Afrique 61, 62, 63, 64, 65, 66, 67, 69, 70, 71 ; Série 4 JJ Supplément: 144 A ,
144 B , 144 D , 144 F, 144 G .
Records in the Departments. Bouches-du-Rhône: Série B and Série C . Gironde:
Série B , Série C (navigation and trade). Ille-et-Vilaine : Sous-série 9 B , Amirauté
de Saint-Malo; Série C=Série 4 F g (Navy and Colonies). Loire Atlantique:
Série B , Amirauté de Nantes—Records of the reports of captains of ocean-
going ships: B 4570 to 4593 (1692-1766). Inventories and documents deposited
with the Admiralty Record Office by ships' captains: 4977 to 4995. Logs:
5004 to 5006 (1706-53). Série C , Chambre de Commerce de Nantes: 722,
738 (slave trade) (1671-1790), 739 to 742, 753 (account of a Negro revolt in
Jamaica, 1760).
Municipal records. L e Havre: Série H H , 66 (1716-72)—trade with the colonies;
72 (1741-86)—the slave trade. Nantes: Série EE-267 (1691-1788); Série
FF-202 (1725); Série H H - 2 0 5 , 206, 241.
Chambers of commerce and industry. Dunkerque: Deliberations and declarations of
slave-ships' captains. Marseilles ( A . C . C . M . ) : Série H . L a Rochelle ( A . C . C . R . ) :
Boîte X I X , D o c . 6511-6767; Boîte V I (Grand Bureau); Boîte X X I , E.g. 7317
and Dossier 102. Municipal Library of L a Rochelle: N o . 856 (1787) Logs of
the Amitié.
Netherlands
Portugal
United Kingdom
Bristol Record Office, Council House, Bristol. M S S . 08226: Bills of lading, 1719-
21; M S S . 16073—H. Bright, slaver, The Sally; transporting slaves to the
Antilles. M S S . 12162: Ship's logs, 1777-91. M S S . 15326: J. H . Morgan.
M S S . 04058: town dues, 53 vols., 1790-1846.
The British Museum, Manuscripts Department. Cotton Manuscripts: C . Otho E . VIII;
C . Vespasian C . XIII. Egerton Manuscripts: 742, 929, 1806, 2395, 2543, 2597.
2648. Harley Manuscripts: 35, 39, 253, 280, 1511, 3361, 5101, 6845, 6922, 7021,
Lansdowne Manuscripts: 52, 100, 844, 1197. Sloane Manuscripts: 159, 358,
Negro resistance to slavery and the Atlantic 117
slave trade from Africa to Black America
750, 793, 894, 2292, 2496 (ff. 70-112). Stowe Manuscripts :(Stowe M S S . 166-77)
Edmondes Papers (Stowe M S S . 256-61) Phelps Papers. Additional M a n u -
scripts: A d d . 12428-40 relating to the Negro insurrections and the slave trade.
A d d . 19049, idem (1733) Newcastle Papers (add. M S S . 3286-33057). Auckland
Papers (Add. M S S . 34412-71). Liverpool Papers (Add. M S S . 38190^89), in
particular A d d . 38343 : plan to reduce the number of Caribs in Saint-Vincent,
c. 1778. Mackenzie Papers (Add. M S S . 39187-211).
Broadlands Archives. Slave Trade: S L T 1-37.
Cambridge, The University Library. D o c . : Extracts from the G . R . G . C o n w a y Col-
lection. Foreign papers : Asiento C o m p a n y , slave trade with Hispanic America.
Negro Treaty at Jamaica, 1739 (Section 21).
Historical Manuscripts Commission. Weston Underwood Manuscripts.
House of Lords, London (The Record Office). Sessional Papers: slave trade (slave-
trade ships' journals and African and West Indies trade accounts, including
slaves, 1759-1800).
Liverpool Record Office. M o o r e Papers : 920 M O O / 3 1 5 ; 1641. Norris Papers : 920 N O R ,
c. 1695-1709. Tarleton Papers: 920 T A R / 1 9 4 - 2 3 2 , 1749-1810. In particular,
K f 7, 1779-1782, K f 96, 1779-1811, concerning the voyages of different slavers,
Liverpool, West Africa, the West Indies.
National Maritime Museum. Navy Board, Lieutenants' logs: 5,205 vols. 1678-1809.
Personal papers : logs of ships sailing to the Antilles. Artificial collections, in
particular a report o n the slave trade in 1730 in the Wellcome Collection.
Individual documents: slave-ships' logs.
Oxford, Bodleian Library. Tanner Manuscripts. Ashmole Manuscripts. Clarendon
Manuscripts. Rawlinson Manuscripts: logs of several ships trading with the
Antilles and North America (Virginia). Miscellanea: M S . E n g . misc. b. 4 ,
1799.
Public Record Office, London. T h e key items are the log books. Captains' logs, 1669
to 1852, 4,563 vols., Admiralty 51. Masters' logs, 1672 to 1840, 4,660 vols.,
Admiralty 52. Ships' logs, from 1799 on, Admiralty 53. T w o additional series:
Series I, masters' logs, 1837 to 1871, 339 vols. A d m . 54. Series II, Explorations,
1766 to 1861,162 vols. A d m . 55. Slave trade: 1816 to 1892. F . O . 84, 2,276 vols.
Slave trade: archives of commissions: F . O . 312 to 315, Cape T o w n , Havana,
Jamaica, Sierra Leone.
United Kingdom
Archives of Commissions. Slave Trade. Cape T o w n : (F.O. 312) 1843 to 1870.43 vols.
Havana: ( F . O . 313) 1819 to 1869. 67 vols.
Berkshire Record Office. Leicester manuscripts: D / E K m B 2 and B 3 (1724, 1734).
Bodleian Library, Oxford. M S . E n g . misc. b . 44 ff. 50-1 (1799). M S . E n g . misc. b . 44
ff. 9 3 - 4 (1792).
118 Oruno D.Lara
Bristol Record Office. Bills of Lading: 1719-21 (08226). Elbridge family, estate papers:
A C / W O / 1 0 (1744-1800). Bright, Henri, Insurance policy: 1762 (16073).
Robinson, John and Tench, John: 1772 (10931). Morgan, James H : 1778
(15326). T o w n dues, 53 vols: 1790-1846 (04058).
British Museum, Department of Manuscripts. Harley Manuscripts. Lansdowne M a n u -
scripts. Sloane Manuscripts. Stowne Manuscripts. Additional Manuscripts.
Broadlands Archives, London. Slave trade: S L T 36 (1859).
Hampshire Record Office, Winchester. Blachford papers: 8 M 57 (1725), 8 M 57/194-
226,235 (1852, 1853).
House of Lords original papers. Slave trade: slave trade ships'journals (1789-1800).
Individual documents. 1743; 1793-94; 1833-36.
Lancashire RecordOffice. D D X 22/8 (1774-78); D D d 239/3-14; D D X 428/5 (1833-36).
Liverpool Record Office. Tarleton papers: K f 7, 1779-82; K f 96, 1779-1811; 380
M D 33-6 (1754-69).
The National Maritime Museum. Natural Collections: Section I. Central Records.
Merchant Navy: shipping records 1787-1856, 44 vols.; ships' log books and
crew lists, 34 vols.
Public Libraries, Bristol. Jefferies Collection: Vol. XIII letters c. 1722-36.
Public Record Office. Legal Records: C.108/280 1606, 1746. High court of Admiralty:
slave trade—government reports (H.C.A.35) 1821 to 1891, 89 vols.; slave
trade: additional papers (H.C.A.36) 1837 to 1876, 8 cartons; treasury papers:
(H.C.A.37) 1821 to 1897, 229 boxes; warrant books: (H.C.A.38) 1541 to 1772,
77 vols.; miscellanea: (H.C.A.30) 1531 to 1888,803 boxes and vols. Admiralty:
log books; station records: Africa, North America and West Indies. Colonial
Office: colonies, general—colonial papers, general series (C.O.I.) 1574 to 1757;
America: original correspondence (C.O.5) 1606 to 1807. Antigua and Mont-
serrat: (C.O.7). Bahamas: (C.O.29). Barbados: (C.O.28). Curaçao: (C.O.66).
Dominica: (C.O.71). Grenada: (C.O.101). Guadeloupe: (C.O.110). Guiana,
British: (C.O.lll). Jamaica: (C.O.137). Leeward Islands: (C.O.152). Marti-
nique: (C.O.166). Montserrat: (C.O.175). St Christopher: (C.O.239). San
D o m i n g o : (C.O.245). St Vincent: (C.O.260). Surinam: (C.O.278). Tobago:
(C.O.285). Trinidad: (C.O.295). Virgin Islands: (C.O.314). West Indies:
(C.O.318). Windward Islands: (C.O.321).
Scottish Record Office Edinburgh. Seaforth: G D 46/17/24 (1803-06). G D 46/17/2a
(1804-05).
C. E. Turner, Esq., Messrs E. W. Turner and Son, Liverpool. Letter books of instruc-
tions to masters of slaving ships with replies from captains, principally concerned
with West Indian voyages, eighteenth century.
Portuguese participation in the slave
trade : opposing forces, trends of opinion
within Portuguese society : effects on
Portugal's socio-economic development
Françoise Latour da Veiga Pinto assisted by A . Carreira
Slave trading went hand in hand with the great Portuguese discoveries of the
fifteenth century. It was probably not initially one of the purposes of trading
expeditions ; but it was in keeping with the spirit of the time, and people took
naturally to it. Its progressive growth was the result of changes in the economic
motives underlying Portugal's expansion.
The conquest of Ceuta in 1415 marked the beginning of Portugal's
maritime adventure, which subsequently started other nations off on the road
to the conquest of new continents and led to the expansion of Europe.
The earliest navigators to round the coast of Africa were prompted
mainly by two economic motives : to discover the source of production of
Sudanese gold, which had so far reached Europe via North Africa, and to
find the sea route to India and her silk and spice markets.
But the ideals of the crusades also played their part, and gave moral and
religious backing to the expeditions. W h e n thefirstsailor-knights rounded the
coast of Africa, they were also in search of the kingdom of Préster John, in
the hope of making c o m m o n cause with him against the infidel. Taking Muslim
prisoners was in any case regarded as a deed of valour deserving the Church's
indulgence. Thus thefirstNegroes to be captured were taken by m e n convinced
that they were doing a great feat—and also a virtuous deed, since every one
of the 'wretches' baptized meant a soul w o n for G o d . The technique initially
used to acquire thefirstslaves,filhamentoor kidnapping, was likewise inherited
from the Middle Ages : surprise attacks were m a d e on isolated n o m a d camps
and the captives brought back to Portugal, with—as recorded by G o m e s Eanes
de Zurara in his Guinea Chronicle (1453)—the 'holy purpose of saving lost
souls'. It was N u n o Tristao w h o in 1441 had the dubious honour of bringing
back thefirstNegroes direct from the west coast of Africa, south of Cape
Bojador: they were Zenaga nomads.
The island of Arguin was discovered in 1443, and on 8 August 1444
(writes Zurara) thefirstpublic sale of slaves was held at Lagos in the presence
120 Françoise Latour da Veiga Pinto,
A . Carreira
of Prince Henry, instigator of the African expeditions. The choicest slaves had
previously been offered to the Church.
F r o m this time on, slave trading came to be regarded both as a means of
providing a commodity exportable to Spain and Italy and as a source of domes-
tic and agricultural labour for Portugal itself. The latter aspect became increas-
ingly important during the fifteenth and sixteenth centuries, as Portugal's
expansion called for more and more manpower. At that time Portugal had a
population estimated at only around 1.5 million. M e n w h o went to sea or
settled in the colonies needed to be replaced; and Negro slave labour met this
need. A third factor very soon came into the calculation when it was realized
h o w useful the blacks were for sugar cultivation. This commodity, still extremely
rare, had been introduced into Europe by the Arabs. Attempts had been m a d e to
grow it in Portugal itself, in the Algarve, but with only very limited success
because it took too m u c h out of the soil. The discovery of the Atlantic islands,
however, was to bring about the rise of the sugar-cane industry and pave the
way for the introduction and development of its corollary, the Atlantic slave
trade.
The Spaniards had earlier introduced sugar cultivation into the Canary
Islands, using the Guanches as slaves. Prince Henry, w h o had been granted by
the crown a trading monopoly for the newly discovered territories, followed
their example in Madeira and the Azores. The Negroes turned out to be more
docile as labourers than the Guanches, and were very soon being re-exported
from Portugal to the islands. D e m a n d grew rapidly in consequence, compelling
the traders to introduce a less 'primitive' method of acquisition than kid-
napping. They had quickly realized that the filhamento system was excessively
bad for trade : for the coastal peoples had soon learnt to beware of ships, and
avoided going on to the beach so as not to be taken prisoner. T h e traders
therefore sought to establish normal trading relations on a barter basis; and
for this they very early used thefirstcaptives as interpreters. The role of the
latter was very important for the development of the trading system. T h e
Venetian C á da Mosto, employed in the service of the Portuguese crown,
records that some slaves, once they had been baptized and could speak their
masters' language, were put aboard caravels and sent back a m o n g their kins-
m e n : they then became freed m e n when they had brought in four new slaves.
They also furnished valuable information, both geographical—e.g. about
deposits of precious metals—and commercial, such as lists of goods in demand
a m o n g the natives, and their habits and customs. Once the Portuguese realized
that they could acquire slaves by a peaceful exchange of goods which the chiefs
and their go-betweens were avid for, a regular trade began to operate. There
was, after all, a meeting of supply and demand : for slavery formed part of
the social system a m o n g the peoples of Senegambia and Guinea, and it was
normal to sell one's o w n kind if they were prisoners of war or were under
Portuguese participation in the slave trade 121
sentence for adultery, felonies or magical reasons. It was also a more refined
way of getting rid of hot-heads and undesirables than by putting them to
death. The traders were therefore to find the same ease of exchange all round
the coast of Africa.
The Portuguese, moreover, were also reaping the benefit of the m u c h more
long-standing internal trade which had been set up by the Arabs. Trans-Saharan
trade started from the Sudan, which furnished gold and slaves taken by the
Islamized Sahel peoples in forays on the area to the south. O n e route was via
the staging-post of H o d e n in the Sahara, where the captives were split u p : some
were bound for Barco, on the coast of Cyrenaica, whence they were sent on to
Tunis and Sicily, while others were taken to Arguin to be sold to the Portuguese
in exchange for horses, wheat and textiles.
This trading system led the Portuguese crown in 1455 to build a fortress
at Arguin. A s Jaime Cortesäo has shown, the foundation of Arguin marked a
turning-point in the organization of Portuguese trade. Conquest and its corol-
lary, the kidnapping and forcible taking of slaves, were replaced by peaceful
trade accompanied by a show of force in the shape of the building of a fortress
—which could in case of need serve as a refuge. The establishment of Arguin
was also to set the pattern for buildings subsequently erected all along the coast
of Africa, not only by the Portuguese but also by their European rivals. Arguin
likewise served as a port of call for ships sent to reconnoitre the south ; and
the trade soon began to thrive. C á da Mosto in 1455 reckoned the number of
slaves brought to Portugal annually at 700-800. A special administration, the
Casa dos Escravos, was set up in Lisbon, and the customs house in the capital
recorded the entry of 3,589 slaves from 1486 to 1493, not including arrivals
from Lagos. C . R . Boxer puts the number of slaves captured by the Portuguese
in Africa between 1450 and 1500 at 150,000.
Then, as territories suitable for colonization were discovered, sugar-cane
cultivation was introduced into them, entailing a need for manpower which had
to be brought from the coast of Africa. This was w h y , after the discovery of
the Cape Verde archipelago, the king of Portugal in 1466 granted the first
settlers a monopoly of the slave trade on the African coast opposite the archi-
pelago, both to provide labour for the plantations and also to help populate
these uninhabited territories. They were, however, forbidden to sell the slaves
outside.
A s the trade increased, the crown wished to control it—without, however,
being able to take it in hand directly. It therefore sought to derive profit from
the trade while keeping its o w n risk to a m i n i m u m ; accordingly it set u p a
farming-out system, the contratos. In 1469 Afonso V granted Fernäo G o m e s
thefirstcontract, giving him the exclusive right to the Guinea trade for five
years (subsequently extended for a further three) in return for an annual
lump-sum payment to the crown and an obligation to discover a hundred leagues
122 Françoise Latour da Veiga Pinto,
A . Carreira
of coast a year, working southward from Sierra Leone. The Arguin trade and
that of the coastal belt, which had been granted to the inhabitants of Cape
Verde, were excluded from the contract. Fernäo G o m e s was successful in his
enterprise, and thanks to his initiative the islands of Sao T o m é and Principe
were dicovered between 1470 and 1472. Thus the contract system, which was
to operate throughout the duration of the Atlantic trade, came into being.
The Spanish asiento was based on a similar system for the delivery of slaves.
Meanwhile the gold trame was increasing in volume, though the Portu-
guese failed to reach the mines and had to be content with trading on the coast.
In 1482 they built a fortress, Säo Jorge da Mina, which m a d e possible a great
expansion of trade in that area. Ironically, one of the barter items the Portu-
guese used to obtain gold dust was slaves, brought mainly from Benin.
F r o m 1483 onwards Diogo Cäo's voyages of discovery opened the doors
of Central Africa to the Portuguese, through the intermediary of the Kingdom
of K o n g o . Thus another centre of the slave trade came into being contempora-
neously with the colonization of Säo T o m é , where the cultivation of sugar cane
quickly developed. Thefirstsettlers on the island were deportees and converted
Jewish children—'new Christians'—who were married off to slaves brought
initially from Guinea and subsequently from K o n g o . This mestico society soon
became slave-traders, after the inhabitants of Säo T o m é had obtained from the
king the privilege of resgate or purchase on the African coast opposite the
archipelago.
W h e n the Portuguese reached the mouth of the Zaire (Congo) river they
found themselves, for the first time in Africa, in contact with a powerful,
well-organized kingdom. T h efirstembassy to arrive at the capital, M b a n z a ,
situated upstream in the interior, was well received by the sovereign, w h o was
receptive to European beliefs and skills. Despite some vicissitudes, after the
accession in 1505 of the manikongo D o m Afonso a very special relationship
grew u p between the Portuguese crown and this African monarchy. D o m
Afonso was genuinely anxious to transform his country with the help of the
whites, while preserving its independence. Several members of the royal house
went to Lisbon, and Catholicism became the State religion. Nevertheless the
real interests of the Portuguese crown in the early sixteenth century were
elsewhere; and, although the king of Portugal kept up a correspondence with
the manikongo, and sent him missionaries and craftsmen, D o m Afonso's hopes
were disappointed and his country fell inescapably into a state of decline. There
were several reasons for this, all more or less directly connected with the slave
trade. Portugal at that time was being pulled in different directions by wide and
varied interests. Having m a d e herself mistress of the route to India, her main
commercial activity was concentrated on the silk and spice trade. The discovery
of Brazil in 1500 led to the introduction of sugar cultivation there in the mid-
sixteenth century; and this in turn brought about an increased demand for
Portuguese participation in the slave trade 123
African labour, once its superiority to native labour was realized. The Spanish
West Indies also began to import slaves for their sugar plantations, while
there was still a demand for labour in metropolitan Portugal and its Atlantic
islands. Thus the m o m e n t when Central Africa, through the kingdom of K o n g o ,
was opening its doors to Western influence coincided with a need for manpower
which was to be met by slave trading. It would be hard tofinda clearer example
of the deep misunderstanding to which the slave trade gave rise between Africa
and Europe : here an opportunity was lost and never regained. It is of course
true that in K o n g o , as elsewhere in Africa, traditional institutions were such
as to facilitate the development of the slave trade; but the fact remains that
the manikongo's hopes of giving his people access to white skills, and so
bringing them out of their isolation, were cruelly betrayed. Moreover, the
kingdom of K o n g o had no other goods to offer except slaves; and, once it
engaged in this trade, it was bound sconer or later to be at the mercy of the law
of supply and demand, and of various competing interests, both abroad, in
the shape of slave-traders, and at h o m e , in the shape of neighbouring peoples
also involved in the trade.
The settlers of Sao T o m é grew more and more active and imported slaves
in ever-increasing numbers, not only for their o w n h o m e market but also for
export. At the same time they gradually established themselves in the kingdom
and along the river, continually improving their links with the hinterland.
During his reign, which lasted until 1543, D o m Afonso managed to curb the
trade within his kingdom; and m a n y times he repudiated it in his letters to the
king of Portugal. But he could not prevent his vassals from enriching themselves
through the trade, while his o w n enfeebled kingdom became the object of
covetousness from across his borders. W h e n he died, his successors were unable
to stop either the growth of slave trading or the attacks of neighbouring tribes
aimed at making prisoners of war to exchange for the whites' barter goods. The
number of slaves being exported from the port of Mpinda around 1530 has
been estimated at 4,000 to 5,000 a year. Meanwhile Brazil's manpower needs
led the traders to look towards the south. Angola was at that time more thickly
populated than K o n g o , and was better able to meet this increased demand.
Moreover the dealers were interested in having their purchasing areas closer
to their embarkation points, so as to reduce as m u c h as possible the loss of
slaves in transit, which was always heavy. Early in the sixteenth century,
traders developed the habit of going direct to the Angolan coast : they first
reached Ambriz, then the Dande and the Cuanza. In so doing they were acting
against the interests both of the Portuguese crown, to which they paid no taxes,
and of the manikongo, by encouraging his vassals to deal with them direct.
With the decline of the kingdom of K o n g o , Portugal's focus of interest shifted
to Angola. In 1571 the king of Portugal granted Paulo Dias de Nováis a deed
of gift over Angola: in so doing he abandoned his policy of exercising loose
124 Françoise Latour da Veiga Pinto,
A . Carreira
sovereignty, and for thefirsttime in Africa adopted the sytem of direct rule.
Dias de Nováis, w h o hoped to find silver mines in the interior, was appointed
governor for life and donee of the area between the D a n d e and the Cuanza
rivers. The crown, as it had done in Brazil, also granted him a captaincy, while
itself retaining the monopoly of the slave trade. But Paulo de Nováis' hopes of
finding precious metals were disappointed; and Angola, in its turn, lost any
means of arousing Portugal's interest except through her manpower. The slave
trade was in fact to m a k e rapid strides at Luanda and, from 1617 (the date of
its foundation), at Säo Filipe de Benguela.
Thus by the sixteenth century the triangular trade, which was to continue
until the nineteenth century, was already established. Apart from Mina gold,
and a few secondary products, Africa was regarded solely as a reservoir of
manpower for the sugar plantations of the Atlantic islands, Brazil and Spanish
America: Europe supplied the manufactured goods.
But the size of the sugar-cane industry, and with it of the slave trade,
aroused the envy of the European powers ; and from the end of the sixteenth
century onwards they did everything in their power to break Portugal's m o n o -
poly. For, after the Treaty of Tordesillas in 1494, the Pope had divided the
world between Spain and Portugal : Africa, Asia and Brazil went to Portugal,
and the rest of America to Spain. The disparity of these rights led to a change
in international law, and the authority of the Pope came under attack from the
Protestant schism. With the enunciation of the Grotius doctrine, the freedom
of the seas was proclaimed; moreover, in practice, the British and Dutch
shattered the maritime hegemony of Spain and Portugal by the end of the
century.
U p to then, Portugal had nevertheless held the monopoly of the slave
trade, although smuggling had been going on from the beginning. But, u p to
the end of the century, attacks by foreign powers—Britain and Holland—had
been mainly directed against the monopoly of Mina gold rather than against
that of slaves. The Dutch-Portuguese war at the beginning of the seventeenth
century, and the foreign competition that followed, finally broke Portugal's
monopoly.
However, despite domestic difficulties caused by the crisis over the m o n -
archy, and foreign wars, Portugal succeeded in keeping an important role in
the slave trade. This was due to the connections she had built up between the
centres of supply—Africa—and of demand—Brazil ; and also to the systems
instituted by the crown for controlling the trade. There were three such systems.
The commonest was that of farming out to a con tratador (thefirstbeing Fernao
G o m e s ) , w h o did virtually nothing but collect an indirect tax, for he was
authorized to issue licences (avengas) to slave traders. The contratadores usually
lived in Lisbon, while the avençadores were the actual slave-traders. Secondly,
the crown itself, quite apart from farming out under contract, issued licences
Portuguese participation in the slave trade 125
direct for the purchase of a specified number of slaves against the payment of
a per capita duty. Lastly, the crown sometimes had recourse to direct manage-
ment through an administrator. This system was rarely used, and was only a
temporary measure to tide over the interval between two contracts. At certain
times these systems co-existed. Farming-out contracts and licences came within
the purview of the royal institutions, such as the Casa da Guiñé (later k n o w n
as the Casa da Guiñé e Mina, and then as the Casa da India), of which the
Casa dos Escravos was one section. Persons authorized to deal in slaves were
also allowed to deal in imported barter goods.
Table 1 is a list drawn up by Antonio Carreira of the main farming-out
contracts from the end of thefifteenthcentury to the beginning of the seven-
teenth :
T A B L E 1—contd
1583-89 Cape Verde and Alvaro Mendes do Because of the great drought
Guinea rivers Crato and Diogo of 1585-87, the contractors
Fernandes were granted an extension
of the contract to the
end of 1590 by way of
compensation.
7-1591 Cape Verde Alvaro Vieira
(Windward
Islands)
1587-93 Angola, Congo Pedro de Sevilha and
and Sao T o m é Antonio Mendes de
Damego
1600-03 Angola Joäo Rodrigues
Coutinho
1613-14 Angola and Cape Antonio Fernandes de
Verde Elvas
1607-08 Cape Verde (unidentified)
1609-14 Cape Verde Joäo Soeiro
1615-? Cape Verde Duarte Pinto de Elvas
1616-? Cape Verde Joäo de Sousa
1617-23 Cape Verde Antonio Fernandes de
Elvas
1624-27 Cape Verde Jácome Fixer
1627-32 Cape Verde and André da Fonseca
Angola
1632-42 Cape Verde Joäo Gonçalves da
Fonseca
There are some gaps in the list. It gives the dates of the drawing-up of the
contracts but not of their signature. It also shows h o w vaguely geographical
areas were defined, thus demonstrating: (a) the lack of accurate geographical
knowledge of the African hinterland (only the points on the coast are stated);
and (b) the fact that the crown had no control over the contractors.
Examples of licences granted by the king north of the Equator, quite
apart from and contemporaneously with farming-out contracts, include one
to Lourenco Alvares for 100 Negroes in 1563; to Dento V a z for 600 Negroes
in 1565; to Manual Caldeira for 2,000 Negroes in 1568 (he also had a farming-
out contract for Sao T o m é and Mina); to Alvaro Mendes de Crasto for 3,000
Negroes in 1583; to Joäo Batista Ravalesca for 1,800 Negroes in 1583; and to
Joseph Ardevicus for 600 Negroes in 1680 for Para and Maranhäo. It is inter-
esting to note that these avengas were issued in large numbers: thus, from 1604
to 1608 the contratador for Angola issued 17,000 licences, while himself remain-
ing in Lisbon.
Portuguese participation in the slave trade 127
The royal monopoly did not extend to Brazil, where slaves could enter
freely, in contrast to the Spanish West Indies which were subject to the asiento
system. The original law providing for the collection of export duty o n slaves
is not extant : the most plausible document on the subject is one by Abreu de
Brito (1592), in which he gives afigureof 3,000 reis a head when the destina-
tion was Brazil and 6,000 reis for the Spanish West Indies. Joäo Rodrigues
Coutinho seems to have arbitrarily increased the duty by 1,000 reis a head
during the 1600s. The vagueness of the texts and the lack of other sources led
Antonio Carreira to the conclusion that the contractors altered the rate of
duty to suit their o w n interests and convenience.
At the end of the sixteenth century, Portugal underwent a great political change
with the union of the crowns of Spain and Portugal in the person of Philip II
of Spain. The sixty years (1580-1640) of Spanish rule over Portugal were far
more important than this item of domestic politics might atfirstsight suggest :
indeed, the period marks a turning-point in European colonial history, and
in the development of the American colonies and its corollary, the slave trade.
During the sixteenth century, Portugal's rivals had tried to break her
maritime supremacy in the Atlantic. These attacks were the work of pirates
and traders, and were successfully repulsed. There had been attempts at occupa-
tion and even raids against the coasts of Mina, Guinea, Cape Verde and Brazil ;
and though they were pointers to the envy aroused by the trade in gold, slaves
and sugar, they were no more than sporadic. The French had tried to establish
themselves in Brazil in 1555, and often carried out attacks on shipping. Cape
Verde likewise underwent regular assaults by the French and British: in 1578
Drake even went so far as to try to occupy Mina.
But after the union of the two crowns these activities, which had hitherto
amounted to nothing more than smuggling and piratical forays, became inter-
national conflicts. Attacks directed against the presence of Portugal in Africa
were obviously designed to wrest her trade from her. T h e wars which Spain
and Portugal faced with the powers of northern Europe had three main objects
as far as Portugal was concerned: to supplant her in her trade with the Orient,
to take over the sugar plantations of Brazil, and (as a sequel) to take over the
sources of African labour.
The union of the two crowns enabled Spain's enemies to turn also against
Portugal; for, though Philip II had decided to leave internal affairs in the hands
of the Portuguese, foreign policy was joint. In this struggle, the most relentless
foes were the United Provinces. Incursions into Africa started in 1598. Then a
twelve-year truce was signed with Holland, in return for the freedom of Portu-
128 Françoise Latour da Veiga Pinto,
A . Carreira
guese ports to Dutch trade. But when the truce ended,fightingbroke out afresh.
The Dutch systematically attacked the vital centres of the empire, disrupted the
trade with the Orient, and occupied one by one the key points of sugar produc-
tion in Brazil and their sources of supply of slaves in Africa. F r o m 1630 to
1641 north-eastern Brazil, including Recife, Pernambuco and Maranhäo, fell
into the hands of the Dutch, while Bahia was twice compelled to surrender.
After the signature of the peace treaty with Britain in 1635, Holland continued
the war and m a d e themselves masters of the Portuguese possessions in Africa :
Mpinda, Sao T o m é , Luanda and Benguela fell into their hands in rapid succes-
sion in 1641.
The Dutch then gained the support of the African chiefs, w h o were
anxious to shake off the Portuguese yoke. The manikongo Garcia II and the
Governor of Sonho dealt direct with the Dutch East India C o m p a n y , even
sending emissaries to Brazil and Holland to establish closer trading relations.
Angola, moreover, was very far from being pacified or colonized, and took
advantage of the Dutch-Portuguese conflict; the uprising there was personified
by the legendary Queen Nzinga, w h o succeeded in rallying around her the
M b u n d u peoples of N d o n g o and M a t a m b a . Caught between twofires,the
Portuguese in Angola seemed to be in a desperate situation. Events turned in
their favour, however, after the restoration of a Portuguese dynasty in 1640.
The Dutch refused to m a k e peace, for Portugal in her weakened state seemed
doomed to lose her Atlantic empire. But the Portuguese settlers in Brazil
rebelled against the Dutch and drove them out of the country. Then, following
the liberation of the American colony, the great landowers were soon concerned
to re-establish the slave trade on a normal footing so as to provide their
plantations with slaves. Thus it was from Brazil that the three expeditions set
out that were to drive the Dutch from the coasts of Angola and the mouth of
the Congo. In 1648 the Portuguese reoccupied the main centres of the slave
trade south of the Equator.
F r o m that time onwards, Brazil became the mainstay of the Portuguese
empire. Trade with India having become secondary, Portugal's economic sphere
of influence was to be centred on the Atlantic through the triangular trade :
the two poles of attraction being Brazil with its plantations (and later its mines)
and Africa as the supplier of manpower. Portugal's role was merely to provide
manufactured goods and to serve as a staging-post between her two colonies.
Portugal then directed all her efforts towards her American colony,
which was rapidly developing. Sugar was n o w in everyday use in Europe. The
plantations needed slaves, and the Brazilian Indians (who had the protection
of the Jesuits, and were not such good workers as the Africans) were replaced
by Negroes. T h e industrialization of sugar-cane cultivation was to lead to a
great 'slave famine' from the second half of the seventeenth century onwards,
not only in Brazil but throughout America.
Portuguese participation in the slave trade 129
Angola that supplied the bulk of them. The mine-owners needed strong m e n ,
and the yellow metal allowed them to pay higher prices for them than the plan-
ters did. There was thus more incentive to import slaves through Rio de Janeiro
—for Minas Gérais—than through Bahia, and this led to conflict between the
two towns. T o end the dispute, the crown eventually had to introduce an import
quota system as between Rio de Janeiro, Bahia, Recife and Paraiba. Thus
Angola, forsaken by the mother country, and with a population m a d e up of
slave traders, convicts, adventurers and slaves, was nevertheless, as C . R . Boxer
has pointed out, 'the corner-stone of the Portuguese Empire'. For Brazil's
prosperity depended on Angolan manpower, and Portugal's prosperity
depended on Brazilian sugar, tobacco, gold and diamonds.
However, foreign competition and the extent of smuggling led the Portu-
guese crown to attempt some reforms. Following the example of its competi-
tors, Lisbon was to set up large companies to counter the decline of the Guinea
trade and to m a k e good the military forces, which were inadequate to protect
the slave trade. N o n e of these companies was ever as successful as their foreign
counterparts, but they are still worth mentioning. The oldest, the Guinea Coast
or Port Palmida C o m p a n y , was founded on 1 September 1664; little is known
about its activities, which were of no great importance. The same applies to the
Companhia de Cacheu, Rios e Costa da Guiñé, set up in 1676, which was
granted a six-year monopoly of the transport of slaves from this area for
Brazil. But the people of Säo Tiago viewed the setting up of this enterprise
with deep mistrust, thinking (no doubt rightly) that it was directed against them
and would deprive them of their freedom of action. O n 12 February 1682 it
was succeeded by the Companhia do Estanco do Maranhao e Para, with a
twenty-year concession: it undertook in that space of time to introduce 10,000
slaves (i.e. an average of 500 a year) into that part of Brazil. It also had a
monopoly of trade in that province. Produce for export was exempt from duty
for ten years. The purchase of slaves had to be carried out in Angola. This
enterprise aroused such hostility a m o n g the settlers that it was disbanded after
three years of operation and its property was confiscated.
O n 14 January 1690 the Companhia de Cacheu e Cabo Verde was set up,
with a lifespan until December 1696: a clause was included in the contract
forbidding the sale of slaves to ' heretics '. Its powers were limited, and conse-
quently its activities were of no great importance. W h e n the contract expired,
the crown negotiated with Spain the transfer of the company's powers and
part of its property to the (Spanish) Royal Commission for India, which on
12 July 1699 obtained the asiento, for a period of six years and eight months,
for the following ports: C u m a n a , Caracas, Havana, Cartagena, Puertovelo,
Honduras and Vera Cruz. Purchasing had to be carried out on the Guinea
Coast to a total of 10,000 tons (of slaves), each estimated at three 'India pieces'
(i.e. a strong full-grown m a n ) of uniform seven-foot stature, the old and those
Portuguese participation in the slave trade 131
with physical defects being excluded. The Spanish crown associated itself with
the enterprise, contributing 200,000 pesos towards the building up of its fleet
This company was as short-lived as the rest, for it was dissolved in 1706.
It was only with the Pombal government that well-structured companies
m a d e their appearance. A s far as the slave trade was concerned, they were
intended to reorganize the triangular trade and to combat the smuggling that
had prevailed on a large scale since the demand for slaves had increased in
Brazil. Ship-owners in the service of Brazilian planters had got into the habit
of obtaining supplies direct, outside the contracts allocated by the crown—
even, in times of acute shortage, going as far as Mozambique. T w o companies
were set up almost simultaneously: the Companhia Geral do Gràu Para e
Maranhäo in 1755 and the Companhia Geral de Pernambuco e Paraiba in
1759. They divided the slave-trade area between themselves, the former c o m -
pany operating in the Guinea coast and Cape Verde area, the latter in Angola
and on the Mina coast. They both had exclusiverightsto the slave and other
trade for twenty years. The Companhia do Maranhäo was in 1757, by a secret
rider, granted additional powers authorizing it to exercise military and political
authority for twenty years in the part of Africa for which it had a concession.
These powers entitled it to organize the trade in Guinea and Cape Verde,
where it likewise fostered the production of subsidiary exports such as cotton
goods and archil. It also took the praiseworthy step of giving a great impetus
to agriculture (particularly the growing of rice, cotton and cocoa) in the
Maranhäo area. O n e of the aims in setting up the company was to ensure a
regular supply of slaves ; and the policy was therefore adopted of making a
profit not so m u c h on the sale of slaves as on the produce of their labour.
Hence, though both companies were reasonably prosperous and could dis-
tribute regular dividends to their shareholders, the Companhia de Pernambuco
e Paraiba showed a loss on the slave trade, and the C o m p a n h a do Maranhäo
a slight profit. The goods supplied by Brazil in exchange were mainly tobacco
and rum. These two companies were dissolved, the former in 1778 and the
latter in 1787, without having been able to eliminate the smuggling, which
remained considerable both in slaves and in overseas produce. It was carried
on from Brazil, mainly by the British. The setting u p of these companies is
clear proof that the triangular system and the so-called 'colonial pact'
inspired by mercantilism, which together formed the basis of the Portuguese
empire's prosperity, were threatened by the free trade which the British were
beginning to practise.
Just as, at the end of the sixteenth century, Portugal had been confronted by
one of the greatest crises in her history, as the result of failure to adapt herself
132 Françoise Latour da Veiga Pinto,
A . Carreira
to the nex order of the freedom of the seas which had replaced the Papacy's
arbitrary division of the world between two nations, so, at the beginning of the
nineteenth century, she w a s unprepared to face the n e w economic order dic-
tated by Great Britain on the basis of free trade. This system again threatened
the existence of her empire, based as it was on the triangular trade and the
colonial pact. T h e slave trade, with its rules and its organized markets, was
inimical to free trade; and the atrocities that had followed one another endlessly
for centuries in the course of the trade were beginning to revolt public opinion.
It would perhaps be more accurate to say that the voices that were raised in
opposition were beginning to get a hearing—others raised earlier having fallen
on deaf ears—and this was happening in Great Britain. Following a long
humanitarian campaign in which such m e n as Sharp, Wilberforce and Macaulay
w o n renown, Great Britain abolished the slave trade on 25 M a r c h 1807. Thence-
forth, the British Government did its utmost to persuade the powers that prac-
tised it to m a k e an end of it. Under pressure from Great Britain, Portugal,
on 19 February 1810, signed a treaty of alliance and friendship, under Article X
of which she undertook
to co-operate in the cause of humanity and justice, by adopting the most efficacious
means for bringing about a gradual Abolition of the Slave Trade throughout the whole
of her territories . . . while reserving to her own vassals in the African territories of the
Portuguese Crown the right to purchase and deal in slaves.
The Portuguese Government, however, had only given in to Great Britain out
of weakness. It had had to take refuge in Brazil, and British support was its
only hope of reconquering its metropolitan territory. T h e abolition of the slave
trade in so rapid and radical a w a y raised problems that were practically
insoluble. Portugal at that time had virtually n o industry; and the economic
transformation of the country was bound to be slow, laborious and beset
with great difficulties.
At the congress of Vienna, Portugal managed to m a k e her case heard.
Under the treaty of 22 January 1815 she obtained the annulment of the previous
agreement. F r o m then on the prohibition applied only to the slave trade north
of the Equator, thus exempting Brazil's trade with Angola, the C o n g o and
Mozambique. The powers that Great Britain was urging to abolish the slave
trade confined themselves to declaring that they were animated
by the desire to co-operate in the most prompt and effective execution of this measure
by all the means at their command, and to use these means with all the zeal and perse-
verance due to so great andfinea cause; [adding that]... thefixingof the time when
this trade must universally cease shall be a matter for negotiation between the Powers.
Portuguese participation in the slave trade 133
This clearly shows that, with the exception of Great Britain, no country at
that time genuinely desired to take immediate or decisive steps.
But the slave trade as a method of recruiting manpower was d o o m e d
in the m e d i u m or long term. The planters and slave-traders realized this—so
m u c h so that the trade took on a spectacular n e w lease of life.
At the same time, Portugal's Atlantic Empire was undergoing profound
and irreversible changes. Since 1808 Portugal had been brought by Great
Britain to take a series of measures that were to impair her future relations
with Brazil. They entailed the opening to trade of all Brazilian ports, and the
ending of the rules reserving to Portugal the processing of colonial raw mat-
erials. Then, in 1810, Great Britain obtained 'most favoured Nation' treatment;
andfinally,in 1811, all ports in Portuguese colonies were opened to trade. But
these liberalizing measures, which were particularly advantageous for Great
Britain, were also highly beneficial to Brazil : for the presence of the government
and the court at Rio de Janeiro, and the liberalization of the economy, gave
rise to an unprecedented development in the colony : administrative, political,
economic and cultural. In 1815, Brazil was elevated to the status of a kingdom,
and became aware of her national identity for the first time. Portugal, on the
other hand, was passing through a severe crisis, aggravated by the effects of a
ruinous war and invasion, and was still under occupation by the British army.
The mother country had become virtually a colony of her former colony, while
Portuguese Africa became daily more dependent on Brazil. In this situation
independence seemed inevitable, and it was consummated when the king
returned to Lisbon. Passed into law in 1822, it cut Portugal off from the
motive power of her economy. Once trade had been liberalized, Brazil no
longer needed the mother country : only Africa was essential to her, to keep
her plantations going. But, because of the slave trade, the development of the
Portuguese possessions in Africa had been completely neglected, thus reducing
Portugal's economic role to one of slave-trader. The prohibition of the trade
north of the Equator had benefited smuggling and the trade in the south.
Angola and the C o n g o were the main suppliers. Great Britain, however, tried
as far as possible to check infringements.
A supplementary convention to the treaty of 1815, signed in L o n d o n in
1817, established the distinction between licit and illicit trading, while Portugal
and Great Britain agreed to a reciprocal right of search by their warships of
vesselsflyingtheirflags.Joint commissions were also set up to try prizes.
But, despite these measures—or perhaps because of them—the slave
trade flourished more than ever. It became clear that the only possible step
was absolute prohibition : this would m a k e it possible to prosecute smugglers
w h o sheltered behind the Portugueseflag.Great Britain, faced with continual
changes of government in Portugal, had several times to break off negotiations.
Finally, on 10 December 1836, barely two months after coming to power,
134 Françoise Latour da Veiga Pinto,
A. Carreña
with British and Portuguese members were set u p to try the crews of vessels
apprehended. These tribunals were set up in British as well as Portuguese
territories : namely at Luanda, B o a Vista, Cape of G o o d H o p e and Jamaica.
The naval patrol responsible for the surveillance of the trade increased in size :
in a single year, from April 1846 to April 1847,fifty-eightcruisers—British
and Portuguese, but also French—were recorded as entering Luanda harbour.
The machinery for enforcing the prohibition had been adopted as the
result of laborious diplomatic negotiations : but m a n y difficulties remained to
be overcome in practice before the slave trade as a whole, and in Portuguese
Africa in particular, could actually be stopped. For one thing, there was no
certainty that these measures would succeed in eradicating the habits of cen-
turies ; and furthermore two types of slave trade had grown up, with a h o m e
market and an overseas market. T h e former gave rise to disguised forms of
slavery, or at any rate forced labour. The latter, which resulted from the Atlan-
tic trade, was hardly likely to disappear until the slave-owning nations gave
up using this form of labour. T h e profits being higher every time, the slave
traders, w h o had well-organized networks of agents both at h o m e and over-
seas, naturally found it hard to resist the appeal of gain: especially since
smugglers could always shelter under theflagsof countries not liable to checking
by the naval patrol.
At the time of abolition there was a clash of opposing interests in Portu-
guese Africa : on the one hand, those of the government, which for various eco-
nomic and foreign-policy reasons genuinely desired abolition, and, on the other,
those of the traders, w h o continued their smuggling with the connivance of the
Brazilian and Cuban planters. It is undeniable, however, that up to 1842 the
slave trade had had the benefit of a good deal of complicity at the highest
levels, and that the Portuguese administration in Africa was riddled with
corruption. Officials at Luanda found it hard to resist the temptation of easy
money. Nevertheless, thanks to the energy and integrity of several governors
(the most notable example being Pedro Alexandrino da Cunha, Governor
from 1845 to 1848), the slave trade in Angola was eventually eradicated. His
predecessor, on the other hand, had been relieved of his office, having c o m e
under strong suspicion of being implicated with the slave-traders.
O n e of the main centres of the slave trade was still the C o n g o area,
together with the coast of Loango, Cabinda, M o l e m b o , Ambriz, etc., where
slave-traders of all nationalities came to get their supplies. Portugal wished to
occupy this area, and one of the subsidiary reasons she adduced, in addition
to her claim to 'historic rights', was the abolition of the slave trade. This ques-
tion dominated Anglo-Portuguese relations for more than a quarter of a
century.
Meanwhile, in July 1850, in the face of strong opposition, the Brazilian
Parliament passed the abolition law; and, for thefirsttime, the government
136 Françoise Latour da Veiga Pinto,
A . Carreira
was strong enough to enfore such a measure. F r o m that time on the Atlantic
trade dwindled.
But the slave trade left m a n y after-effects; and it continued in various
forms throughout the Portuguese colonial period. There are several reasons for
this. O n e derived from the habits that had been formed, and the existence of
a h o m e market organized by the Africans themselves. Another was the need to
solve the problem of 'pockets' of slaves still collected together for sale. A
third was the colonial administration's intention of improving the land, which
led it to 'engage' labourers on terms very similar to those of their forebears
w h o had been transported across the Atlantic. Slavery was abolished in 1858,
though with a twenty-year transitional period. But before that, on 23 October
1853, a decree had been promulgated authorizing the transport of slaves from
Angola to the island of Principe to develop coffee and cocoa growing there.
After being baptized, they were marked on the right arm with a mark signifying
that they 'were freed' (sic). According to the law, they had to serve for seven
years in the plantations ; in other words, they were free by right and slaves in
fact. In one form or another, the laws of 1875 and 1878 and the decrees of
1899, 1903 and 1909 countenanced disguised forced labour in the Portuguese
African colonies and the transfer of labour to Sao T o m é and Principe.
So shocking was this institutionalized state of affairs that Norton de
Matos described and denounced it in 1912. H e was Governor of Angola at
the time, and tried to change conditions of work in Africa : but the Portuguese
colonial administration continued to engage African labour on terms very
close to slavery. This led Henrique Galväo, then Inspector-General of the
Colonies, to write in 1947: ' T h e situation is worse than simple slavery. . . .
The native is not bought, he is hired by the State. . . . A n d his employer cares
nothing whether he falls ill or dies : he merely asks for a replacement. ' This
courageous voice was not the only one to be raised against a disgraceful state
of affairs, and several colonial careers were cut short because of protests by
officials unwilling to fall in with this system. But, as Antonio Carreira testifies,
having had direct experience of it, the majority were willing to be cogs in a
machine in which corruption arose from collusion between the administration
and private interests.
A n d , as always happened when the slave trade was flourishing, public
opinion only heeded the protests raised against abuses when it was ready to
do so, and only when conscience was no longer stifled by the interests at stake.
between just and unjust wars. The prisoners of a just war could be reduced to
slavery, and if they embraced the Christian faith all the cruelties associated
with their condition were justified. Nevertheless, it is clear from accounts that
have c o m e d o w n to us that some charitable souls strove to draw attention to
the horrible fate of the poor wretches w h o were uprooted from their homeland
and separated from their kin in conditions of unspeakable misery. For instance,
Zurara in his Chronica da Guiñé, while exalting Prince Henry's virtues, records
h o w the slaves were split up quite without pity, the sole criterion for the
division being equality between 'lots', in turn subdivided into 'pieces'. It
was not until a century later, however, that a voice was boldly and vehemently
raised in opposition. It was that of Fr Fernando de Oliveira, w h o in 1555, in
his book Arte da Guerra do Mar, severely criticized the slave trade in general
and denounced the criterion of the just war. H e asserted in substance that it
is wrong to m a k e war on people w h o are not warring and w h o want peace;
that a slave should only serve for a time limited by law; that slave-traders do
not seek only the slaves' conversion, for if ' their advantage were removed, they
would not go in search of them ; and slaves serve their masters m u c h more
than they do G o d , since they are compelled to carry out certain tasks which
are contrary to divine law'.
D o w n the centuries, there is no lack of descriptions of the violence
involved in the capture of slaves in Africa and at the depots while awaiting
shipment, and then the horrors of the crossing in the tumbeiros, or coffins, as
the slave-ships were called. The level of losses, initially as high as 20 per cent,
fell as time went out, reaching an average of 5 per cent towards the end. The re-
bellions and the ensuing punishments, the epidemics, the disasters in storms—
all this has come d o w n to us in eye-witness accounts, often imbued with horror
or compassion. Yet the slave trade was only enabled to last so long because
there was a convergence of economic interests, coupled with a religious justi-
fication, and because circumstances in Africa were propitious. F e w African
chiefs were averse from taking part in a trade from which they stood to gain.
Paradoxically, the Jesuits, in protecting the Indians against the Brazilian
colonists, encouraged the slave trade. W h e n they first arrived on the American
continent the colonists enslaved the native Indians, w h o were neither as tough
nor such good workers as Negroes. The Jesuits took their part successfully,
thanks to their influence at Court and the eloquence of the most famous of
their number, Antonio Vieira. H e also protested, along with other Jesuits,
against the despotic attitude of the slave-masters towards their Negro slaves;
but they never condemned the principle of the Negro trade. The ban on the
enslaving of Indians, proclaimed by the government in Lisbon in 1570, served
on the contrary to give it a new lease of life.
The Church's attitude with regard to the question was moreover ambi-
valent. Whereas under the Papal Pull of 1639 all Catholics w h o engaged in
138 Françoise Latour da Veiga Pinto,
A . Carreira
slave trading with Indians were excommunicated, it was not until 1839 that
a similar measure was taken in respect of the Negro trade. In addition, as far
as Portugal was concerned, the Church had a material interest in the business
from the start, through the dues she collected for the baptism of slaves. Every
slave shipped had to be baptized ; and, though the ceremony of baptism was
carried out in groups, the officiating priest m a d e his charges on a per capita
basis. In the eighteenth century the rate was 300 to 500 reis for adults and
50 to 100 reis for children and infants in arms. T h e payment of these dues
often led to conflicts between the traders and the clergy (notably in 1697 and
1719), so that the civil power was compelled to intervene. In other words, the
State religion, which in Portugal was ruled by the Inquisition up to the eigh-
teenth century, not only gave its moral sanction to the traffic in h u m a n beings
through baptism, but also m a d e a profit out of it. In such circumstances public
opinion could hardly have been expected to condemn a situation which enabled
the maintenance of the economic system responsible for the prosperity of
Brazil and the Kingdom. W h e n , therefore, Pombal abolished slavery in Portu-
gal, in 1773, the aim was primarily to avoid drawing off the manpower that
was desperately short in the mines and plantations of Brazil.
It was not until the nineteenth century that Portuguese public opinion
revolted against the slave trade. Unlike Great Britain, where it was extremely
vehement and was led by great humanitarian figures, in Portugal it was led
by a liberal political élite. Admittedly Portugal was so torn by domestic strife
up to the middle of the century that it would have been difficult for her to
turn away from her immediate conflicts and concern herself with an overseas
problem. O n the other hand, politicians such as Sá da Bandeira saw the advan-
tage to Portugal, after the loss of Brazil, of developing Africa, and the impera-
tive need to halt the manpower drain which the slave trade represented.
Humanitarian opinions also found expression, in keeping with the spirit of
the age. Naval officers posted to the coast of Africa were as a rule genuinely
shocked at the continuance of the trade. Later the Lisbon Geographical Society,
which was founded in 1875, conducted an anti-slavery campaign. Accounts by
Portuguese explorers from the interior of Angola, like those of their foreign
predecessors, told of the horrors of the internal trade—sequels of the Atlantic
trade and of that with the Arab countries.
But, above all, opinion was extremely alarmed at the international
campaign directed against Portugal. T h e various diplomatic vicissitudes that
had marked the negotiations between Palmerston and the Portuguese Govern-
ment in favour of abolition had aroused British public opinion against Portu-
gal; and its conviction of Portuguese insincerity w a s strengthened by the
accounts of explorers such as Livingstone, Cameron and Stanley, w h o on
their travels in Central Africa had witnessed gangs of slaves being escorted
by Portuguese pumbeiros. Portuguese public opinion was outraged at the accu-
Portuguese participation in the slave trade 139
try to pick out the areas in which its influence m a d e itself directly and specifi-
cally felt; and w e accordingly propose to take the demographic and the financial
aspects.
S o m e writers, such as Joël Serräo, consider that the population influx
arising from the slave trade was essential in thefifteenthand sixteenth centuries,
in that it m a d e up for the population losses caused by the discoveries and over-
seas expansion. C . R . Boxer estimates that in the course of the sixteenth century,
2,400 m e n , mostly young and fit, left Portugal annually. This is a large number,
considering that—according to the 1527 census—the total population of Portu-
gal at that time varied between 1 million and 1.4 million.
O n the opposite side, it is generally reckoned that imported slaves m a d e
u p a tenth of the population of the large cities, and this proportion seems to
hold good for the duration of the slave trade. W e have no accurate figures
for the rural areas.
At the beginning of the sixteenth century the slaves imported into Portu-
gal were as heterogeneous as the discoveries themselves: M o o r s , Chinese,
Indians and Negroes were all to be found in Lisbon. The last n a m e d were in the
majority: they were employed in the hardest agricultural work, sent w h e n
necessary to unhealthy parts of the country, used for clearing the ground and
also in domestic service. The growth of a society based on slave labour undoubt-
edly had a variety of consequences. Moralists attributed the laxity of morals
to it, and d o w n the centuries kept up a barrage of criticism of the licentiousness
and frivolity of all classes of society, accompanied by a highly developed taste
for idleness—the heavy work being left to slaves.
N o r must w e overlook Brazil's influence on Portugal: for Brazil was
herself profoundly marked by the centuries-old influx of African labour. This
factor, however, is virtually impossible to evaluate, because it is, so to speak,
'two-way'.
It is interesting to note, on the other hand, that, after abolition, white
Portuguese emigration to Brazil to some extent took the place of the slave
trade, being in a way a clandestine form of it similar to those mentioned above.
W h a t happened was that Brazilian planters 'engaged' Portuguese workers on
terms very similar to those of the Negroes shipped to the plantations of Säo
T o m é . This is borne out by a very marked increase in Portuguese emigration
to Brazil from 1850 onwards. These Portuguese, mostly from the northern
provinces were indebted almost for life to their bosses for the cost of their
passages; they took the place of the Negroes on the plantations, and led exactly
the same sort of life.
Turning n o w to the financial effect of the slave trade on Portugal's
socio-economic development, the most reliable data available from existing
sources are those concerning the profits m a d e by the crown. These can be
calculated from the duties collected on contracts and the various charges and
Portuguese participation in the slave trade 141
taxes levied to meet particular items of expenditure: for instance, the levy
introduced in 1664 to cover expenditure on the celebration of the peace between
Portugal and the Netherlands, and to help pay for Catherine of Braganza's
dowry on the occasion on her marriage to Charles II of England, originally
intended to be applied for sixteen years, this levy was subsequently extended
for a further twenty. In 1724 a tax was introduced to pay for the construction
of the fortress at Ajudá; while in 1757 the rebuilding of Lisbon, which had been
destroyed in the earthquake of 1755, was charged to the slave trade. Thus the
royal treasury received a substantial return throughout the duration of the
trade. It is, however, very difficult to attribute it to this or that particular
activity, except in the case of taxes levied for specific purposes, as mentioned
above.
In regard to the financing of the slave trade, and hence the question of
those w h o m a d e money out of it, Frédéric M a u r o has drawn attention to the
part played by the Jews—and the ' n e w Christians' from the sixteenth century
onwards—in the formation of the Portuguese upper middle class. There is
room for a thorough study not only of the general question of their importance
for Portugal's commercial vitality at the time of the expansion, and their role
in the early stages of development of Brazil's sugar economy, but also of the
slave trade, which is inextricably bound up with those topics. After all, there
were m a n y Jewish and ' new Christian contractors ' whose commercial activities
were never confined to the slave trade. Moreover, while it is difficult to assess
the profits that were m a d e out of legal slave trading, it is impossible to estimate
those m a d e by smugglers. The latter played a considerable part over the cen-
turies, but w e can only guess at the purpose for which the capital thus acquired
was used in Portugal itself.
Once again, the question of the slave trade is inseparable from the overall
problem of a given economic system. In very general terms, the main benefi-
ciaries were not so m u c h those w h o engaged in the trade as those w h o turned
cheap labour to account to improve their land and their mines. In this sense
the effects of the slave trade on the socio-economic development of the country
were greater, and are m u c h more apparent, in Brazil than in Portugal.
Bibliography
Archives
Arquivos de Angola. Vol. I, Nos. 5-6, March 1936, Vol. II, N o . 7, April 1936; N o . 8, M a y
1936; N o . 9, June 1936; N o . 11, August 1936; N o . 13, October 1936; N o . 14, November
1936; N o . 15, December 1936. Vol. Ill, Nos. 16-18, January-March 1937; N o . 19, April
1937; N o . 22, July 1937. Vol. X I X , Nos. 75-8, January-December 1962 (2nd series).
Archivos dos Servicos de Finanças (Praia, Cabo Verde). Livro de Entrada de Navios de
Longo Curso no Porto de Vila de Praiai (1812-27).
142 Françoise Latour da Veiga Pinto,
A. Carreira
Contemporary studies
A D A M S , Captain John. Remarks on the Country Extending from Cape Palmas to the River
Congo. London, 1823.
A L V A R E S , Manuel (Padre). Etiopia Menor ou Descriçao da Provincia da Serra Leoa (1616).
(Unedited manuscript in preparation by Teixeira da Mota.)
A N O N . Estabelecimentos e Resgates dos Portugueses na Costa Ocidental da Africa. Colecçao
de Viagens, Exploraçoes e Conquistas nos Portugueses. Lisbon, Imprensa Nacional, 1881.
. Bosquejo sobre o Comercio em Escravos, e Reflexoes sobre este Trato Considerado
Imoral, Politico e Cristamente. London, Ellerton & Henderson, 1821.
A S S U M P C À O , Lino d'. Exploraçâo d'Africa. Bol. de Sociedade de Geografía de Lisboa, 5th
series, N o . 6, 1885.
B E R R E D O , Antonio Pereira de. Anais Históricos de Maranhao. S. Luis do Maranha, 1864-
65 (4 vols.).
B E T T E N C O U R T , C . Pacheco de. Memoria sobre e Aboliçào da Escravidào nos Colonias
Portuguesas e Organizaçào do Trabalho Agricole. Lisbon, 1867.
B O T E L H O , Sebastiäo Xavier, Memoria Estatistica sobre os Dominios Portugueses na Africa
Oriental. Lisbon, Tipografía de José Baptista Morando, 1835.
. Escravatura. Beneficios que Podem Provir as Nossas Possessoes de Africa da Proibaçào
deste Trafico. Lisbon, 1840.
B R I T O , Domingos de Abreu de. Inquerito a Vida Administrativa e Económica de Angola, e
do Brasil, emFins do Século XVI (1592). (Preface and notes by Alfredo de Albuquerque
Feiner.) Coimbra, Imprensa da Universidade, 1931.
C A D A M O S T O , Luiz de. Navegaçoes. Colecçao de Noticias para a Historia das Naçoes Ultra-
marinas que Vivem nos Dominios Portugueses. Vol. II. Lisbon, Academia Real das
Ciencias de Lisboa, Tipografía da Academia. 1867.
C A D O R N E G A , Antonio de Oliveira. Historia Geral das Guerras Angolanas (manuscript of
1680 annotated and corrected by José Matías Delgado). Lisbon, Agencia Geral das
Colonias, 1940; N e w edition by Imprensa Nacional/Casa da M o e d a , Lisbon, 1972
(3 vols.).
C A R D I A L S A R A I V A . A Origen da Escravatura. . . (1829). Obras 325/347, Lisbon, 1975.
C A V A Z Z I , Joäo Antonio. Descriçao Histórica dos Très Reinos : Congo, Angola e Natamba.
Lisbon, J.I.U. Agrupamento de Cartografía Antiga, 1965 (2 vols.).
C O R D E I R O , Luciano. Viagens, Exploraçoes e Conquistas dos Portugueses, 1516-1619.
Escravos e Minas de Africa, Segundo Diversos. Lisbon, Imprensa Nacional, 1881.
C O R T E - R E A L , J. A . Respoata a Sociedade Anti-esclavagista de Londres. Lisbon, 1884.
C O U T I N H O , D . José Joaquim da Cunha Azevedo (Bishop of Elvas). Analise sobre a Justiça
do Comercio do Resgate de Escravos na Costa da Africa. Lisbon, N o v a Oficina de Joäo
Rodrigues Neves, 1807.
Documentos Acerca do Trafico da Escravatura Extraídos dos Papéis Relativos a Portugal
Apresentados ao Parlamento Británico. Lisbon, 1840.
D O E N E L A S , André. Descriçao da Costa Ocidental d'Africa. (Unedited manuscript, dated
Santiago, 7 November 1625. Teixeira da Mota Collection.)
Portuguese participation in the slave trade 143
Books
A L M A D A , André Alvares d'. Tratado Breve dos Rios da Guiñé. Lisbon, 1946.
A N D R A D E , Elisa. Les Iles du Cap Vert: de l'Esclavage à l'Immigration 'Spontanée' (les
Migrations Capverdiennes à Dakar). Dakar, United Nations, 1973.
A N T O N I L , André Joäo. Cultura e Opulencia do Brasil (1690-1701). Salvador, 1955.
A Z E V E D O , Joäo Lucio de. Épocas de Portugal Económico. Lisbon, 1929.
B A L A N D I E R , Georges. La Vie Quotidienne au Royaume de Kongo du XVIe au XVIIIe Siècle.
Paris, Hachette, 1965.
B A R R E T O , Joäo Meló. Historia da Guiñé. Lisbon, 1938.
B I R M I N G H A M , David. Trade and Conflict in Angola: The Mbundu and their Neighbours
Under the Influence of the Portuguese, 1483-1790. Oxford, 1966.
. The Portuguese Conquest of Angola, London, Institute of Race Relations, Oxford
University Press, 1965.
B O X E R , C . R . Relaçoes Raciais no Imperio Colonial Portugués—141511825. Rio de Janeiro,
1967.
144 Françoise Latour da Veiga Pinto,
A. Carreira
S C E L L E , Georges. La Traite Négrière aux Indes de Castille. Paris, L . Larose & L . Tenin,
1906. (2 vols.)
S I M O N S E N , Roberto. Historia Económica do Brasil 1500-1820. Säo Paulo, 1937.
S T A M M , Anne. L'Angola à un Tournant de son Histoire 1838-1848. Paris. (Thesis.) (Mimeo.)
T A U N A Y , Affonso Escragnolle de. Subsidios para a Historia do Trafico Africano no Brasil.
Säo Paulo, 1941.
TEIXEIRA, Candido da Silva. Companhia de Cacheu, Rios e Costa da Guiñé. Bol. do Arquivo
Histórico Colonial, Vol. I, Lisbon, 1950.
V A N S I N A , Jan. Kingdoms of the Savanna. Madison, University of Wisconsin Press, 1966.
V I A N N A F I L H O , Luis. O Negro na Baia. Rio de Janeiro, José Olympio, 1946. (Documentos
Históricos, N o . 55.)
. O Trabalho do Engenho e a Reacçao do Indio. Establecimento da Escravatura Africana.
Congresso do Mundo Portugués, Vol. X . Lisbon, 1940.
W Y N D H A M , H u g h A . The Atlantic and Slavery. London, Oxford University Press, 1935.
Articles
Mbaye Gueye
The slave trade was a very ancient practice in Africa. The Europeans did not
invent it. They only exploited it by impelling the Africans to ' derive the greater
part of their resources from it'.1 With the coming of the Europeans, the volume
of the trade swelled to huge proportions, causing widespread social upheaval
in Africa.
Unfortunately w e do not have all the necessary material on the internal
slave trade. W e cannot attempt to m a k e even a rough assessment of its m a g -
nitude from currently available sources. The little information w e d o possess
is either fragmentary or written long after the event, comes mostly from the
colonial authorities and deals m o r e with the struggle to suppress the domestic
slave trade than with the trade itself.
Prior to foreign intervention, the slave trade was undoubtedly practised
in Africa but on an extremely small scale. It was devised chiefly as a means of
reintegrating into society individuals w h o had been cut off from their families
following a war or other catastrophe. For the organization of African society
does not allow for isolation and individualism. The African ideal is that of a
community existence based on powerful family ties with a view to a 'well-
ordered, secure life'.2 People only count in so far as they are part of a harmoni-
ous, homogeneous entity. In these conditions, a m a n on his o w n formerly
had n o chance of survival. Enslaving peoples w h o m natural or other disasters
had cast adrift was a useful means of providing them with a social framework
relevant to their expectations in life. Those w h o purchased them gave them a
new identity. The slaves would give up their o w n patronyms for that of their
new master. This type of integration did not jeopardize the group and could
not fundamentally disturb the original balance of the community for it con-
cerned only a tiny minority of individuals.
It was the steadily increasing demand for slaves a a result of foreign
intervention in the affairs of the continent which brought about a fairly sub-
stantial increase in the volume of the trade, hitherto restricted to transactions
on a narrow local scale. The material advantages to be gained by trading in
slaves were an incentive to some of the clans, especially in medieval times, to
intensify their raids on neighbouring tribes, to have something to barter for
The slave trade within the African continent 151
would be launched. They would setfireto the huts. A n y m a n trying to resist would
be put to death. The w o m e n and children were taken and put up for auction.
The spoils would be shared out evenly between the chief and his warriors.7
The recurrent wars and the devastation they brought with them m a d e
the hideous spectre of famine a familiar sight. T o obtain food, the heads of
some families would sell some of their household slaves. If they had none, they
would sell their children or p a w n them to wealthy people in the hope of redeem-
ing them when times were better.8
During periods of famine, chiefs would intensify their raiding forays to
procure slaves w h o would then be sold in exchange for food supplies. The
poorer inhabitants of the famine-stricken areas would try to flee to avoid
being captured. But usually the chiefs of the territories in which they sought
asylum would promptly seize them and sell them without any further ado.
This is what happened to some of the inhabitants of Kajor and Jolof w h o went
to Waalo to escape the terrible famine which had swept through their land. The
king of Waalo seized them and sold them to the Compagnie des Indes.9
The chiefs' desire to acquire European goods at a low price induced them
to sharpen the penalties for offences and crimes; the apparently most trivial
offences were n o w severely punished.
Insolvency n o w became liable to the penalty of slavery. The creditor
would take the offender and put him up for auction.10 Theft, murder and canni-
balism were likewise punishable by enslavement. Thieves whose guilt was
proved became their victims' slaves. Those guilty of certain offences liable to
afinewhich they were unable to pay also forfeited their freedom. But although
thieves, criminals, insolvent debtors and cannibals were all mercilessly reduced
to servitude and sold as slaves, war and slave raids nevertheless remained the
main source of slaves.
Caught up in the mesh of the slave trade, which was m u c h more lucrative
than trading in kola, ivory or cattle, the African traders progressively went
over to trading in slaves, organizing it in such a way as to minimize the risks
inherent in such a large-scale business. A category of local traders emerged
k n o w n as merchants (French : courtiers) by the Europeans and as Juula by the
Africans. They were mostly to be found a m o n g the Sarakole, the Mandingo
and the Hausa.
These slave-merchants would go to the various markets where the slaves
were bought and sold. Each territory had its market-day, on which all the
different dealers would meet. The largest slave markets were Segu, Bambarena,
Khasso and Bambuhu. 1 1
Every year the African merchants would set off for the regions of Upper
Senegal/Niger and Hausaland in search of slaves w h o m they would then take
off to the places where they would be most likely to secure the highest prices
for them. A s the slave trade developed, particularly in the eighteenth century,
The slave trade within the African continent 153
ends slung behind their necks.i0 They were given just enough food to keep
them going from one stage to the next. At each halt they were put in irons
before being allowed to go to sleep.51 The slave-drivers would take it in turns
to keep watch over them until it was time to depart. All along the way the
caravan would leave a trail of h u m a n beings w h o were no longer able to endure
the fatigue and hunger in its wake, to be devoured by the hyenas and jackals.22
Those w h o could not keep up with the rest of the caravan would be driven on
with whips, and those w h o could not go on form sheer exhaustion would be
slain in cold blood in front of their terrified companions, and their bodies left
to the wild beasts.23 This implied that the same punishment would be inflicted
on any slave showing any signs of ill-will. H u m a n bones laid strewn all along
the routes that led from the interior to the trading posts.
These gruesome slave-trains were m a d e up of long lines of
haggard, emaciated men, worn out by the lack of food, dazed by the blows they were
dealt, doubled over with the weight of their loads; crippled, spindle-legged women
covered in hideous wounds and forced to help themselves along with long sticks; old
people completely spent, bent double with fatigue and age.24
W h e n after several days' march in the silence of those African desert trails
they would reach the trading posts, it was only thefirststage in their grim
Odyssey.
At the trading stations, the African merchants would bide their time
over the sale of their slaves in anticipation of substantial profit margins. If the
price they were offered was too low they would refuse to sell. While they were
waiting for the highest bid, they would deposit their captives in the neighbouring
villages, and there the slaves would be chained together, unable to m o v e , until
such time as they would be purchased by the agents of the European companies.
F r o m there they would be dispatched to the coastal termini where they would
be kept until there were enough of them to warrant shipment to America.
A s the slaves were bought up by the traders, they were shackled together
two by two with collars and chains until their turn came to be sent d o w n to
the coast. The device used was ' an iron chain five or six feet long with a flat
iron collar at one end which would befittedaround their necks and clasped in
such a w a y that it could not be unlocked without tools ' 2 5 Once the whole
operation was settled, the merchants would return h o m e . 2 6
The slave trade organized in this way was not the only means of supplying
the European traders with slaves. For States like Benin, Ashanti and D a h o m e y
were not prepared to b o w to a system in which they were merely middlemen.
At the end of the seventeenth and the beginning of the eighteenth century,
first Ashanti and then D a h o m e y resolved to put an end to their inland position
and open up a window to the coast in order to trade directly with the Europeans.
The slave trade within the African continent 155
They did away with all the merchants w h o had previously passed through
their territories to take their slaves to the coast to sell them to the European
slave-traders. F r o m that time on, they became involved in slave-dealing on a
large scale.
Periodically they would send troops into the neighbouring countries to
capture slaves w h o m they would then sell in order to secure arms and other
European goods. In Ashanti and D a h o m e y the slave trade became a State
monopoly. Most of the slaves were n o w sold by the State and no longer by
private individuals.
In Central and East Africa the internal slave trade was controlled by
foreigners. T h e Portuguese led expeditions inland. F r o m ancient times the
Arabs had specialized in hunting d o w n Africans and reducing them to slavery
Slave raids and the search for ivory were the two main activities of the Arabs,
in East Africa.27
Alongside this slave trade which served to export captives to America
or Asia there was another trade network within the continent itself which
helped to meet local labour demands.
For the expansion of the Atlantic trade did not bring about the collapse
of the old trading traditions. Although the economic nerve-centres had shifted
from the hinterland to the coast, the former trade relations between Black
Africa and North Africa were as lively as ever. Only luxury goods were traded.
Lacourbe reports that at the end of the seventeenth century an Arab horse was
worth twenty-five slaves.28 Pruneau de Pommegorge claims to have seen an
African chief buy a horse for 'a hundred slaves and a hundred oxen'. 29 T h e
emphasis on horses was due to the fact that war had become a truly lucrative
industry and cavalry necessarily played an important part in military strategy.
Slaves were also used in marriage negotiations as part of the 'bride
price'. In princely marriages, the bride price was mainly composed of slaves,
whereas for commoners it consisted simply of a handful of tobacco leaves and
a few animals. Since local custom did not allow mastes to part with their o w n
household slaves, they would buy trade slaves or ordinary slaves to give away
to their future parents-in-law.
At the time of the overseas trade, slaves captured in raids or purchased,
or prisoners of war, were not all sold to the European slave-traders. S o m e of
them were bought by Africans and remained in Africa. They then became part
of their master's domestic slave household. But since they had not been born
under their master's roof, they were called ordinary slaves. Admittedly they
did the same work as the household slaves, but their status was inferior, for
their master could sell them without incurring any recrimination, whereas
household slaves could not be parted with unless it was absolutely necessary.30
Ordinary and trade slaves were regarded as foreigners. They had virtually
no legal protection in c o m m o n law against arbitrary treatment by their masters,
156 Mbaye Gueye
w h o could maltreat or sell them as and when they thought fit. They could be
included as part of their master's property in payment of some object purchased
by him, or be pawned to a distrustful creditor.31
The internal trade by itself was not sufficient to meet domestic labour
requirements. With the extension of the Atlantic slave trade, the local rulers
became increasingly caught up in the relentless workings of the slave machine.
W a r became their normal occupation. W h a t was needed was a category of
people w h o would cultivate the land to provide food for the local population.
Agricultural villages were set up everywhere, peopled with slaves w h o had been
purchased or captured during raids. Thus the Bakuba in the Congo neither
maltreated 'nor sold their prisoners of war. They settled them in areas far from
their native lands, and called them Mitsungi.'32 Their masters could pick out
any number of them and sell them or hand them over as hostages, 'as pledge
for a debt or in payment of the bride price \ 3 3
In West Africa, ordinary slaves were used for a variety of purposes.
During the rains, they were employed to work in the fields. F r o m dawn to
about two o'clock in the afternoon they would work for their masters. F r o m
then on they could work for themselves. O n Fridays and feast days they were
free all day.34 W h a t they produced on those days was their o w n , and could be
used to buy back their freedom or that of their children. But the price of freedom
was extremely high, and cases of self-redemption were extremely rare. A n d since
when they died, 'their sole heir was their master, it was he w h o reaped the
benefit of the extra work'. 3 5
In Senegambia ordinary slaves were divided into two categories : slaves
w h o had been captured during the countless raiding expeditions, and slaves
bought at the slave markets. The former were kept in special villages both in
time of peace and war. After several years in such villages the bravest of them
were selected to become warriors, and were henceforth royal slaves. They
would fight under the c o m m a n d of the chief, and he alone had the right to
punish them. Slaves w h o had been purchased could be sold at any time. They
were part of their master's concession and he had the right to maltreat them.
Their existence was often an unhappy and degrading one. Their main preoccu-
pation was to satisfy their 'animal needs: eat when they could, sleep as m u c h
as possible and breed when the opportunity arose'.36 The master's only obli-
gation was to feed and clothe them. 37
A trade slave w h o had been in his master's service for some time could
request permission to marry. T h e master would then choose a wife for him
without any regard for the candidate's wishes. H e could also take her away
again as and when he wished. However, a trade slave w h o was fortunate enough
to be given a wife w h o had been born in her master's house automatically
belonged to his wife's category. H e was only sold if he tried to escape, was
particularly insolent or committed a crime. Marriages between two trade slaves
The slave trade within the African continent 157
were on the whole only afleetingsource of joy to them, for the imperatives of
their existence or the whims of their masters could separate them from each
other or from their children. A n d yet there is no evidence of revolt. It m a y be
that it seemed futile to attempt anything of the kind, although it would appear
that individual escapes were not infrequent. At any event runaway slaves m a d e
no attempt to form armed gangs to take their revenge or free their brothers w h o
were still in captivity.
Ordinary female slaves were not allowed to do private work. They were
permanently at the beck and call of their masters' wives. A child born of ordi-
nary slave parents automatically acquired the privileged status of household
slave. H e could neither be sold nor maltreated, and was usually given the
same upbringing as the master's o w n children. N o r could his mother be sold
until she had weaned him.
A s w e have already said, w e cannot give an accurate appraisal of the
extent of the domestic slave trade. Apart from a few references in accounts by
travellers, there are no texts giving detailed information on the subject. F r o m
a certain time on, the internal trade was probably practised on a very large
scale since it served both as a reservoir for the export trade and as a form of
currency in commercial transactions at h o m e . It even contributed to the devel-
opment of household or domestic slavery. W e do not k n o w exactly h o w it
operated or h o w it compared in volume to the export trade.
It would perhaps not be presumptuous to suggest that the height of the
internal slave trade was between the end of the eighteenth century and the
middle of the nineteenth. By the middle of the eighteenth century, the slave-
trading nations of Europe had already organized themselves in readiness for
the large-scale export of slaves overseas. The slave trade then went deep into
the forest and mountain areas which were as yet untapped. A s a result, even
remote communities became involved in the trade.
The slave trade engendered a permanent state of internecine conflict.
D r a w n into its web, the local rulers spent most of their time at war. Plunder,
theft, rape, capture of h u m a n beings and animals became the order of the day.
The air was rent with the wails of the victims.
This atmosphere of violence, hatred and terror affected the spiritual and
moral values of society. The ancestral moral virtues were flouted daily. T h e
rulers were n o doubt conscious of the danger, but the cogs of the infernal
machine m a d e short work of their better thoughts and drove society o n to its
downfall.
It was for this reason that the Muslims resorted to armed combat to
defeat the despotic regimes, in the hope of restoring a more equitable society.
They took the offensive as from the end of the eighteenth century. In 1776 came
the establishment of theocratic rule in Fuuta Tooro. A few years later, U s m a n
D a n Fodio was victorious in Nigeria, and A h m a d o u Cheikou in Massina. In
158 Mbaye Gueye
the middle of the nineteenth century, El Hadj O m a r took u p the combat and
islamized the Nigerian Sudan. 3 8 All these wars, which furthered the expansion
of the internal slave trade, coincided with the decision by the Western European
nations progressively to put an end to the slave trade.39 In 1807 Great Britain,
and in 1815 France decided to abolish it. Finding no outside market for their
slaves, the Africans were compelled to use them at h o m e . Slavery was the natural
ransom that conquering armies would d e m a n d of those they had defeated.
The sudden slackening of European d e m a n d presented the serious prob-
lem of h o w to dispose of the slaves. Around 1843, after a war between the
Bambara and the Sarakole in which the latter were defeated, the Bambara
king arrived in Bakel with 800 prisoners for sale. But he found no market for
them. N o t knowing what to d o with his prisoners, he
All they needed to do was to buy slaves inland, where they were assured that the slaves'
lives were in danger from the harsh treatment they had been subjected to ever since
the abolition of the Atlantic slave trade had made it impossible for the African
merchants to dispose of their merchandise.44
The colonial service also bought indentured slaves for military purposes. In
spite of the measures taken by Faidherbe to reorganize the battalion of Tirail-
leurs Sénégalais (an infantry battalion), most of the conscripts were in fact
young slaves w h o had been purchased and were enlisted for fourteen years in
the French army. They were given an intensive military training and were
The slave trade within the African continent 159
subsequently used during the conquest of French West Africa and Madagascar.
With the adoption of this system by the Europeans soon after the official
abolition of the Atlantic slave trade, the purveyors of slaves were given a new
incentive to resort to ' every immoral and criminal method of procuring slaves \ 4 8
The indenture system thus led to a revival of 'surprise raids, kidnappings,
plundering and war' 4 6 in the French and British possessions, just as there had
been in the heyday of the Atlantic trade. W h a t was even m o r e serious, the
number of slaves taken in by the French and British authorities was minute
in comparison with the vast numbers that were offered for sale. In 1845,
Breghost de Polignac estimated that 60,000 slaves were put up for sale in the
various markets in Upper Senegal/Niger. France's average annual purchases
barely exceeded 500. Thus even if this institution potentially saved a few
hundred lives, it nevertheless had an extremely prejudicial effect on the hinter-
land peoples w h o carried on waging war as a veritable industry. The prevailing
insecurity was obviously incompatible with the development of a modern
economy.
By 1830 the agricultural resettlement schemes had c o m e to grief. It was
suggested that the system be suppressed to put an end to abusive practices.
It was thought that w h e n the order abolishing it became k n o w n inland, the
caravans which would periodically m a k e their way to the trading posts would
no longer have any slaves to sell, and the hinterland peoples would cease trading
in slaves and turn to other occupations.47 In 1844 France abolished the inden-
ture system but allowed the colonial administration to carry on buying slaves
to swell the ranks of the African battalion.48 In spite of the precautions taken
by the administration to restrict conscription to the numbers strictly required
to organize the black troops for the defence and security of the colony, the
internal traffic continued to be plied as briskly as before as long as there was
some market for at least part of its merchandise. W h a t could not be sold to
the Europeans automatically reverted to the category to be put u p for sale
on the various market-places, to supply the African domestic market. T h e
result was a net increase in the number of ordinary slaves.
The difficulty of finding markets for their trade slaves led some of the
African merchants to seek new occupations. S o m e sought to compensate for
the loss of the enormous profits they had earned with the slave trade by going
into agriculture. T h e Sarakole forsook the slave trade for the cattle trade,
while the Hausa and Yoruba increasingly devoted themselves to trade in palm
oil.
These new ventures meant that the hinterland peoples were at last able
to take part in the economic revolution that Europe sought to stimulate in
Africa for the benefit of its o w n captains of industry.
The overall result was a metamorphosis in the outlook of the chiefs in
he years following the abolition of the indenture system. Realizing that there
160 Mbaye Gueye
would no longer be a market for their slaves, they encouraged their subjects to
devote their energy to the production of export crops which would be the only
way of procuring European goods. In 1858, one of the hinterland chiefs declared
that he had had no slaves to sell since the d e m a n d for them had ceased. H e n o w
employed them in ground-nut plantations, which was far more lucrative.49
With the increased production of lawful export goods, the domestic
slave trade progressively declined. The new farmers, w h o had an ample, assured
supply of servile labour in the shape of their household slaves, were quite
capable of doing without ordinary slaves, w h o were always tempted to escape.
A s the colonial conquest progressed, the internal slave trade lost its vitality.
T o give weight to their campaign against slavery, the colonial authorities
sought the support of the hinterland chiefs. Each time a trade treaty was
concluded with the native leaders, the Africans had to commit themselves to
ceasing all slave traffic. Faidherbe adopted this policy in all his dealings with
the Senegambian chiefs. T h e treaties provided that never again would they
sell free subjects, nor allow raiding parties to destroy villages, nor capture and
enslave foreigners travelling through their lands.50 But the mere fact of signing
the treaties did not m e a n that the slave trade simply vanished. Only those w h o
had found a suitable substitute really gave it up. T h e development of export
crops alone provided 'a means of alleviating and then gradually eliminating
this noxious trade'.51
The European authorities were quick to grasp the situation. T o begin
with they were careful to be extremely tactful with the chiefs over the thorny
issue of slavery. Their courts only tried cases of slavery committed by European
citizens in the European possessions. In the occupied territories, colonial
authorities and African chiefs co-operated to combat the slave trade until its
final extinction. In 1892, the governor of the French possessions took a wise
decision on slavery : he m a d e all the African chiefs in these territories sign an
agreement whereby they agreed to prevent slave traffic in the territories ruled
over by them. Ordinary slaves w h o in principle could be sold out of hand were
n o w given the same privileges as household slaves, w h o as time went on came
to be regarded more as servants than as slaves.52
Their subjects did, however, retain the right to buy slaves from foreigners.
It was deemed preferable to ' admit slaves from distant, barbaric lands into the
homes of people w h o 5 3 agreed to treat them as servants, rather than leave
them in the hands of people w h o would truly treat them as slaves'.54
A s can be seen, the main object was to weaken the internal slave trade.
The African chiefs still practised it, to be sure, but less ostentatiously. S o m e of
them, claiming to apply the provisions of the agreement, would confiscate the
caravans passing through their territory and keep them for themselves. Caravan
drivers would refuse to go through areas where their slaves might be arbitrarily
seized at the w h i m of a chief.55 They would only m o v e w h e n it was dark.
The slave trade within the African continent 161
Because of all the inherentrisks,after 1893 it was more often children w h o fell
prey to the slave-traders. Slaves freed by the colonial authorities were kept
in 'free' villages where the authorities could requisition them at any time for
head porterage.
A s from 1898, with their supremacy firmly established, the colonial
authorities increased their coercive measures against the African slave-dealers.
The definitive abolition of the internal slave trade compelled the Africans to
turn to agriculture. Around 1900, numerous directives were issued with a view
to ending the slave trade once and for all. For example, a circular promulgated
that year provided that 'all caravans of slaves intended for sale, from any part
of the colony, should, o n being reported, be immediately put under arrest \ 5 6
The slaves should be freed an placed in free villages, the slave-owner given a
penalty offifteendays' imprisonment and a one hundred franc fine per slave,
and his merchandise confiscated.57
At the beginning of the twentieth century the slave trade was still prac-
tised. But by and large it had declined substantially, owing to the strict appli-
cation of the administrative directives. In 1905, the Governor-General of
French West Africa prohibited all purchase of slaves. In spite of severe sanc-
tions, some Africans continued to derive the greater part of their income from
this traffic. Slaves were as a rule exchanged for cattle.58 But transactions were
becoming difficult or even impossible because of the precautions the African
traders had to take, and especially because of the scarcity of prospective buyers
w h o were disinclined to run the risk of being involved in illicit dealings, or
took advantage of the situation by forcing the sellers to d o business at absurdly
low prices under threat of denunciation.59 Although it was an undeniable fact
that the slave trade still existed, all the reports by colonial authorities at the
beginning of the twentieth century stated that it was n o longer the powerful
institution it had been. There was a period of calm in internecine conflicts
following the colonial conquest. The modernization of the economy meant
that recourse to slave labour was increasingly hazardous. It could legitimately
he hoped that the domestic slave trade would eventually die a natural death.
But the slave trade is an institution that dies hard. It persisted on the African
continent for more than a century after the abolition of the Atlantic slave trade.
Notes
1. G . Hardy, Histoire Sociale de la Colonization Française, p. 69, Paris, Larose, 1953.
2. James Pope Hennessy, La Traite des Noirs à Travers l'Atlantique 1441-1807, p. 37,
Paris, Fayard, 1969.
3. Edrisi, Description de l'Afrique et de l'Espagne, p. 90, trans, by Dozy and Goeje,
Leyden, 1866.
4. Edrisi, op. cit., p. 9.
5. M u n g o Park, Travel in the Interior Districts of Africa in the Years 1795-1777, p. 433,
London, 1800.
162 Mbaye Gueye
Bibliography
A N E N E , J. C . Slavery and Slave Trade in Africa in the XIX and XX Centuries. Ibadan
University Press, 1962.
C H A M P A G N E A N D O L I V I E R . Le Voyage de la Jeunesse dans les Quatre Parties du Monde.
Paris, 1882.
D U I G N A N A N D C L E N D E N E N , C . The U.S.A. and the African Slave Trade 1619-1862. Stanford,
Calif, Hoover Institution Studies, 1963. 72 p.
D U R A N D , J. B . L . Voyage au Sénégal ou Mélanges sur les Découvertes, les Établissements et
le Commerce Européen. Paris, Agasse, 1802-1807. 3 vols. 360, 384 and 67 p.
E D W A R D S , B . History of the West Indies. Stockdale, 1794. (2 vols.)
G A B Y , J. B . Relation de la Nigritie Contenant une Exacte Description de ses Royaumes et
de leurs Gouvernements. Paris, Couterot, 1689. 91 p.
G O L B E R R V , S. Fragments d'un Voyage en Afrique Fait Pendant les Années 1785, 1786, 787.
Paris, Treutel, A n X (1801). 2 vols. 512 and 523 p.
K A Y , G . La Traite des Noirs. Paris, Laffont, 1968. 287 p.
L A M I R A L . L'Afrique et le Peuple Africain. Paris, 1789.
P A R K , M u n g o . Travels in the Interior Districts of Africa in the Years 1795-1797. L o n d o n ,
Bulmer, 1800. 551 p.
P O M M E G O R G E , P . de. Description de la Nigritie. Amsterdam, 1789.
S A U G N I E R . Relations de Plusieurs Voyages à la Côte d'Afrique, au Maroc, au Sénégal, à
Gorée, à Galam. Paris, Gueffier Jeune, 1791. 341 p.
L A V A L L É E , C . Journal de la Traite des\Noirs. Comments^by J. Mousnier. Paris, Éditions
de Paris, 1957.
W I L L I A M S , E . Capitalisme et Esclavage, Paris, Présence Africaine, 1964. 355 p.
The slave trade and the
population drain from Black Africa to
North Africa and the Middle East
I. B. Kake
It has been customary for historians to study the phenomenon of the slave trade
in the perspective of America and the West Indies only. Yet long before Euro-
peans began trading in slaves, the peoples of North Africa and the Middle
East had been transferring black populations to their countries.
The slave trade in that part of the world goes back to antiquity, but
it was from thefifteenthto the end of the nineteenth century that it was devel-
oped on a particularly large scale.
W h a t routes were used to bring the black slaves back ? W h o organized
the expeditions ? Where did the slaves come from ? Where did they go to ? H o w
did they travel ? W h a t fate awaited them at their destination ?
Islam, like Christianity, did not do away with slavery but tempered it. M o h a m -
m a d accepted the Arabs of his time as they were. The Koran, while acknow-
ledging bondservice as an established fact, sought to alleviate its conditions and
possibly to prepare the way for its disappearance. T o free a slave, says the
Book in m a n y of its verses, is one of the most laudable acts a Believer can
perform, worthy enough to merit redemption of one's sins. T o enslave a
Muslim against his will is an offence against G o d . According to the sharVah,
prostitution of captives or even trading in them for purely lucrative ends is no
less reprehensible: 'the worst of m e n is he w h o sells m e n , ' said the prophet
M o h a m m a d , w h o appointed one freed slave, the Ethiopian, Bilal, to the much-
coveted position of Muezzin, and another to the commander of an army.
During his lifetime O t h m a n , the third Caliph, bought 2,400 captives for
the sole purpose of setting them free, and was highly praised by the devout for
doing so.1
Only non-Muslims could be taken as slaves. In practice, it was not easy
to m a k e the distinction. After the celebrated Battle of Tondibi, the Moroccans,
having defeated the Songhai, took back with them forty camel-loads of gold-
dust and 1,200 prisoners. O n e of them, A h m e d Baba, a famous jurisconsult
The slave trade and the population drain 165
from Black Africa
from Timbuktu rose u p in the name of Islamic law and even had the audacity
to demand an explanation from the Sultan, w h o eventually freed him.
In 1611, A h m e d Baba was approached by his admirers from the region
of Tuat. They were appalled by the enormous consignments of'ebony' passing
through their oases, and spoke to him of their misgivings.2
Could one be involved in this kind of traffic without putting one's soul
in peril ? In the Sudan, they knew, there were m a n y Muslims ; was it not to be
feared that there might be some 'brothers' a m o n g those poor wretches torn
from their families?
In reply to these questions, A h m e d Baba drew up a treatise entitled
Frame-work for an Appreciation of the Legal Position of Sudanese Taken as
Slaves. It contains a wealth of quotations, good intentions, and reservations,
and in it the Sudanese jurisconsult declares that although it is difficult to dis-
tinguish Muslims from non-Muslims, it is nonetheless a crime for a Muslim
to buy a Muslim. Slavery, he goes on to say, is admissible in the context of the
Holy W a r if the slaves are non-Muslim, but the forms must be respected. First,
pagans must be called upon to embrace the Muslim religion. If they refuse,
they have the option of paying capitation, in exchange for which they are
allowed to keep their religion. Only if they refuse to comply with either of
these alternatives can they be taken as slaves.
It can be seen that the attitude of Islam to slavery and the slave trade
was, like that of Christianity, not very clear. Without going as far as Berlioux,
w h o maintained that to abolish slavery and the slave trade the Koran would
have to be torn up, 3 one is forced to face the fact that the Eastern slave trade
was carried on solely by the Muslims of the Maghreb and the Middle East.
Let us n o w look at the great routes along which The consignments of 'ebony'
were, for centuries, brought back to the Muslim countries via the same trade
routes as the other commodities (gold, ivory, etc.) that took the Muslims to
Nigritia. Four main routes were followed: the West-East route, from the
Maghreb to Western Sudan ; from Tripolitania to Central Sudan ; from Egypt
to the Upper Nile; and from the Middle East—Egypt to Waday-Darfur. Each
of these routes had its 'golden age' in the history of the slave trade.
Marcel Emerit has attempted to describe some of these overland routes.4
Every two or three years, he writes, a great caravan would leave the W a d
N o u n for Timbuktu, bearing a cargo of woollen or silk bands, spices and
incense. F r o m the W a d N o u n it took seven days to reach Seguiet el Haura, a
large river that flows into the ocean. Then for three days it would follow its
tributary, the River Butana. After another seven days it reached Ouadane.
F r o m Ouadane some caravans went on to Senegal by a relatively easy route.
166 /. B. Kake
Those caravans going to Timbuktu, took twelve days to reach Tichitt, and
another twenty days marching eastwards, to get to Araouan, whence they m a d e
their way to Timbuktu. In 1591, it took Pjouder's troopsfiftydays to go from
W a d N o u n to Timbuktu.
In the sixteenth century and throughout the period of the Gaoan Empire,
the flow of caravan traffic from the West was considerable. It helped to increase
the circulation of gold in North Africa and thereby indirectly aided the devel-
opment of the Barber towns. But by the eighteenth century it had declined
considerably.
The central route started from an area extending roughly from Lake
Chad to Hausa territory. T h e slaves were taken northwards via Zinder and
Agades. It was a twenty-five-day journey on foot to Ghat.
The caravans, including those bringing slaves from Darfur, would
converge on the Fezzan. They were then taken over by the Tuaregs and were
either taken off to Tripolitania via Marzuq, or to Ghudamis via Ghat.
At Ghudamis, another staging point, the caravans split up, some bound
for Morocco and others for Tunisia. F r o m K a n o to Tunis, changing masters
at each main halt, the black slaves would cover a distance of 3,000 kilometres
on foot, and in what a climate! That hundreds survived the journey at all is
to be wondered. For some the adventure was not yet over. F r o m Tunis, or
from Tripoli, they were dispatched to the Levant and sold for the fourth or
fifth time.
In the East the main centres were Zanzibar and Kilwa, which in the
nineteenth century were the principal suppliers of slaves to the Middle East.
In March 1826, Ali Khûrshîd Aghâ was appointed Governor of the province
of Sennar by the Egyptian authorities ; in his ' reign ', slave trading became a
seasonal and well-organized government activity. Using the thin pretext of
military manœuvres, his troops raided the Dinka, Ingassawa and Shilluk tribes
and marched them off d o w n river.
Subsequently, in 1870, Zobeir, a notorious slave trader, was appointed
Governor of the province of Bahr-el-Ghazâl and devastated both Darfur and
Kordofan.
The volume and magnitude of the slave trade greatly increased after
1840 when Sa'id (Ibn Sultan), ruler of Muscat, moved permanently to Zanzibar.
H e introduced the clove to Zanzibar, and large plantations were developed
which demanded a substantial labour force. A third reason for the increase
in the slave trade was the instability of the hinterland, which m a d e it easy for
the Arabs to side with one or other faction against another and to use the pris-
oners taken during these internecine conflicts to augment their trade.
The decisive factor in the Arab slave raids was their ample supply of
fire-arms, which enabled m e n like Tippoo Tib to muster well-trained raiding
parties against which the bows and arrows of the hinterland tribes were powerless.
The slave trade and the population drain 167
from Black Africa
The major centres of the slave trade on the coast were Malindi, M o m b a s a ,
Tanga, Pemba, Zanzibar, Kilwa and Bagamoyo. Although the latter had
become an important terminus by the middle of the nineteenth century,
Zanzibar still remained the nerve centre of the trade. Hence the truth of the
saying ' W h e n you pipe in Zanzibar, they dance at the lakes.'
N o r m a n R . Bennet mentions three main routes of trade penetration in
the nineteenth century :5 thefirst,based on Kilwa, extended to the area around
and beyond Lake Nyasa. All along this route, the Y a o tribe procured slaves
for the Arab traders ; the second route began at Bagamoyo, opposite Zanzibar,
passed through Tabora and the land of the Nyamwezi, and then went on to
Ujiji, across Lake Tanganyika and into the interior of the Congo; and the
third itinerary began at such ports as Pangani, Tanga and M o m b a s a , passing
by M o u n t Kilimanjaro across Masai territory to the eastern shores of Lake
Victoria.
With the expansion of the slave trade, centres like Ujiji and Tabora
became the outposts of the trade, and tribes like the Y a o , the Nyamwezi and
the Ganda became the sorry intermediaries in that ignoble commerce.
The Arab traders penetrated deep into the Congo and even Angola,
according to accounts in 1852 by Portuguese officials w h o had come in contact
with them. Some authors report that up to 10,000 slaves were being sold
annually at Kilwa and Zanzibar around 1810, whereas by the 1860s the figure
had risen to 70,000 for Zanzibar alone.
The best example of the popular image of the ruthless slave-trader was
Tippoo Tib, w h o ruled supreme in the Congo basin during the last quarter of
the nineteenth century. This skilful trader raised a private army, establishing
his basefirstat Ujiji, then moving to Kasongo, Kibonge and Ribariba. His
empire stretched from Lake Tanganyika to the Ituri forest and into the Congo
basin as far as Basoko. H e met and assisted a number of explorers such as
Livingstone, Stanley, Wissman and Junker. For a time his position was legalized
by the Belgian authorities, w h o appointed him Governor of the Falls region
in the Congo Free State. But he represented such a threat that they took up
arms against him, defeating his son Sefu and nephew Rashid in 1893 during
the Arab W a r of 1892-94. Tippoo Tib withdrew to Zanzibar, where he wrote
his autobiography in Swahili.
Another condottiere of the same ilk was Râbih Ibn Abdullah, w h o
dominated the Chad region between 1892 and 1900. H e controlled Bagirmi,
Bornu, K a n e m , Tibesti and the regions of Borku and W a d a y . Most of the
slaves sold by Râbih were brought from Dâr Fartît, on the northern frontier
of the present-day People's Republic of the Congo. Like Tippoo Tib, he clashed
with European interests. H e was killed in 1900,fightingthe French troops at
Kousseri in the Baguirmi region west of Lake Chad.
The slave trade in Central and East Africa was thus mainly in the hands of
168 /. B. Kake
the Arabs, w h o between 1840 and the turn of the century transformed it into
a ruthless,flourishingand well-organized business.
During these voyages, the slaves were treated with great cruelty by the Muslim
traders. The ghellabis (slave-traders) were utterly inhuman, with more regard
for their camels than for their black slaves.
Since the camels in the caravans were heavily loaded with their cargoes
of water, g u m arabic, elephant tusks, etc., all the black slaves, with the exception
of children under the age of 10 or 12 had to follow on foot. A n y w h o lagged
behind from sheer exhaustion were goaded o n by the ghellabis with a whip or
kurbash.
The caravan would usually set off at d a w n and not halt until evening.
Water was parsimoniously rationed out, and the wretched slaves would often
drink only once a day. They died more from thirst than exhaustion. Berlioux
recounts the horror of those desert crossings :
Only by seeing the caravans in the immense solitude of the desert can one imagine
how much the heat and the privations must have added to the suffering of those slaves
newly deprived of their freedom. . . . Along that interminable route there are a few
oases, but sometimes there is nothing but stark desert for several days on end. This is
where the slave caravans suffer their greatest losses, not only from exhaustion, but
because the slave-traders prefer to economize their provisions rather than save the
lives of a few of these poor wretches.6
Those w h o were shipped off to be sold in Arabia or the Persian Gulf Emirates
were scarcely better off. They were transported in boats k n o w n as dhows.
D h o w s were usually fairly small, and since they had to cater for a relatively
heavy traffic, the slaves were packed into them and m a d e the journey in
extremely arduous conditions.
W h e n merchants spoke of the arrival of a caravan, they would assess its
size by the number of heads, amking no distinction between camels and slaves.
The leader of the caravan used the same expressions to goad on the slaves as
the camels.
W h e n a Turk bought a black slave, Frédéric Cailliaud wrote, he would
have him circumcised and then choose some bizarre n a m e for him, for fear of
giving him a n a m e that a m a n might bear.7
Slaves, w h e n not captured during raids, were acquired at markets special-
izing in the trade. S o m e of these were to be found in Black Africa, like the one
at K u k a (a town in the C h a d region), whose slave market was described by
m a n y European travellers in the nineteenth century.
Throughout the year it would be teeming with unfortunate creatures of
The slave trade and the population drain 169
from Black Africa
It is not easy to set a precise figure on the drain represented by this traffic,
but an average of 20,000 a year seems a probable figure for the centuries
during which the Muslim slave trade was at its height.9
By way of hypothesis, R a y m o n d M a u v y estimates that 100,000 black
170 /. B. Kake
slaves were taken to the Muslim world in the seventh century, 200,000 in the
eighth, 400,000 in the ninth, 500,000 in each of the tenth to the thirteenth
centuries, 1 million in the fourteenth, 2 million in each century from the fifteenth
to the nineteenth inclusive, and 300,000 in the twentieth century, making a
total of 14 million altogether. These are provisional figures pending m o r e
detailed studies, which in fact will only be possible for the nineteenth and
twentieth centuries.
The Arabs kept n o official record of the numbers, nor did they write
about their o w n slave trade as s o m e European authors wrote about the Atlantic
slave trade. In any general history of the black slave trade, the role of the
Muslims cannot be ignored. Their trade, however, appears to have been o n a
smaller scale than that of the Europeans, although it lasted longer; indeed
s o m e of its consequences are still apparent in the Middle East to this day.
Although the conditions in which the slaves were captured and carried
off to the Muslim countries were particularly atrocious, the treatment which
the survivors of the desert crossing received o n arrival w a s o n the whole
reasonably tolerable.
Negresses were sought after by the Moroccans not only as concubines, but
also as wives, o n a par with white w o m e n . This explains the large n u m b e r of
mulattos of every shade in M o r o c c o today. E d m o n d o de Amicis remarks :
Curious twists of fate! A poor ten-year-old black boy, sold at the confines of the
Sahara for a bag of sugar or a piece of cloth, can, if fate is kind to him, find himself
The slave trade and the population drain 171
from Black Africa
30 years later a Minister of Morocco discussing a trade treaty with the British A m b a s -
sador, or, even more likely, the little black girl, born in afilthyhovel and exchanged in
the shade of an oasis for a skin of eau de vie, canfindherself while still almost a child,
bedecked with jewels and richly perfumed, in the arms of the Sultan.u
In any case, in Muslim countries the Negress was regarded as an object of
pleasure. She was also a musician and a highly esteemed cook.
The fate of the m e n , with a few individual exceptions, was less enviable.
M a d a m e Valensi, in her study of the black slaves living in Tunisia in the nine-
teenth century, observes that their condition w a s lowly.12 There are n o k n o w n
cases of social ascension a m o n g them. S o m e did become saints, and their
miracles are reported in the hagiography; but here there w a s no escape from
slavery, no hope of ever being redeemed or repatriated.
At best, they were freed, mainly on the death of their owner. In this way
blacks could put d o w n new roots in Tunisia and, before slavery was abolished,
merge with the Tunisian population and even o w n property. But their status
was always one of inferiority.
At times even black slaves had to endure hardships reminiscent of those
suffered by their brothers in misfortune on the plantations of tropical America.
According to G . Mouette, the black slaves in M o r o c c o during the reign
of the Sultan Mouley Archy (eighteenth century) were very badly off.13 They
were put to death for the slightest mistake. T h e workshops were full of them,
in irons and covered in wounds.
But the fate of the eunuch slaves was even worse. At the end of the nine-
teenth century, there was still a vast establishment at Messfoua (Morocco)
preparing eunuchs for the Sultan. Eight out of ten of those w h o were operated
on died. Léon Frank records that between 100 and 200 m e n were turned into
eunuchs annually at A b u Tig, a small town in Upper Egypt. 14
O n e of the last bastions of black slavery in the Muslim world w a s the
army. F r o m the earliest days of the Hegira, Islam employed what M a n g i n
calls the 'black force'.15
' A m r ' , the second Caliph's lieutenant, conquered Egypt and Nubia and
there raised black troops. It w a s these troops that were the backbone of the
army which invaded North Africa. It was this force that provided the sover-
eigns of Spain and the Maghreb with the disciplined, loyal and brave element
which their armies lacked. In the eighth century, the O m a y y a d Caliph Adb-ar-
R h a m a n I (755-87), founder of the Caliphate of Spain, rescued the Spanish
peninsula from anarchy with the help of a 40,000-strong black army. T h e last
of the sovereigns of this dynasty also had m a n y blacks brought from the interior
of Africa and shaped them into a formidable cavalry corps.
The ostentatious H a r u n Al-Rashid himself bought a great n u m b e r of
black slaves, w h o m he armed. In Egypt, the Tulunids and later the Fatimites
had black troops.
172 /. B. Kake
The role of the black force during the Crusades is a subject that remains
to be studied; it must have been an important one and no doubt accounts for
the tenacity of Islam.16
The black slaves imported into the Maghreb as a result of this flourishing
trade were used as guards and soldiers.
The Moroccan Sultan Moulay Ismail (1647-1727) called upon blacks
not only for a bodyguard of unswerving loyalty but also to form a large stand-
ing army; he also gave them a political role of the highest importance through-
out his realm by establishing military colonies.17 The Turks had done the same
before him, when they created at different points groups of auxiliaries w h o were
k n o w n as abids (slaves) when they belonged to the black race.
Mulay Ismail gathered together, through purchase, tribute or war
contribution, all the black slaves in the country, a huge operation that was not
conducted without difficulty, particularly in Fez. His nephew Abhed, Governor
of Draa, led an expedition as far as the Sudan, bringing back a large number
of slaves. H e provided them all with wives, then settled them in vast agri cultural
colonies established at selected points, such as road junctions or in the middle
of turbulent tribes. The Sultan raised a black army under the patronage of an
Islamic saint, Sidi el Boukhari.
E z Ziani, w h o held an important post at the Sharifian court at the
beginning of the nineteenth century, tells us that at the end of Moulay Ismail's
reign, 150,000 abids were on the army lists. It was these troops w h o defended
Morocco's independence against the Spaniards and the Turks. A n d after the
death of the founder of their corps they were to become king-makers.
Conclusion
All in all, the Muslims, as well as the Christians, contributed through the
slave trade to the spreading of the black race beyond its original frontiers.
The Sanaran oases and the southern confines of the Maghreb are largely
populated by blacks, w h o constitute a quarter of the population of southern
Tunisia, three-quarters of the inhabitants of the Draa valley, and almost the
entire population of the Fezzan.
In the Maghreb and in Egypt, negroid types are not unusual. In Arabia
there is still a faily strong element of black blood a m o n g the coastal population.
A s noted earlier, the black question is not often spoken of in the Muslim
world. This is due primarily to the fact that the black slaves were not confined
to ghettos as they were in America; more often than not they mingled with the
white families, the black servants living under the same roof as their masters.
However, in spite of their integration into social life, the black is still a second-
class citizen in the Muslim countries.
The slave trade and the population drain 173
from Black Africa
A n abscess can lead to blood poisoning. It may also develop into gangrene which
may require amputation of a limb. Yet, if treated surgically it will probably leave an
ugly scar and the memory of a throbbing pain. Such have been Arab relations with
Black Africa. The past brings forth the ugly image of the Arab slave-trader which mars
the present and strains the dialogue, creating awkward moments of embarrassment.18
This article should be seen as an attempt to lance the abscess, to open a dialogue
and to plan for the future in full awareness of the past.
Notes
1. André Falk, Visa pour l'Arabie, p. 169, Paris, Gallimard, 1958.
2. E . Zeys, 'Esclavage et Guerre Sainte', consultation d ' A h m e d Baba aux Gens du Touat,
X V è m e Siècle, Bulletin de la Réunion d'Études Algériennes, 1900.
3. E . Berlioux, La Traite Orientale, Histoire des Chasses à l'Homme Organisées en
Afrique, Paris, Guillaumin, 1870.
4. M . Emerit, Les Liaisons Terrestres entre le Soudan et l'Afrique du Nord au XVlWme
e
et au Début du XIX ™ Siècle, Algiers, 1954.
5. N o r m a n R . Bennet, 'Christian and Negro Slavery in Eighteenth Century North
Africa', Journal of African History, 1960.
6. Berlioux, op. cit.
7. Frédéric Cailliaud, Voyage à Méroé, au Fleuve Blanc, Paris, 1826.
8. 1 thaler = 3.75 francs.
9. R a y m o n d M a u v y , Les Siècles Obscurs de l'Afrique Noire, Paris, Fayard, 1970.
10. Jérôme and Jean Tharaud, Fès ou les Bourgeois de l'Islam.
11. E d m o n d o de Amicis, Le Maroc, p. 323, trans, from the Italian by Henri Belle, Paris,
Hachette, 1882.
12. L . Valensi, Esclaves Chrétiens et Esclaves Noirs à Tunis', Annales-Economies-Sociétés,
November/December 1967.
13. G . Mouette, Histoire des Conquestes de Mouley Archy, Connu sous le Nom de Roy de
Talifet, p. 407.
14. D r Louis Frank, Collection d'Opuscules de Médecine Pratique avec un Mémoire sur le
Commerce des Nègres au Kaire, p. 202, Paris, 1812.
15. Charles Mangia, La Force Noire, Paris, Hachette, 1910, 355 p.
16. See Crusade Historians, Historiens Orientaux, Vol. IV, p. 147-8.
17. See Magali Morsy, Moulay Ismail et l'Armée de Métier, Revue d'Histoire Moderne
Contemporaine, April-June 1967.
18. Samir M . Zoghby, 'Blacks and Arabs: Past and Present', Current Bibliography on
African Affairs, Vol. 3, N o . 5, M a y 1970.
Bibliography
North Africa and Egypt
B R A I T H W A I T E , John. History of the Revolutions in the Empire of Morocco Upon the Death
of the Late Emperor Muley Ishmael. London, J. Darby Brown, 1729. 381 p.
174 /. B. Kake
Middle East
It is very clear that the east African slave trade as a factor of continuing historical
signifance traces its roots no further than thefirsthalf of the eighteenth century.
Coupland's argument that it was of continuing importance from the earliest contacts
with Asia simply cannot be substantiated.3
Somali coast) to Egypt in ancient times and also that black slave soldiers from
East Africa were exported to Mesopotamia. H e concludes that the slave trade
was a constant factor on the East African coast between A . D . 100 and 1498. *
A Chinese scholar, Tuan Ch'eng'shih, writing in the middle of the ninth cen-
tury, refers to slave exports from Po-pa-li which, according to Oriental scholars
such as Fredrich Hirth, J. J. L . Duyvendak and Paul Wheatey, is in Somalia.
According to a document dated 1119, most of the wealthy families of Canton
possessed African slaves.5 Another Chinese writer, Chan Ju-kua, makes several
references to African slaves in his work published in A . D . 1226. H e asserts, for
instance, that African 'are enticed by offers of food and then caught and carried
off from P e m b a for slaves to the Ta-shi [Arab] Countries, where they fetch
a high price'.8 The Arab book Adjaib al-Hind, written during the latter part of
the tenth century, stated that 200 slaves were exported from East Africa to
O m a n annually and that 1,000 ships from O m a n were involved in the trade
with East Africa.7 R . B . Serjeant, using the Hadrami Chronicles, also confirms
that slaves were being exported from East Africa to Arabia before the Portu-
guese period.8 East African slaves were also being imported into the Persian
Gulf, especially into Bahrain, between the tenth and twelth centuries.9 The case
of India is m u c h clearer. Substantial numbers of African slaves were reported
by travellers in the Middle Ages to be in Gujarat and the Deccan Areas. F r o m
1459 to 1474, King Barbuk of Bengal possessed 8,000 African slaves.10 M a t h e w
has argued that most of these slaves came from the present United Republic
of Tanzania.
Slaves continued to be exported from East Africa during the Portuguese
period to Arabia and the Persian Gulf. In 1631, for example, 400 Africans from
M o m b a s a were shipped as slaves to the market at Mecca. 1 1
It is thus clear that from at least the seventh century slaves were being
exported in small numbers from eastern Africa, stretching from Ethiopia and
Somali in the north to Mozambique in the south. They worked on the date
plantations in Basra, Bandar Abbas, Minab and along the Batinah coast;
in the pearl-diving industry in Bahrain and Lingeh on the Persian Gulf; as
slave soldiers in various parts of Arabia, Persia and India; as dock workers and
d h o w crews in m u c h of the Arab-controlled Indian Ocean; and as concubines
and domestic servants in Muslim communities throughout Asia.12
The African exodus to Asia and the Middle East and the presence of
Africans in the eastern world is a crucial subject which can only be understood
by paying greater attention to the pre-1800 period. W h a t were the specifics of
the Asian economic situation which created the need for slaves ? W a s there any
difference in status between African and non-African slaves ? H o w did the
Islamic ideas on the institution of slavery affect the slave trade ? W h y is it
that today there are few socially or culturally separate Afro-Asian communities
in Asia ? W h a t was the impact of the African presence upon the indigenous
Population movements between East Africa, 177
and the neighbouring countries
cultures of Asia and the Middle East ? These and other similar questions need
to be explored.
Moving on to the nineteenth century, w efindthat the historians' main
concern has been the volume of the slave trade. Scholars such as R . P . Baur,
R . W . Beachey and Richard Rensch maintain that several millions of East
Africans were sold into slavery in the nineteenth century. Baur, for instance,
asserts that 30,000 slaves were exported from the East African coast annually
in the 1880s.13 Professor Beachey affirms that over 5 million east Africans were
sold into slavery during the nineteenth century.14 Three doctoral theses have
recently shown that the above estimates were nothing but wild guesses.15
Before w e can engage meaningfully in a quantitative discussion of the
Indian Ocean slave trade, w e should emphasize that before the nineteenth
century, the majority of slaves were household servants, artisans, soldiers,
sailors, c o m m o n labourers and concubines. They rarely engaged in large-scale
production of commodities. (The only known exceptions are the salt works of
Persia in the ninth century and salt mines in the Sahara). The expansion of
commerce in the late eighteenth and early nineteenth centuries gradually
transformed agriculture in eastern Africa. M o r e and more land was brought
under cultivation between 1820 and 1870. Traders became farmers, and slave-
traders became slave-owners. A slave system fradually emerged in East Africa,
in which the ownership of the means of production—land and slaves—defined
the principal social groups in society.
The development of European sugar plantations in the islands of Bourbon
and Ile de France relied on slave labour. The slave population of Bourbon grew
from 387 in 1808 to 30,000 in 1779 and 50,000 in 1809-10, while that of Ile de
France rose from 19,000 in 1766 to 55,000 in 1809-10. 16 Most of these slaves
came from Mozambique, although about a quarter of them came from Kilwa.
Numerically, this slave trade to the Mascerene islands was not large, amounting
to about 6,000 per year at the most. Furthermore, it was hampered by the
Anglo-French rivalry, which led to the British taking the Ile de France (now
renamed Mauritius), a ban on slave importation in 1821, and a treaty with the
Sultan of Muscat in 1822 banning the export of slaves by Omanis to Christian
nations. But Bourbon (renamed Réunion) remained in French hands and con-
tinued to receive slaves from various East African ports—Zanzibar, M o m b a s a ,
Takaungu and L a m u . Moreover, in the 1840s and 1850s the French obtained
slaves from Zanzibar under the so-called 'free labour' system, according to
which slaves had to sign a labour contract affirming that they were going
voluntarily before their Arab masters could be paid by French agents. Soon
'free labourers' were coming from Zanzibar, Kilwa and M o z a m b i q u e in
large quantities.
In 1847, Seyyid Said, under strong pressure from the British, signed a
treaty banning the exports of slaves beyond his dominions in East Africa. But
178 Bethwell A. Ogot
by the 1850s and 1860s, more slaves than ever were still being exported to
Arabia and the Persian Gulf. Moreover, slaves in large quantities were n o w
needed by the expanding agricultural economy of East Africa.
Most of the successful Arab traders had decided to invest their profit in a
new cash crop—cloves—which had been imported into Zanzibar from Réunion
by about 1820. Between 1835 and 1845, most of the successful O m a n i traders
became large estate owners, possessing 200-300 slaves per plantation. The large
profits from the clove industry stimulated migration from O m a n . According
to estimates, the population of the Omanis in Zanzibar rose from 300 in 1776
to about 5,000 in 1872. In 1877 alone about 1,000 Arabs emigrated from O m a n
to Zanzibar. In the 1840s, clove cultivation spread to Pemba, where both Arabs
and the W a p e m b a themselves took to it.
The clove trade was not limited to the Indian Ocean market. Ameri-
can and European traders took their share of cloves. For example, in 1841,
American traders bought 110,200 pounds of cloves and, in 1859,840,000 pounds.
The French bought cloves worth $47,983 in 1856 and $60,000 in 1859. The
British and the Germans also joined in the trade. Nevertheless, India and Arabia
remained the most important consumers of Zanzibar and P e m b a cloves.
The clove planters invested heavily in slaves. By 1849, Zanzibar alone was
estimated to have 100,000 slaves. True, it is difficult to have any accurate popu-
lation censuses at this time. Nevertheless, all estimates by contemporary
observers agree that the slave population in Zanzibar had increased to over
200,000 by 1860 out of a total population of about 300,000. Most of these
slaves were owned by the O m a n i Arabs and numbered less than 5,000.
Seyyid Said w h o had acquired forty-five plantations had 6,000 to
7,000 slaves on one plantation alone. Indeed, the period of large and steady
clove harvests coincided with the time when the export of slaves from the inte-
rior of East Africa was greater than ever. According to Cooper, between
15,000 and 20,000 passed through Zanzibar each year. Including slaves that
were sent direct to the Persian Gulf and Arabia, the slave trade of the northern
section of the East African coast was in the neighbourhood of 20,000 to
25,000 slaves a year. According to Curtin, the Atlantic slave trade did not
exceed this magnitude until the eighteenth century.17
Throughout the nineteenth century, Kilwa was the major supplier of
Zanzibar slaves, drawing them from a wide area, especially from the Lake
Nyasa region and northern Mozambique. The neighbouring peoples such as
the W a h a d i m u of Zanzibar or the Mijikenda of Kenya, did not provide slaves.
Perhaps the slave traders did not wish to antagonize them because of their
proximity.
W h a t kind of a plantation society emerged in East Africa? By 1860,
m a n y observers were referring to the Arabs as a landed aristocracy. But not
all Arabs were planters, nor were all planters wealthy aristocracy. At the top
Population movements between East Africa, 179
and the neighbouring countries
of the hierarchy was the Sultan. Seyyid Bargash, for instance, earned $25,000
per year from his estates, which were worked by about 4,000 slaves. B y 1890,
he possessed 6,000 slaves. His sister, Bibi Z e m Z e m , owned about 600 slaves;
and Seyyid Suleiman, another member of the Al-Busaidi tribe, owned over
2,000 slaves. O n the whole, the largest landlords owned between 1,000 and
2,000 slaves, while the average landlord owned thirty slaves. A t the bottom of
the scale was the smallholder w h o owned one or two slaves. The important
point to bear in mind therefore was that free laboour was marginal to the Zanzi-
bari economy, and on the plantations virtually all labour consisted of slaves.
By 1870, Zanzibar society had undergone a profound change. The
plantation had become important as an investment and as a way of life. But
it did not dominate society. Commerce was still important to a large segment of
the Omani élite. Moreover, political power was a matter of dynastic and c o m -
munal politics, not a derivative of plantation ownership.
But the plantation system was not restricted to Zanzibar and Pemba.
It extended to the mainland, with old crops such as grain and coconuts as the
main bases. W h a t changed was the farming methods—from subsistence farm-
ing depending on a family supplemented by a few slaves, to plantations, a
large-scale operation based on slave labour. Arabia and the Horn of Africa
imported foodstuffs from East Africa. In East Africa, places like Zanzibar
with expanding populations and reliance on cash crops had to import food
from the mainland.
Grain cultivation therefore expanded all along, the East African coast,
from Mrima Coast to L a m u , supplying markets in Somalia and Arabia, as well
as Zanzibar.
The significance of this development is demonstrated in the history of
Malindi, an old town which had been abandoned. But from about 1860,
Malindi soon became an important grain-exporting centre. It also contained
thousands of slaves.
By 1874, Malindi was well established. Grain exports were worth about
$150,000 a year. Each year, thirty dhows left Malindi with millet, destined
for the Hodramant, whilefifteento twenty exported sesame. In the words of
John Kirk, Madindi had become 'the granary of East Africa'. The height of
Malindi's prosperty was reached in the 1880s.
Thus infifteenyears, Malindi had graduated from being an abandoned
town to the granary of East Africa. The main reason was the abundance of land
slave labour. B y 1873 Kirk estimated that Malindi had 6,000 slaves. B y the
1880s, there were about 10,000 slaves, owned by about 2,000 Arabs and
Swahili. The richest of them all was Salim bin Khalfan Al-Busaidi, w h o
migrated to Malindi from Muscat in the 1860s, as a m a n of modest means. H e
became Governor of Malindi in 1870, and from 1885-87 and again from 1891
until his death in 1920, he was Governor of M o m b a s a . H e became the largest
180 Betwell A. Ogot
Arab landowner in M o m b a s a and Malindi. A t the time of his death, his pro-
perty was worth £175,000.
The important conclusion is that Malindi was built up in a generation by
immigrants with no local roots, but with connections in their places of origin—
L a m u , Muscat, the Hodramant and Zanzibar.
Between 1873 and 1907, several restrictions were placed on the slave
trade in East Africa, resulting in itsfinalabolition in 1907.
Notes
Bibliography
. Slavery and Slave Revolts in the Sultanate of Zanzibar in the Nineteenth Century.
Journal of the Historical Society of Nigeria, Vol. VI, 1972, p. 215-28.
A L P E R S , E . A . The East African Slave Trade. Nairobi, East African Publishing House,
1967.
. The French Slave Trade in East Africa, 1721-1820. Cahiers d'Études Africaines,
Vol. 10, 1970, p. 80-124.
. Re-Thinking African Economic History. Kenya Historical Review, Vol. I, 1973,
p. 163-88.
. Trade, State and Society among the V a o in the 19th Century. Journal of African
History, Vol. X , 1969, p. 405-20.
B E E C H , Mervyn W . Slavery on the East Coast of Africa. Journal of the African Society,
Vol. 15, 1916, p. 145-9.
B E R G , F . J. The Swahili Community of M o m b a s a , 1500-1900. Journal of African History,
Vol. IX, 1968, p. 35-56.
. Mombasa Under Busaidi Sultanate : The City and Its Hinterland in the 19th Century
University of Wisconsin, 1971 (Ph.D. thesis).
B R O D E , Heinrick. Tippoo Tib: The Story of His Career in Central Africa. London, Edward
Arnold, 1907.
B U R T O N , Richard. The Lake Regions of Central Africa. London, L o n g m a n & C o . , 1860.
2 vols.
. Zanzibar : City, Island, and Coast. London, Tinsley Bros, 1872. 2 vols.
CHRISTIE, James. Cholera Epidemics in East Africa, ...from 1821 till 1872, London, M a c -
millan, 1876.
. Slavery in Zanzibar A s It Is. In : E . Steere (ed.), The East African Slave Trade. London,
1871.
C O O P E R , Frederick. Plantation Slavery on the East Coast of Africa in the Nineteenth Century.
Yale University, 1974. (Ph.D. thesis.)
. The Treatment of Slaves on the Kenya Coast in the 19th Century. Kenya Historical
Review, Vol. I, 1973, p. 87-108.
C O U P L A N D , Sir Reginald. East Africa and Its Invaders. Oxford, 1938.
. The Exploitation of East Africa, 1856-1890: The Slave Trade and the Scramble.
London, Faber & Faber, 1939.
E L T O N , James Frederick, Travels and Researches among the Lakes and Mountains of
Eastern and Central Africa. E d . by H . B . Cotterill, 1879.
F I T Z G E R A L D , W . W . A . Travels in the Coastlands of British East Africa and the Islands of
Zanzibar and Pemba. London, C h a p m a n & Hall, 1898.
G A V I N , R . J. The Bartle Frere Mission to Zanzibar. Historical Journal, Vol. 5, 1962.
p. 122^18.
G R A Y , Sir John. The British in Mombasa, 1824-1826. London, Macmillan, 1957.
. A History of Zanzibar from the Middle Ages to 1865, London, 1962.
H A R R I S , Joseph E . The African Presence in Asia. Evanston, Northwestern University Press,
1971.
H U T C H I N S O N , E . The Slave Trade of East Africa. London, 1874.
I N G R A M S , William H . Zanzibar : Its History and Peoples. London, H . F . & G . Witherby,
1931.
J O N E S - B A T E M A N , P. L . (ed. and trans.). The Autobiography of an African Slave-Boy. London,
1891.
J O N E S , M . K . The Slave Trade at Mauritius, 1811-1829. Oxford University, 1936.
K E L L Y , J. B . Britain and the Persian Gulf, 1795-1880. London, Oxford University Press,
1968.
. Sultanate and Imamate in Oman. London, Oxford University Press, 1959.
182 Bethwell A. Ogot
Hubert Gerbeau
domain whose global nature cannot escape him. That it should be exceedingly
hard for him to grasp its components does not surprise him. T h efirstdifficulty
he meets with is that of the ill-defined limits of the oceanic area. A s an initial
hypothesis, he m a y consider that any phenomenon involving the transport
of slaves from Africa or arriving there via the Indian Ocean falls within his
purview. M o r e difficult to solve are the problems relating to the immensity
of the geographic sectors, the h u m a n diversity in the coastal countries and
islands, and the length of the periods concerned. Each of these aspects has
been dealt with in the works of m a n y specialists w h o usually have no connection
with one another. T h e historian of Zanzibar or of Mauritius in the nineteenth
century had little occasion to do any work on India or China in the fifteenth
century, and vice versa. This is a drawback, but not a serious worry ; that, as
w e shall see, stems from the very nature of the subject-matter involved.
T h e specialist in the slave trade is a historian of m e n and not of m e r -
chandise, and he cannot accept the silence of those transported. Traders,
sailors, administrators and planters cannot give him enough information.
W o u l d one write the history of Auschwitz drawing only on Nazi sources?
This comparison makes us aware of a twofold danger : those w h o , using only
one type of document, see but a part of the picture and are therefore biased,
and those w h o , reacting against deception, put their o w n interpretation on
the thoughts of silent actors and are therefore overbold. T h e study of the
transported slaves is not as simple as that of deported persons during the last
war. The zeal of the abolitionists sometimes lights the way, but often obscures
it too. Does the historian himself remain uninfluenced by the irrationalism of
a history where opposing schools of thought seem to be divided on the basis of
colour, where some side with the victims and others with the executioners?
Whether this difficulty is felt or not, it is reflected in the tone and arrangement
of published works. Those w h o are more technically minded will be criticized
for their dispassionate indifference, others, more givan to polemics, will be
taken to task for their unscientific bombast. Those w h o are concerned about
the dearth of records become over-meticulous, counting, standing up and
knocking d o w n their Negroes like skittles; others, obsessed by the existence
of this forest of fossilized m e n , of w h o m only patchy traces remain, launch
into bold hypotheses and parade their millions of captives in flamboyant,
funereal processions. At best, must the historian not borrow from both schools
of thought, introducing a h u m a n dimension into the infinitely detailed analyses
and building up his general assumptions with scientific accuracy ? But even so,
will he be able to force the slaves out of their silence ? The ways of approach
are narrow, and often very indirect, as w e shall see in the last part, but the
postulate that I have advanced on the content of a history of the slave trade
n o w inclines m e in this direction.
If the requested study on the slave trade is taken to m e a n a history of
186 Hubert Gerbeau
heart of India or the Arab countries, or even more so if employed in the coastal
regions and islands, continued to form an integral part of an oceanic whole
whose unity has been emphasized by Allen.
Here a crucial question arises: was the 'Indian Ocean' slave trade a
factor for destruction or construction? Did it alter, strengthen or undermine
the three 'strata of unity'? The land and sea networks covered by the slave-
trader on the ocean and its precincts must be evaluated with the yardstick of
the history of civilizations within the scope of which I have sought to place this
study of the slave trade. There are additional questions to be borne in mind:
Are those elements which were not originally contained in the crucible going
to melt and enrich the alloy, or are they going to introduce the straw that will
cause future cracks ? Those elements are not only the slaves transported from
the heart of Africa but also the Europeans w h o came late to the Indian Ocean
and settled in other lands.
It is not easy to distinguish between those w h o are actors or objects in
the traffic and those w h o are not. The term 'slave trade' m a y seem quite clear,
yet in fact it is anything but so. At the Unesco meeting of experts in Mauritius,-
in July 1974,1 w e expressed the wish that to the Cartesian notions of 'free' and
'slave' should be added the notions of 'half-free', 'subjected', 'dependent',
'quasi-', 'pre-' and 'post-' slave. T h e exact term has not yet been found, but
it does correspond to a real situation which can be outlined empirically. Models
exist in R o m a n antiquity (the client, the freedman) and in the European Middle
Ages (the serf). The characteristic of the intermediate models between free m a n
and slave seems understandable in the Indian Ocean in terms of a discrepancy
between the legal status and the real position. In Madagascar there were slaves
w h o owned slaves, and in India other slaves legally ran the State as high
officials and counsellors, before becoming sovereigns. But in the sugar-produc-
ing islands, 'free employees' were marched, with pitchforks at their throats,
to the beaches of Mozambique before being crammed into ships as wretchedly
as their 'freely employed' companions in India and ended u p , like them,
in work camps where the commander's stick and the master's arbitrary at-
titude survived the abolition of slavery. In this intermediate category w e must
also include the 'patronized' slave of the last years of French colonial slavery
and the affranchi à livret (freedman with papers) of thefirstyears of emancipa-
tion, the 'apprentice' of the English colonies, certain domestic slaves in
Madagascar and certain 'family captives' in Africa. These last four or five
examples, it will be objected, are admissible in a history of slavery but ill-
chosen in a history of the slave trade. In self-defence, I might refer to the sale
of punished domestic servants to slave-traders, but the problem on which w e
must concentrate is more general. In order to define it with greater precision,
I shall request a twofold favour : that I be allowed to quote an example chosen
some distance away from the Indian Ocean, and that if the slave trade be taken
188 Hubert Gerbeau
While these migrations are still rooted in disruption and violence, the
silence of those concerned is less heavy. Research on them would probably be
rewarding. T o attempt to m a k e an inventory of them would lead m e too far
from m y subject, and I shall therefore confine myself to drawing attention to a
problem which is one both of vocabulary and of classification. It would be
convenient to exclude from m y study all those w h o were not slaves in the legal
sense of the term. But caution is advisable—an unduly meticulous legal ap-
proach m a y distort reality to the point of making a travesty of history.
In the list of research projects to be undertaken—which I shall therefore
restrict here to slaves properly so called—I shall have to deal with extensive
geographical and chronological sectors in which the state of knowledge varies
considerably. Sometimes such knowledge is like a building, strong and firm
yesterday, but today rocked by the effects of new research. Often the accumula-
tion of problems to be solved seems overwhelming but the specialists w h o are
going to tackle them will surely manage to clarify them. Yet will light be
fully shed on the Arab slave trade, on the slave trade in the Far East and on
the clandestine slave trade of the nineteenth (and twentieth) century ?
The Bureau of the Scientific Committee for the Drafting of a General
History of Africa, at its meeting in Fez in February 1975, expressed the wish
that w e should not ' attempt to sum up the wealth of material already published ',
but it seems to m e that the best way of presenting the ' forms to be assumed by
the research on this vast subject and the avenues such research might explore'
is to cutline, in a periodic framework relating to the Ocean, what is already
k n o w n and what might be learned, before concluding with a brief synopsis.
tells us that slaves were taken from the Horn of Africa, in other words present-
day Somalia. T h e Berbera region furnished a small number and the Ras
Hafun region even more. Beyond that zone, the Periplus, which describes the
southern Arabs as beingfirmlysettled along the East African coast, makes no
mention of slaves a m o n g items traded. F r o m the end of the seventh century
onwards, these Arabs were joined by Muslim refugees. The towns of M o g a -
dishu, Brava and Kilwa were founded by the latter in the tenth century. F r o m
there they flocked to the island of Mafia, to various points along the coast,
and to the C o m o r o Islands. T h e earliest contacts of Arab traders with the
Malagasy coast seem to date also from the tenth century (Vérin, 1967).
Between the time with which w e are familiar through the Periplus and
Ptolemy, and the turning-point marked by the tenth century, the source
materials contain practically no information about the East African coasts and
islands which the Greeks called Azania and the Arabs, Sawâhil. But there must
have been a considerable slave trade there, if w e are to judge by the 'Zendj'
or 'Zanj' revolt, in other words the Bantu w h o were taken to Mesopotamia to
work in the sugar-cane plantations and, in the ninth century, played a decisive
part for twenty years in the waging of war and the formulation of a n e w State.
The Zendj werefinallyexterminated, but their revolt contributed to the fall
of the Abbassid Caliphate and put an end to the construction of dams in
southern Iraq, which H . Deschamps sees as the 'firstmodel of a great tropical
construction project involving the labour of hundreds of Negro slaves '.
F r o m the tenth century onwards, the accounts of Arab geographers
enlighten us to some extent on the slave trade. Masoudi, about 1050, speaks of
trade between Mogadishu and P e m b a in slaves, ivory and iron which were
exchanged for pottery from China and Persia. Edrisi, in the middle of the twelfth
century, tells h o w children from Zanguebar were lured with dates and captured,
and refers to the expeditions that enabled the prince of the Island of Qishus,
in the Sea of O m a n , to supply himself with captives in the 'Zendj' country.
The prosperity of Mogadishu and Kilwa which Ibn Battuta visited in the
fourteenth century is not unrelated to the slave trade practised by the sultans
of the east coast. Along this coast, an Islamized mercantile society of mixed
blood raised to its zenith a culture which Chittick proposes to call ' primitive
Swahili'.
Arab sailing boats from the R e d Sea took on slaves in the C o m o r o
Islands from Muslim traders. In thefifteenthcentury, those traders, with
reinforcements from Shiraz, increased their activities and brought wealth to
these islands which ' had become slave-trade centres and stores of h u m a n flesh
between Africa and Arabia' (Faurec, 1941).
However, the mass conversion of the Negro peoples along the east
coasts of Africa certainly obstructed the slave trade; indeed, it was m u c h more
rife in western Sudan during the same period. For although the practice of
The slave trade in the Indian Ocean 191
slavery had spread despite the recommendation of the Koran, it was still agreed
that only non-Muslims could be forced into slavery. The result was not the
disappearance of the slave trade, but an extension of the distances travelled by
the traders and captives as the non-Muslim territories became more and more
remote. All in all, the slave trade was one of the major activities of the Muslim
merchants in the Indian Ocean. Their best outlets were in the Near East,
which they reached by way of Y e m e n and the Persian Gulf. (C. Cahen, 1970).
It m a y be that the decline in the exportation of slaves from Malaysia and the
Indonesian Islands at the end of the Middle Ages caused an increase in the slave
trade along the coasts of East Africa for the markets of Islam. The strong
position held by Muslim traders in all the ' South Seas ' towards the middle
of thefifteenthcentury, after China gave up her maritime policy in the Indian
Ocean, is another factor weighing in favour of this hypothesis (Labib, 1972).
W h a t was the extent of the slave traffic up to that time in the trade
between Africa and China? This is a difficult question to answer. Exchanges
seem to have been controlled by Indonesian intermediaries and appear to have
been considerable, judging by the number of Chinese porcelain pieces discovered
by East African archaeologists. The slave traffic, however, is scarcely mentioned
in the records. In the eighth century, two Negro slaves were shown to the
Emperor of China, and in the twelfth century inhabitants of Canton were
using African slave labour. The seven naval expeditions carried out by the
eunuch admiral Cheng Ho—the first began in 1405 and the last ended in 1433—
attracted considerable attention. They stopped briefly at points along the East
Indies, the Persian Gulf and a number of ports on the east coast of Africa,
including Brava and Malindi. The exploit became a favourite topic in Chinese
popular literature, but the ruling classes found these prestige operations
launched by the emperor unnecessary and ruinous (Wang G u n g w u ) . W e r e
African slaves brought back by the Chinese ships o n that occasion ? It seems
reasonable to put the question.
The African slave trade to India was on a larger scale and is better k n o w n .
W h e n the Muslims conquered the valley of the Ganges in the eleventh and
twelfth centuries, a ' slave dynasty ' held power for some time. In the thirteenth
century, from Ceylon to Gujarat, Ethiopian slaves k n o w n as habshis or siddis
were m u c h sought after. They served as soldiers and sailors. There is a record
of the arrival in India of a large number of slaves from East Africa in the
fifteenth century. A number of them rose to responsible positions, and some
even to high office. For instance, in Bengal where the sovereign owned 8,000
African slaves, King Fath Shah tried to get rid of the most influential ones.
In return, they killed him. F r o m 1486 to 1493, two slave soldiers of African
origin ruled over Bengal. Under the succeeding sovereign, w h o was an Asian,
the Africans had to take refuge in Deccan (Keswani, 1974).
T o take stock of thefifteenthcentury which, in the Indian Ocean, some-
192 Hubert Gerbeau
times seems like the rather insipid continuation of exploits of civilization and
slave-trade phenomena that had been going on for centuries, would be a very
premature undertaking. There are still a great m a n y obscure areas. Specialists
in Indian, Chinese and Islamic studies m a y one day bring new manuscripts to
light or propose a 're-reading' of extant documents, concentrating on the
problem of the slave trade. Archaeology should also shed further light on places
and movements. I shall return to this point later.
W h e n Vasco da G a m a ' sfleetpenetrated into the Indian Ocean from Cape
Guardafui to Sofala in 1498, the coast was lined with prosperous sultanates.
Its Arabization and Islamization m a d e it appear to the caliphs as a dependency
of the Muslim world, 'a notion whose full implications were to be discovered
by the Portuguese when they came face to face with the Egyptians and Turks '
(Otinno, 1975).
Progress in the Mediterranean area and the first phase of the voyages of
discovery across the Atlantic were stimulated by the planting of sugar cane
and the concomitant search for slave markets. Profits from the Negro slave
trade were a consideration in the financing of later voyages of exploration
(J. Heers, 1966). W h e n the Portuguese entered the Indian Ocean, however,
they were 'in quest of spices and nothing else' (Godinho, 1969). W h e n they
visited the towns along the East African coast at the beginning of the sixteenth
century, they noted that slaves there wore simple loincloths, that buildings
were beautiful and that the social élite wore silk and jewels. But their goal was
farther off. They were interested in East Africa 'to the extent that it lay on
the "route to the Indies", and controlled access to it and traffic along it'.
This was the Portuguese attitude d o w n to the nineteenth century (Mollat,
1974). Slaves and gold came later. In Sofala, merchants from Gujarat exchanged
cotton goods from C a m b a y and glassware from Melinda, for gold from
M o n o m o t a p a , ivory and captives which they took h o m e with them. Following
their example, the Portuguese entered into relations with the Kaffirs (Godinho,
1969). In the course of punitive expeditions against the Kingdom of M o n o m o -
tapa, a handful of Portuguese Africans remained behind between the Zambezi
and Limpopo rivers and, after 1574, lived largely on the slave trade (Mauny,
1971).
The Portuguese, sailing towards India, recognized a number of islands in
the south-west of the Indian Ocean and gave them names. O n e of D o n Sebas-
tian's captains, w h o took it upon himself to send his sovereign 'a host of slaves
for his galleys ', had a short-lived plan to conquer the C o m o r o Islands. M o r e
tangible were the slave-traders' activities in Madagascar. In the seventeenth
and eighteenth centuries, the Portuguese, through the intermediary of Malagasy
The slave trade in the Indian Ocean 193
chieftains, loaded their ships with slaves from the northern part of the islands.
Their preference was to frequent the north-west coasts, which were lay-over
points between Mozambique and G o a , and there take on slave cargoes bound
for India (Vérin, 1972). Miss Keswani had pointed out that the importation of
African slaves was carried on actively in Madagascar during the Portuguese
period (Unesco, 1974).
Other slaves were taken away by the various Europeans w h o penetrated
into the Indian Ocean. The Dutch, on their way to Indonesia, began as early as
1596 putting into the Bay of Antongil which was to become the favourite place
for their Negro slave trade in Madagascar. Their settlement in Mauritius in
1638 and in the Cape in 1652 stimulated this traffic. But it was for a more
distant destination that the Jacht Sillida carried off 236 Malagasies on 5 D e c e m -
ber 1681 : they were to join other slaves, mostly from Malabar, to work in a
gold-mine in western Sumatra (Lombard, 1971). Here there was a sharing of
wretchedness, and a meeting of cultures, but h o w m a n y acculturations failed
to take place because of the 'mandor's' whip?
The English ports of call, the Danes stopping along the coast of Coro-
mandel on their way to their outpost at Tranquebar, and the French settled in
Fort-Dauphin, all provided new opportunities for slave trading, but the best
ones were seized by the pirates, beginning in 1685, when the European powers
temporarily withdrew from Madagascar. Driven out of the West Indies by the
advance of colonization, hundreds of freebooters took refuge in the ' Great
Isle'. They became the brokers of the slave trade until about 1726, buying
Malagasies and reselling them to the English of Bristol, the Dutch of Batavia
and the French of Martinique, as well as to the Arabs of Boina and Majunga.
The corsairs delivered their o w n merchandise and slaves to the neighbouring
island of Bourbon (Réunion) where a French governor had signed a contract
with them to purchase slaves w h o m he then resold to those under his admi-
nistration. According to the account of the Provençal pirate, Misson, the
founder of Libertalia, ' A slave in Barbados costs from £750 to £1,250, whereas
in Madagascar with some £12 of merchandise one can buy all one wants. W e
can get a fine chap there for an old suit' (Filliot, 1975).
This cynical calculation had been made before Misson, since Barbados
Island had received 335 Malagasy slaves as early as 1664. The need for m a n -
power in the West Indies and on the American continent was to keep up this
long-distance traffic until the eighteenth century, with a peak period between
the years 1675 and 1725. All told, approximately 12,000 inhabitants of M a d a -
gascar went to the N e w World in servitude (Hardyman, 1964). They were soon
joined there by slaves from East Africa, for example, in Santo D o m i n g o where
the Governor estimated that in 1785, some 3,000 to 4,000 slaves came in from
the Mozambique region, as compared with 34,000 slaves from the Atlantic
coast (Debien, 1974; Toussaint, 1967).
194 Hubert Gerbeau
A s regards the ' slow abolition of the slave trade in the Indian Ocean ', there
are m a n y avenues beckoning the historian. The period of this study should
extend from the second third of the nineteenth century into the twentieth.
Before the years 1830-60, with chronological variations depending upon the
sectors, it would seem a trifle rash to speak of a ' slow abolition '. The fifteenth
century saw the end of a phase of traditional slave trading that had lasted for
over a thousand years. It did not disappear, however, but was taken over and
stimulated by the colonial slave trade which was at its height in the second half
of the eighteenth century and thefirstthird of the nineteenth. Then came the
period of secondary and clandestine forms of the Western slave trade accom-
panied and then outdone by the Muslim slave trade.
The study of these questions would be greatly facilitated by the publica-
tion of new inventories of archive sources. Valuable guides already exist and
might be used as models. For example, there are those of M . D . Wainwright
and N . Matthews. 4
The Guide to Sources of African History, prepared with the help and under
200 Hubert Gerbeau
the auspices of Unesco, is invaluable, but unfortunately the volumes are appear-
ing rather slowly and there are still m a n y gaps in the geographicalfieldcovered.
The authors of this guide themselves are hoping that an inventory will be m a d e
of the wealth of documentation preserved in Africa itself. But w e should go
further and try to secure the participation of all the countries bordering on
the Indian Ocean or involved in its history. Portuguese archives are still little
k n o w n . Godinho's thesis5 gives an idea of their volume and mentions the
enormous amount of inventory work that remains to be done in certain record
offices such as that of Torre do T o m b e . There is still m u c h material to be
discovered and catalogued in the National Archives of India (Keswani, in
press). This would seem to be equally applicable to most of the archives in the
Far East. A very helpful list concerning the Indian archipelago was drawn up
by Denys L o m b a r d at the request of Unesco. Y . A . Talib and H . N . Chittick
have stressed the need for new editions of Arab sources. It has emerged from
discussions on this subject that it would be useful not only to m a k e inventories
and publish new texts, but also to devote specific attention to the texts already
available. This applies to the m a n y accounts of travellers as well as to printed
documents of parliamentary of legal origin.6
However m u c h the inventories of archives in some European countries
m a y have progressed, research on the slave trade encounters a number of
difficulties. Since the store of documents has grown with the centuries, those
subsequent to the eighteenth century are often abstracted rather briefly and
sometimes catalogued in an approximate fashion. The ideal would be to have a
c o m m o n index for all the record offices, and the computer m a y perhaps m a k e
this possible. Then research workers would simply have to press the keys
marked 'slave trade' and 'Indian Ocean' in order to receive a plan of the itin-
erary to be followed round the world, with trails blazed so that they would not
get lost in the voluminous but scattered archives obtaining in large cities, such
as London, Lisbon and Paris. Sometimes the working tools already exist but
funds for their publication are wanting. This is true of the remarkable inven-
tories that have just been m a d e at the French National Archives, Overseas
Section, and which relate in Paris to the 'Réunion' series, and in Aix-en-
Provence to the 'Madagascar and Dependencies' collection. O n e example
should be cited, namely the Bibliography of Mauritius (1502-1954) by A Tous-
saint and H . Adolphe, published in Port-Louis in 1956. T h e work includes a
list of archives concerning Mauritius to be found in collections throughout
the world. This volume, which it is hoped will be updated, is a prototype of
what might be attempted for the whole of the Indian Ocean.
A n evaluation of the wealth produced by the slave trade in external
economic systems could be m a d e only in conjunction with a study of the receiv-
ing countries. This question was of concern to those w h o lived in the years
immediately following emancipation of the slaves. They carried out studies on
The slave trade in the Indian Ocean 201
the comparative profitability of free and slave labour. Such studies were
conducted in the West Indies as well as in the Mascarene Islands and often
show slave labour to be the less economical. However, m a n y assiduous inquiries
are still needed before it can be proved that the slave's output was 'unecono-
mical '. Having read the work by R . W . Fogel and S. L . Engerman, 7 one would be
tempted today, on the contrary, to look into the profitable aspects of slavery,
even in the mid-nineteenth century. Another point that needs clarification
has to do with the financing of the slave trade, and the profits m a d e by the
exporter and the carrier. S u m m a r y evaluations do exist. I quoted Misson's
sally about the price of slaves in Madagascar and the value that was put upon
them in Barbados. In the mid-nineteenth century, a slave exchanged for two
goats near Lake Tanganyika was sold for $20 in Zanzibar and over $60 in
Muscat. These two towns, which were relay points along the slave routes and
centres for financing and redistribution, owed their wealth to the slave traffic.
The constitution of commercial networks, the profit-and-loss balance, and the
share of the slave trade in commerce as a whole are studies which still need to
be undertaken in most of the regions in the Indian Ocean. A remaining task
would be to study the slaves' descendants—freed slaves or fully fledged
citizens. This is not only a demographic problem but also one of integration in
society or rejection by it. In what generation is restitution m a d e for the rob-
bery of Africa? At what point is a balance struck between what the slaves'
descendants have received from the host country and what they have given it?
The major difficulty is still that of counting the slaves. This is the key
both to an accurate answer regarding the enrichment of external economic
systems and to an evaluation of the demographic consequences for Africa.
E . A . Alpers has criticized Coupland's views on the connections between the
slave trade and the low population density in East Africa (1967). The matter
does not seem to have been fully settled. While plenty of estimates have been
m a d e for the eastern part of the continent from the middle of the eighteenth
century onwards, there are virtually none for the previous periods. The contri-
butions m a d e by the slave trade in the islands, m a n y of which were 'population
traps ', are beginning to be assessed more accurately. But losses in the trans-
portation over land and sea are often still u n k n o w n and m a n y generalizations
seem to be rash. Internal displacements—a sort of slave trade in a vacuum—are
still certainly being minimized, as are the volume and duration of the clan-
destine traffic in the European colonies and Muslim countries. It is on these
last points that the overall evaluations m a d e by Curtin and Deschamps will
probably have to be modified most.
A great deal is expected from G . I. Inokori's work on population and the
impact of the slave trade on societies and powers in Africa. In the eastern
part of the continent, I would suggest only a few avenues of research : u p to
about 1750, the political and social balance seems to have been very little
202 Hubert Gerbeau
affected by the slave trade; after that date devastation and anarchy were
rampant along the slave routes. But all the regions were not involved to the
same extent. Sometimes a strengthening of power was not unconnected with
profits from the slave trade, as in the case of Seyid Said in Zanzibar; in other
cases, a n e w power was set up thanks to the trade, as for example that of
Tippoo Tib w h o , about 1872, founded a State on the Lomani River, a tributary
of the Congo.
Sometimes the slave trade brought about a certain interpénétration of the
African and European social systems, as for instance in Portuguese territories.
M o r e often, it accentuated cultural antagonisms and helped to establish a firmer
claim to political, social and religious originality, especially in the Islamized
portion of East Africa. In casting about for types of research to be undertaken,
the need for a methodical correlation between lands of departure and lands of
destination becomes evident. The slave trade is sometimes overworked as an
explanation of events. Thus 'it is impossible to go on maintaining that the
"Africans" of Madagascar w h o came there before the eighteenth and nineteenth
centuries (Makoa, Mozambika) were brought in as slaves' (Ottino, 1974).
M o r e often, however, w e are afraid of going too far the other way, because the
silence about the slave and the silence of the slave are profound. W e are
afraid of minimizing the economic and cultural influence of the slave in a
receiving society by failing to pay attention to the quality of the transplanted
African values or by being ignorant of the quantitative extent of the slave trade.
Although the slave trade sometimes brought about a reduction in the population
when an epidemic was carried by a contaminated ship, it was generally found to
add to the population, as the clandestine arrivals alone show. While still
aboard ship, the slave in transit gave vent to his feelings by his songs, his
rebellion or his suicide. It m a y not always be possible to locate him in the
archives, but he did leave traces of his departure and his arrival. I should like
to recall that there are two ways of approaching the phenomenon of the slave
trade when written documents are scarce. O n e way is via archaeology, which
m a y confirm, ' sometimes in a spectacular fashion, realities of ancient times
that are reflected in the texts'; and the second is via oral tradition which,
although 'a very tenuous Ariadne's clew',8 m a y save us from losing our way
once and for all. P . Vérin observed in the Boeny area, in Madagascar, the
presence of eighteenth-century monuments whose construction was directly
linked to slave-trade profits. T h e excavations currently under w a y in East
Africa and Madagascar, those recently begun in the Comoros, and perhaps
even those being planned in the Laccadive and Maldive Islands m a y yield a
wealth of information. N o site in the Indian Ocean should be excluded out of
hand. The difficulty facing the historian of the slave trade is h o w to single out
the detail which is significant for his subject from the mass of data available,
without making arbitrary additions.
The slave trade in the Indian Ocean 203
Notes
1. Meeting of Experts on the Historical Contacts between East Africa and Madagascar
on the O n e Hand, and South-East Asia on the Other, Across the Indian Ocean,
Port Louis, Mauritius, 15-19 July 1974.
204 Hubert Gerbeau
Bibliography1
1. I have mentioned only those reference works and publications of a general nature which contain
important information about the slave trade in the Indian Ocean and I have confined the list
of articles and specialized publications, as far as possible, to the most recent ones. Those often
contain summaries or critical analyses of previous studies and lists of source materials and
bibliographies.—H.G.
The slave trade in the Indian Ocean 205
at least ten centuries towards the Islamic countries, for which very little
precise information has been collected up to n o w .
A n evaluation should be m a d e of the slave trade in the Indian Ocean, which
lasted from ancient times to the twentieth century, m u c h longer than
that in the Atlantic. Here again present estimates vary greatly: they
range from 1 to 5 million for the period from 1451 to 1870.
A very thorough study should be m a d e of the post-abolition clandestine slave
trade in all its forms, particularly in the south Atlantic and Indian Oceans.
Although m u c h good work has already been done, the meeting considered
that in too m a n y instances the establishment of thefiguresused was based on
a partial, or even partisan, critique of the sources and that the investigation
should therefore be broadened. However there should be preparation for the
further research to be carried out by basing it on the adoption of stricter working
methods.
While recognizing that regional or global quantification was necessary
in order to satisfy the legitimate concern for a proper assessment of the damage
caused to Africa, and also to m a k e the requisite economic analysis, the meeting
hoped that the research entailed, which would certainly be of long duration,
would not block all the discussion and research that needs to be pursued in so
m a n y other fields.
The meeting noted that hardly anyone disputed the fact that several
tens of millions of black Africans were uprooted from Africa and transported
to more or less distant receiving countries and that this drain, quantitatively
huge and qualitatively catastrophic, could not be compared, so far as its effects
were concerned, to the voluntary or at least free migration of Europeans to
North America in the nineteenth century.
bordering on the Indian ocean and the islands of that ocean. The examples
given show that each degree of increased intensity in the production of the
colonies was reflected in different degrees of intensification of the slave trade.
Similarly, the introduction of the steam engine and of the cotton-gin
were important factors in speeding up the d e m a n d for black labour.
In most cases it was necessary for such labour to be renewed very fre-
quently. The life-span of slaves was short and the birth rate very low, thus the
maintenance or increase of the labour force required was possible only by
increased slave imports to keep pace with the development of economic c o m -
petition a m o n g European countries.1
M o r e empirically, the other deductive method would be the further
preparation of serious monographs before attempting to generalize and draw
together numerical results or m a k e classified assessments.
Those in favour of this method, less concerned with overall explanations,
stressed the urgency of certain improvements in the technical methods of
research, such improvements were felt to be needed also in the case of the other
approach.
The meeting stressed that archives should receive special attention. In
certain cases, they had been removed or concealed where they related to the
slave trade;2 in other cases they had not been classified;3 or insufficient use
had been m a d e of them where they were abundant.
In general, the meeting advocated the preparation as proposed by the
Director-General in his opening address, of a Guide to Sources relating to the
History of the Slave Trade in the Archives of the Caribbean Area.
The meeting also considered that a careful re-reading of k n o w n sources
could provide m u c h new quantitative material (for example concerning deaths
at sea) and also linguistic information. While the records were mostly drawn
up by and for slave-owners, they could yield m u c h hitherto scarcely used
information. A thorough scrutiny of the various kinds of sources would m a k e
it possible to classify in the order of its real importance the information
published by each of those sources.
Finally, it was considered desirable to carry out a systematic search
in certain countries (e.g. Turkey, Egypt, the Maghreb countries, Iran, Arabia,
India and Europe) a m o n g sources hitherto inaccessible or not sufficiently avail-
able to the public and which could provide information on the various aspects
of the slave trade. It was thought that private archives and those of European
trading companies could also yield important details if their owners agreed to
co-operate in the collective search.
Oral tradition was thought to be no less deserving of attention. In Africa
itself it could, in particular cases, still provide valuable material. In Brazil,
the Caribbean area, the United States, the islands of the Indian Ocean, and a m o n g
the African communities which had returned from India to Kenya, in Gujarat
214 Summary report of the meeting of experts
on the African slave trade
and in the region of the Persian Gulf, however, it was important that intense
and speedy action should be taken before the disappearance of elderly witnesses
able to provide both information on the slave trade and important linguistic
material.
T o increase our information on the transplantation of African cultures,
a careful survey should be undertaken, rapidly and in depth, of all the traces
of African languages in the three Americas. This study might initially be under-
taken through co-operation between African linguistic specialists and American
scholars, pending the creation of institutes of African linguistics, particularly
in the Caribbean area.
In Africa, a systematic mapping should be undertaken of destroyed or
deserted villages wherever they can validly be linked to the slave trade.
In the Caribbean, Brazil and North America, immediate action should
be taken systematically to assemble objects related to the slave trade, or objects
which have African prototypes.
In a more general vein, the present vagueness of definitions relating
to the ethnic origin of the transported slaves led the meeting to recommend
that scholars should not be satisfied with vague epithets referring to the embar-
kation area in Africa (e.g. ' C o n g o ' , 'Angolan') or to a general linguistic group
(e.g. 'Bantu').
Interesting examples were given of the results obtainable when greater
detail is sought. In the Cape Verde Islands between 1834 and 1856, a register
gives 5,890 names of slaves of w h o m 141, w h o had not been baptized, were
entered under their African names with an indication of their origin (Mandingo,
Joloff, M a n d y a k , Flup, etc.). O n the other hand, the example of the Malays in
the Indian Ocean should be carefully distinguished from that of the ' M a l e '
of Brazil. In connection with these latter the meeting received divergent infor-
mation. However, the word ' M a l e ' is synonymous with Muslim, as is 'Fulani'
in Guyana.
M o r e generally still, reference was m a d e on several occasions to the
advantage of having a descriptive graph of the quantitative evolution of the
slave trade. The information provided by recent studies o n this point could be
gradually corrected and m a d e more accurate as research methods become more
sensitive. Such an overall picture of the phenomenon, in conjunction with
regional and country graphs, would m a k e it easier to perceive the variations
and contradictions of the slave trade. It would also contribute to emphasizing
the importance of never overlooking chronological factors in any quantitative
assessment of the phenomenon.
ever more scanty the further back one goes in history. The state of knowledge
is relatively good concerning the routes used in transporting the slaves and
the ports of embarkation, but study of the economic and political impact of
the slave trade is m u c h less advanced. It is difficult to break d o w n such work
into component parts and dissociate the quantitative elements from the quali-
tative, the economic from the political.
N o n e of the experts present disputed the idea that the slave trade was respon-
sible for the economic backwardness of Black Africa. S o m e experts discussed
the positive role that might have been played as producers and consumers
by the Africans removed from the continent if they had not been transported
as slaves away from Africa.
It was found that the external demand for labour became increasingly
pressing with time and that in the overall study of the slave trade chronological
sequences must be preserved. T h e demand by the Muslim labour markets
was followed, after thefifteenthand sixteenth centuries, by that arising from
the first European experiments with plantations. Then, as the major phenomena
of the plantation economy and mining developed in the seventeenth and eigh-
teenth centuries in the Americas and later in the Indian Ocean, the slave
216 Summary report of the meeting of experts
on the African slave trade
trade grew to massive proportions. Despite its legal abolition, it was maintained,
to a varying extent according to region in the nineteenth and in places even into
the twentieth century, and took different clandestine forms.
While the analysis of the pressures exerted on Black Africa by the demand
for labour appeared to be relatively well developed today, the analysis of eco-
nomic and social consequences was found to be far less advanced. In m a n y
cases, hypotheses still have to suffice.
It would seem that, before thefifteenthcentury, there was an economic devel-
opment that was characteristically African. The accelerated demand for
labour abroad impaired and then put an end to this development. This
is the most logical explanation for the absence of economic vitality in
African societies at the time of the European capitalist expansion.
The slave trade appeared to have provided some already organized African
trading societies with the ready-made solution of exchanging h u m a n
beings for imported goods. Where no specialized trading function existed,
those w h o held political power had to m a k e a choice between accepting
the proposed slave trade or refusing, with all the consequences. European
pressures in thisfieldcontinued to increase from the sixteenth century—
when they already existed for example in the Congo and in Z i m b a b w e —
to the eighteenth century. In the case of some African societies the choice
was often decisive, for instance the O v i m b u n d u in Angola, in order to
survive as an organized group, entered into the system of the Portuguese
slave trade.
The import of manufactured articles probably reduced the Africans' incentive
to produce: this was no doubt the case of iron production in Senegambia.
There was a similarly increasing demand for raw materials—ivory, furs
and skins, g u m , etc.—which were useful for industrial development in
Europe. It is also probable that the diversion of a considerable part of
the labour force to slavery and the slave trade prevented the establish-
ment of a pool of m a n p o w e r available for agriculture and the production
of manufactured goods.
Little by little the slave trade acquired the support of a new class of rich mer-
chants, whose origins varied according to the region and w h o were often
able to oppose the African political authorities successfully w h e n the
latter showed unwillingness to co-operate in the slave trade. This mer-
chant class should be carefully studied.
It was considered that the development of a deep-seated sense of insecurity
and the increase of inter-ethnic or social tensions created an 'anti-
economic mentality' in Africa: all that the Africans were concerned
about was to survive through modest and routine work in proportion
to needs. It was felt that this point should also be the subject of very
careful studies.
Summary report of the meeting of experts 217
on the African slave trade
century bore any resemblance to those which had existed at the begin-
ning of the slave trade.
The question arises w h o best protected those dependent on them and to the
detriment of w h o m , in this redistribution of political factors.
In any event, it seems indisputable that such upsets were accompanied
by an increase of social tensions, a worsening of servitude, especially quanti-
tatively and by a transformation of the former processes of social integration
that the various forms of personal dependence provided in African society
prior to thefifteenthcentury.
A s an extreme case, it must be recalled that, at least in East Africa, and
no doubt elsewhere, rulers founded their power and wealth in the nineteenth
century on the systematic exploitation of the sale of slaves destined for the
Indian Ocean ports or for plantations which were by that time established on
the soil of Africa itself.
slaves. T h e tension was m a d e even more dangerous as the quest for larger-
scale production m a d e the treatment they received more and more unbearable
for the slaves.
In Brazil and in Réunion there gradually emerged a society in which
apart from agriculture, most of the 'small trades' were carried on by the slaves.
There thus developed a whole series of producing trades which were not under
the control of the planters. These are at present being studied by C u b a n
scholars.6
While Haiti considers itself born of the slave trade, the societies to which it
gave rise became creóle by force of circumstances in the course of time. In
these culturally and ethnically more or less composite societies, it is still diffi-
cult to identify the role of Africa and African cultures. T h e degree of survival
of African influences is quite clearly linked directly with social and political
developments in each case under consideration.
Wherever the Black Africans' reaction to protect themselves w a s not
rapid and radical, integration of the slaves into the culture of the European
master class took place, more or less quickly. This gave rise to a linguistic and
religious fragmentation. T h e greater the religious, linguistic and day-by-day
integration of the slaves into a European type of life, the more one-sided the
process of ' creolization ', the m o r e difficult it is to find traces of African culture.
The meeting considered that these very processes of integration should in
themselves constitute a subject of research.6
T h e Muslim societies were in a different category. T h e religion and the
language of the Arabs would appear to be irreversible factors making for
integration, at least in the case of Africans removed from the black areas of
the continent to the Middle Eastern Islamic countries.
The areas where research should eventually be carried out are enormous.
They should include Fernando P o , Sao T o m é , the Cape Verde Islands, the
Azores, the Canaries and Madeira, which were k n o w n and populated in certain
cases before their discovery by Europeans. It should also include the islands
in the Indian Ocean, the Caribbean, Brazil, the United States and Mexico.
Brazil offered m a n y examples of African survivals. In addition to existing
inventories, there should n o doubt be more thorough and scientific studies.
Bahia has a million black inhabitants; African Muslims set u p a resis-
tance movement in the nineteenth century north of Bahia and organized
themselves into a theocratic republic linked to the African continent. Afro-
Brazilians returned in the nineteenth century to the countries round the Gulf
of Benin. A n old m a n of 96, Baba Ijesa,7 spoke in Yoruba with two of the
222 Summary report of the meeting of experts
on the African slave trade
elusions on this matter was that m a n y of the local studies have not been cir-
culated widely enough—for example, the studies on marronnage carried out in
Haiti, C u b a and the Caribbean region in general.
The dates of abolition of the slave trade and later of slavery vary widely and
reflect different factual situations. W h e n theirfinancialinterests were at stake,
owners frequently found it more economical to free their slaves ! Such reasons
explain w h y emancipation began in C u b a and Brazil a long time before slavery
was officially abolished. S o m e of the freed slaves travelled back to what is
n o w Nigeria and to D a h o m e y (now Benin) at their o w n expense. The abundance
of such examples, particularly in the Caribbean, indicates that a general study
of the subject would be worth while12.
Slave revolts undoubtedly played a part in accelerating abolition and
in the development of a wage-earning structure. The Haitian Revolution spread
terror in the slave-trading colonies and metropolitan countries and the slaves
regarded it as symbolic. During the period between the abolition of the slave
trade and that of slavery itself, frequent revolts occurred in the English- and
Spanish-speaking Caribbean, with the support of Christian sects or churches.
In this respect, and perhaps involuntarily, Christianity encouraged the appear-
ance of emancipation movements and Messianic cults.
Here, too, Islam was in a unique position. Rejecting the idea that a
Muslim could ever be a slave, and believing that a 'pagan' one ipso facto was,
Islam had nothing to say about the two abolitions which were the cause of so
m u c h ideological and political discussion in the Christian world.
Whether early or late, abolition of the slave trade hardly ever put an
end to the manpower drain of Africa. In the Indian Ocean clandestine slavery
continued to exist until late in the nineteenth century. Other means of procuring
labour, such as the identure system, took the place of the slave trade.
Abolition m a d e very little difference. The relations of the masters and
the newly emancipated did not improve. The condition of the emancipated was
often worse,financially,than before.
Under cover of the n e w legality, all sorts of schemes were introduced
to enable the masters to perpetuate their control of the labour force (the
gourmettes of Senegambia and the 'freedom villages' of West Africa are exam-
ples). The existence of a free labour market meant that the masters could avoid
part of the costs they had previously borne in connection with their slaves.13
Slavery was an obsolete system, but in addition it was n o w a less economical
proposition than wage-earning labour. Moreover, w h e n the labour market was
saturated, wages fell.
A s a rule, 'official' liberalism considered that freedom was a sufficiently
226 Summary report of the meeting of experts
on the African slave trade
generous gift to absolve the liberators from any further responsibility for the
fate of the former slaves. Irrespective of the status of those w h o organized their
return—States institutions, churches, benevolent societies—the Africans w h o
were repatriated to Sierra Leone and Liberia constituted a relatively small
minority. T h e same was true of the blacks repatriated from B o m b a y to Kenya,
whose case merits further study.
The experts were generally inclined to conclude that abolition brought
no radical changes, but simply led to the transition from one state of production
and exploitation to another. Abolition m a d e it possible to exploit an expanding
African labour market. A t that point, trade with Europe could have served as
an incentive to the development of the domestic economy of Africa. But habits
acquired during the period of slavery appear to have limited the stimulus that
might have been expected.
Before such a stimulus could m a k e itself felt, it was stifled by the colo-
nial conquest which blocked the development of African industry by intro-
ducing foreign business enterprises—and these, once again, exploited the con-
tinent so as to meet the needs of other countries.
There is ample room for further economic study, based on these initial
reflections, concerning the nineteenth and twentieth centuries.
T h e abolition of slavery by Portugal in 1888 led Brazil to break off its
relations with that country a year later. T h e Portuguese economy suffered the
ill-effects of this secession for m a n y decades.
Lastly, the experts turned their attention to the effects of abolition on
inegalitarian attitudes towards blacks. They concluded that abolition had led
to an increase in racialist attitudes of all kinds with regard to the Negro world
which was regarded as 'uncivilized', a world that had no right to its o w n culture
or its o w n religion. ' Scholars ' were quick to justify this harsh and unjust atti-
tude and to draw a distinction between the 'primitive' Negroes, with w h o m
nothing could be done, and the 'superior' Negroes, w h o could be assimilated.
N e w lines of research
The experts recommended the following activities and subjects for research:
Exchanges, with assistance from Unesco, of teachers and students from uni-
versities in Africa, the Caribbean and the Indian Ocean region, w h o are
interested in the study of the various forms and consequences of the
slave trade.
T h e establishment of bilateral research teams of Latin American, Caribbean
and African scholars to m a k e an inventory of African cultural survivals
(linguistic expressions, for example) of African life in the Americas.
T h e African States should be asked to include the teaching of Caribbean
Summary report of the meeting of experts 227
on the African slave trade
Closing session
are capable of examining, with complete lucidity and objectivity, issues that are
extremely controversial because they have a connotation that is in some cases ideolo-
gical as well as affective, and of arriving at recommendations that are satisfactory from
the scientific point of view . . .
Recommendations
All the archives concerning the slave trade must be m a d e accessible to scholars,
without any restrictions. Unless matters were improved, m u c h archival material
might be lost, and hence international opinion should be alerted.
It is matter of urgency that a scientific classification be undertaken of
public and private archives in Africa, the Americas and Europe relating to the
slave trade.
It would be desirable that Unesco provide rapid assistance in the prepara-
tion of a guide to sources relating to the slave trade to be found in collections
of archives in the Caribbean area.
There exist, particularly in Brazil, in the Caribbean area, but also in various
parts of the Indian Ocean region and in North America, persons w h o possess
traditions concerning the slave trade, as well as surprising vestiges of trans-
planted African languages. Rapid and vigorous efforts should be m a d e to
record this living evidence of survivals of African influences outside Africa.
Traces of African languages o n a large scale (Haiti, Bahia, etc.) or in
more fragmented form must be preserved and recorded, and then studied by
competent experts, pending the establishment, which w a s also recommended,
of linguistic institutes for the study of the African languages in the countries
of the black diaspora, particularly in North and South America, the Caribbean
and the Indian Ocean region.
The experts strongly hoped that the governments concerned would agree to
include the history of Africa in syllabuses in the Caribbean area and the history
of the Caribbean in syllabuses in African countries.
Notes
1. It was suggested that the experts pay the greatest attention to the pitfalls of inadequately
digested mathematical techniques used on behalf of a dangerous ideology. T h e
following works were recommended by one of the participants: Calcul et Anthro-
pologie Paris. (Collection '10/18'); André Régnier, La Crise du Langage Scientifique,
Paris; Pourquoi la Mathématique, Paris (Collection '10/18').
2. Examples were given for Portugal and Guadeloupe.
3. The Copenhagen Archives relating to the Virgin Islands are a case in point. However,
D r Neville Hall, D e a n of the History Faculty at the University of the West Indies,
M o n a (Jamaica), was given access to them recently.
4. It should be emphasized that the benefits of the slave trade accumulated by the receiving
countries were a powerful stimulus to international trade, both in volume and in
value, and that this commercial development was itself an incentive to modern
economic development in Western Europe and North America.
5. See Pedro Deschamps Chapeaux, Contribución a la Historia de la Gente sin Historia,
Havana, Editorial de Ciencas Sociales, 1974.
6. Scholars in Puerto Rico have begun to undertake research of this kind.
7. E b u n Ogunsanya, The Yoruba Dialect in Bahian Portuguese, R o m a n c e Languages
Department, Radcliffe College, Harvard University, 1971 (Senior Theses, B . A . ) ;
Interviews with Eduardo Magobeira (Baba Ijesa), Bahia, June-August 1970.
8. See Jane McDivitt, From Anguish to Affirmation—A Study of the Poetry of the Afro-
Brazilian, Harvard University, 1976, (unpublished doctoral thesis); Anani Dzid-
zienya, The Minority Position of Blacks in Brazil, London, Institute of Race Rela-
tions, 1972.
9. See the final report of the Meeting of Experts o n the Historical Contacts between
East Africa and Madagascar on the O n e H a n d , and South-East Asia on the Other
across the Indian Ocean, held in Mauritius in 1974 (Unesco doc. S H C . 7 4 / C O N F /
611/10.
10. See Richard Price, Maroon Societies, A n n Arbor, Michigan.
11. See R . Berrou and P. Pompilus, Histoire de la Littérature Haïtienne Illustrée par les
Textes, Paris, Éditions de l'École, 3 vols.
12. See Revista la Torre, special issue published in November 1973 on the abolition of
slavery in the Caribbean.
13. See Antonio Carreira, Angola, da Escravatura ao TraballoLivre, Lisbon, Arcadia, 1977
Appendixes
Appendix 1 : List of participants
J. F . A D E A J A Y I L. E D M O N D S O N
Vice-Chancellor, University of Lagos Department of Government
(Nigeria) (and Vice-Dean, Faculty of Social
Fitzroy A . BAPTISTE Sciences), University of the West
Department of History, M o n a (Jamaica) Indies,
University of the West Indies,
Jean F O U C H A R D
St Augustine, Trinidad (West Indies) Société d'Histoire de Haïti,
Max BENOIT
B.P. 64, Port-au-Prince,
N o . 19 Turgeau, Port-au-Prince (Haiti)
(Haiti)
Edward K . B R A T H W A I T E Hubert G E R B E A U
Department of History, University Centre Universitaire de la Réunion,
of the West Indies, M o n a (Jamaica) 97489 Saint-Denis, (Réunion)
Antonio C A R R E I R A Mbaye G U E Y E
Rua Maestro Jaime Silva, N o . 9-80, Faculté des Lettres et Sciences
Dto Lisboa-4 (Portugal) Humaines,
John H . C L A R K E Dakar (Sénégal)
Hunter College, 695 Park Avenue, Joseph E . H A R R I S
N e w York, N Y 10021 History Department, Howard
(United States) University,
Philip D . C U R T I N Washington, D . C . 20059
Department of History, (United States)
Johns Hopkins University,
J. E . INIKORI
Baltimore, M D 21218 (United States)
J. DÉVISSE
Department of History,
A h m a d u Bello University,
14 Avenue de la Porte de Vincennes,
Zaria (Nigeria)
75012 Paris (France)
Alioune D I O P Ibrahima Baba K A K E
Société Africaine de Culture, 79 R u e Marcadet,
Paris (France) 75018 Paris (France)
Michèle D U C H E T D . LARA
E N S Fontenay, Institut Caraïbe de Recherches
Université de Paris VII, Historiques
29 Rue Boussingault, 14 R u e Henri-Wallon,
75013 Paris (France) 93800 Epinay s/Seine (France)
234 Appendixes
M . LIMA Frank M o y a P O N S
Rua Alves Redol, 17/CV/Esq, Atarazana N o . 3 (Altos),
Lisboa-I (Portugal) Santo Domingo
Pierre M O N O S I E T
(Dominican Republic)
Musée d'Art Haïtien Waldeloir R E G O
P . O . Box 1309, Port-au-Prince Ladeira do Desterro, 19,
Caixa Postal 1023,
(Haiti)
Salvador/Bahía (Brazil)
D.T. NIANE
Walter R O D N E Y
Fondation L . S. Senghor,
186 South Ruinveldt Gardens,
B.P. 2259 Dakar (Senegal) Georgetown (Guyana)
René PIQUION Rubén SILIE
Directeur de l'École Normale Calle Diagonal ' C N o . 54,
Supérieur d'Haïti Santo Domingo
2 bis Rue de Bois Patate (Dominican Republic)
Port-au-Prince (Haiti) Y . A . TALIB
Bethwell A . OGOT Department of Malay Studies,
Director, University of Singapore
International Louis Leakey M e m o - (Singapore)
rial Institute for African Prehistory, H . F. S. TJOE N Y
P . O . Box 46727, Nairobi (Kenya) Dean of the Faculty of Social and
A. F. PAULA
Economic Sciences,
Head of the Central Historical P . O . Box 2611,
Archives, Paramaribo (Suriname)
Roodweg 7 bis, Willenstho, Hugo TOLENTINO
Avenida Bolívar 110,
Curaçao (Netherlands Antilles)
Santo Domingo
Raoul P I E R R E - L O U I S
(Dominican Republic)
Secretary of State
J. Michael T U R N E R
for National Education (Haiti) Departemente Geographia e Historia,
F. L . Veiga P I N T O Fundaçao Universidade de Brasilia
37 Avenue D u m a s , (Brazil)
Geneva (Switzerland)
Other observers
Unesco
M r Director-General of Unesco,
Excellencies,
Ladies and Gentlemen,
In opening this meeting, and with the Director-General's permission, I invite the
meeting to observe a minute of silence in m e m o r y of all the u n k n o w n maroons, of all
our ancestors, and particularly of a greatly lamented 'Griot' François Duvalier.
W e are grateful to His Excellency, the Life President of the Republic for having
extended his patronage to this meeting, and w e sincerely thank him for all his interest
and support in connection with this meeting of experts jointly organized by Unesco
and the Haitian Government.
W e are very happy and proud, M r Director-General, to have you a m o n g us
on this occasion, and it is a great pleasure to be able to express to you directly the
respect, admiration and fraternal affection which, for m a n y reasons, w e bear you.
Your participation in this inaugural sitting is for us a major contribution which w e
greatly appreciate.
Allow us, M r Director-General, to present our respectful greetings to one of
our o w n people, your o w n wife, so modest and yet so distinguished. Both of you are
here a m o n g your o w n .
I n o w welcome the honourable participants and observers to the sunny and
friendly land of Haiti, the h o m e of Toussaint Louverture, B o u k m a n , Halaou, Biassou,
Jean-Jacques Dessalines, Alexandre Pétion, Henri Christophe and François Duvalier.
A visitor w h o sees Haiti for thefirsttime from the air is bound to be struck by
the craggy nature of the country. If he comes closer, he will, if he looks carefully,
perceive the teeming of intense life, he will hear virile songs accompanied by drums,
which provide encouragement and support for those working on the land, according
to the fantasy of the combite musicians. Here and there, smoke rises from modest
cottages, from hamlets scattered on the tops of the mountains, on the hillsides, and
in the lush valleys.
The visitor then exclaims: 'This is Haiti', Haiti the country of plateaux and
mountains, Haiti the land of places of great suffering, glory and hope, and of unsus-
pected potentialities. The names of these places are Breda, Cormiers, Haut du C a p ,
Arcahaie, Vertieres, La Crête à Pierrot, Gonaives, Marchaterre and Bonnet à l'Evêque
where rises King Christopher's Citadelle in all its majesty.
Appendixes 237
There are other secret spots which do not have well-known names; these are
the dark caves in our mountains, our steep cliffs and hidden dells in our plains; all
of them friendly and impregnable hiding places for the maroons of former times. W e
can include in this context every inch of the tortured and holy land of Haiti, for long
the cradle and bulwark of négritude in America, so often burned, ravaged and bathed
in blood, sweat and tears, but which continued to nourish that mysterious 'tree of
black freedom', the trunk of which, although hacked and scattered to the winds, still
each time grows again from its m a n y deep roots.
Ladies and Gentlemen, participants and observers, w e welcome you with
respect, trust and friendship. Y o u will find here surprising survivals from our Mother
Africa in gestures, words, songs, dances and m a n y other significant details. Y o u will
also find kindness which reflects a real wish to please, but which does not exclude
dignity and self-control, a welcome full of the warmth of easy-going h u m a n friend-
liness which does not exclude respect for others; a sense of solidarity born of long
suffering which does not exclude independence of character; a w a y of smiling tinged
with melancholy and dreaminess, the gaiety of laughter clothed in light, music, colour
and dancing which does not exclude clear-headedness and is often a m a s k behind
which life's aggressions can be challenged. There is also the faithfulness to ourselves
and our values born of our determination to survive, but which does not exclude
openness to h u m a n contacts and discussions.
In order to become at last truly ourselves, w e k n o w that at the crossroads of
the present w e still have to overcome obstacles of a new creeping and insidious kind,
such as land erosion, drought, floods, the slow destruction of our historical m o n u -
ments, the unsuitability of our educational system in comparison with our needs and
aspirations, underproduction—in a word : underdevelopment.
In this new kind of struggle, applying the development strategy which w e have
chosen, w e Haitians need sincere, understanding and reliable friends w h o are able
to avoid wounding our native pride, to accept us as w e are, and to give their friendly
co-operation as w e tread the difficult path ahead.
N o w is the time for thought, joint effort and mutual enrichment. In this connection,
the great migrations and the wanderings of those willingly or unwillingly uprooted
from their native lands are particularly revealing. M a n is in himself a whole universe,
and even when he was transported naked, empty-handed and far from his o w n kin,
he still kept his memories of h o m e , his visions, his dreams, his ideas and his emotions
and, in his n e w surroundings, his daily acts still reflected the traditions of the past,
imprinted indelibly on his innermost unconscious.
By studying these movements, w e get a deeper grasp of the contributions and
reactions of different civilizations, and can discern through the curtain of time our
ancestors kneeling to their o w n gods in their hidden temples.
The studies which you will undertake on the slave trade in all its aspects,
implications and consequences will be both moving and valuable.
F e w terms evoke in us such strong reactions, such an emotional shock, as the
words'slave trade', few terms carry such tragic memories, so indelible that no passage
of time could ever quite efface them.
W e , too, following on the original inhabitants of this land, have our eyes
238 Appendixes
ceaselessly fixed on the ocean over which through the centuries has c o m e so m u c h
good and so m u c h evil. Thefirstpredators w h o settled on our countryside brought
with them the cross in one hand and the sword in the other; in doing so they set the
course of our historical destiny. The result of their despoiling passage was the slave
trade, suggested and indirectly instigated by Las Casas.
Y o u will, during these few days, identify the cultural imprint which, through
their long journey, their complex process of adaptation and their protective and
survival mechanisms, the victims of the slave trade clearly and indelibly impressed
on the differentfieldsof h u m a n activity in the places and societies where they had
to m a k e their lives.
This is, without doubt, an exciting and constructive task which, while there
m a y be gaps in our knowledge and m a n y traps to be avoided, is pregnant with unex-
pected discoveries that will provide the impetus for n e w historical, sociological and
philosophical advances for the benefit of mankind.
While these remarks are not off the subject, they must seem to you w h o are
precise m e n of science rather illusory and pointless.
Y o u will have to set d o w n the interactions, extrapolations and end results of
extraordinary adventures lived by our fathers uprooted from Africa and cast into
the outer darkness of slavery.
F r o m the confrontation of your different theories and painstaking research
w e shall obtain a clear, precise and informative picture of the impact of the slave
trade and its indelible imprint on the old as well as the new world.
I d o not wish to take up more of the precious and unfortunately limited time
which you have to discuss your researches and reflections on so fascinating a subject
as the slave trade, but in this arduous task, you have m y warmest wishes for the
successful accomplishment of your task. M a y you have a happy and fruitful stay in
Haiti.
Raoul P I E R R E - L O U I S
Secretary of State
for Education, Haiti
Appendix 3 : Opening speech
of the Director-General of Unesco
M r Minister,
Excellency,
Ladies and Gentlemen,
First of all I wish to express m y deep gratitude to the Government of the Haitian
Republic for its kindness in hosting this meeting of experts in connection with the
General History of Africa project. I also wish very sincerely to thank M r Raoul
Pierre-Louis, Secretary of State for Education, for his personal co-operation in the
preparation of this meeting and for the important address that he has just delivered.
I a m grateful to him for having so affectionately welcomed the Haitian lady w h o has
shared m y life and efforts for more than twenty-five years. This is thefirsttime that
Unesco has organized a meeting on this important project concerning the history of
Africa outside the African continent. It was right that it should be held in Haiti. But
the occasion has above all a special significance by the very reason of the topic of your
discussion, the question of the slave trade. For Haiti remains a living symbol of both
the sufferings and the heroic struggles of the black slaves uprooted from their African
soil but never resigned to their fate. Their victorious action m a d e possible for the
first time in the history of mankind the establishment, out of the ruins of a slave
society, of a State based on the right to individual freedom.
While the slave trade determined the future of the communities resulting from
the African diaspora which today form the population of m a n y Latin American and
Caribbean areas, it also left a very deep imprint on the history of Africa. This means
that the results of the work of this meeting will be very important for the project o n
the General History of Africa, the drafting of which has been entrusted by Unesco to
an international scientific committee composed of specialists from Africa and all the
other regions of the world. I have pleasure today in welcoming a number of its m e m -
bers here present.
T o further its work the committee recommended the holding of just such
meetings of experts, colloquia and seminars on certain vital topics such as that for
which w e are convened today.
There are five main items on the agenda for your discussion. T h efirstis the
scale of the slave trade. In the study of this subject, comparisons of the different
methods employed should enable more precise statistical data to be evolved.
Following on this quantitative approach, you are called upon to discuss in
substance the demographic, political, economic, social and cultural consequences of
240 Appendixes
the slave trade, both in Africa and the receiving countries, particularly in the
slave trade, both in Africa and the receiving countries, particularly in the Americas.
Next it is proposed that the meeting study movements of thought and ideolo-
gies, both those used to justify the slave trade and the abolitionist movements, together
with the interpretation of different contemporary schools of thought and research.
M o r e particular attention will be focused o n the factors which led to the abolition of
the slave trade.
Finally, turning to action and the organization of future studies, you are asked
to m a k e proposals for the practical follow-up of this meeting. O n its side, Unesco
pledges itself to contribute its full co-operation.
While it is true that other peoples, for example the Amerindians, have suffered
at one time or another in history from violent oppression which forced them into a
situation of slavery, it is essentially the Africans w h o , in modern times, were reduced
to slavery and transported in large numbers to other continents by means of an orga-
nized m o v e m e n t . T h e slave trade, of which it has been said that it w a s an endless
bloodletting, drained the African continent of a large part of its vital resources, for
it w a s generally of their youngest and strongest members that their peoples were
bereft.
T h e slave trade therefore had far-reaching consequences for the economic,
social, cultural and even political life of Africa, although it is not yet possible to quan-
tify them precisely. A great deal has been said and written about the slave trade but,
in fact, there is still n o satisfactory answer to a number or questions, starting with
the far-off origins of the traffic in African slaves, which probably go back as far as
the beginning of Mediterranean history. Similarly, still too little is k n o w n about the
traffic through the Sahara or that via the east coast of Africa across the Indian Ocean
in the direction of India, Indonesia and as far as China. There is indeed evidence that
black slaves were presented to the Emperor of China in the seventh century, while
African slave labourers are reported in Canton in the twelfth century.
It would seem that in the eleventh and twelfth centuries, after the conquest of
the north of India by the Muslims, power w a s in the hands of an 'African slave
dynasty'.
T h e African slave presence in Asia was reinforced in thefifteenthcentury,
particularly in Bengal where social, economic and political life is said to have been
enlivened by the activities of some 8,000 black slaves.
T h e traffic grew between the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries, w h e n
Portuguese and Dutch traders selected Antongil Bay in Madagascar as the bridgehead
in the direction of Sumatra. Little has been written about this period and w e must
wait until various archives give up their secrets. These include the Portuguese and
Arab records, documents which m a y exist in countries lying between M o z a m b i q u e
and the R e d Sea, archives in the Seychelles which served as a staging-post between
Africa and the other Mascarene Islands, plus archives in India and the Indonesian
archipelago.
However, the real slave trade which was to have far-reaching repercussions m a y
be taken as that which developed across the Atlantic. Quantitatively large, it was also
important by virtue of its organized character and n o doubt also because of the extent
of its manifold consequences.
Appendixe!, 241
The most recent research, even that which has m a d e use of the most modern
technology such as computerization, is still far from providing complete information
on the loss of h u m a n resources forced upon Africa. T h efiguresput forward so far
remain approximations. Methods of estimation, moreover, vary from one school
to another. Y o u are therefore asked to compare the different approaches followed by
establishing statistics and to suggest a method that might provide m o r e precise results.
But apart from methodological problems, there still remains a question of
scientific interpretation. Here again, your meeting has an important task to perform.
This is to find a w a y to deal with certain basic questions, from the standpoint of the
strictest objectivity, through use of more varied and m o r e numerous data, drawing
on all the sources that have remained hitherto inacessible or have rarely been con-
sulted, or those containing information which has been wrongly interpreted. Such
sources include oral tradition, an invaluable store of ethnic memories.
In connection with the very substance of your meeting, I should myself like,
in a very personal w a y , to lay before you a number of questions.
First, what were the circumstances in which the slave trade was carried on in
Africa itself? It is important ot get a clear idea of what is k n o w n about the trading
posts and holding areas in which the captives were assembled in conditions such that
some died even before embarkation on the slave-ships. It would, n o doubt, be advisable
to have recourse to sources hitherto inadequately investigated, and to cross-check
information supplied by the various documents, such as the records of ship-owners,
slavers, the big monopoly companies and national naval archives. In particular an
even closer analysis should be m a d e of ships' articles which provide valuable evidence
concerning the loading, travel and unloading of slaves; and court records of civil and
criminal proceedings concerning slaves and slave-traders should be more thoroughly
studied.
It is also desirable to s u m up present knowledge concerning the w a y in which
the man-hunts were carried out, the victims captured and reduced to slavery on the
African continent, and to study completely objectively the role both of foreign powers
and of the local authorities.
O n e of the too little k n o w n and yet real aspects of the subject on which fresh
and more thorough research is required is the topic of domestic anti-slavery and anti-
slave-trade movements. T h e resistance struggles leading to the victorious winning of
independence in America have their early roots in this determination on the part of
the victims of the slave trade to maintain their h u m a n dignity and safeguard their
existence.
While new life can thus be instilled into the study of the circumstances of the
slave trade, there is also need for a more precise appraisal of its consequences in Africa.
The foremost of these are in the h u m a n context. There was a terrible loss of life, which,
as I have said, literally drained the blood of Africa and also, n o doubt, left huge
stretches of land uncultivated, seriously interfering with social and economic life
and hindering cultural development and technological progress.
Thus for more than four centuries, population growth in Africa lagged greatly
behind that in any other continent over the same period.
While these losses, in terms of h u m a n life, are, if not precisely, at least with
increasing accuracy, being quantified in all their tragic reality, other, and not the
242 Appendixes
least important, effects have not yet been elucidated. Examples of such effects are the
perversion of men's minds caused by the slave trade and interferences of all kinds
which had a direct impact on the normal development of Africa. T h e fact that there
were some Africans w h o turned into accessaries to the heinous crimes committed in
the course of the slave trade, so becoming the suppliers of the slave-traders, deserves
further elucidation. But at the same time it is important to give consideration to a
basic fact, namely the strength of the spiritual and moral values, and the peoples'
powers of resistance, which gave rise in Africa itself to opposition movements.
Thus these values survived, and cultural identity persisted through all the
sufferings of enslavement and transportation. This is because this culture was deeply
rooted in the heart of men's innermost consciousness, an integral part of the very
existence of the communities concerned. It formed the very essence of their lives. It
was thus able to stay alive during exile, preserve dignity in servitude, and supply the
inspiration for revolt and the conquest of freedom and independence.
T h e qualitative factors connected with the study of social systems and of
spiritual, moral and cultural values thus have a part in your work alongside the
quantitative factors being determined under increasingly strict control and with ever
greater precision.
This work, while essential for a proper African epistemology, is also of prime
importance in throwing light o n the history and the present situation of Europe and,
of course, Africa.
It is becoming increasingly clear that the slave trade had a fundamental part
to play as far as Europe was concerned, for thefirstindustrial revolution can n o
longer be isolated from the primitive capital accumulation deriving from the 'triangu-
lar trade' and the monopoly system. In recent years m a n y historians and economists,
belonging to different schools of thought, have endeavoured to ascertain h o w his
kind of trade, based on the exploitation of slave labour, can have stimulated the
technological explosion.
These studies have clearly shown that the contribution of the slave trade to
the industrial and commercial development of countries embarked on an era of
capitalist expansion was decisive, as was therefore its influence on the socio-economic
and political institutions of Europe and North America.
Thus, to paraphrase A i m é Césaire, 'those w h o invented neither gunpowder
nor electricity' were, whether they liked it or not, at the origin of the extraordinary
economic drive which produced modern technological civilization; it can be said of
them, to quote the poet again, that 'without them the earth would not be the earth'.
M a y b e it will be for them to contribute n o w to bringing this civilization into better
balance and harmonizing it so that the earth m a y be a better place for each individual
and for all mankind.
A s regards Latin America and the Caribbean, by a happy chance the Inter-
governmental Conference on Cultural Policies, held by Unesco for thefirsttime in
this region, and which has just ended in Bogotá, almost coincided with your meeting.
In the course of that conference a number of delegates stressed that m a n y liberation
movements had started in the Caribbean and then spread to the continent, thus
sealing the historic link of unity between the Islands and Latin America. In an initial
summing up of the situation on the closing day of the conference, I myself m a d e a
Appendixes 243
point of stressing the pioneer role of Haiti and the value of the example set by its
struggles, which indissolubly linked together liberation from slavery and the winning
of political independence.
There is one other basic feature of the Caribbean to which I should like to
draw attention here. This is the welding into an original identity of the differing cultural
traditions coming from Africa and elsewhere. T h e old-time slave-traders were accus-
tomed to split up ethnic and linguistic units so as to dominate more easily the groups
subjected to the slave trade by reducing them to the single elementary status of slave.
However, by some miracle, despite this forced separation, a real cohesion survived.
This miracle is essentially that of culture, a community of culture. It was linked to
shared values and beliefs, and to religious, spiritual and artistic forms of expression
which m a d e it possible to create a sense of c o m m o n origin and active solidarity.
Thus, through this very uprooting, culturally integrated communities were created
all over again ; while they used borrowed languages, they none the less provided the
foundation for the awareness of a collective consciousness, which itself became the
basis for a will to c o m m o n action.
This meeting will also have to take into account this cultural integration both
to understand the past with its independence and abolitionist movements and to
look into the future. Y o u r meeting is indeed called upon at the end of its work to
frame practical plans for future action. T h e results of your work will primarily contri-
bute to the drafting of the chapters and sections concerning the slave trade in the
General History of'Africa. However, they should also open up n e w avenues of research,
including the organization of collective undertakings and the publication of books
intended for the general public, and works of reference. In this connection, I have
asked for a study to be m a d e of the possibility of supplementing the Guide to the
Sources of the History of Africa series published under the auspices of Unesco, with
a publication on archival sources relating to the slave trade to be found in the Americas
and the Caribbean.
In addition, organized efforts to stimulate the collection of historical documents,
and the reproduction of texts which are difficult to find could supplement documen-
tation n o w available.
Your recommendations should also be directed towards strengthening Unesco 's
programmes concerning relations between Africa and the Caribbean and, I would
say, America in general. These programmes should, moreover, help to increase our
understanding of the way in which ethnic groups and peoples transported from dif-
ferent African regions were welded into a national community.
I have the intention of proposing, at the next session of the Unesco General
Conference, the convocation of a meeting of experts on the black African cultural
presence in the Americas and the Caribbean. It would be the purpose of such a
meeting to facilitate the framing of a research and cultural dissemination programme
on the African diaspora.
Arrangements are also being m a d e to assemble and translate for publication
oral traditions transmitted in the African languages. A t the same time the exchange
of information and cultural programmes, specialists and students, between Africa
and the African diaspora will be encouraged. This will contribute by the same token
to strengthening the bonds of solidarity existing between Africa and the peoples of
244 Appendixes
Professor Curtin's book, The Atlantic Slave Trade: A Census (1969), has
stimulated a great deal of quantitative research relating to the slave trade. O n e
recent contributor to the debate is Leslie B . Rout, Jr,2 w h o shows that Curtin's
estimate of slave imports into Spanish America up to 1810 is about 67 per cent
too low. O n present evidence it would seem that Curtin's global estimate for
the Atlantic trade m a y be at least 10 per cent too low. W e think therefore that
it would be more realistic for the m o m e n t to raise Curtin's figures for the
Atlantic trade by 40 per cent, making total exports from Africa by way of that
trade 15.4 million.
F r o m the comments of Professor Hubert Gerbeau w h o is familiar with
the slave trade from the East African coast, the figure for the Indian Ocean
trade is about 4 million. O n present evidence, thefigurefor the trans-Saharan
and R e d Sea trades m a y be put at about 10 million. This brings the total to
about 29.4 million. The present evidence permits us to say, therefore, that
19 million represents the lowest possible number and 30 million, the highest.
N e w research should provide more statistical information, especially
on mortality between the time of capture and the time of departure from Africa.
While in some aspects of the slave trade the total numbers m a y not be very
important, in other aspects a proper understanding of the issues requires a
quantitative analysis.
Notes
1. O f the specialists w h o have worked specifically on some aspects of the slave trade,
w e have the following:
J. U . J. Asiegbu, University College, Port Harcourt, whose main work on the
subject is Slavery and the Politics of Liberation 1787-1861, London and N e w York,
L o n g m a n , 1969.
E . A . Oroge, formerly of the University of Lagos, Lagos, whose main work
is ' T h e Institution of Slavery in Yorubaland with Particular Reference to the Nine-
teenth Century' (University of Birmingham, P h . D . thesis, 1971).
J. E . Inikori of the Department of History, A h m a d u Bello University,
Zaria, whose main works relating to the slave trade are: 'English Trade to Guinea:
A Study in the Import of Foreign Trade on the English E c o n o m y 175&-1807'
(University of Ibadan, P . D . thesis, 1973); 'Measuring the Atlantic Slave Trade:
A n Assessment of Curtin and Anstey', Journal of African History, Vol. XVII,
An account of research on the slave trade 249
in Nigeria
Antonio Carreira
Bibliography
Most of the literature on the subject is listed in the short essays recently pub-
lished under the title Notas sobre o Tráfico Portugués de Escravos na Costa
Occidental Africana. The only authoritative work is E d m u n d o Correia Lopes'
Escravatura—Subsidios para a Sua Historia, Lisbon, 1944.
Current research
In our view, a major research project should be set u p to study records and
accounts connected with the slave trade. Such a project would also involve an
overall survey of the economics of the slave trade: vessels used, products and
goods transported, origins and destinations, costs at the places of origin and
selling prices on the consumer markets, the purchase and selling prices of slaves
and, lastly, all the factors that would facilitate an appraisal of the significance
of this movement of goods and persons and its repercussions on the economic,
social and political lives of the nations which benefited from it.
This is a difficult and exacting task, but it could be accomplished by a
number of research teams if the necessary funds were m a d e available.
In our view, this is the only way tofillthe large gaps in practically all
the data available for each area, particularly in regard to the number of slaves
shipped from each sector (and, where possible, the various ethnic divisions),
and mortality at the ports of embarkation, during the voyage and at desti-
nations. With such information (if obtained) w e could attempt more accurate
estimates of the numbers of slaves shipped and correct points of view expounded
in the existing literature.
O u r studies over the past ten years would suggest that the biggest gaps in our
knowledge relate to the seventeenth century. Until n o w , the figures for this
period have been no more than estimates—at times of a dubious nature. The
252 Antonio Carreira
figures which w e give further on in this study show glaring disparities in the
volume of the slave trade in each of the areas of the different traders and/or
contractors. A s a basis for our work, w e divided the west coast of Africa into
three sectors. This should provide a framework for examining the disparities
in the variousfigures(whether estimated or available from the customs records).
First sector
F r o m the Bay of Arguim and the mouth of the Senegal River to Cape
Palmas (the southernmost part of Sierra Leone) or the rivers of Guinea and
Cape Verde.
The slaves taken here (fifteenth century) were legally shipped to Portugal,
Madeira, Cadiz, Seville, Sanlucar de Barrameda and other ports in southern
Spain. Slaves were also shipped illegally to the West Indies. T h e slave raids
and sale transactions occurred in Argium, around the mouth of the Senegal
River and the ports of Sine, Salum, Cacheu, Bissau and Ribeira Grande (San-
tiago Island, Cape Verde). However, there are no accurate figures for this
traffic; there are estimates for the years 1455-99 and for the entire sixteenth
century (see Table 1). Figures are available only for the period 1757-94 when
a total of 24,594 adults and seventy-two children were dispatched to Bahia,
Pernambuco, Para and Maranhäo from Cacheu and Bissau. With respect to
the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries w e have only passing references to the
fierce slave wars waged against the populations in large areas of Senegal
(south), G a m b i a , Firdú, Casamansa (including Futa Toro and Futa Djaló),
Guinea and part of the interior of the continent. O n e of the main aspects of
these wars was the involvement of the dominant classes seeking to gain political
power and further the cause of Islam. Religious interests were more powerful
than political and social considerations. F r o m 1840 onwards, the slaves were
practically always sent to C u b a or another Caribbean island d o w n the Gambia,
Casamansa and other rivers. O n e of the main reasons for this was the war
between the emancipated Fulas and the black (i.e. captive) Fulas which lasted
from 1863 to 1888.
F r o m our knowledge of the region and its history, w e are convinced that,
of the three sectors, this area supplied the lowest number of slaves for foreign
markets. Towards the end of the eighteenth century, Oliveira Mendes wrote :
Bissau, Cacheu and some other islands are hardly worth mentioning. While there
are blacks in the backlands those who could be taken into slavery are barely sufficient
for working- the land on the islands.
The social and political organization of the peoples in the area did not favour
(but rather went against) any significant volume of slave trading with other
countries. Considerable numbers of slaves were absorbed by the h o m e markets.1
Portuguese research on the slave trade 253
1. Most of thesefigureswere obtained from the available Portuguese literature and through m y
own research in the Lisbon and Cape Verde archives. Certain details m a y have to be corrected
or altered (figures, and origins and destinations) in the light of a study of the sources of the
various authors. Thefiguresfor children include babies.
2. Figures estimated on the basis of 750 slaves shipped a year x 45 years.
3. A s above on the basis of 3,500 slaves a year.
4. Statistics from Abreu e Brito and estimate by Cadornega.
5. 19,940 shipped by the Companhia de Gräo Para and the Companhia de Pernambuco e Paraiba;
and 4,654 slaves shipped by individual traders in the period 1778-94.
6. The total number of slaves shipped from Angola in the nineteenth century was 1,117,743 adults
and 263 children. The legal traffic (over 28 years) amounted to 494,529 adults and 263 children
(= 494,792) giving an annual average of 17,691.
7. In the 12-year1 period of illegal traffic in Angola, an average of 51,934 slaves a year were shipped,
which adds 20.7 per cent to the legal traffic.
From Cape Palmas to Cape Lopo Gonçalves, comprising the area which
used to be known as Costa da Mina (Malagueta Coast—Liberia, Ivory Coast,
the Gold Coast (now Ghana), and the Slave Coast including the Forcados,
El-Rei and Escravos rivers).
254 Antonio Carreña
Trafficking began here very early (1482-85), but the Portuguese were so
obsessed with the idea of gold that they failed to develop the slave trade. Sub-
sequently, the problems arising from the conflict of interests between the British,
Dutch and others led to a climate of instability and the decline of the Portuguese
slave trade. Thefigurescompiled relate to the period 1726-1806 when 470,694
adults and 169 children were shipped through Cotonou, Popo, L o m é , Badagri
and other ports. In the nineteenth century only 62,786 adults were shipped
(giving a total of 533,480 adults and 169 children). W e do not k n o w the rele-
vantfiguresof the trade carried on by the British, Dutch and others.
Most of the slaves were sent to Babia, Pernambuco, Rio de Janeiro,
Para and Maranhäo (with smaller consignments going to Para and Maranhäo
than to the other States).
Third Sector
for purposes of appraisal, that during the slave-trade period the clandestine
shipments m a y have totalled roughly 50 per cent of the legal traffic entered in
the customs records (plus the slaves taken by other nations engaged in the
African slave trade) it is probable that a further 1,974,019 adults were shipped,
giving a total of at least 5,822,060 slaves (adults and children).
U p until 1578, the slaves taken from Angola (Luanda and Benguela
and to a certain extent from Loango and other river areas) were assembled o n
the island of Sao T o m é from where they were exported to Brazil and the
Spanish West Indies. Subsequently, the slaves were shipped directly from Pinda,
Luanda and Benguela to Central and South America (particularly Brazil).
Spanish domination (after 1580)—particularly in the seventeenth century—
resulted in the shipments of slaves to the River Plate (Montevideo and Buenos
Aires) being stepped u p in view of the better prices and the fact that the tran-
sactions were settled in silver coinage (pataca and peso), whereas at most other
destinations they were bartered for goods (cloth, beads, ornaments, iron bars,
guns, spirits, etc.).
In all the sectors (besides omitting the ethnic origins of the slaves) the
records generally fail to indicate embarkation and destination ports. This
makes it difficult to arrive at specific figures. In other instances, there is con-
siderable confusion over the names of the ports of disembarkation. Alongside
these irregularities, w e must also consider the fact that vessels often m a d e out
their papers for a certain port and then diverted their consignments to other
ports where the prices were higher. These diversions were justified by 'protests'
stating that they were forced to put into port.
Other questions which need to be clarified, particularly in relation to
Angola, are : the organization of the markets where slaves and produce were
sold, which date from the early seventeenth century at least; and the activities
of the Pumbeiros, Aviados, Fuñantes and others involved in slave trading in the
backlands, w h o sometimes acted as allies and other times as enemies of the
captains and majors. The same applies to the role of these agents in setting off"
tribal wars with the aim of buying u p prisoners and shipping them into slavery.
These aspects are dealt with in Angola—daEscravaturaaoTrabalhoLivre{\911).
Table 1 gives a clearer picture of the development of the slave trade in
these three sectors.
Archive materials
Public archives
Generally speaking, the public archives in Lisbon are badly organized and in
some cases to not have the catalogues and index-cards which would facilitate
research work. In some archives, the documentation is arranged somewhat
256 Antonio Carreira
haphazardly and without any respect for chronological order. This is due to a
lack of trained personnel andfinancialresources. Despite this, most of the
documents are in a good state of preservation. Research into the slave trade
basically involves going labouriously through thousands of records and account
books.
The most important repositories of documentation in Lisbon are:
(a) Arquivo Nacional da Torre do T o m b o ; (b) Arquivo Histórico Ultramarino ;
(c) Arquivo Histórico do Ministerio das Finanças (covering a specific period) ;
(d) Biblioteca Nacional (particularly in the reserve stock); (e) Biblioteca do
Ministerio da Marinha; (f) Biblioteca da Ajuda (the latter two are not all that
important); (g) Biblioteca da C á m a r a Municipal de Lisboa; (h) Fundo do
Erario Público (the latter two house only certain types of documentation).
It would be extremely useful if Spanish research specialists were inter-
ested in this subject. This would facilitate access to the Madrid, Simancas and
other archives. In view of the obstacles involved, this kind of archive research
can only be undertaken with positive government support.
Private archives
T o the best of our knowledge, there are few private archives in Portugal (on
family estates, in churches, etc.) apart from the archive at the h o m e of the
Marques do Lavradio (which has been the subject of research projects and a
number of brief publications). If any other private archives do esist, they are
not likely to house any significant material concerning the slave trade.
In the former Portuguese colonies (Cape Verde, Guinea, Sao T o m é and
Angola), there is hardly any documentation available on the slave trade, if w e
discount Angola. A wealth of material (historical and recent) has been
destroyed through lack of suitable premises, indifference on the part of the
public authorities, the climate (hot and humid) and the usual pillagers. Coupled
with this, there is the difficulty (or impossibility) of reconstructing m a n y of the
relevant facts. In Angola (and to some extent on Sao T o m é ) , a fair number
of documents have yet to be examined. This is not the case with Cape Verde.
M u c h of the Angolan archive material would have been lost had it not been
for the far-sightedness of a dedicated group of civil servants, w h o published
part of the catalogued documentation. W e are referring to the publication
Arquivos de Angola, founded in 1933, which appeared fairly regularly over a
period of thirty years. It is the most important repository of documents relating
to the slave trade, the markets and the economic life of the territory since the
sixteenth century.
The parish registers in Portugal and in her former overseas territories
are another valuable source. These registers should contain useful information
on the slave trade.
For tugúese research on the slave trade 257
In economic terms
Sugar
In 1591, Abreu e Brito drew up an inventory recording the existence in Per-
nambuco of sixty-three sugar plantations with an annual production of
378,000 arrobas of 'brown sugar' worth 75,600 cruzados (one cruzado —
400 reis). In 1629 (Mauro), the number of sugar plantations rose to 346; and
in 1761 (Antonil), exportable production (batido, white, macho and brown)
accounted for the following quantities and values:
Bahia: 14,500 35-arroba chests = 507,500 arrobas. 1,070,204,400 reis.
Pernambuco: 12,300 35-arroba chests = 430,500 arrobas. 834,140,000 reis.
Rio de Janeiro: 10,220 35-arroba chests = 357,700 arrobas. 630,796,400 reis.
Total: 37,020 35-arroba chests = 1,295,700 arrobas. 2,535,142,800 reis.
In 1638, exports were in excess of 1,800,000 arrobas (Mauro).
Tobacco
Bahia: 25,000 rolls. 303,100,000 reis.
Alagoas and Pernambuco: 2,500 rolls. 41,550,000 reis.
Total: 27,500 rolls. 344,650,000 reis.
Gold
100 arrobas 'apart from what was extracted (and is till extracted) secretly from
other streams which the miners did not declare as they did not wish them to
be taxed', 614,400,000 reis.
Between 1721 and 1754, the gold sent from Brazil to Portugal fluctuated
between 11,000 to 20,000 arrobas a year (Magalhäes Godinho).
In the space of a century sugar took over as the leading export product.
It supplied vast sections of the European market, and brought about a radical
change in eating habits. Sugar exports rose from 378,000 arrobas a year at the
end of the sixteenth century to 1,295,700, which means that they increased
around three and a half times.
Thesefivekey products had a total value of 3,743,992,800 reis. They all
relied heavily o n slave labour.
W e should also mention the discovery of diamonds (1729). They proved
to be a further source of revenue. But like gold they were badly used. They
enabled the Portuguese aristocracy and upper middle classes to give full rein
to their propensity for ostentation, vanity and luxurious living. The country
began to import somewhat wildly (especially from Great Britain) a whole
range of useful, essential and superfluous consumer goods as a form of regale-
ment for the privileged classes, thus mortgaging Brazil's production. Great
Britain recognized an easy way of advancing the 'Industrial Revolution', by
having the Portuguese trading deficit settled in gold and diamonds.
W e should mention two other Brazilian products: cotton and coffee.
In 1776, the exportable cotton production was 42,664 arrobas; it had risen to
560,000 arrobas by 1796 (Borges de Macado).
Coffee growing, which dates from the end of the eighteenth century,
relied just as heavily on slave labour. The slave was responsible for clearing
and setting out the plantations, tending the seedbeds, weeding, and cultivating
the coffee plants. In the space of a hundred years, coffee rose to head the list
of exports, taking over from sugar which had begun to feel the effects of c o m -
petition from producers in the West Indies. In regard to coffee, w e should also
note the influence of the European immigrant, w h o arrived at the d a w n of
the nineteenth century to contribute to the development of the south of Brazil
at the very time when it was recognized that the slave trade and African forced
Portuguese research on the slave trade 259
labour had to end. But w e should not forget that the slave was an important
factor (indirect, to be sure) in the recruitment and transportation to Brazil of
European immigrants. Recruitment was financed from a percentage of the
customs duties levied on the slave trade. Coffee proved to be a turning-point
in the Brazilian agricultural economy and superseded sugar as the country's
leading product. Conditions favourable to increased coffee consumption had
developed in Europe (and elsewhere). Coffee became widely drunk for its
stimulative effects at the expense of tea, which until then had been drunk
throughout Europe.
The economic development of Brazil has to be ascribed in part to vol-
untary and involuntary immigration. Voluntary immigration, in particular,
m a y be considered a constant feature of Portuguese life.
The African slaves working on the plantations and in the mines soon
began (in the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries) to disturb agriculture and
other forms of economic activity. They destroyed farms and settlements; they
established quilombos with the aim of shaking off the yoke of slavery and
trying to wipe out or reduce the effects of their submission to the white m a n .
Slave rebellions occurred here and there and became c o m m o n , or very frequent,
in the nineteenth century. It is our view that they were fomented, led and directed
by Muslim slaves, m a n y of them learned m a n from the Costa da Mina, where
there was a struggle to impose the Islamic doctrine.
Gold and diamonds also brought about an unaccustomed upsurge of
wealth, which unhinged the economy of regions specializing in sugar cane,
tobacco, manioc and the manufacture of sugar and spirits, because of the high
cost of slaves. With his highly valuable products, the miner could buy his
labour force at prices which the farmer could ill afford. The miner did not
haggle over prices. A slave costing from 150,000 to 200,000 reis in Bahia would
fetch, in the mining areas, between 250 and 500 oitavas of gold (an oitava
generally equalled 1,400 reis) which was between 310,000 and 700,000 reis
(1700-03). Agricultural production could not support a similar increase in
labour costs. The price disparity led to the emergence of 'the poor [or impo-
verished] farmer or plantation owner' and the wealthy miner or prospector.
Panic broke out in m a n y agricultural regions ; the cost of essential foodstuffs
soared out of all proportion in the ports and in the interior. In m a n y respects,
the situation of the poor and the middle classes became critical. The less-well-
to-do farmers and plantation-owners were forced to sell their slaves. It was not
that they had to realize their capital; they could simply n o longer afford to
feed and clothe them. However, apart from these considerations, they also
had to cope with the continual problem of runaway slaves and incitement by
trouble-makers. W h e n slaves escaped, a double loss was usually involved:
the loss of the labour force and the capital investment which it represented;
the need to replace that labour force and the corresponding new investment.
260 Antonio Carreira
For a brief period the mining area was invaded by a legion of runaway
slaves and others, brought from the north-east by the atravessadores (contra-
bandists). In 1735, a government census showed that there were 101,651 slaves
in the mining areas; by 1750, thisfigurehad risen to over 150,000. A n d w e
have no idea h o w m a n y slaves w h o escaped from the farms and plantations of
the north-east took to the backlands, the rivers and igarapés and hid there.
The euphoria over the gold and diamond discoveries was felt at all levels
of society. Contraband trade went on unchecked and developed its o w n orga-
nizational structure. This phenomenon resulted in a spread of highway rob-
beries, killings and m a n y other forms of violence. The entire mining and pros-
pection area became unsafe.
At the same time, Portuguese emigrants flocked to the Brazilian mining
areas from Europe in the hope of striking it rich, or just to escape poverty,
the hardships of rural life or even the persecutions of the Inquisition.
F r o m Trás-os-Montes, das Beiras, do Minho, etc., virtually anyone w h o
had the price of a ship's passage embarked in search of his 'bonanza'. People
from the most varied walks of life headed for the mines : gypsies, vagrants,
N e w Christians and Jews, rural labourers, craftsmen, small farmers and small
traders, mixed with adventurers and criminals. They all sold their belongings
and set their sights on Brazil. Crews went missing immediately after their
ships put into port and hid with friends or acquaintances in the backlands. In
this w a y , around 800,000 Portuguese migrated to Minas Gérais and other
regions in southern Brazil between 1705 and 1750; and this was at a time when
Portugal's population numbered only a little over 2 million. Faced with such
a large-scale abandonment of the country, the Portuguese Government intro-
duced various measures aimed at controlling embarkations and the issue of
passports.
The wave of emigration in the eighteenth century proved to be a decisive
factor in the 1822 Secession.
In the main, it was Brazil that benefited from the economic progress
m a d e in the country with the aid of slave labour. Only the occasional 'crumbs
of wealth' reached Portugal, and even these were badly used, as already
mentioned. A sizable portion was simply given away to Great Britain, while
another part went to various other European countries. In m a n y of these
countries a class of nouveaux riches burgeoned, engaged in the slave trade;
the shipping and trading companies connected with the slave traffic also
flourished. This prosperity is quite evident in the movement of ships and goods
in the ports of Great Britain (Bristol, Liverpool and others), France (Bordeaux,
Marseilles, Nantes, etc.) and Holland.
All in all, the (limited) benefit which the Portuguese derived from all
these ventures is reflected in the sweat and toil of the immigrant, whose main
concern was to save up enough money to support his family in Portugal, to
Portuguese research on the slave trade 261
acquire a plot of land (or increase it if he already had one), to buy a few teams
of oxen, and to improve his house or build a new h o m e . Relatively few immi-
grants m a d e their fortunes in a big way. Those w h o did, bought or built manor
houses—especially in the north of the country—or invested their capital in the
trading and slave-trafficking operations which were set up in the middle of the
eighteenth century, Such was the background to the emergence of the rural
and merchant middle classes in northern and central Portugal and the 'joke'
of our second-rate capitalism. The fact that so few Portuguese became rich in
Brazil gives a certain idea of the cultural standing of the vast majority of emi-
grants, particularly those w h o went to South America. Emigration proceeded
without any reference to qualitative considerations ; it was a purely quantitative
phenomenon, and the majority of emigrants were unskilled or minimally
trained workers w h o were as a rule illiterate. Brazil accepted anyone w h o was
willing to work in the country, as it was interested in building up the Brazilian
population. Hence most of the Portuguese found themselves on the lower
rungs of the employment ladder. This is borne out by the kind of epithets
with which the Portuguese immigrant was tagged, m a n y of which were dispar-
aging. These workers were never afraid to take up a new type of work and could
turn their hand to anything that came along.
Despite all this, emigration was largely responsible for the fact that the
Portuguese acquired new habits and new forms of behaviour, and evolved a
different view of the world and other peoples, which was m u c h broader and
more enlightened than the narrow-minded approach characterizing life in
Portugal. The Portuguese acquired a new mentality and raised his o w n cultural
level. W e should also mention eating and other habits in European countries,
which were the outcome or the large-scale introduction of tropical products :
sugar, coffee, cocoa (hence chocolate), peanuts, piñón seed, palm oil and coco-
nuts, etc. Most of these foodstuffs entered Europe as raw materials and were
then processed. Sugar had to be refined and purified; peanuts were imported
for their edible oil (in view of the growth of the population and the inadequate
olive-oil production) and for their bagasse which was used in soap-making;
piñón seed was also used in soap-making; palm oil and coconut oil were used
in the manufacture of margarine and in the soap industry. T h e processing
operations required the construction of large factories (for processing oils,
cocoa and chocolate). Cocoa and chocolate became very popular in Europe.
The peanut, introduced into Africa in the first half of the nineteenth
century, became a leading crop within little overfiftyyears. T h e seed headed
the list of exports in Senegal, Gambia, Guinea-Bissau and other areas. T h e
expansion of peanut farming brought about a radical reorganization of local
economies and significant social and political changes in practically all the
areas concerned.
Cocoa, which was originally a leading crop on the islands of Sao T o m é
262 Antonio Carreira
and Principe, was also introduced on the island of Fernando Po, on the Ivory
Coast, the Gold Coast, n o w Ghana, and other places ; a very high volume of
production was achieved, particularly in the Ivory Coast and in the Gold Coast.
This kind of agriculture and mining could only be developed because of
the huge demand on the European and American consumer and producer
markets.
These products were grown in the tropics for two reasons :first,to meet
the demand on the domestic consumer market and/or the export markets;
second, to obtain the revenue which would enable African producers to engage
in the trade from which they were practically excluded during the slavery era.
These products served as a basis for thefiscalsystems necessary to the European
administrations in the various territories (through the hut levy, taxes, licences
and other forms of taxation). T h e administrations also resorted to indirect
strategies, such as creating a demand for certain essential goods a m o n g African
populations w h o had never or hardly ever felt the need for them. This was the
practical way to control the African markets and import European and Ameri-
can manufactured products.
These processes occurred persistently over a long period of time. H o w -
ever, they only gained a certain m o m e n t u m in the second half of the nineteenth
century, at a time when European policies on the domination of the African
continent were clarified and defined. The main historical development in this
lengthy process of evolution was the political and social crisis of the eighteenth
century (the French Revolution, the Napoleonic Wars, etc.) which culminated
in the General Act of the Berlin Conference (1884-85) with all its political and
economic implications.
There is no doubt that a number of European countries derived con-
siderable wealth from Brazilian gold and diamonds ; raw materials (especially
those w e have listed) brought them even greater prosperity. Portugal benefited
the least from all this trade. Despite her pioneering activities, she received a
very small slice of this prosperity. The blame for this phenomenon m a y be laid
squarely upon the society of the day, which saw everything purely in terms of
territorial occupation.
Cultural considerations
Note
1. See Notas sobre o Trafico Portugués de Escravos na Costa Occidental Africana, p. 33-4.
The Catholic Church
and the slave trade
Luigi Conti
The official position of the Church towards the slave trade is the same as its
position with regard to slavery in general.
The Catholic Church's action concerning the slave trade has been both
direct and indirect.
Direct action
their evangelical mission and pressing for a fresh condemnation. This was
issued by the Holy Office on 20 March 1686.
At the beginning of the eighteenth century, during the pontificate of
Clement X I (1700-21), R o m e was forced to take more severe measures: despite
all the previous documents on the subject it was clear that slavery continued to
exist and was even spreading. But R o m e was convinced that no improvement
was possible without the real co-operation of the King of Portugal, whose
colonial Empire included a large part of the N e w World. So in 1707 the Sacred
Congregation 'de Propaganda Fide' adjured the Papal Nuncios in Lisbon and
Madrid, and all those in a position to do so, to act so as to bring about the
abolition of slavery—'di procurare in ogni canto l'estirpazione degl'istessi
gravissimi sconcerti'. But this appeal met with practically no response.
In the Instruction sent by the Sacred Congregation 'de Propaganda Fide'
to the new Papal Nuncio in Lisbon, Vincenzo Bichi, the question of slavery
was dealt with at length. The Congregation required slaves to be given a
holiday not only on Sundays and feast days but also on Saturdays. This is
probably thefirstdemand in history for a five-day week.
In their meetings on 15 December 1738 and 28 November 1741, the
Cardinals of the Sacred Congregation 'de Propaganda Fide' again dealt at
length with the question of slavery. Thus on 22 December 1741, Pope Benedict
X I V (1740-58), in the Papal Constitution Immensa, once more condemned
slavery in the same terms as Paul III and Urban VIII. Although the Constitu-
tion referred specifically to the enslavement of the American Indians (and, as
a result, the king of Portugal, by the law of 6 June 1755, forbade the enslave-
ment of the Indians and ordered them to be set free), it was also applied to the
enslavement of Negroes. In several other documents the Sacred Congregation
extended the ban on slavery a m o n g the Indians to slavery a m o n g the blacks.
In 1758 a copy of the Constitution Immensa was sent to the Prefect of the
Capuchins in the Congo.
W h e n the anti-slavery movement was gaining ground in Europe and
Africa at the end of the eighteenth and the beginning of the nineteenth century,
the Popes and the Sacred Congregation 'de Propaganda Fide' contribued
amply to the eradication of slavery and the awakening of consciences.4
Pius VII wrote to the governments of Spain, Portugal and Brazil. In
1823, in a letter to the king of Portugal, Pope Pius VII again insisted on the
abolition of slavery in the king's colonial empire.5
A n y scientific inquiry on the subject should appraise the decisive part
that Pope Pius VII played through his Representative at the Congress of
Vienna (1814-15) to bring slavery to an end. It was through this Congress
that Pius VII brought the full weight of his authority to bear on the subject.
A n d in fact he did bring about abolition.
O n 3 December 1837, Gregory X V I , in the Brief 'In Supremo Aposto-
The Catholic Church and the slave trade 267
latus Fastigio', after listing his predecessors' provisions with regard to slavery,
went on to condemn it severely in all its forms. The reference to the trade in
black slaves is clear, for it was still widely practised despite the fact that it
had been legally abolished by the Congress of Vienna. 8
Pius I X raised his voice against slavery in 1851 at the beatification of
Pierre Claver (1580-1654), a Jesuit missionary k n o w n as 'the Negroes' apostle'.
O n 5 M a y 1888, Leo XIII, in a letter to the bishops of Brazil, congratu-
lated them warmly on what they had done to abolish slavery, and recalled the
teaching of the Church in this matter.7
Throughout the period in which the slave trade was being carried on the
missionaries, also encouraged by the declarations of the Popes and of the Sacred
Congregation 'de Propaganda Fide', tried with all the means at their disposal
to teach slaves, both Indians and blacks, to baptize them and set them free.
The Sacred Congregation 'de Propaganda Fide' and the Charity of the Holy
Child frequently provided money for this purpose. A well-known example of
this kind of activity is the mission at Bagamoyo in East Africa.
Naturally, after the abolition of slavery a m o n g the American Indians,
the Church's activities in thisfieldturned m o r e towards slavery a m o n g the
blacks.
The work of the missionary bishop Cardinal Lavigerie (1825-92) for
the abolition of slavery is well k n o w n .
It should be noted that the missionaries—Dominicans, Franciscans,
Jesuits and others—who went to the N e w World soon found themselves
fighting against those w h o exploitedfirstthe Indians then the blacks. M a n y of
them were tortured or even killed by the settlers.
The bad example set by those owners receives a good deal of attention,
but this cannot detract from the vast and beneficent work carried out by the
Church a m o n g the Indians and the Negroes.
Indirect action
A s some people nowadays deplore, the Church did not organize crusades or
stir up revolutions against the various forms and manifestations of slavery.
But the Church did act, in obedience to Christ and to the Gospel, in an indirect,
patient, constant, planned and effective manner—one which was the more
likely to succeed because it could create an environment and conditions
favourable to the abolition of the slave trade in general and of the trade in
African Negroes in particular.
The Church has always preached monogenism, and so has taught and
practised the principles of equality and fraternity between m e n in the universal
fatherhood of G o d . The Church has done this despite and in the face of times
conditioned by the h u m a n and social sciences.
268 Luigi Conti
Notes
P. D . Curtin
Research on the slave trade in the United States is n o w very extensive and I
cannot k n o w all of it. But the most recent bibliography is :
H O G G , Peter C . The African Slave Trade and its Suppression. A Classified and Annotated
Bibliography of Books, Pamphlets, and Periodical Articles. London, 1973.
Other important ongoing research is being carried out by David Eltis, Depart-
ment of Economics, Rochester University, Rochester, N . Y . ; Stanley Engerman,
Department of Economics, Rochester University, Rochester, N . Y . ; and Joseph
Miller, Department of History, University of Virginia, Charlottesville, Virginia.
The slave trade and the peopling
of Santo Domingo
Jean Fouchard
Contemporary accounts and recent studies alike have provided us with gener-
ally accurate information about the living conditions of the Negroes w h o were
imported into Santo D o m i n g o , their physical and moral characteristics, their
temperament, age, stature, reactions to slavery, religious beliefs, food, housing,
furniture, names, physiological condition, artistic sense, tastes, customs and
so on.
But there are two main questions which still preoccupy historians and
ethnologists : h o w m a n y slaves were imported into Santo D o m i n g o , and what
were the relative proportions of the different ethnic groups a m o n g the Africans
w h o formed the island's population?
W e still have n o answer to thefirstquestion. Statistics relating to the
slave trade in Santo D o m i n g o are too partial and fragmentary. W e d o k n o w
that at certain periods in the history of the colonization of the country, the
southern strip was supplied principally through the illicit slave trade, which
increased considerably during the American W a r of Independence and towards
the end of the official slave trade; but w e do not possess thefiguresthat would
enable us to estimate the size of this parallel traffic.
F r o m the beginnings of colonization up to 1764, all w e have to go by is
scattered information, incomplete and occasional statistics, and necessarily
partial estimates. Between 1764 and the end of the official trade in the island
in 1793, the Santo D o m i n g o newspapers supply us with invaluable informa-
tion about the arrival of the slave-ships.
W e are thus reduced to a rough estimate, but one which confirms the
'dreadful number' of deaths and the fact that Santo D o m i n g o 'devoured'
its slaves at a terrifying rate. Neither the ridiculously low birth rate nor the
increasingly large consignments of imported slaves could compensate for the
high rate of consumption, which was due to harsh conditions, forced labour
driven to inhuman limits, tyranny and cruelty, not to mention almost universal
and permanent malnutrition.
Hilliard d'Auberteuil, a notary at C a p Haïtien for twelve years, gives
a horrifying account:
The slave trade 271
and the peopling of Santo Domingo
A third of the negroes from Guinea die normally during thefirstthree years after
their transplantation, and the working life of a negro acclimatized to the country
cannot be put at more than 15 years More than 800,000 negroes have been brought
into the colony since 1680: so large a nursery should have produced millions of slaves,
yet there are only 290,000 now [1776] in the colony.1
Sudanese
This group includes the various peoples of the West African coast and the
nearby communities on the banks of the Senegal, Gambia and Niger rivers :
Senegalese, Wolofs, Calvaires; Fulani, Tukulors; Bambaras, Mandingos,
Bissago(t)s; Susus.
Guineans
These are the peoples w h o lived further south but still north of the Equator,
in the whole of the area round the Gulf of Guinea, including the Ivory Coast,
the Slave Coast and the Gold Coast (now Ghana) : Kangas, Bourriquis, Misé-
rables, Mesurades, Caplacus, Nagos, Mines, Minas, Yorubas, Thiambas;
Fons, Agousas, Socos, Fantins, Mahis, Dahomans, Aradas, Cotocolis, Popos,
Fidas, Hausas, Ibos, M o k o s of Benin.
Bantus
These peoples lived south of the Equator, chiefly in the kingdoms of Congo
and Angola, which marked the limits of the French slave trade. They included:
Kongos, 'Francs Kongos', Musombis, Mondongos, Malimbas, Angolas.
T o these were added, towards the end of the colonial period, large n u m -
bers of Mozambicans (especially from 1773 on), together with a very few
Negroes from such places as Madagascar and Mauritius—the sole contibu-
tion, though a large one, from East Africa.
The slave trade 273
and the peopling of Santo Domingo
N o definite answer to this question has yet been found. Attempts had been m a d e
to solve the riddle by examining voodoo and oral tradition, settlers' correspon-
dence, the minutes of the Santo Domingo notaries, the bills of lading of the
slave-ship owners, and workshop inventories, but without being able to satisfy
our legitimate curiosity.
Let us briefly examine these various approaches. S o m e specialists have
tried to maintain that the practice of voodoo as the predominant popular
religion in the colony is conclusive proof that Guiñean slaves were in the
majority in Santo Domingo. It is an attractive theory, but it does not stand
up to analysis. Furthermore, it is contradicted by the advertised descriptions
of slaves and by the workshop inventories, which on the one hand show that
Kongos were in the majority a m o n g the maroons and on the other hand
reveal no very considerable proportion of D a h o m a n s (Aradas excepted).
While it is true that voodoo, originating in D a h o m e y (now Benin), did take
root and spread in the colony, this was not because of any massive presence
of D a h o m a n slaves, for there was never any such thing. The reasons for the
introduction and widespread practice of voodoo must be sought elsewhere.
In a recent paper, Lilas Desquiron 3 pointed out the considerable
contribution m a d e by Kongos of the Bantu group to the establishment of
voodoo in Haiti. Moreover ethnologists have shown that voodoo had borrowed
some elements from Catholicism. It thus appears that voodoo, by reason of the
disparate nature of its elements, cannot indicate the predominance either of
the Guiñean or of the Bantu group a m o n g the early population of Santo
Domingo. True, the word 'Guinea' for a long while symbolized Africa, but
so, towards the end of the colonial period, did the word ' C o n g o ' . The runaway
274 Jean Fouchard
chief Macaya recognized the king of Congo as 'born master of all blacks',
and even before the ceremony at Bois-Caiman a Congolese song was adopted
as an anthem for the rebels and for voodoo assemblies.
Be that as it m a y , while the voodoo songs with their m a n y verses refer
to the gods or has of Africa, in terms either of the rada or of the petro ritual,
they always refer to them together, for instance:
Mrin sôti Ian Guinin, mrin sôti Guéléfé [Ifé] . . . palez hounsis congos Ian Guinin . . .
of té-léguey . . . Legba Petro, Legba Ibo, Legba Dahoumin, Legba Allada, Legba
Badagri . . .
The litany k n o w n as the 'Prayer of Djor' shows even more clearly the number
of'peoples' which combined to form the Haitian community:
Rélé toutes toutou l'Afrique Guinin, toutes nanchons [nations] rada [Aradas], ibo,
caplaou, en-mine [Amine, Mine], mondongue, mandingue, sinigal [Senegal], canga,
congo, nago, danhomé, wangol, mahi, foulah, mayoumbé, fon, bambara, haoussa,
congo-franc . . .
The voodoo songs thus reflect a recognition of the original loas of all the
'nations' contributing to the peopling of Santo D o m i n g o and of the m a n y
different contributions to the growth of voodoo itself, rather than any ethnic
distribution.
Does an examination of the settlers' correspondence, of the accounts of
contemporary historians, of workshop inventories or of bills of lading give any
better results ? No—colonial documentation provides no exact answer to our
questions as to whether the Guineans or the Bantus were in the majority at
the end of the colonial period.
But it is certain that if workshop inventories, for example, are analysed
systematically as more and more archives are discovered, w e shall obtain an
increasingly accurate picture. In the end w e shall k n o w what was the most
usual 'distribution' for the period w e are concerned with, in the workshops
and in the sugar, indigo and coffee mills and plantations. Were the Aradas in
the majority in the sugar industry, and the Kongos in the coffee industry?
W h a t was the real proportion oîbossales (newly imported slaves) and 'creóles'
(born in the colony) used in agricultural labour, domestic service and factory
work at the end of the colonial period, even before the slackening off and
eventual abolition of the official slave trade?
The inquiry is only just beginning. It will be a long and difficult one:
workshop inventories do not abound. Every so often a fresh bundle of them
is found in some dusty old cupboard.
M . Debien has analysed several hundreds of workshop inventories and
brought together an invaluable source of documentation. At the same time, in
The slave trade 275
and the peopling of Santo Domingo
order to find out the origins of the West Indian slaves, he also consulted the
even rarer bills of lading of slave-ship owners, but came to the conclusion that
these documents threw no light on the subject. N o n e of the bills of lading
consulted so far has shown the cargoes broken d o w n in terms of ethnic groups,
though they do tell us the names of the slave-ships' h o m e ports (Nantes,
La Rochelle, L e Havre, Bordeaux, Lorient, Marseilles, St M a l o , Honfleur)
and sometimes the ship's tonnage and the length of the crossing.
There still remain the announcements and advertisements in the Santo
D o m i n g o press. These notices are of two kinds. O n e group refers to slaves w h o
are up for sale as the result of the temporary or permanent return of some
settler to France. Unfortunately, these advertisements d o not give exact
descriptions of the slaves. Moreover they relate to only a tiny fraction of the
total number of slaves, and generally to domestics. M o r e interesting for us
are the notices about slaves w h o had run away, w h o were in prison or were up
for sale for having attempted to run away. These advertisements are numerous
enough to provide a very serious basis for investigation. W e possess no fewer
than 48,000 of them spread out over some thirty years. With a few exceptions
they all indicate the 'nation' the fugitive belonged to. It might be objected
that, since such advertisements refer to maroons, they necessarily m a k e n o
reference to the 'peoples' w h o were not given to running away. But there were
no such peoples. A more serious drawback is that the lists of runaways do not
show the actual proportion of each 'nation' in relation to the total slave
population of Santo D o m i n g o , but merely the proportion of each 'nation'
in relation to the total number of runaways. But this information is in itself
very important, because it reveals that K o n g o slaves were in a clear majority
a m o n g the runaways. This remained true almost without exception from 1764
to 1793, i.e. throughout the last phase of the colonial period.
So were K o n g o slaves in general in the majority, or were they merely
the 'people' most given to escaping, despite their reputation in the colony for
being 'the most lively and the readiest to submit to servitude'?
The table appended to this paper shows h o w Kongos were in the majority
a m o n g the runaways for the years 1764, 1765 and 1766 for example, while in
the same years the slaves imported came largely from the Guinea and Gold
Coasts.
The notices of slave-ship arrivals in the colony provide another source
of information. These represent the actual voices of the colonists, the evidence
of the slave-traders themselves, the day-books of Santo Domingo's trade in
slave labour.
Here too there will be certain instances of lack of precision, but fortu-
nately these d o not invalidate the overall information supplied; and the great
majority of these notices are absolutely exact. Only the professional scruples
of the historian compel m e to quote the few exceptions.
276 Jean Fouchard
These three groups have fashioned our people and, via the strangest of
melting-pots, have stamped it for ever. They came to sow and quicken our land,
and they worked in blood, sweat and tears to produce stitch by stitch, with
French thread and Bantu spindle, a new ethnic fabric, without ever cutting the
umbilical cord that links us forever to Africa.
Notes
1764 1765
1773 1775
1774 1776
Coast, 1); (b) Bantu group (Angola bicans, 2 ) ; and (c) Sudanese group
Coast, 30); and (c) Sudanese group (Senegal, 2).
(Gorée, Senegal, 1). Group providing most imports: Guiñean
Croup providing most imports: Bantu. (Gold Coast).
Number of Negroes declared: 10,921. Number of Negroes declared: 10,336.
Group providing most runaways: Bantus Group providing must runaways: Bantus
(Kongos), out of about 2,100 an- (Kongos), out of about 1,700 an-
nouncements. nouncements.
1777 1779
times not yet branded and unable to Coast, with a very fine cargo of
speak French: the newly imported 331 head of Negroes for D e m o n -
Negroes included Kongos, M o z a m - haison Lelong and C o . , w h o will
bicans, Nagos, Senegalese, Mandin- start putting them up for sale the
gos and Ibos. All this confirms that 25thinst.';(d) 25 March 1793—'The
the slave trade was still going on in Bonne Henriette of Bordeaux with a
1792 and even up to the end of superb cargo of 378 blacks coming
March 1793. from the Angola Coast ' ; (e) 27 March
It would be especially interesting 1793—'The Postilion of St Malo com-
to know more about the slave trade in ing from Senegal for Foache, M o -
its final manifestations. But, unfor- range, Hardivillier.
tunately, for these last two years the This annoncement is the last to
evidence of the newspapers is limited appear about the official slave trade.1
to just a few announcements: the Curiously enough it ended with an
Sérapis coming from Mozambique; uprooting of the same Senegalese
a cargo of 282 Negroes from the Negroes as those with which it had
Gold Coast; three others from the begun a century and a half earlier.
same place (Gold Coast); Nine It was the firm of Stanislas Foache
cargoes coming from the Angola —the biggest slaving company in
Coast. Santo Domingo—which had the
In 1792 the press was generally melancholy distinction of being re-
silent about the composition of sponsible for the final crime, so
cargoes, and the number of Negroes nonchalantly recorded in the colonial
announced did not exceed 2,000. gazettes.
In 1793 the Moniteur Général, Group providing most imports: Bantu
though a daily paper carrying a (Kongos and Mozambicans), fol-
supplement, made only the following lowed by cargoes from the Gold
announcements: (a) 14 January 1793 Coast and Senegal.
—3 Kongos, new Negroes from on
board the General Washington; (b) 1. The illicit trade was to continue a little
20 February 1793—Sale of Bossales longer. In this last brief period supplies
from Senegal from a boat coming came largely from neighbouring countries.
from Havana; (c) 22 March 1793— The trade ended as it had begun, with
slaves sent from the nearby islands, as in
'The Nouvelle Société of Nantes the early operations before the foundation
arrived from the Zaire River, Angola in 1664 of the West India C o m p a n y .
Bibliography
All these newspapers were consulted for this article, which supplements
and summarizes some of m y o w n earlier work on Santo Domingo, especially
that on slavery and runaway slaves, to be found chiefly in two books: Les
Marrons du Syllabaire, Port-au-Prince, Imprimerie Deschamps, 1958; and
Les Marrons de la Liberté, Paris, Éditions de l'École, 1972.
Joseph. E . Harris
A major problem the historian confronts in assessing the scope and impact
of the slave trade is the quantitative factor which of course relates to the scope
and qualitative impact. Joseph E . Inikori,2 a m o n g others, has commented in
several places on this critical issue, focusing particularly on efforts to quantify
the Atlantic slave trade. His criticisms of the pioneer book, The Atlantic Slave
Trade: A Census, by Philip Curtin, seem to be basically sound and underscore
the dilemma historians of the slave trade face, namely, the need to develop
numerical guidelines or parameters while at the same time guarding against
presenting unjustified figures.
Whatever one m a y think or say against existing estimates for the Atlantic
slave trade, and there are grounds for scepticism, suchfiguresdo serve the vital
function of providing a basis for critique which should clarify problems so that
additional research might bring us closer to truth.
It seems to m e that such a point might n o w have been reached for the
Atlantic slave trade so that within a few years there should be a greater
consensus. However, estimates for the trans-Sahara, R e d Sea and Indian Ocean
trades still lack the documentation even to propose a basefigurewhich would
very likely assume undue acceptance as authoritative. T h e data for those
areas are just too scattered and insufficient to warrant an overall estimate at
this time. Simply to conclude that the likely underestimation or overestimation
m a y be compensated for by some other more plausible, but still unsure, factor
should be undertaken with great caution, especially in publications.
The preferred data for estimates are records of companies, government
customs and census bureaux. U p to the nineteenth century, these kinds of evid-
ence hardly exist for the Indian Ocean, R e d Sea and Mediterranean trades.
After 1800, there are still virtually no company records; and census data for
recipient countries do not seem to be m u c h better. However, European observers
recorded some customs returns of a few African and Arabian ports, and some
counts have been m a d e of slaves on captured vessels. But this still leaves us
with very little direct evidence for the Indian Ocean and R e d Sea trade. This
has not, however, prevented a controversy over the scale of the trade.
For the R e d Sea area, estimates have been m a d e by Richard Pankhurst
290 Joseph E. Harris
(1964) w h o averaged reports for ports and noted a likely high count of 1 million
for the nineteenth century. For the southern (Swahili) coast, nineteenth-
century data came from British consular reports in Zanzibar and the navy
patrols. Most estimates have been based on those reports, which are criticized
as reflecting abolitionist proclivity for highfiguresto justify greater vigilance
for suppression. S o m e observers have argued further that abolitionists also
did not take into account the d e m a n d for slaves for plantation labour in East
Africa and thus assumed that all slaves were for export when in fact some were
kept in Zanzibar and P e m b a . A distinction should therefire be m a d e between
local and export trade for Zanzibar which seems hard to establish at this point,
especially since the Zanzibar archives have been closed to researchers since
1964.
The problem of quantifying becomes greater at the Asian points of entry.
In the Persian Gulf for example, one of the most active ports, Sur, had n o
customs office, and Muscat's records are scattered and difficult to obtain. In
addition, quantification is hampered by the inability to distinguish between
sales and resales. Slaves were frequently m o v e d from Mecca, Jidda, Sur,
Muscat and other points to Basra, Bushire, and on to India which itself received
some direct shipments.
Indian shipments came through several small areas in the north-west,
Gujarat in particular, but estimates are virtually non-existent. For at least two
depots, Surat and B o m b a y , there are scattered documents in the East India
C o m p a n y records which are available in India; police records are also useful
since the Commissioner of Police was charged with the responsibility of
monitoring the import of slaves and later with the distribution of freed slaves
a m o n g families in India or placing them in mission stations or on government
farms.
The argument here is for the organization of a concerted approach to
these problems in a number of key locations k n o w n to have been important
slave depots, markets, etc. Critical aspects of this would be the identification
of all available official and unofficial records in East Africa and across the
length of Asia. This obviously would require the involvement of researchers in
the affected areas; and the search should not be limited to coastal regions.
Indeed, m y research in India, Hyderabad in particular, revealed the importance
of the slave trade and documentary evidence in an interior centre. Repositories
in Hyderabad contain numerous uncounted stacks of uncatalogued documents
on political, economic, and military matters written in Arabic and Urdu. A
cursory examination of a sample of those documents by an informant confirmed
their relevance to the slave trade and the African presence in the area. A some-
what similar situation exists in Iran, K e r m a n province and the area around
Bandar Abbas in particular, where evidence in Arabic and Farsi needs to be
identified and m a d e available to interested researchers.3
A commentary on the slave trade 291
Economic Consequences
Agriculture
Although little has been done, w e do k n o w that African slaves worked on date
and coconut plantations around Basra (Iraq), Bandar Abbas and Minab in
Persia, and the Batinah or Trucial coast on the Persian Gulf. The relationship
between date plantations and the slave trade needs serious investigation;
indeed, dates were exchanged for slaves. W h a t other sources of demand
existed ? H o w and when did that demand impact on the slave trade and slavery
—and what were the economic benefits for the producing economies ?
There is a very valauble source I should mention here: J. G . Lorimer,
292 Joseph E. Harris
A Gazetteer of the Persian Gulf, Oman and Central Arabia, Vol. II, Calcutta,
1908. In that Gazetteer, Lorimer provides estimates of Africans in certain areas.
For Bahrein he estimates some 11,000 Africans; Kuwait, 4,000; Lingeh,
1,500; Qatar, 6,000; for O m a n he simply notes, 'exceptionally numerous'.
His counts were based on various British reports for 1905-07. W e should note
that some of thesefiguresare for areas in which intensive date-palm cultivation
occurred—Bassa, Qatar, O m a n , for example.
Pearl Diving
The other area with a high African population in Lorimer's survey is Bahrein.
Here several nineteenth-century observers noted the major economic activity
for African slaves in Bahrein was as pearl divers. The d e m a n d for them w a s
reportedly very high, as was the mortality rate. Captain Prideaux reported
that pearl diving was so deliterious to the health in the 1840s that middle-
aged Africans were hard to find, and a Bahrein Sheik told the British political-
officer in the 1890s that the demand remained great. Lorimer simply observed
that 'free negroes or negro slaves' were a large proportion of the divers.
W h a t needs to be determined is the specific relationship between the
Persian Gulf pearl industry and companies in Europe and elsewhere. A n d what
about the profitability of the industry, whether it was of long standing—that is,
prior to the 1840s when observers seem to have been noticing it ? For the present,
no conclusion is m a d e here other than that African labour m a d e this economic
contribution. The extent must await further research.
African crews
In addition to agriculture and the pearl industry, I will comment briefly on
African crews serving on Arab and European vessels. There m a y be studies on
this subject, I just do not k n o w since I have not devoted m u c h attention to it.
But there are frequent references to the African crews on dhows going to and
from East Africa, and one British official in India observed the large number
of Africans in the British navy during the 1850s. Africans also worked on the
docks at several ports on the Persian Gulf and Indian Ocean. These occupations
certainly contributed to economic development in affected regions.
Military
O n e final area is the military. O f course the use of African soldiers contributed
to political and economic development in several Asian areas, India in particu-
lar. There is some documentation for this in general histories of India and
travel accounts of Ibn Batoutah and others. But I prefer to call attention to
two examples. Thefirstis to Malik A m b a r , the Ethiopian w h o usurped power
in central India in 1602 and governed until 1626. A bit has been written on
him and his achievements, including the expansion of trade, construction of
A commentary on the slave trade 293
roads, canals, mosques and public buildings, etc. H e also imported Africans to
serve in his army, a point of interest in terms of African settlers in India.
But the key point I wish to m a k e here is that in addition to promoting
trade with Persians and Arabs, he negotiated also with the Portuguese and
British and this aspect of A m b a r ' s contribution has not received m u c h attention
to m y knowledge.
A different aspect of this relates to relations between A m b a r and another
area ruled by Africans, Janjira Island which emerged under Africans (Siddis)
in the latefifteenthcentury and became a critical naval force on the north-
west coast of India. A m b a r sought an alliance with them in 1616 and failed;
the Moguls negotiated an alliance about which an Indian military historian
has written :
It is only when the Siddis of Janjira offered their services to the Moguls against the
Maratha power on the sea that Arangazib (the Mogul emperor) gave half-hearted
recognition to afleetbeing organized on a reasonable scale. During 200 years of
Mogul greatness, the Indian Sea was under alien control.5
The Moguls thus began to subsidize the navy of the Janjira Siddis in exchange
for an alliance.
Another Indian scholar, Jadanath Sarkar, has written that Shivaji, the
Maratha hero :
achieved this [building a Maratha nation] in the teeth of the opposition of four
mighty Powers like the Mogul empire, Bijapur [another Indian kingdom], Portuguese
India, and the Abyssinians of Janjira.6
Notes
1. 'Black American Diasporic Relations'. I would like to m a k e this observation on the
American diaspora. W h e n Africans liberated Haiti in 1804, that country emerged
as a symbol and rallying point for the evolving black identity in the American
hemisphere. Whites in the United States were fearful that the Haitain example
would spill over into the United States and blacks began to establish Haiti and its
A commentary on the slave trade 295
revolutionaries as legends in song and literature; and the 1820s witnessed United
States blacks migrating to Haiti, a continuing tradition in the American black
diaspora.
2. Joseph E . Inikori, 'Slave Trade and the Atlantic Economies, 1451-1870'; and
'Measuring the A tlantic Slave Trade', Journal of African History, Vol. X V I I ,
N o . 4, p. 495-627.
3. Joseph E . Harris, The African Presence in Asia: Consequences of the East African
Slave Trade, Evanston, 111., Northwestern University Press, 1971.
4. ibid., p. 69.
5. K . M . Panikkar, India and the Indian Ocean, London, 1945, p. 8.
6. Jadunath Sarkar, History of Aurangzib, Calcutta, 1919, Vol. IV, p. 237-8. Note that
Janjira is regarded as a 'Mighty Power'.
7. In recent years Afro-American historians have contributed m u c h to the understanding
of the ethos of black Americans by studying their songs and literature. See : Sterling
Stuckey, 'Through the Prism of Folklore: The Black Ethos in Slavery,' The Mas-
sachusetts Review, IX, 3, 1968; and John Blassingame, The Slave Community
(Oxford University Press, 1972). Perhaps these works could serve as models for
similar studies of Afro-Asian communities.
8. Harris, The East African Slave Trade and Abolition in Kenya, Department of History
Howard University, 1974;'Blacks in Asia,' World Encyclopedia of Black Peoples,
Algonac, Michigan, 1975 ; Abolition and Repatriation in Kenya, Nairobi, East African
Literature Bureau, 1977.
9. O n e is the biographical study: W . J. Rampley, Matthew Wellington: Sole Surviving
Link with David Livingstone (London, n.d.); and the other is autobiographical,
James J u m a Mbotela, Uhuru wa Watumwa (London, 1934) and translated as The
Freeing of the Slaves in East Africa (London, 1956). Both of these studies had a
limited circulation, mainly in London and East Africa, and are n o w out of print,
except for the Swahili account. Both studies contain valuable data pertinent to the
East African slave trade and to the repatriation of ex-slaves on the Kenyan coast
during the nineteenth century.
T h e present state of research
in Brazil
Waldeloir Rego
It was on the Bahia coast that the Portuguese discoverers and colonizers
landed, and it was there, in 1549, that Brazil'sfirsttown was founded, later to
become thefirstcapital and the centre of important events. So it was from
Bahia that the African slaves spread outward over the rest of Brazil. It should
be noted, however, that most of them stayed in Bahia, where one still meets
with survivals of D a h o m a n religious rites. Bahia is also the only place where
religious ritual is practised in the F o n language. O n e can still distinguish rituals
which originated in Mahis, Savalu, A b o m e y and m a n y other places in D a h o m e y .
Traces of Nigerian ritual, in the Yoruba language, are even more marked.
Until recently a Nigerian teacher was giving lessons in the Yoruba language,
and innumerable foreign researchers (mostly African) c o m e to Brazil, and to
Bahia more especially, to study the African diaspora.
Studies concerning black people are very inadequate in Brazil. Genuine
specialists are rare, though m a n y people toy with the subject w h o are not really
interested, w h o have not the necessary training for scientific work, and w h o
really pursue other, sometimes commercial, ends. S o m e use the subject just
to lengthen their curriculum vitae or to obtain grants for travel abroad, using
studies about the black people as a pretext. Others again have purely political
aims.
The Brazilian Government gives some support, though it is still modest,
to studies on this subject, especially through the Cultural Department of the
Ministry for Foreign Relations. T h e Joaquim Nabuco Research Institute in
Pernambuco has long been interested in the question of the black people in
Brazil. In Bahia, where most of them are concentrated, a section of the Federal
University of Bahia, the Centro de Estudos Afro-Orientais (Centre of Afro-
Oriental Studies) enjoys limited support from the Ministry of Education and
Culture. But lack of resources has so far prevented it from achieving anything
of importance, apart from a course in the Kikongo language given by a teacher
from Zaire, N ' L a n d u Ntotila. This is a high-level course, but it is in danger of
being dropped this year through lack of funds. A s for the course in the Yoruba
language mentioned above, that has already been suspended despite the
interest it aroused a m o n g students and followers of the Yoruba religion.
The present state of research in Brazil 297
Create a scientific body able to collect as quickly as possible all the available
material o n existing black culture, some of which is in the process of
disappearing.
M a k e all Brazilian archives concerning black people available without restric-
tion, whether the material is held publicly or privately.
Finance, through public or private, State or para-State institutions, visits b y
experts to countries where studies on the blacks are necessary.
Help researchers in their studies by providing them with the facilities needed
for their work, copies of documents, etc.
Recruit as quickly as possible Yoruba-, F o n - and Kikongo-speaking African
teachers to give courses in Bahia.
K e e p African specialists in touch with Unesco activities in this field.
The state of research in Guyana
Walter Rodney
G u y a n a has n o past or ongoing research into the history of the slave trade to
Guyana. Historical work on the regime of slavery itself is dated and superficial.1
Rodway's History was based on secondary sources and translations from
the Dutch. General texts compiled in the present century have not gone beyond
this point.
A number of theses have been concerned with economic and social life
in G u y a n a in the nineteenth century, with emphasis on post-Emancipation
developments. They provide only brief introductions to the last years of slavery.
References to slavery in British Guiana are also to be found in reconstructions
of Caribbean history and of the history of the British West Indies in particular.
In effect, therefore, the field is still completely open and the areas of
research correspondingly wide. A s an exception to the prevailing neglect, there
is a researcy project into the phenomenon of escaped slaves in British Guiana
conducted by Alvin T h o m p s o n of the University of the West Indies, Barbados.
The development of slave society in Guyana is assumed to have followed
the sam^ patterns as that of slave societies emerging under similar conditions
in the Caribbean. The crops were cotton, coffee, cocoa and above all sugar.
Slaves grew their o w n provisions and were also briefly engaged in gold-mining
in the eighteenth century. The only unusual activity in British Guiana (relative
to the Caribbean islands) was the creation of polders on the s w a m p y coastal
environment.
The Guyana National Archives house documents which relate mainly
to the British period of slavery. Efforts are being m a d e to recover copies of
relevant documents in the Netherlands and the United Kingdom.
1. See, for example, James Rodway, A History of British Guiana, Georgetown, 1890,
3 vols.
T h e slave trade from the fifteenth
to the nineteenth century
Y . Talib
Documentary sources
Accounts and Papers (1837-38). Vol. II, Paper 697, House of C o m m o n s , Slave Trade.
Correspondence, orders and regulations.
Accounts and Papers (1841). Vol. XXVIII, Paper 238.
Slave-trade correspondence presented to Parliament in 1842. (F.O. 54/5.)
Public Record Office, London. (F.O. 84) Slave Trade. ' U p to 1840 this series contains little
material on the Arab slave trade from East Africa and Abyssinia; after that date the
volume of relevant correspondence increases greatly. Slave-trade correspondence between
the Foreign Office and the other departments of State before 1839 is collected in the
"Domestic Various" volumes of the series ; but after that year the concentration of the
direction of slave-trade policy in the Slave Trade Department of the Foreign Office
brought such an increase in the volume of correspondence that the "Domestic Various"
category had to be replaced by a number of new categories, "India Board", "Admiralty",
"Colonial Office", etc. F r o m 1840 onwards all correspondence on the slave trade received
at the India Board from the Indian Presidencies was passed to the Foreign Office, to
be dealt with in the Slave Trade Department.—J. B . Kelly, Britain and the Persian Gulf,
1795-1880, p. 868, Oxford, 1968.
Report from the Select Committee on the Slave Trade (E. Coast of Africa). Parliamentary
Paper, XII (1871), United Kingdom.
Report addressed to the Earl of Clarendon by the Committee on the East African Slave
Trade, 24 January 1870, LXII, 1871.
Correspondence respecting Sir Bartle Frere's mission to the East Coast of Africa—1872-
73, Parliamentary Paper, L X I , 1873.
Correspondence respecting the abolition of the legal status of slavery in Zanzibar and
P e m b a (C.8858) (1898), London.
Enclos to B o m b a y See. Letters, Vol. 51, enclos to See. Letter 115 of 15 Oct., 1842. Report
on the Slave Trade of Abyssinia by Capt. W . C . Harris, enclosed in Harris to Willouby,
20 July 1842 (No. 37, Sec. Dept.). Enclosed with the report is a m a p of the slave routes
through Sheoa. See also Vol. 34, enclos to See. Letter 59 of 17 July 1841, Haines to
Willouby, A d e n , July 1841 (No. 54 Sec. Dept.).
S A L D A N H A , J. A . (ed.). Precis on the Slave Trade in the Gulf of Oman and the Persian
Gulf—1873-1905, with a retrospect into previous history from 1882, Calcutta, 1906.
(A principle source for the history of the slave trade of East Africa with the Arabian
peninsula.)
Archive du Ministère des Affaires Étrangères (Aff. Étr.j Paris. (Mémoires et documents,
Série Afrique ( M é m o et doc. Afrique). Boutres Françaises, Recrutement de Travailleurs
pour les Colonies Françaises de l'Océan Indien.)
300 Y. Talib
Africans in India (with some items on West Africa, South America and West Indies)
Malay Archipelago
M A X W E L L , R . J. The Law Relating to Slavery among the Malays. Journal of the Malayan
Branch of the Royal Asiatic Society, Vol. X , Part I, 1932. (p. 254 refers to 'Habshis*
as a separate category of slaves.)
Sudan
S T A C K , (Sir) Lee. The Slave Trade between the Sudan and Arabia. Journal of the Central
Asia Society, Vol. 8, 1921, Part 3, p. 163-4.
Y U S U F F A D L H A S S A N . The Slave Trade. The Arabs and the Sudan, p. 42-9. Edinburgh Uni-
versity Press, 1967.
Ethiopia
P A N K H U R S T , R . The Ethiopian Slave Trade 1800-1935. A N e w Assessment. Journal of
Ethiopian Studies, 1964.
S E R J E A N T , R . B . South Arabia and Ethiopia—African Elements in the South Arabian
Population. Proceedings—3rd International Conference of Ethiopian Studies. Vol. I,
p. 25-33. 1966.
Arabia
Arab Slave Trade in the Indian Ocean and the Persian Gulf
Trade, p. 187-202, The Portuguese East African Slave Trade, p. 217-28. The Attack on
the Arab Trade. First stage. The End of the Arab Trade, p. 259-74, Appendix B. Captives
from the Arab Slave Trade.)
M A L E C O T , Georges. Bourbon et l'Abyssinie: Les Tentatives de Recrutement de Travailleurs
Le Problème de Main-d'Oeuvre à la Réunion. Les Voyageurs Français et les Relations,
entre la France et l'Abyssinie de 1835 à 1870. p. 72-93. Paris, Société Française d'Outre-
Mer, 1972.
M A R I T E A U J. Life of Sir B . Frère. London, 1895. 2 Vols.
M A R T I N , Gaston. Histoire de l'Esclavage dans les Colonies Françaises. Paris, Presses
Universitaires de France, 1948.
M A R T I N , Jean. La Révolte Servile de 1891 à Anjouan. Revue Française d'Histoire d'Outre-
mer, N o . 218, 1st quarter, 1973, p. 45-85.
N I W U L I A , Moses D . E. Britain and Slavery in East Africa. Washington, D . C . 1975. 274 p.
. The Role of Missionaries in the Emancipation of Slaves in Zanzibar. Journal of
Negro History (Georgia), Vol. L X , N o . 2, April 1975, p. 268-87.
O ' N E I L L , H . E . The Mozambique and Nyasa Slave Trade. London, 1888.
P E Y T R A U D , Lucien. L'Esclavage aux Antilles Françaises avant 1789, Paris, 1897.
P O P O V I O , A . La Révolte des Esclaves en Irak aux IIIe¡IXe Siècles. Paris, Paul Geuthner,
1977.
R Ü S S E L , Lilian. General Rigby, Zanzibar and the Slave Trade. London, 1938. (Christopher
Rigby was the British Consul and Political Agent in Zanzibar from 1858 to 1861.)
S U L L I V A N . Dhow Chasing in Zanzibar Waters. London, 1873.
W I C K E R S , Lucien. L'Immigration Réglementée à l'Ile de la Réunion. Faculté de Droit de
l'Université de Paris. (Doctoral thesis.)
L A N U X , Jean Baptiste de. Mémoire sur la Traite des Esclaves à une Partys de la Coste de
l'Est de l'Isle de Madagascar (1729)—L'impression d'un Mss—Conservé au Musée
Leon Dieux, St. Denis, L a Réunion, Recueil de Doc. et Trav. Inédits pour Servir à l'His-
toire des Mascareignes Françaises. October-November. 1932, p. 79-85.
L A V I G N E , R . P. Louis. La Traite dans les Parages de Madagascar [aux Comores etc.].
Ann. de la Sainte Enfance. Paris, 1868, p. 191-6.
R E Y N A U D , Et. Journal de Bord du Négrier'Marengo' Cape Reynaud, allant de l'Isle de
France à Sansibar et de Retour, 1804,101 p. (Original Ms.).
V I D A L (ed.). Bourbon et l'Esclavage Paris, 1847. 64 p.
Additional bibliography
Slavery
C R A T O N , Michael; W A L VIN, James; W R I G H T , David. Slavery, Abolition and Emancipation.
Black Slaves and the British Empire. London, 1976.
E D M O N D S O N , L . Transatlantic Slavery and the Internationalization of Race. Caribbean
Quarterly, Vol. X X , N o s . 2 and 3, June-September 1976.
ELTIS, D . The Traffic in Slaves between the British West Indian Colonies, 1807-1833.
Econ. Hist. Rev., Vol. X X X , 1972, p. 55-64.
G O I T I E N , S. D . Slaves and Slavegirls in the Cairo Geniza Records. Arabica, Vol. 9, 1962,
p. 1-20.
G R E E N , William A . British Slave Emancipation : the Sugar Colonies and the Great Experi-
ment, 1830-1865. Oxford, Clarendon Press, 1976.
T E M P E R L V , Howard. Capitalism, Slavery and Ideology. Past and Present, N o . 75, M a y 1977,
p. 94-118.
W H E A T L E Y , Paul. [Nu Pi] Slaves. Geographical Notes on S o m e Commodities Involved in
Sung Maritime Trade. Journal of the Malayan Branch of the Royal Asiatic Society.
Vol. 32, Part 2, N o . 186, 1961, p. 54-5.
Statistics
Few figures are available on this aspect of the slave trade and they vary greatly.
Kelly quoting nineteenth-century sources, gives thefigureof 8,000 to 15,000 slaves exported
annually from the East African littoral to the southern Arabian coast and the Persian Gulf.
R . M . Colomb gives the figure of 10,000 to 20,000 slaves exported from Zanzibar to the
Persian Gulf annually.
Mozambique
William Wilburn {Oriental Commerce, London, 1813, Vol. I, p. 60) mentions that the prin-
cipal trade of Mozambique is slaves, of which about 10,000 are annually exported at an
average of from $40 to $50 each.
Cape Town
In 1801, 'the population of Cape T o w n is estimated at 6,000 whites, inclusive of the mili-
tary, and 12,000 slaves' (William Wilburn, op. cit., p. 35).
304 Y. Talib
Mauritius
' E n 1820 il n'y avait pas moins de 16,000 esclaves malgaches à l'île Maurice.' Hilsenberg,
Noue. Ann. Vay. Vol. XI, 1829, p. 160.
W o r k in progress
Middle East
Jeddah, Mukalla, Shihr, Muscat, Bushire, Basra, M o c h a , Hodeida, Qatif, Sur
India
Mauritius
Port-Louis
Réunion
St. Denis
South Africa
Cape T o w n
Research on African influence
in the Dominican Republic
Introduction
with the aboriginal inhabitants of the island. A t the same time, by so doing,
he denied his origins as he placed his ancestral m e m o r y in the hands of a new
type of colonizer w h o subjected him to a rather less rigid form of slavery.
In addition, owing to the fact that the Dominican Republic achieved
its independence in a struggle against the Haitian occupation, the problem of
racial prejudice and, consequently, a more pronounced repudiation of African
origins was considerably accentuated.
Hence our ruling classes largely identified themselves as a national entity
negatively with respect to Haiti, creating from then onwards a strong anti-
Haitian feeling and, through this feeling, bringing about an anti-African
psychological projection. Thus of all the cultural contributions which go to
m a k e u p Dominican national identity today least is k n o w n about the African,
and it is the one about which Dominicans in general feel a certain shame.
Such an attitude, as w e k n o w , merely helps to strengthen the bonds of
social domination over a people which, being for the most part mulatto, is
discriminated against on account of the colour of its skin and, in its rush to
acquire Spanish characteristics, has succeded in creating a new colour—that
of the 'Indian', which is what all Dominican mulattos call themselves. This
is a way of solving the problem of origins by eliminating the black and recuper-
ating the autochthonous population element only.
That is w h y when w e visit Dominican museums African history is shown
as something incidental and in history textbooks the part played by Africans
is not mentioned except with reference to their backwardness.
Hugo Tolentino Dipp. Is finishing the second volume of his work Raza e
Historia en Santo Domingo. Occupies the post of research professor in
the University of Santo D o m i n g o .
Rubén Silié. Isfinishinga study on fugitive slaves in the frontier region; he
also directs a study o n 'anti-Haitianism' in the Dominican Republic.
Occupies the post of research professor in the University of Santo
Domingo.
Fadrique Lizardo. Isfinishinga study on the influence of African culture in Santo
D o m i n g o ; also engaged in systematic research on general themes con-
cerning the country's folklore directly connected with African influence.
Carlos Esteban Deive. H a s just started a research on slavery in the Dominican
Republic. H a s also carried out studies concerning the question of popular
religiousness from the point of view of African influence on it. Occupies
the post of researcher on contract at the Dominican M u s e u m of Mankind.
Brazilian and African sources for
the study of cultural transferences from
Brazil to Africa during the nineteenth
and twentieth centuries
J. Michael Turner
researched and analysed. O f importance also is the fact that these themes often
have a direct as well as indirect bearing on certain foreign policy strategy that
is currently under consideration by governments, thereby not being relegated
to forgotten library shelves or local archives. T h e contemporaneousness of
African-Brazilian studies should also be considered a point of interest and
emphasis.
Salvador, Bahia serves as a point of departure for any study concerned
with African-Brazilian cultural and historical connections. Bahia because of
its economic importance during the era of the Atlantic slave trade received
large numbers of African slaves, w h o in coming to Brazil brought not only
their ability to work in the sugar-canefields,but also their varied African
cultures and personalities. These cultural traits were representative of different
ethnic groups from Senegal to the Cameroons, and also from Angola and
M o z a m b i q u e , all mixing racially and socially with Portuguese and Amerindian
cultures with the result being the cultural heterogeneity which is today's almost
mythic Bahia, a region considered both by its native Bahians and the rest of
Brazil as an area apart and culturally special from the rest of the country.1
Research on Afro-Brazilian culture, as manifested in the various cults and
sects of Afro-Brazilian religion has tended to focus upon the city of Salvador
and to a lesser extent upon the interior of the stade of Bahia. The literal 'centre'
for research in Bahia concerning African influence in Brazil is the Centro de
Estudos Afro-Orientais, C E A O , semi-independent from the Federal University
of Bahia. Founded in 1959,2 the centre was thefirstinstitute in Brazil to be
concerned with Africa and African studies. Being situated in Salvador, quite
logically it concentrated its research interests on the city and the constellation
of African retentions in that particular urban environment. Its library facilities
during the 1960s represented the most comprehensive collection of books and
periodicals concerning Africa to be found within Brazil. A s m a n y of the first
research fellows of the centre were trained ethnologists and anthropologists
the library tended to mirror these interests, ethno-cultural studies being m o r e
numerous than political and economic monographs. Important as the centre's
organ of diffusion and m e d i u m of information expression within Brazil of the
international research concerning Africa is its journal, Afro-Asia. This remains
the sole Brazilian-African studies journal.3 Despite a series of economic vicis-
situdes the C E A O and its journal have continued with pioneering work, while
having to deal with the problems of having been the first in the field.
For researchers in Bahia w h o wanted to concern themselves with African
influence within Brazilian, perhaps more specifically Bahian, culture the centre
proved an invaluable agent. But if the research was of a more general nature
concerning Afro-Brazilian history or a more global project concerning the
African continent the research facilities of C E A O by 1970 were seen to be
increasingly inadequate, as for reasons offinancialexigency the latest publica-
Brazilian and African sources for the study 313
of cultural transferences from Brazil to Africa
tions were not being purchased. There was a certain introspection within the
centre and its research which tended to define Africa as being a coastal strip
between G h a n a and the Cameroons, with heavy emphasis being given to the
cultural transferences between Benin, Nigeria and Bahia. 4 Researchers, par-
ticularly foreign researchers were guided into certain cultural areas and during
the early 1970s Ihe orientation of C E A O seemed to be linked to a series of
repetitive studies of candomblé cults and rites located in Salvador and its
environs.6 Certain transformations occurred in the mid-1970s and the centre's
definition of Africa also changed as a new cultural axis was established between
C E A O and the Université Nationale du Zaïre, with an exchange of language
professors, Portuguese being taught in the African country, a Bantu language
in Bahia. The major influence within the Bahian African Studies Centre remains
ethno-cultural, with linguistics occupying a major portion of the research time
of the centre's members. 6
Researchers whose concerns are more directly related to themes within
Afro-Bahian, Afro-Brazilian history are to be directed to the Archive of the
State of Bahia and to the Municipal Archive in Salvador. Despite the tragic loss
for researchers in the burning of documents relative to Brazilian slavery
in 1890,7 ample material relative to property exchanges, sale of slaves, Church
ownership and African commerce to Bahian ports can be obtained in the two
major public archives. Classification of documents, seemingly the bane of
researchers in any country, remains a problem in the Bahian archives, although
incomplete guides are available. Because of interest in the subject of Bahian
slave rebellions and revolts, particularly in the nineteenth century, a brief
collection of holdings of the State Archives is available to researchers, although
personal experience of the writer has attested to the limitations of that particu-
lar guide and the necessity of direct 'attack' upon the shelves of the archives
for unearthing potentially useful cartons of information. Another problem of
a logistical nature for the researcher in Salvador archives is the daily operating
schedule, 2 p . m . to 6 p . m . on weekdays. Fortunately one other important source
of research material for Afro-Brazilian history has morning work hours—the
State Library—thus allowing for organization of a full workday.
The new State Library was completed in 1971, and at the time of utiliza-
tion by the writer, was still in a test phase, surely concluded with refinements
in the institution's workings and organization, five years later. The newspaper
holdings of the library are of interest as they date from the nineteenth cen-
tury, with also a rather complete collection of twentieth-century newspapers
from throughout the state of Bahia, particularly Itabuna and Ilhéus. A n unex-
pected discovery while reading newpapers from Ilhéus for the 1930s was the
presence of an Afro-Brazilian organization in that city, ideologically linked to
the United Negro Improvement Association of Marcus Garvey and his ' Back-
to-Africa M o v e m e n t ' that had attracted Afro-Americans in the United States
314 /. Michael Turner
during the 1920s.8 During m y research visit to Salvador in 1971, plans were
being m a d e for the transference of quantities of State newspapers, miscel-
laneous periodicals and journals, and magazines pertaining to Bahia and its
history. Mechanisms were being installed for microfilming and reading of
microfilms, the catalogue system of the library was both logical and useful
to the novice researcher. Important also is the fact the complex was seen to be
a model of n e w bibliographic techniques, a break in the traditional information
sources represented both by the archives and the Geographical and Historical
Institute of Bahia, a m o n u m e n t to Bahia's past historic culture and at present,
dimished grandeur.
T h e Bahia Institute, in c o m m o n with m a n y historical m o n u m e n t s is
exhibiting tangible signs of old age and disrepair. However, for its collection
of nineteenth-century Salvador newspapers, rare books and manuscripts the
institute demands consultation from the serious historical researcher.9 Salvador
is a citadel of tradition as apparent and representative within its intellectual
and academic life as within its social institutions. O n e method of meeting and
conversing with this academic establishment is through the institute, whose
members tend to congregate for genteel intellectual exchange and cafezinho
two or three evenings a week. T h e academic disciplines are not limited to only
history or geography, but can include a fair range of the old guard from all
areas of the humanities and the social sciences. These contacts are also useful
in that they provide the possibility of gaining entrance to private library
collections, which can only be consulted through personal recommendation.
Presenting a greater problem to the researcher is the actual condition
of the institute and the lack of facilities for working within the ancient building.
A very cramped reading r o o m which during its single daily afternoon session
occupied by the city's university and high-school students working on historical
assignments, ofen requires a researcher to work with crumbling nineteenth-
century newspapers or documents in a hallway or under a staircase, for simple
lack of desk space. Preservation of documents is at best rudimentary, with
time and small animals making irreparable inroads on the newspapers. Plans
have been discussed but never initiated for a systematic microfilming of the
institute's newspaper holdings, but have been indefinitely delayed for lack of
financial resources. The necessity to reclassify and re-order the system of docu-
mentation has also been discussed but not enacted by those responsible for
the institute. A part of the problem clearly is in the nature of the institution
itself, an historical tradition attempting to function as such within contempo-
rary society and academia; the primary characteristics of the institute are its
insularity to excessively ' innovative ' techniques and methodology in the h u m a n -
ities,10 and in an effort of self-preservation an almost blind commitment to
maintaining the Salvador academic status quo. Gaining their confidence is a
researcher's decision which obviously is based on the requirements of the
Brazilian and African sources for the study 315
of cultural transferences from Brazil to Africa
particular project and the utility of the institution and members to the success-
ful completion of the research. For studies concerning eighteenth- and nine-
teenth-century slavery in Salvador and surrounding area, the newspaper col-
lections are useful. Social and family historians would also benefit from the
holdings of the institute, its collection also interesting economic historians.11
Private collections either owned by individuals or institutions are numer-
ous in Salvador and also relevant to the study of Bahian slavery or Afro-
Brazilian history in various eras before and after abolition. T h e two major
Salvador convents, C a r m o and Desterro, have oflicial histories and substan-
tial documentation of eighteenth- and nineteenth-century commercial transac-
tions that shed good insights o n the relationship between the Salvador Church
and the institution of slavery.12 Also of interest is the collection of the recently
deceased professor and cocoa fazendeiro Frederico Edelweiss, an extensive
collection of books and documents covering a range of academic disciplines all
dealing with Bahia. H e called his collection a 'Bahia Studies P r o g r a m m e ' cap-
tured in a multi-room library;13 in the case of Afro-Banian Studies while dupli-
cation does exist between some of the Edelweiss holdings and that of C E A O ,
there are sometimes singular holdings owned by Edelweiss not found in the
centre. His collection of Amerindian linguistic texts and tracts is unmatched,
truly invaluable. It is m y sincere hope that the collection in its entirety will be
quickly m o v e d to a special section of the library of the Federal University of
Bahia, access to be m a d e available to all interested researchers. During the
past Edelweiss was at the disposition of all researchers w h o c a m e to Salvador,
allowing one to work unrestricted in his library; as his Bahian collection w a s
symbolized by an inclusiveness and globality of approach, its utility to the
researcher in varied disciplines should be stressed.
Culture and cultural history clearly dominate research patterns of the
recent past in Salvador and in Bahia state. With its African studies centre
performing the function of intellectual patron, little emphasis has been placed
upon more contemporary Brazilian-African relations, something of an irony
as the centre itself was a result of the first Brazilian diplomatic initiative
towards Africa in 1960 during the government of Jânio Quadros. 1 * This m o r e
contemporary approach to Africa and Brazilian-African relations is to be
found in the African studies centres in Rio de Janeiro, (linked to the Candido
M e n d e s University Foundation) and Säo Paulo, a more integral part of U S P .
T h e Centro de Estudos Afro-Asiáticos in Rio is administratively an
integral part of the Candido M e n d e s University Foundation and offers multi-
disciplinary courses concerning Africa (Asia receives significantly less atten-
tion), to any interested university student in the Rio area, regardless of the
student's institutional affiliation.16 The heart of the Rio centre is the library,
a collection very strong in contemporary African affairs and recent African
independence movements. This contemporary interest of the Rio centre is
316 / . Michael Turner
reflected in its director and staff, the majority with personal experience in
Portuguese-speaking African countries, and countries in southern Africa. The
centre has attempted to chronicle Brazil's developing relationship with Angola,
M o z a m b i q u e , Guinea-Bissau and Cape Verde, and is receiving ample docu-
mentation and primary sources from these countries, including newspapers.
The centre has also been able to establish personal contacts with m a n y of the
leaders of these new Portuguese-speaking countries and it has served in an
advisory capacity to Itamarati, the Brazilian diplomatic service, in helping to
define Brazil's evolving contacts and possibilities of exchange with these
countries.16
S o m e attention has been given by the Rio centre to that city's Afro-
Brazilian population and it has sponsored some seminars which have allowed
Afro-Brazilians an opportunity for some self-analysis and group expression.
The major emphasis of the Rio centre is international relations within Africa
and between Brazil and the African continent. The centre is less culturally
oriented, less involved with anthropological and ethnic studies than C E A O in
Salvador. The course offerings in Rio are concerned with an analysis of con-
temporary African political ideology and strategies for economic development,
other courses tending to focus upon the problems of decolonization and neo-
colonialism and the role of international cartels and multinationals on the
African continent.17 A s described by its director, the major function of the
Rio centre is to disseminate information about Africa, serve as an essentially
neutral African information ' b a n k ' to the Rio community; unfortunately
these functions at times have tended to compromise academic excellence as a
large part of the centre's time is devoted to a quasi-public-relations effort for
the continent. In an effort to redress this intellectual imbalance the centre is
inaugurating in N o v e m b e r 1977 its o w n journal. The centre's plan for the
journal is to include scholarly research papers, primary African documents
and opinioned interpretations of contemporary African events all under one
cover.
While admittedly courting the Rio public, the centre's staff exhibits
a sound knowledge of Africa and a working experience of the continent; it
has set a difficult task for itself as it has taken a middle position between a base
popularization of a subject catering to a capricious public interest stoked only
by media coverage of Africa and those serious students of Africa w h o are
interested in analysing a continent of multi-cultures or attempting to under-
stand h o w their o w n country of Brazil fits into (or is attempting tofititself
into) the overall African picture. T h e Rio centre because of these various
contradictions is recommended to the researcher with an interest in Brazil-
African relations, particularly in terms of international relations and political
science. It provides alternative sources of information and a balance to the data
provided by the Itamarati archives and the National Archive and Library,
Brazilian and African sources for the study 317
of cultural transferences from Brazil to Africa
Legón, as there is a definite interest on the part of some of its staff in Latin
America, specifically Brazil.38 G h a n a is not usually considered a traditional
area of Brazilian historical influence but the country proved to be an inter-
esting source, one requiring m o r e than the limited research time available
to the writer. A s a recipient of current Brazilian economic and diplomatic
influence and interest, G h a n a along with Ivory Coast, Nigeria, G a b o n and to
a lesser extent Senegal and Zaire constitute the Black African focus of Brazilian
approximation towards Africa, as distinct from Brazil's special (if indeed it
could be called special) relationship with Portuguese-speaking Africa.37 W h a t
is needed is research on the African reactions to this diplomatic initiative, as
seen distinctly from the African side.
Newspapers published by the Brazilian-Africans themselves also provide
an excellent source for studying social and cultural history. This is particu-
larly true in francophone Africa during the period 1920-40 with the D a h o m a n
newspapers. 38 While some of the collection can be found a m o n g the families
themselves and in the Benin archives, the most significant holdings are in the
Versailles deposit of the Bibliothèque Nationale in Paris. T h e Afro-Brazilians
are the editors-in-chief, the reporters, and are engaged in discussing events of
interest to their specific community, at that time attempting to achieve vertical
social mobility and class ascendency, envisioning for itself a kind of lateral
group identity, an intermediary position between the African 'masses' and
the European colonialist élite. T h e contradiction and at times evident anxiety
of this position is most accurately reflected in the newspapers. 39 Family history
is well served by the newspapers, as well as additional perspectives o n the
colonial era as witnessed by that small literate African public of the early
twentieth century. They also provide data for comparative history studies
(if m o r e are needed) of models of British and French colonial patterns, cause
and effect and of the influence of the different métropoles, Paris and L o n d o n .
A s a footnote to the interest in pan-African studies, the continuing research
into the historical attempt to self-define 'Africaninity', the D a h o m a n press
again proves its utility.
If one surveys thefieldof African-Brazilian studies it becomes evident
that the initial studies were concerned with cultural transferences from one
side of the Atlantic to the other, Bastide, Pierson, even Gilberto Freyre noting
the African presence generally in the Americas and specifically in Brazil.
With Pierre Verger's publication of the massive Flux et Reflux in 1968, 40
a data bank was established for future research in thefield.Verger's almost
forty years offieldwork not only definitively established the African historical
presence in Brazil, but also returned the cultural Odyssey to Africa. Transatlan-
tic cultural studies had been given a firm base. Verger, by his presence in Bahia,
influenced young researchers in the late 1960s most particularly a fellow of
C E A O , anthropologist Julio Braga, w h o did research in Benin on the Afro-
Brazilian and African sources for the study 323
of cultural transferences from Brazil to Africa
late nineteenth century. C u b a also saw large numbers of its free black popula-
tion leave the island and return to Nigeria during the nineteenth century. There
was significant competition between the returned Cubans and the returned
Brazilians in nineteenth-century Lagos, although both groups were less
favoured than the English-speaking returned former slaves from Sierra Leone,
the Saros.45 The subject of African emigration, the quasi-stranger groups such
as the West Indians and Afro-Latins arriving in West Africa are deserving
of a systematic study and analysis together with the collective problems of
'the return' and re-integration which need further research and discussion. W h a t
were the contributions of other areas in Brazil, the central-south, Pernambuco,
Maranhäo to the immigrant groups that left Brazil for Africa? W h a t apart
from the obvious slave-trade links were the relations between Angola, M o z a m -
bique and Brazil during the nineteenth century. W h a t is the evidence of Afro-
Brazilians returning to these countries? Central Africa needs considerably
more study to determine the range and extent of its historical ties to Brazil.
Archives and sources newly available in Lisbon hopefully should provide
some of the answers, while awaiting a sincerely desired era of stability in Angola
and M o z a m b i q u e which might permit access to archival sources n o w closed
and a population n o w distracted by seemingly incessant civil strife.
The m u c h discussed Brazilian approximation towards Africa of the
1970s is still wanting m u c h interpretation and analysis. Still to be heard from
in a significant way are the African countries themselves, to give voice to their
interest in this approximation effort, to articulate their conditions and require-
ments of Brazil, in particular as they relate to Brazil's relationship towards
southern Africa and to the so-called south Atlantic strategy. It would also be
instructive to study the differences and similarities between Brazilian and
United States foreign-policy initiatives towards Africa, as seen from an African
perspective or viewpoint, to determine each policy's strengths and weaknesses.
Is Brazil in a distinctly better position than the United States because of history,
culture and climate to offer to the African continent the needed technology
and resources for that continent's future development? W h a t are the possibil-
ities of Brazil's acting as mediator between 'north' and 'south', to the Third
and the First world ? W h a t is the image and meaing of Africa for the Afro-
Brazilian, and does this image have any bearing on Brazil's international
image within Africa?48
These are some of the m a n y research-oriented questions and problems
awaiting further elaboration and work. T h e subject, Africa-Brazil relations
covers at multitude of countries, more than one continent and a variety of
of languages and cultures. Research costs are prohibitive, there is always the
danger of becoming a generalist as the researcher is partly involved with Africa
and partly involved with Latin America. However, the compensations in h u m a n
terms are also intercontinental and for growth and development as a field
Brazilian and African sources for the study 325
of cultural transferences from Brazil to Africa
Notes
1. Salvador, Bahia, is called popularly boa terra, in part because of its being Brazil's
first capital, the alleged moral laxity of m a n y of its inhabitants, a casual attitude
towards life's problems, essentially a kind of living m u s e u m , where architecture,
art and the populace represent a more ancient Brazil, one lost with the coming of
the twentieth century.
2. Waldir Freitas Oliveira, 'Desenvolvimento dos Estudos Africanistas no Brazil',
Cultura, N o . 23, October-December 1976, p. 114.
3. T h e Rio Centro de Estudos Afro-Asiáticos is planning through the series, Cadernos
Candido Mendes, to begin publication of its o w n Journal of African Studies.
4. Primary study of Banian-African cultural relations was m a d e by Pierre Verger, Flux
et Reflux de la Traite des Nègres entre le Golfe de Bénin et Bahia de Todos os Santos
du XVIIe siècle, Paris, 1968. Iexla Pessoa de Castro and husband Guilherme tended
to focus their studies studies of Portuguese-Yoruba linguistics in Ife, Nigeria,
results were published in several numbers of the C E A O African Studies Journal, Afro-
Asia (1968-69). Julio Braga, C E A O anthropologist, Didi dos Santos, a pai de santo
and ethnologue and his wife Juanita Elbein dos Santos, anthropologist, all focused
their studies of the origins of Afro-Banian religious cults in western Nigeria and
eastern Benin, period 1968-71.
5. O n e African researcher, Elbun Ogunsanya, a linguistics and romance languages
student from Radcliffe College, Harvard, in 1970 encountered certain difficulties as
she attempted to research in cults and with people not officially under the patronage
of C E A O . B y 1974 three or four foreign researchers began appearing at the more
celebrated candomblé terreiros on the same evening (period June-August 1974),
causing the present writer to think that the researchers would to better to research
the influence of the researcher on the ritual process of candomblé.
6. O f importance is the work of the Swiss linguist Rolf Reichert, Os Documentos Arabes
do Arquivo do Estado da Bahia, Salvador, 1970, w h o as the resident Islamicist of
C E A O worked with all of the existant Arab documents from the 1836 jihad in
Salvador, providing Portuguese translations. See Turner, review article ' O s D o c u -
mentos Arabes', International Journal of African Studies, Boston, 1975.
7. After the end of Brazilian slavery, it was decided by the new republic that the historical
blot of having had slavery as a national institution could perhaps be erased by
destroying all relevant documentation, which occurred in 1893 as mandated by the
State.
8. O Commercio de llheus, June-October, 1931.
9. Nineteenth-century newspapers included in the collection of the I G H B are: Diario da
Bahia (1830s), O Commercio (1840s), O Diario da Bahia (1850s), Journal da Bahia
(1850s-1870s).
10. In 1973 a P h . D . candidate frotn Harvard University, Jane McDivitt, was doing a study
of Afro-Brazilian poetry and other literature which evoked at times hostile responses
from the members of I G H B w h o refused to admit the existence of such a field of
study. T h e Ghanaian researcher Anani Dzidzienyo also encountered incredulity
at his insistence that political behaviour of Afro-Brazilians could serve as a subject
for study and analysis in 1970-71.
326 J. Michael Turner
11. Newspapers in collection with listingTof port activities in Salvador, other relevant
commercial news a represent valuable secondary source or, depending upon availa-
bility of archival material, at times a primary source.
12. Study of Susan Soeiro, thesis for P h . D . N e w York University, 1975, economic history
of eighteenth-century Salvador as indicated by documents located in the Convent
of the Desterro, research in Salvador 1970-71.
13. The Edelweiss collection for Afro-Brazilian culture was also extensive and worth a
visit for encountering old and very rare books. H e also had old but general works
concerning Africa, most anthropological studies.
14. Freitas, 'Desenvolvimento', p. 114-15.
15. T h e C E A A of Candido Mendes offers a series of extension courses, open to the Rio
community attracting as wide an audience as possible, charging tuition fees for
each course offered.
16. In 1976 its director, José Maria Pereira journeyed on a semi-official mission to Angola,
Mozambique and Guinea-Bissau to investigate the possibilities of greater cultural
and educational exchange between Brazil and those countries, principally to bring
African students to study in Brazilian universities, and aid in Brazilian technological
assistance in African educational projects and planning.
17. Course offerings for academic year 1977, include several courses on African ideology,
decolonization (the Portuguese example) and problems of African development using
models from North Africa, West, Central and Southern Africa.
18. T h e m u c h contested and discussed 'Black Rio' cultural social movement despite
alledged foreign influence and intervention in Brazilian culture is serving to provide
a sense of cultural identity to m a n y of Rio's Afro-Brazilian residents. M u c h of the
intellectual life of the city's Afro-Brazilians, conferences and symposiums are
beginning to take into account the cultural phenomenon that began with the popu-
larity of American ' soul ' music and black American life styles but is slowly finding
its o w n Brazilian voice and raison d'être.
19. The Second Annual Conference on Black (Afro-Brazilian) contributions to Brazilian
culture were held at the Federal University of Fluminense, Niteroi, in November
1977.
20. In Salvador, while there is also evidence of the 'Black Rio' movement, for Afro-
Brazilians of that ciiy it is necessary to m o v e past the omnipresent Afro-Bahian
religious cult life which has so marked Afro-Bahian culture. In Rio there is not the
same strong cultural tradition for that city's Afro-Brazilian population, allowing
greater possibility for self-expression, for this 'Black Rio' began in Rio and not in
Salvador.
21. O n e of the advisers to Itamarati's participation in the recent World Festival of African
Art and Culture in Lagos, Nigeria, was the U S P centre, whose director, Professor
F. M o u r ä o gave one of the seminar papers at the Colloquium on African Culture
which opened F E S T A C .
22. In October 1976, African students at U S P presented an exposition on Africa, aimed
at the Säo Paulo business community to demonstrate investment possibilities and
potentialities on the continent, the exposition was held at U S P , with administrative
assistance by the centre.
23. In July 1977, Professor M o u r ä o went in the company of the Rector of U S P on a tour
of West African universities to begin a series of exchanges between U S P and these
African universities.
24. O n e of the topics for the Fluminense Conference in November, 1977 was the need
for a kind of clearing-house of information on Afro-Brazilian studies, what resources
Brazilian and African sources for the study 'ill
of cultural transferences from Brazil to Africa
are available in terms of documentation and what kinds of research are currently
being undertaken within Brazil.
25. In Säo Paulo, the sociologist Eduardo de Oliveira e Oliveira is engaged in a study of
Brazilian Négritude, with interested Afro-Brazilian students at Campinas, there
are functioning Afro-Brazilian institutes in Joinville Santa Catarina (a week of
Afro-Brazilian culture sponsored by the institute and the state of Santa Catarina
was planned for July 1977), Porto Alegre, and a number of similar centres in Rio and
Salvador, that of Did dos Santos, Institute of Afro-Bahian Studies.
26. Personal communication from Professor Fola Soremekua, History Department,
Universite of Ife, Nigeria, 21 October 1976.
27. Paper presented by Professor Anani Dzidzienyo at Ife Conference, in July, 1976 on
'Images of African and the Afro-Latin American', paper of Dzidzienyo at South
Eastern Conference o n Latin American Studies, Tuskeegee, Alabama, April 1977,
'Activity and Inactivity in the Politics of Afro-Latin America'.
28. Dakar served as the administrative centre for l'Afrique Occidentale Française thereby
receiving the archival collection after the dissolution of the massive African colonial
empire.
29. Archives d'Outre-Mer, also called because of its Paris address, R u e Oudinot, the most
complete repository of French colonial documentation.
30. See Turner, 'Les Brésiliens—The Impact of Former Brazilian Slaves U p o n D a h o m e y ' ,
Boston University, 1975 (unpublished P h . D . thesis): ' O s Escravos Brasileiros n o
D a o m é ' , Afro-Asia, N o s . 8-9, 1970; Lathardus Goggins (ed.), 'Reversing the
Trend: Afro-Brazilian Influences in West Africa' The Thematic Conceptual Ap-
proach to African History, D u b u q u e , Iowa, in press; ' A Manipulaçâo da Religiäo:
o Caso dos Afro-baianos', Cultura, N o . 23, October-December, 1976;'Brazilian-
African Points of Contact', Cadernos de Candido hiendes, Revista do Centro Afro-
Asiático, N o . 1, November, 1977.
31. Dahomey-Benin, a country the size of Kentucky has had an unfortunate political
history since its independence from France in 1960. During the period 1970-73, a
rotating three-president council was enacted in an attempt to stop almost chronic
coups d'état. The system ended in a coup with brought to power present military
Marxist dictatorship.
32. Documents from the Cuidah Catholic mission proved invaluable in reconstructing
the social life of returned Afro-Brazilians during the nineteenth century, aided by
African Mission Society records in France and Italy which cover the society's
nineteenth-century workings in T o g o and Nigeria as well as D a h o m e y .
33. Example of African neighbours, thefirstPresident of T o g o , Sylvanus Olympio (assas-
sinated while in office), was born in D a h o m e y and is buried in D a h o m e y , on ancestral
land of his Afro-Brazilian descendants. T h e D e Sousa family, a key Afro-Brazilian
clan, has branches in T o g o as well as in Benin.
34. O f great value is the collection under the jurisdiction of M r s D a Rocha T h o m a s , of
Casa de A g u a , Lagos, Nigeria. She is President of the Lagos Brazilian Friendly
Society and provided the writer with invaluable leads during his time in Lagos
in 1972.
35. Turner, 'Manipulaçâo', Cultura, p . 61; 'Points of Contact', Cadernos.
36. In personal communication from Professor Dzidizienyo, Ghanaian professor at Cape
Coast University, G h a n a , did a thesis on Portuguese Africa and Brazil, 15 March
1977.
37. W a y n e Selcher, The Afro-Asian Dimension of Brazilian Foreign Policy, Gainesville,
1974.
328 J. Michael Turner
Leslie Bethell (author of The Abolition of the Brazilian Slave Trade, Cambridge,
United Kingdom, 1970).
Professor Julio Braga, Centro de Estudos Afro-Orientais, Universidade Federal da
Bahia, Salvador.
C E B R A P Research Centre Sao Paulo.
Professor Colson, Universidade de Santa Catarina.
Robert Conrad (author of The Destruction, Universityof California, Berkeley Press.)
Professor Carl Degler, History Department, Stanford University, Palo Alto,
California.
Professor Anani Dzidzienyo, Department of Afro-American Studies, Brown Univer-
sity Providence, Rhode Island.
Professor Florestan Fernandes, Dept 0 Sociología, Universidade de Säo Paulo.
Professor Katharine Fringer, Dept 0 Geog./História, Fundacäo Universiadade de
Brasilia.
Jean-Claude Garcia-Zamor, University of Florida, Gainesville, Florida.
Professor Brasil Gerson (author), Pallas Editora, Rio de Janeiro.
Professor R o y Glasgow, Dept 0 de Historia, Universidade Federal de Fluminense,
Niteroí, Rio de Janeiro.
Professor Carlos Hasenbalg, I U P E R J , Rio de Janeiro.
Marvin Harris, Department of Anthropology, Columbia University, N e w York.
H . Hoetink, University of Puerto Rico, Puerto Rico.
Octavio Ianni, Dept 0 de Sociología, Universidade de Säo Paulo.
D r M a r y Karasch, Fulbright Professor, Universidade de Brasilia.
Herbert S. Klein, Department of History, Princeton University.
Professor Jane McDivitt, Department of Portuguese, University of Iowa, Iowa City.
Professor Katia M . Mattoso, Universidade Católica da Bahia, Salvador.
Professor Corcino Medeiros dos Santos; ' G E H ' , Fundacäo Universidade de Brasil.
Professor Michael Mitchell, Afro-American Studies Department. Department of
Politics Princeton University, Princeton, N . J .
Clovis M o u r a c/o C E A A , Candido Mendes, Rio de Janeiro.
Professor Maria Beatriz do Nascimento, C E A A , Conjunto Universitario de Candide
Mendes, Ipanema, Rio de Janeiro.
Professor L . Nieilson, Dept 0 de Historia Universidade Federal de Santa Catarina,
Florianopolis, Santa Catarina, Brasil.
330 J. Michael Turner
The African slave trade from the fifteenth to the nineteenth century