Agricultrue Priests and Warriors

Download as docx, pdf, or txt
Download as docx, pdf, or txt
You are on page 1of 6

The agricultural transition: how and why?

The Iranian Plateau was surrounded by semi-arid regions where among the first
agropastoral economies existed as long ago as 10,000 yr BP.9 Some four to five
millennia BP,the first expansion and contraction cycles of agricultural activity and
population density took place in the fragile Mediterranean environments of Europe.
Meanwhile, in the rest of Europe the transition process from hunter-gathering to various
forms of agriculture and horticulture and livestock raising was well underway. Similar
transition processes
took place in other parts of Asia and in the Americas – sometimes successful and
enduring, sometimes broken off in complex interplays of environmental change and
social response processes. Sometimes – as with the Jomon peoples in Japan – the
transition never took place or occurred much later because the known forms of
agriculture were not an attractive enough alternative. Although our brief overview is
incomplete and each place and time surely had its specific characteristics, it appears
there were universal forces at work to push the agrarianization process forward. The
first main route was plant-food production, from wild plant-food procurement to crop
production. The second main route was animal domestication, from predation to taming
and protective herding to livestock raising and pastoralism. In the process, the
dependence on wild plants and animals continuously decreased.10 Can we get a deeper
understanding of this transition process and its environmental ramifications?

4.4.1. The origins and spread of agriculture and pastoralism


The origins and spread of agriculture and pastoralism – in the sense of plant and animal
domestication – has been the subject of intense investigations, as is evident from the
previous
narratives. The prevailing view nowadays is that agriculture probably originated
some 12,000 yr BP in the so-called Levantine Corridor near the Jordan Valley lakes in
the
form of the domestication of cereals and pulses.Within a millennium animal
domestication
took place: dogs, then sheep and goats11. It is hypothesized that preceding
huntergatherer
populations lived in small refuges and that by this time the steppe vegetation
started to become richer across the Fertile Crescent as a consequence of climate
change.12 The invasion of annual grasses was followed by oak-dominated park-
woodland
and
increased dramatically the gross yields of plant-foods per unit area, particularly starch-
protein
staples, that correspondingly led to increased carrying capacity. It is suggested that these
increases prompted significant extensions both in the storage of plant-foods and in
sedentism,
and that the ensuing increases in birth rate eventually produced stresses on carrying
capacity,
which, in certain locations, led to the cultivation of cereals. (Hillman 1996: 195)13
This process of cereal cultivation started spreading to the south and east, accelerated by
the increasing climatic seasonality and unpredictability coupled with the dry conditions.
The spread of forest reduced the open range that encouraged territoriality and
predomestication
of animals by the protection and propagation of local herds (Hole 1996).
It is evident from these facts and explanations that ‘climatic and other environmental
changes were powerful forces in the spread of agriculture and possibly in the inception
of animal domestication.’ (Hole 1996: 264)
In any case ‘the’ agricultural revolution has not been one momentous event – one of the
reasons why we prefer to talk about the process of agrarianization (cf. Chapter 2).
Instead, it may have been a gradual intensification of the relationship between groups of
humans, their environment and each other (Harris 1996). Clearing plots of land, usually
by fire; having animals around, becoming part of their habitat; gathering roots and
tubers, gardens emerging. These could have been the slow changes in various places
that
led to ‘agriculture’ and its associated phenomena such as sedentarization, domestication
and urbanization.
Insidious complementary (sub)mechanisms have been proposed, for instance about
the role of micropredators.When the temperature started to rise in the early Holocene,
not only wild cereals spread but also parasites:
The climatic amelioration during the terminal Pleistocene was a bonanza for many
temperature-
and humidity-sensitive micropredators and their vectors. Coastal changes, particularly
swamp formation with the rising sea levels, created ideal conditions for anophelene
mosquitoes.

4.4.2. Causes and consequences of agricultural expansion


Why peoples made steps in the agrarianization process is, at least partly, a question
about motives and means and as such in the domain of economic anthropology.14 The
transition probably resulted from many, site-specific forces at work, with various
options
– food gathering, hunting, horticulture, pastoralism, agriculture – making up a locally
specific mix of competing or complementary alternative strategies. As it turned out,
this process was irreversible (cf. Chapter 2). Several interrelated trends can be seen: an
increase and spatial concentration in food production and people, increasing
specialization
and the growth of organizational systems dealing with the food system – production,
distribution, storage, consumption – and increasing differentiation of power
(stratification)
(Goudsblom 1996). Tools, rules and markets accompanied this process.
Many questions can be asked about why and how. Did people develop tools by
chance, out of boredom and surplus labour or out of necessity? Did customs and rules
and the associated institutional frameworks regarding, for instance, land access and
control
reflect survival strategies or mental attitudes or both? Was food produced for direct,
own consumption or for (market) exchange in the later stages? Food shortages led to
hunger and starvation, in turn, often threatened social organization – as the numerous
peasant revolts testify. As a result, the explanation of why peoples shifted to agriculture
has wider ramifications.

Virtues and vices of foraging life


One element in the discussion is the interpretation of the pre-agricultural stage: how did
hunter-gatherers live? Until the mid-20th century the view prevailed that ‘Stone Age’
people
lived in ‘a mere subsistence economy’, were incessantly searching for food in a meagre
and unreliable environment, and had limited leisure and no economic surplus. In his
book Stone Age Economics (1972), Sahlins refuted or at least complemented this view
with a different assessment. Data on several contemporaneous hunter-gatherer groups –
Australian Aborigines, the South African !Kung Bushmen and the South American
Yamana – indicate that their members spent on average between two and five hours of
work per day per person on the appropriation and preparation of food. It also showed
that they had a fairly varied diet, often underused their economic potential and did not
care much for material possessions or foresight. Sahlins suggests several sources of the
discrepancy between the prevailing (European) view and these observations. Firstly, the
ethnographic records suffer from the naïveté with which European travellers perceived
what to them were exotic environments. Moreover, they met mostly hunter-gatherer
tribes who had already been forced into a marginal existence by expanding colonialism.
The second reason for a distorted view was the European economic context in which
these tribes were judged:
Modern capitalist societies, however richly endowed, dedicate themselves to the
proposition of
scarcity. Inadequacy of economic means is the first principle of the world’s wealthiest
peoples…
The market-industrial system institutes scarcity, in a manner completely unparalleled
and to a degree nowhere else approximated… insufficiency of material means becomes
the explicit, calculable starting point of all economic activity… it is precisely from this
anxious

The roots of economic behavior


In search of the foundations of economic theory,
great debate has been ranging about the material and social roots of human behaviour.
In an attempt to structure somewhat the diversity of (anthropological) thought,
several schools can be distinguished, as done by for instance Dupuy (2001) in his book
Anthropologie économique. One school are the formalists, who claim universality for
the Homo economicus, ‘cet être générique guidé par le seul goût du profit personnel et
pour qui “la fin justifie les moyens”. ’ (Dupuy 2001: 14) It is in the nature of human
beings, according to this view, to maximize the use of scarce means in a process of
(market) competition.
A second school, the substantivist, is rooted in the work of Polanyi and emphasizes
the role of social relationships in economic processes. Reciprocal and redistributive
mechanisms did and do co-exist with more or less institutionalized market processes,
the latter being cut off from social relation based upon kinship, religion or political
power. A third, and related, school is (neo)Marxist, with Sahlins as one of its adherents.
Following Marx’s analysis of pre-capitalist societies, the emphasis is not so much on
the distribution and circulation of goods distribution as on their production. What
matters
most in economic processes is the mode of production in the sense of productive
forces and their organization and of the associated political and ideological
relationships.
It seems the past two centuries of (European) thinking in the social sciences
vividly demonstrate how open our past was, is and possibly always will be to divergent
and value-laden interpretations.
vantage that we look back upon hunters… Having equipped the hunter with bourgeois
impulses and palaeolithic tools, we judge his situation hopeless in advance. (Sahlins
1972: 3-4)
Yet scarcity is a relationship between means and ends constructed by people. It can be
argued that many hunter-gatherer peoples lived a life of material plenty, highly mobile
and therefore without ‘big things’ that would have to be carried around. They did not
store food because it may have given rise to distributional and transportation problems.
Besides, why store food and care for the day of tomorrow if nature is experienced as
abundant – a view interpreted by Europeans as a lack of foresight and prodigality. Other
consequences of such a mobile life were shared property and harsh demographic
controls.
They probably enjoyed a great deal of leisure time, which was filled with all kinds
of ceremonies and rituals. For this reason, they may often have declined agriculture
because it required more work. In fact, the most important economic impediment is, in
Sahlins’ words, the imminence of diminishing returns which forced them into moving
around with all the above consequences.
Why, then, did the transition to agriculture occur in so many instances? Apart from
considerations such as the quest for more protection from animals, invaders and
diseases,
one reason may be that in quite some regions life was or became much harder than
the life of the hunter-gatherers Sahlins talks about – because of climate change, resource
limitations and depletion, population pressure or all of these at once. Listen to the
lament of an Eskimo hunter (Rothenberg 1969: 242):

My biggest worry is this: that the whole winter long I have been sick and helpless as a
child.
Ay me.
Now with me sick there is no blubber in the house to fill the lamp with.
Spring has come and the good days for hunting are passing by, one by one.
When shall I get well?
My wife has to go begging skins for clothes and meat to eat that I can’t provide –
O when shall I be well again?’

The idea that people started farming because they enjoyed leisure time seems erroneous
– so is the idea that people were farmers ‘by nature’ or ‘stumbled’ upon technological
innovations. In her book Population and Technological Change (1981), Boserup argued
that the transition to agriculture was largely born out of necessity: increasing population
pressure forced peoples to produce more food by putting in more labour at a generally
decreasing labour productivity rate (cf. Section 5.6). As such it was a response to
scarcity:
‘progress’ born out of necessity (Wilkinson 1973).Without such a response to
population growth nor growth-reducing measures or outmigration, a (neo)Malthusian
collapse would occur – no doubt this happened occasionally.
What were the most important ‘causal’ factors? Population – both size and density –
is often mentioned. So is technology – the use of increasingly advanced tools and
practices, in response to the rising need for more food. The nature and dynamics of
socialrelationships is a third factor. Trade is proven to be of enormous importance in
someregions as a means to reduce vulnerability for droughts and other natural disasters.
Violent forms of interactions such as conquest and piracy, and exploitation in the form
oftribute and taxes have been other forces in the agrarian regime. Evidently,
understanding socio-cultural organization is crucial in understanding human-
environment interactions.

Peasants, priests and warriors


Sedentation and agrarianization changed the relationship between humans and their
environment. With increasing population density, interactions within and between
human groups became more important and lower mobility intensified the exploitation
of the surrounding environment. Cultivation practices developed in a sequence of
intensification
measures – shorter fallow periods, irrigation, multi-cropping (cf. Section 5.6).
As people started to invest more of their labour in harvesting and feeding animals, in
irrigation channels and – often indirectly – in soil amelioration, the land became
‘valueadded’.
Accumulation of material possessions became possible and important. Notions
of collective – tribal and familial – and individual property became elements of the
emerging social fabric (cf. Chapter 2).
Agrarian populations were more productive than foragers – in food per unit land
rather than in food per unit labour effort. However, they were also more vulnerable.
Along the lines of the ‘triad of basic controls’ proposed by Norbert Elias, Joop
Goudsblom
(1996) distinguishes between dangers coming from the extra-human world –
droughts and floods, wild beasts and pests, earthquakes and volcanic eruptions; from
inter-human relationships – hostile neighbours, invading warriors; and from
mismanagement
due to intra-human nature – negligence, ignorance, lack of self-restraint or discipline.
In a meticulous sociological investigation Goudsblom relates the rise of social
organization to the risks early agrarian communities faced. Priests fulfilled a mediating
role between ordinary people and the extra-human world but, Goudsblom argues, they
also played a pivotal role in inducing the self-restraint required for a farming life of hard
work and for the exigencies of food storage and distribution: ‘…rites conducted by
priests helped to strengthen the self-restraint which could keep people from too readily
drawing upon their reserves.’ (Goudsblom 1996: 42). Harvest feasts and sacrifices are
social institutions to manage the pressures of frugality. Priests are resource-managers
avant-la-lettre – not a strange idea when one knows about the rules in Christian and
Buddhist monasteries.
A second observation is that the priest-led – religious-agrarian – regimes were probably
first but came almost everywhere in competition with warrior-led – military-agrarian
– regimes. The latter usually won, a dominant but not universal trend. The emergence
of a warrior class, that is, of professional killers and pillagers, should be seen as one
stage in the monopolization of violence and cannot be explained solely in terms of their
discipline, equipment and organizational skills. It can be argued that the most crucial
force behind it was the bonding of warriors and peasants (cf. Chapter 6):
The warriors needed the peasants for food, the peasants needed the warriors for
protection.
This unplanned – and, in a profound sense fatal – combination formed the context for
the great variety of mixtures of military protection and economic exploitation that mark
the history of the great majority of advanced agrarian societies…. wherever in agrarian
societies rural settlements developed into city-states which were subsequently engulfed
by larger empires, the priests became subservient to the warriors. (Goudsblom 1996: 59)
Increasing population density
Theories about agricultural development and carrying capacity suggest an intimate
relationship between the possibilities of the natural environment and the human
populationdensity (cf. Chapter 5). Most hunter-gatherer groups have a population
density below 0.1 people/km2, which is representative for the onset of agriculture
(Sieferle 1997). Population densities in grasslands and shrublands had similar values; in
most tropical regions they seldom exceeded 2 people/km2 (Gourou 1947). The
increased productivity of agrarian communities had major direct and indirect
demographic consequences. For instance, women could have more children as birth
spacing became shorter for settled life compared to nomadic life and epidemic diseases
may have spread more easily because of the higher population densities and the
proximity to domesticatedanimals. Whatever the details, the opportunity to feed people
beyond subsistence needs and the corresponding increase in population density surely
added new dynamics to human groups and their natural environment. Besides the socio-
cultural dynamics discussed above, there are two other related facets: environmental
degradation and urbanization.
More intense exploitation of the local resource base also intensified environmental
change. In some cases it was rather direct and visible, for instance erosion from
overgrazing or salinization from irrigation. Sometimes, it operated over longer time-
scales, such as a change in regional climate as a result of deforestation. In the process
populations may have come to be in a better position to manage short-term risks related
to frequent events, such as those related to variations in rainfall. Food storage and trade
were also key in this respect. However, the associated techniques and practices
sometimes had a new, unknown impact on the longer-term future. Learning to cope with
such longer term and less frequent or more erratic events is more difficult. Risk may
also have increased because the ‘escape space’ had become smaller in a broad sense –
unexploited resources, the existence of survival skills and the like. Another risk element
arose because increased productivity was only possible with investment, i.e. stored
labour efforts.
These are particularly susceptible to deterioration, catastrophes or destruction. For
instance, when a society put in great investment to control the environment, at the same
time it became more dependent upon it and upon the means to operate and maintain it.
If such activities were undertaken with an improper or incomplete understanding of
environmental processes, they could accelerate negative feedback loops. As a result, the
values of a society, its past responses to environmental challenges and its capacity to
learn from it are part of the human-environment interactions.
As an ever larger fraction of the population could be fed without working the land,
physical and social dehomogenization became possible: urbanization. Small settlements
of a few families mostly involved in agriculture, grew into villages and towns and
expanded further in some places into cities that depended on the surrounding regions
for their food. Figure 4.4 illustrates this point. As peoples developed from one
agricultural stage to the next, the potential to sustain a certain population density
increased. In certain river plains already millennia ago population densities of several
hundreds of persons per km2 could be sustained. An ‘urbanization potential’ developed:
in certain places and times, leaders, craftsmen, merchants and others started to
concentrate around fortified villages which extracted part of the food surplus from the
agricultural population.

You might also like