Usury (: "Usura" Redirects Here. For The Electronic Dance Music Group, See U.S.U.R.A

Download as docx, pdf, or txt
Download as docx, pdf, or txt
You are on page 1of 4

"Usura" redirects here. For the electronic dance music group, see U.S.U.R.A.

Of Usury, from Brant's Stultifera Navis (the Ship of Fools), 1494; woodcut attributed
to Albrecht Dürer
Usury (/ˈjuːʒəri/[1][2]) is, as defined today, the practice of making unethical or immoral
monetary loans that unfairly enrich the lender. Originally, usury meant interest of any
kind. A loan may be considered usurious because of excessive or abusive interest
rates or other factors. Historically in Christian societies, and in many Islamic societies
today, charging any interest at all would be considered usury. [3][4][5] Someone who
practices usury can be called a usurer, but a more common term in contemporary English
is loan shark.
The term may be used in a moral sense—condemning, taking advantage of others'
misfortunes—or in a legal sense where interest rates may be regulated by law.
Historically, some cultures (e.g., Christianity in much of Medieval Europe, and Islam in
many parts of the world today) have regarded charging any interest for loans as sinful.
Some of the earliest known condemnations of usury come from the Vedic texts of
India.[6] Similar condemnations are found in religious texts from Buddhism, Judaism,
Christianity, and Islam (the term is riba in Arabic and ribbit in Hebrew).[7] At times, many
nations from ancient Greece to ancient Rome have outlawed loans with any interest.
Though the Roman Empire eventually allowed loans with carefully restricted interest
rates, the Catholic Church in medieval Europe banned the charging of interest at any rate
(as well as charging a fee for the use of money, such as at a bureau de change).
Public speaker Charles Eisenstein has argued that pivotal change in the English-
speaking world came with lawful rights to charge interest on lent money,[8] particularly the
1545 Act, "An Act Against Usurie" (37 H. viii 9) of King Henry VIII of England.

Banking during the Roman Empire was different from modern banking. During
the Principate, most banking activities were conducted by private individuals who
operated as large banking firms do today. Anybody that had any available liquid assets
and wished to lend it out could easily do so.[9]
The annual rates of interest on loans varied in the range of 4–12 percent, but when the
interest rate was higher, it typically was not 15–16 percent but either 24 percent or 48
percent. The apparent absence of intermediate rates suggests that the Romans may have
had difficulty calculating the interest on anything other than mathematically convenient
rates. They quoted them on a monthly basis, and the most common rates were multiples
of twelve. Monthly rates tended to range from simple fractions to 3–4 percent, perhaps
because lenders used Roman numerals.[10]
Moneylending during this period was largely a matter of private loans advanced to
persons persistently in debt or temporarily so until harvest time. Mostly, it was undertaken
by exceedingly rich men prepared to take on a high risk if the profit looked good; interest
rates were fixed privately and were almost entirely unrestricted by law. Investment was
always regarded as a matter of seeking personal profit, often on a large scale. Banking
was of the small, back-street variety, run by the urban lower-middle class of petty
shopkeepers. By the 3rd century, acute currency problems in the Empire drove such
banking into decline.[11] The rich who were in a position to take advantage of the situation
became the moneylenders when the increasing tax demands in the last declining days of
the Empire crippled and eventually destroyed the peasant class by reducing tenant-
farmers to serfs. It was evident that usury meant exploitation of the poor.[12]
The First Council of Nicaea, in 325, forbade clergy from engaging in usury[13] (canon 17).
At the time, usury was interest of any kind, and the canon forbade the clergy to lend
money at interest rates even as low as 1 percent per year. Later ecumenical
councils applied this regulation to the laity.[13][14]
Lateran III decreed that persons who accepted interest on loans could receive neither
the sacraments nor Christian burial.[15] Pope Clement V made the belief in the right to
usury a heresy in 1311, and abolished all secular legislation which allowed it. [16] Pope
Sixtus V condemned the practice of charging interest as "detestable to God and man,
damned by the sacred canons, and contrary to Christian charity." [16]
Theological historian John Noonan argues that "the doctrine [of usury] was enunciated
by popes, expressed by three ecumenical councils, proclaimed by bishops, and taught
unanimously by theologians."[14]
Certain negative historical renditions of usury carry with them social connotations of
perceived "unjust" or "discriminatory" lending practices. The historian Paul Johnson,
comments:
Most early religious systems in the ancient Near East, and the secular codes arising from
them, did not forbid usury. These societies regarded inanimate matter as alive, like plants,
animals and people, and capable of reproducing itself. Hence if you lent 'food money', or
monetary tokens of any kind, it was legitimate to charge interest.[17] Food money in the
shape of olives, dates, seeds or animals was lent out as early as c. 5000 BC, if not earlier.
...Among the Mesopotamians, Hittites, Phoenicians and Egyptians, interest was legal
and often fixed by the state. But the Hebrew took a different view of the matter. [18]
The Hebrew Bible regulates interest taking. Interest can be charged to strangers but not
between Hebrews.
Deuteronomy 23:19 Thou shalt not lend upon interest to thy brother: interest of money,
interest of victuals, interest of any thing that is lent upon interest.
Deuteronomy 23:20 Unto a foreigner thou mayest lend upon interest; but unto thy brother
thou shalt not lend upon interest; that the LORD thy God may bless thee in all that thou
puttest thy hand unto, in the land whither thou goest in to possess it.[19]
Israelites were forbidden to charge interest on loans made to other Israelites, but allowed
to charge interest on transactions with non-Israelites, as the latter were often amongst
the Israelites for the purpose of business anyway; but in general, it was seen as
advantageous to avoid getting into debt at all, to avoid being bound to someone else.
Debt was to be avoided and not used to finance consumption, but only taken on when in
need; however, the laws against usury were among many laws which the prophets
condemn the people for breaking.[20]
Johnson contends that the Torah treats lending as philanthropy in a poor community
whose aim was collective survival, but which is not obliged to be charitable towards
outsiders.
A great deal of Jewish legal scholarship in the Dark and the Middle Ages was devoted to
making business dealings fair, honest and efficient.[21]
Usury (in the original sense of any interest) was at times denounced by a number of
religious leaders and philosophers in the ancient world,
including Moses, Plato, Aristotle, Cato, Cicero, Seneca, Aquinas, Muhammad,[25]
[22] [23] [24]

Jesus,[26] Philo[citation needed] and Gautama Buddha.[27] For example, Cato said:
"And what do you think of usury?"—"What do you think of murder?"
Interest of any kind is forbidden in Islam. As such, specialized codes of banking have
developed to cater to investors wishing to obey Qur'anic law. (See Islamic banking)
As the Jews were ostracized from most professions by local rulers, the Western churches
and the guilds [28], they were pushed into marginal occupations considered socially
inferior, such as taxand rent collecting and moneylending. Natural tensions between
creditors and debtors were added to social, political, religious, and economic strains.[citation
needed]

...financial oppression of Jews tended to occur in areas where they were most disliked,
and if Jews reacted by concentrating on moneylending to non-Jews, the unpopularity—
and so, of course, the pressure—would increase. Thus the Jews became an element in
a vicious circle. The Christians, on the basis of the Biblical rulings, condemned interest-
taking absolutely, and from 1179 those who practiced it were excommunicated. Catholic
autocrats frequently imposed the harshest financial burdens on the Jews. The Jews
reacted by engaging in the one business where Christian laws actually discriminated in
their favor, and became identified with the hated trade of moneylending. [29]
In England, the departing Crusaders were joined by crowds of debtors in the massacres
of Jews at London and York in 1189–1190. In 1275, Edward I of England passed
the Statute of the Jewrywhich made usury illegal and linked it to blasphemy, in order to
seize the assets of the violators. Scores of English Jews were arrested, 300 were hanged
and their property went to the Crown. In 1290, all Jews were to be expelled from England,
allowed to take only what they could carry; the rest of their property became the Crown's.
Usury was cited as the official reason for the Edict of Expulsion; however, not all Jews
were expelled: it was easy to avoid expulsion by converting to Christianity. Many other
crowned heads of Europe expelled the Jews, although again converts to Christianity were
no longer considered Jewish (see the articles on marranos or crypto-Judaism).
The growth of the Lombard bankers and pawnbrokers, who moved from city to city, was
along the pilgrim routes.

Die Wucherfrage is the title of a Lutheran Church–Missouri Synod work against usury
from 1869. Usury is condemned in 19th-century Missouri Synod doctrinal statements.[30]
In the 16th century, short-term interest rates dropped dramatically (from around 20–30%
p.a. to around 9–10% p.a.). This was caused by refined commercial techniques,
increased capital availability, the Reformation, and other reasons. The lower rates
weakened religious scruples about lending at interest, although the debate did not cease
altogether.
The papal prohibition on usury meant that it was a sin to charge interest on a money loan.
As set forth by Thomas Aquinas, the natural essence of money was as a measure of
value or intermediary in exchange. The increase of money through usury violated this
essence and according to the same Thomistic analysis, a just transaction was one
characterized by an equality of exchange, one where each side received exactly his due.
Interest on a loan, in excess of the principal, would violate the balance of an exchange
between debtor and creditor and was therefore unjust.

You might also like