Add-On Goods and Contingent Charges. How Behavioural Economics Has Affected The Regulation of Overdraft and Payment Protection Insurance Markets
Add-On Goods and Contingent Charges. How Behavioural Economics Has Affected The Regulation of Overdraft and Payment Protection Insurance Markets
Add-On Goods and Contingent Charges. How Behavioural Economics Has Affected The Regulation of Overdraft and Payment Protection Insurance Markets
1. Introduction
How does behavioural economics affect financial regulation? This question is explored in the
context of the UK retail banking sector. Specifically the paper reviews the influence of add-on
goods theories (e.g. Ellison, 2004; Gabaix and Laibson, 2006) and contingent charges (e.g.
DellaVigna and Maldendier, 2004; Piccione and Spiegler, 2012; Shapiro, 1995) on the regulation
of two touchstone retail banking markets; the overdraft and payment protection insurance
(hereafter termed PPI and also termed credit insurance in the USA)1. It is reported developments
in the theory of add-on markets and contingent charging has influenced regulation in these
markets.
Regulatory actions within the PPI market addressed concerns with how this service was
distributed, through banning joint sales within seven days of the associated credit agreement (CC,
2009). Distinctly the regulation of overdrafts and the associated personal current accounts have
viewed overdrafts to be an intrinsic element of a product bundle rather than an add-on good.
Subsequently regulatory actions have addressed the symptoms arising from an add-on markets
rather than the causes of this customer harm. While both markets have witnessed a large decline
in profitability after regulatory interventions, the overdraft market has continued growing in clear
It is concluded the dynamic and fragmented regulatory structure, multiple policy agendas and a
successful legal intervention have all influenced how these financial services markets have been
regulated and reduced the potency of behavioural economic concepts. In particular aspects of
overdraft markets remain challenging to address including the ability to exclude competition from
aftermarkets.
1
The application of behavioural economics within financial regulation is important for many
reasons; not least retail banking has undergone a tumultuous decade. From being at the forefront
of economic development and inclusion, public perceptions of banking have been transformed.
This industry has passed through both systemic crisis and repeated scandal shattering public trust
in this industry. These concerns have been particularly acute in the UK where a bank run was
observed for the first time in over a century (Shin, 2009) and mis-selling scandals have led to
astronomical levels of redress2. While these shifts in perception have been driven primarily by the
global banking crisis in 2007-8, this jaundiced viewpoint of the banking industry owes much to
how banks have distributed products and charged customers. A significant driver of this process
has been the ascent of behavioural economics and the dissemination of these concepts amongst
Understanding how add-on good markets and contingent charges operate has been particularly
important in this development. While examples of add-on goods and contingent charges as diverse
as hotel minibar pricing, gym memberships, dry cleaning and car rentals have been discussed in
the literature, retail banking is a key area in which add-on goods and contingent pricing are believed
to exist. The provision of retail banking services has provided one of the most commonly used
examples of how behavioural economic models of add-on goods and contingent charging operate
(e.g. DellaVigna and Malmendier, 2004; Ellison, 2004; Gabiax and Laibson, 2006; Piccione and
Spiegler, 2012). Clearly retail banking is a prime candidate to examine how behavioural economics
Turning to the contribution of this work, is important not to replicate materials already considered
in one of the many reviews of behavioural economics seen in recent years. Behavioural economics
review articles have appeared on an assortment of topics including economics and psychology
(DellaVigna, 2009), the psychology behind financial crises (Garling et al, 2009), behavioural
economics and credit (Elliehausen, 2010), behavioural economics applied to firms (Armstrong and
2
Huck 2010), consumer behavioural biases in competition (Huck and Zhou, 2011), behavioural
economics and marketing (Chuah and Devlin, 2011), behavioural economics and financial literacy
(Altman 2012), behavioural economics in financial regulation, (Erta et al, 2013), herding in financial
markets (Spyrou, 2013), contrarian and momentum trading (Galariotis, 2014), behavioural
concerns in pricing (Grubb, 2015) and behavioural finance and associated experimental evidence
(Duxbury, 2015a and 2015b). Moreover much of the theoretical development of this subject has
been reviewed within textbooks (notably Spiegler, 2011). This paper therefore contributes by
To address this question the paper is structured as follows. After this introduction the theoretical
developments of add-on markets and contingent charging are briefly outlined. The literatures
surrounding the overdraft and PPI markets are then summarised. In section four, regulatory
reporting in these markets is reviewed before conclusions are drawn in the final section.
Examining how prices are formed and markets are organised are prominent matters within
economics. Despite this importance, situations where primary markets for base goods are observed
in combination with aftermarkets for add-on or contingent goods was an overlooked concern for
many years. Historically markets were viewed to operate and establish prices independently with
traditional market analysis focusing on the supply side concerns, examining how markets were
organised under different information and technological assumptions and frequently assuming
customers behave rationally (see Huck and Zhou, 2011). This disregarded situations where
behavioural biases might influence competition and distort customer demands. Remedying this
3
situation has been at the heart of a flourishing literature assessing the market interaction between
Add-on goods and contingent charges influence how customers search for appropriate products
and whether the customer obtains an appropriate service or pays a reasonable or excessive price
for these services. In order to make an appropriate financial service purchase individuals might be
expected to have a clear understanding of the financial services characteristics, how their own
preferences relate to these characteristics and their future demands for this service. Despite these
expectations many consumers have a poor comprehension of financial services (Bucks and Pence,
2008) particularly the young, old and less wealthy (Agarwal et al 2009). When consumers decision
making deviates from assumed perfect rationality, this can become a source of oligopoly power
(Scitovsky, 1950). This power arises when customers pay too much for a good or service,
overconsume a service, misjudge prices, buy an ill-suited or inferior quality product or stay with
their current supplier excessively. These circumstances whilst favourable to firms, can punish
customers and result in considerable allocative inefficiencies and waste. Add-on goods and
contingent charging are techniques creating such challenges for customers and opportunities for
firms.
Within add-on goods markets, a base good of interest to the customer is offered in a primary
market together with another add-on good offered within an aftermarket. As the customer is
actively searching for the base good or service, the primary market may witness competition in
price and quality differences. The aftermarkets where add-on goods are sold may display different
competitive conditions. As the conditions of sale of an add-on goods may not be clear, some
customers may undertake a purchase decision for an add-on service without realising the costs of
4
In such a situation, price competition in aftermarkets can be constrained and higher prices develop.
The extent to which prices may rise is constrained by a range of factors. If it is easy for a customer
to observe the high costs of an add-on service, to switch to an alternative supplier or cancel the
add-on good, prices of these additional goods can be constrained. Similarly, if customers
comprehend their demands for the add-on goods, poor decisions may be avoided. Lastly, if firms
are unable to exclude other firms from aftermarkets, competition may develop within associated
independent markets.
Cognisant of this information, firms may frame the purchase decision and adjust how primary and
add-on goods are distributed to overcome these constraints on profitability, facilitating customers
over or under estimating their demands and leading to overpayment or excessive use of a service
(see Huck and Zhou 2011). This may occur through the design of the contingent charges
associated with using the add-on service (DellaVigna and Malmendier, 2004). Contracts may also
be adjusted to make switching more challenging. The comprehension of the add-on goods utility,
quality and cost may all be obscured using complex pricing formats and small print (Piccione and
Spiegler, 2012; Sato, 2014). Indeed within overdraft markets overdraft charges have been arranged
in a manner to encourage customers to incur higher fees3. Lastly, the firm could place the add-on
good at the heart of a bundled product, making this service intrinsic to the provision of the primary
good and challenging for other firms to contest in this aftermarket. These outcomes will all make
aftermarkets more profitable than primary markets. To gain market share firms may cross-
subsidise primary markets from aftermarket profits, attracting more customers to the primary
market and creating more opportunity to cross-sell add-on goods (Gabaix and Laibson, 2006).
Further discussion of the development of the theoretical literature is provided by Huck and Zhou,
5
Such an application is observed for the overdraft markets. Armstrong and Vickers (2012) examine
the pricing of overdrafts theoretically, viewing these services as a tied aftermarket and
complimentary yet distinct to the base service. This model assumes customers have differing
decision making abilities. Some customers are nave customers and choose the lowest costs of
primary personal current account services (deposits and payment service prices) whilst the diligent
customers, who can take actions avoid high charges, chose the lowest overall costs (deposit,
payment services and overdrafts). If there are enough diligent customers or low enough contingent
charges then efficient contract terms will develop. Alternatively if there are enough nave
customers and contingent charges are high then the aftermarket profits could subsidise the base
good. Firms will then compete more for the initial purchase with subsequent profits passed back
to the customer in the form of subsidised base good. This may lead to an inefficient pattern of
pricing, redistributing costs from customers using overdrafts to those customers using these
services.
For the case of PPI we observe a similar process developing. This type of add on insurance service
is not compelling for many customers to purchase and is offered with the base product of interest,
credit. To overcome disinterest in PPI, sales staff are incentivised to encourage customers to
purchase PPI due to its high profitability and benefit to banks. PPI could be aggressively marketed
yet more commonly has been sold assumptively and through emotional appeals to risk averse
customers (see Ranyard and McHugh, 2012b). The high profits derived from PPI may then
subsidise the associated credit market to attract more customers 4, who are encouraged to purchase
PPI. While some customers, cognisant of their demands for PPI will not purchase this service, if
there are enough customers which do not comprehend this service or can be persuaded to
purchase PPI, this sequence of circumstances will intensify overtime. In particular when sales staff
discover those customers least able to determine the utility of this service are the most susceptible
6
In both these cases add-on good models predict inappropriate purchase decisions of expensive
and potential low quality services and excessive profits being derived over the long term without
regulatory intervention.
To explore these theoretical developments we examine two markets which employ add-on
services: overdrafts and PPI. Both markets have been highly profitable and the focus of widespread
public unease and regulatory attention. Despite these similarities these products also differ;
functionally through serving distinct needs and by using differentiated distribution models.
Overdrafts are generally priced on a contingent basis depending on their use; PPI policies, be these
paid through single or regular premiums, are priced at the point of sale. These markets also vary
in the access provided to aftermarkets. Overdraft services are effectively closed to competitors
whilst borrowers have the option to obtain PPI from alternative providers.
During the last decade the retail banking business has been transformed. A major aspect of this
change has been the low interest rate environment and the associated decline in the profitability
of many core retail banking services. As interest rate margins have narrowed and previously
lucrative services produce lower returns; an increasing reliance on non-interest and fee based
income (Lepetit et al, 2008; Valverde and Fernndez, 2007) and questionable practices (Tennant
and Sutherland, 2014) has emerged. While these trends have been witnessed globally, concerns
have focused on two problematic markets in the UK; PPI and overdrafts.
7
Both these markets have been substantial sources of profits. Estimates of revenues from personal
current accounts and overdraft markets vary yet are substantial. The Competition and Markets
Authority (hereafter CMA) (2015) estimated there were 68 million active personal current accounts
generating revenues of 8.7 billion in 2014. Of these customers, 25.3 million used an overdraft
(39% of customers) generating 2.9 billion of revenues for authorised and unauthorised overdraft
providers in 2013; a figure equal to 115 for each personal current account customers which
incurred an overdraft in that year (CMA, 2014). These values have changed over the previous
decade; the OFT (2008) estimated 12 million UK customers used overdrafts producing revenues
of 8.63bn in 2006, displaying an increase in usage and decline in costs. These high costs of
overdraft provision are also observed internationally; for the USA, Parrish and Frank (2011)
reported consumers paid $23.7bn in overdraft fees in 2008; an increase of 35% since 2006
($17.5bn).
PPI markets have also been highly profitable. At its peak in 2006, the most common form of PPI
was for unsecured personal loans, accounting for 45% of the overall UK PPI market and valued
at 2,013m (CC, 2007). Mortgage PPI for first and second charge mortgages accounted for 24.9%
of the PPI market and was valued at 1,099m in 2006. This sector also expanded rapidly with
annual growth rates of between 15-20% for the 2000-2005 period (OFT, 2006) and is currently in
decline (CC, 2008). For example the take up of mortgage PPI on all new mortgage contracts has
also fallen from a high point of 24% in 2003 to 18% in 2007. For the USA, Baker and Siegelman
(2014) report in 2010 the credit life insurance market was worth $770m and the accident and health
credit insurance was valued at $875m. These values have also been declining over the previous
decade.
Lastly, overdrafts and PPI are two of three most mistrusted financial services markets of the last
decade. Considering data assembled from the 14 publically available annual reports of the UK
Financial Ombudsman Service, unresolved complaints raised by customers and forwarded to this
8
arbitration service between 2001-14 are recorded in Table 1. Whilst a complaint does not indicate
any firm wrong doing, it acts as a rough proxy for the concerns arising in different financial services
markets5. It is observed that PPI and personal current accounts have been the largest source of
complaints to the UK Financial Ombudsman service since 2008. Further the percentage of
complaints attributed to add-on goods (an imprecise measure due to the partial reporting of these
financial services) has increased dramatically from below 10% of complaints in the early 2000s to
over 80% of complaints in 2008. While acknowledging the imprecision of this measure, add-on
services appear to be a significant and growing public anxiety in financial services markets.
INSERT TABLE 1
3.2 Overdrafts
Overdraft lending provides a source of emergency capital or an ad hoc bridging loan for
accommodating short term liquidity concerns. This lending is contingent on customers actions
and is either agreed or authorised by the bank or unauthorised by a bank and accepted at the banks
discretion. Overdrafts are accessed after the primary good is purchased and are priced as part of
an entire bundle of financial services; the personal current account. Historically, overdraft lending
was considered an indulgence of the customer (Whitney, 1918) where fees are levied to cover the
The design of personal current accounts and overdraft charges has developed and varied greatly.
In the UK free banking forms of charging have been widely used since 19846, gaining most market
share by 2006 (OFT, 2008) and are increasingly observed in Australia, Ireland and the USA (see
Senate Economics References Committee, 2011; Central Bank of Ireland, 2012; Federal Deposit
Insurance Corporation, 2008). In free banking current accounts payment services are not directly
paid for by customers and are often assumed to be subsidised by customers using overdraft
9
services (Armstrong and Vickers, 2012) or personal current account deposits (see Ashton and
Hudson, 2013).
Despite the scale of personal current account provision, there is a scarcity of academic work. In
the UK past examinations of personal current accounts have generally addressed concerns other
than pricing, including the transmission of monetary policy (e.g. Heffernan, 2002) and personal
current account switching (e.g. Gondat-Larralde and Nier, 2006). In the USA these literatures have
been more extensive, originally examining pricing for personal current accounts (termed checking
accounts) for payment service use (Ederington and Skogstad, 1977; Mingo, 1980; Osborne and
Wendel, 1981) and assessing credit service demands (Bar-Ilan, 1990; Boyd, 1976; Morgan, 1978).
More recently this body of work has examined customer decision making using proprietary data
of personal current account use (e.g. Fusaro, 2008; Fusaro and Ericson, 2010; Stango and Zinman,
2009) and customer switching (Kiser, 2002). A limited number of studies have also been
undertaken in other nations including Canada (Seldon and Solmer, 1996) and the Netherlands
(Cuhna et al, 2011) examining the pricing of transactional and deposit services and demand for
credit respectively. Lastly, work predominantly from Scandinavia has assessed the costs of
payment services used within current accounts (for example Guibourg and Segendorff, 2007;
Humphrey et al, 2003). A legal review of UK bank overdraft fees and charges is provided by
Whittaker (2011).
PPI provides varying combinations of accident, sickness and unemployment insurance and is used
to protect the loan payments of policyholders in the event of losing their income. This financial
service, devised in 1917 (Baker and Siegelman, 2014) is unusual in that the amount insured declines
over the term of the policy and provides cover to both the borrower and lender. These outcomes
10
are attractive to many lenders (see Ashton and Hudson, 2012), reduce the probability of loan
default and may have freed banks to lend to customers previously red-lined and excluded from
Past UK academic research considering PPI has focused on mortgage PPI. This literature has
examined the determinants of PPI take-up, perceptions of, and satisfaction with these products.
While some contributions have reported the decision to take out mortgage PPI is rational (Pryce,
2002), other survey evidence has indicated mortgage PPI is very expensive, limited in coverage and
has regressive elements (Burchardt and Hill, 1998). Other UK PPI markets have also been
investigated. For example, Ranyard and McHugh (2012a) examined customer decision making in
PPI markets generally, reporting the willingness to pay for PPI is insensitive to changes in the
quality of cover. Ashton and Hudson (2014) examined unsecured lending PPI and reported
interest rate setting of loans significantly reduced when loans were offered jointly with PPI. Lastly
Ranyard and McHugh (2012b) reported PPI can ameliorate perceptions of risk associated with
borrowing. Ferran (2012) provides a legal overview of the PPI mis-selling episode.
US academic assessments of PPI have focused on the sale of PPI (termed credit insurance), with
sales approaches and involuntary tying arrangements a primary concern. This emphasis arises from
the widespread use and high profitability of PPI in the USA. Early survey evidence indicated most
customers do not perceive sales to be coercive yet felt obliged to purchase PPI (Polden, 1983).
Durkin (2002) indicated cross selling lends itself to coercive sales and PPI sales have focused on
older and lower socio-economic groups (Barron and Staten, 1995). Similarly, Lecko and
whether credit deals actually included PPI and other extra product features. Other US
contributions have emphasised the limited competitiveness of mortgage PPI markets, overpriced
policies, excessive coverage provided (Cyrnak and Canner, 1986) and the small quantities insured
11
(Durkin and Elliehausen, 2012). Discussion of on-going policy issues in US PPI markets is
The overdraft and PPI markets have both been the subject of extensive regulatory examination in
the UK during the last decade. This is summarised in Tables 2 and 3 for the overdraft and PPI
markets respectively. In both markets current and past regulators have contributed to the
assessment of these markets. These include financial regulators such as the now defunct Financial
Services Authority (hereafter FSA) and the new financial regulator, the Financial Conduct
Authority (hereafter FCA). These regulators empowered by financial markets and services
legislation have undertaken actions including enforcement of regulations and regulatory reporting
of entire markets. Competition law and consumer protection regulators have also been involved
with the investigation and subsequent regulation of these markets. These regulators empowered
under competition and enterprise laws have undertaken markets reports and legal proceedings.
These regulators include the now defunct consumer protection body, the Office of Fair Trading
(hereafter OFT) and the competition law enforcement body, the Competition Commission
(hereafter CC). These regulators have since been merged to form the Competition and Markets
Authority (hereafter CMA). There are also general reports commissioned by the UK finance
ministry or parliament to confront increasing public concerns within banking markets (e,g
In considering the findings from Tables 2 and 3 it is striking how prolonged these processes of
regulatory intervention have become, with many regulatory reports providing repetitive findings
for these markets. Through examining these commonalities and differences observed within this
regulatory reporting, a range of insights are drawn. Initially it is apparent differing regulatory
agendas exist within UK financial and competition regulation. These include persistent concerns
12
with financial exclusion and customer responsibility, inert customers, pricing and product
complexity and the treatment of less affluent. These often conflicting priorities may have
For both markets there have been neoliberal (see Moloney, 2010) anxieties that financial services
is disseminated widely to limit financial exclusion, enable informed consumers to partake in these
financial markets allow consumers to take responsibility for their own financial dealings (FSA,
2008) and provide a degree of competitive market discipline for the incumbent firms. Within the
overdraft market, concerns arise that all persons need access to personal current account services
to benefit from a monetarised economy and that high overdraft fees and charges may be restraining
this process. In the PPI market the government support of mortgagees has been phased out (see
Ford and Quilgars, 2001) and new forms of loan protection such as PPI are required ((Department
The regulatory reports also persistently elaborate situations where customers are inert. In overdraft
and personal current accounts, customers do not switch their personal current account supplier or
sufficiently track the market offerings. UK customers switching personal current account has fallen
over time from 6% in 2006 (OFT, 2008), to 3.8% in 2010 (Independent Commission on Banking,
2011) and to 3% in 2014 (CMA, 2015). In PPI markets despite having access to both independently
and jointly distributed PPI policies, customers have persistently opted to purchase PPI from their
credit supplier. The point of sale advantage led to around 80% of all PPI to be sold in combination
with credit services (OFT, 2006). Some firms have also faced fines and public censure for
amplifying this inertia through selling PPI assumptively and encouraging consumers to view joint
distribution as a normal practice. Indeed most customers were reported to focus predominantly
on the interest rate of the loan and felt taking out PPI would help their credit application (OFT,
2006).
13
A distinct consumer protection agenda has also developed in PPI and overdraft regulatory
reporting indicating customers can be unaware of the characteristics and costs of the service they
have purchased, may be confused as to how prices are established and perplexed by usual forms
of product distribution. Within overdraft markets there are continuing concerns that free banking
and packaged accounts remain confusing for customers and may not lead to informed decisions
charges in this market has limited product comparison, restrained switching activity and made
control over overdraft use and subsequent charges arduous for some. For example the OFT (2008)
reported over a fifth of consumers were unaware of insufficient funds charges until they had
incurred such a charge. Such limited customer attentiveness has led to discussion as to how to
inform customers they are incurring fees. These actions have included the ability for customers to
opt out of unauthorised overdrafts (see OFT, 2011, 2013) and/or receive text alerts, warning
consumers they have performed a transaction which may result in charges being levied (OFT,
2009).
For PPI similar concerns have arisen, yet reflecting the different market circumstances. Over 93%
of UK PPI for unsecured lending used a single premium for the duration paid at the start of the
loan period (CC, 2008b), a practices which made it difficult for customers to learn through
repeated purchase experience. The high levels of commission paid to PPI distributors have also
been a competitive impediment (59% of premiums are paid in commissions, OFT, 2006). Further
repeated regulatory reports have questioned the link between policy attributes and the potential
pay-out from such policies, reporting that many policies are overpriced and of poor quality. For
instance the OFT (2006) reported PPI claims paid as a percentage of gross written premium was
18% relative to a comparable figure of 84% for car insurance over the same period (CC, 2008b).
A last common theme running through these reports has been a concern that the less affluent and
least able to navigate these markets may be suffering unduly. Within the overdraft markets some
14
commentators (e.g. OFT, 2008) have speculated distributional cross-subsidies exist, in a Reverse
Robin Hood form (see Mullineux, 2009). Similarly within PPI markets there has been repeated
concerns that those purchasing PPI have been associated with lower levels of education, lower
social class and have tended to be younger and older customers (e,g. CC, 2007).
Turning to the differences between the regulatory reporting for these markets; many differences
are observed. The overdrafts reports have persistently emphasised the importance of traditional
explanation for the markets ills, rather than embracing concepts of add-on goods and product
distribution as the primary cause of excessive profits and customer harm. Further, while the
examination of the PPI market has been mostly concluded the regulatory examination of the UK
overdraft market is on-going; a situation not least resulting from the legal intervention into this
case.
The importance of the legal appeal in the overdraft judgement by the banks also has been
significant. Legal action ensued as to the fairness of unauthorised overdraft charges with a case
between the OFT and seven banks leading to rulings that bank overdraft charges are unfair by the
High Court and the Appeal Court before eventually being rejected by the Supreme Court in 2009
(see Whittaker, 2011). Crucially this final judgement viewed overdraft services to be an integrated
part of the pricing of personal current account services and not an exceptional or incidental add-
determined. Amongst other arguments, this judgement assumed the scale of income derived from
overdraft contingent charges was so substantial it must be an essential part of the service bundle.
It is important to note this ruling was made without reference to empirical investigation and can
be applied to other markets where contingent charges are employed. In particular the implication
that customers must read all clauses to be aware of harmful contingencies is of concern for future
15
This outcome contrasts with the PPI case where the regulatory outcome focused far more on
amending the add-on good market structure. The CC (2009) ruled joint sales of PPI with loans
should be prohibited within seven days of the credit agreement. The form of distribution was
deemed to be crucial to the concerns with excessive profits and consumer harm observed in this
market. Further premiums should be paid through instalments rather than as a single premium to
enhance customer learning in these markets, improved customer information was required and
needed to be provided and PPI should be unbundled from other financial services (CC, 2009).
Moreover a process of customer redress was initiated and remains on-going for mis-sold PPI (see
5. Conclusions
In this paper we have examined and reviewed the application of behavioural economic theories of
add-on goods and contingent charges within two markets: overdrafts and PPI. Through a
discussion of these markets and a review of the UK regulatory reporting, a number of insights are
drawn. A primary conclusion is that the regulatory process for PPI embraced and applied the
insights of behavioural economics far more than observed in the overdraft market. While there
was extensive mis-selling of PPI, this appears to be addressed through regulatory intervention,
resulting in the decline of this market. In the overdrafts market regulatory reporting has examined
features and symptoms of add-on goods, yet not amended the forms of distribution underlying
these concerns. Certainly the profitability of overdrafts has been diminished and constrained by
the array of regulatory measures. While some of these measures, such as enhancing financial
literacy may be of questionable value (see Gu and Wenzel, 2014) other regulatory actions have had
an undoubted positive impact. Further, successes have been observed for tangential policy aims
including public engagement with the personal current account market. Despite these
16
achievements, competitive and customer concerns persist within the overdraft market and have
Why has this difference occurred? These different regulatory responses have emerged due to
different neoliberal and consumer protection regulatory agendas employed by different regulators
at different times. These have allowed potentially conflicting requirements to develop; a not
implausible claim in light of the fragmented and dynamic regulatory structures overseeing these
markets. This is particularly acute in personal current account markets where deposits, payment
services and overdrafts, all part of a personal current accounts have had different and changing
regulators. Deposit or banking elements are currently regulated by the FCA and were regulated by
the FSA. The credit element of overdrafts was regulated by the OFT, the payments system
considered by the Payments Council and allied competition issues addressed by the OFT and the
CC and then the CMA. This has at least resulted in substantial repetition within regulatory
reporting.
Lastly, throughout these regulatory processes, it was accepted PPI was an add-on good and
overdrafts are not. This owes much to the Supreme Court ruling (2009, see Whittaker 2011) on
unauthorised overdraft charges. It was assumed PPI is distributed as an optional extra which a
customer chooses to purchase at the point of sale, while overdrafts are distinct and viewed to be
an integral aspect of the product bundle, the personal current account. Clearly overdraft providers
have navigated the law more successfully in reaching this consensus. Subsequently we should
recognise financial regulation can form as much as a political compromise between competing
constituents as a reflection of technical and economic concerns. Economic psychology has been
important in these regulatory cases yet on occasion it can be legally and politically appealing to
17
References
Agarwal, S., Driscoll, J. C., Gabaix, X, and Laibson, D. (2009), The Age of Reason: Financial
Decision over the Life Cycle and Implications for Regulation, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity,
Fall, pp.51-117.
Altman, M. (2012), Implications of behavioural economics for financial literacy and public
policy, Journal of Socio-Economics, Vol.41, p 677-690.
Armstrong, M., and Huck, S. (2010), Behavioural Economics as Applied to Firms: A Primer,
Competition Policy International, Vol.6, No.1, pp.3-45.
Armstrong, M. and Vickers, J. (2012), Consumer Protection and Contingent Charges, Journal of
Economic Literature, Vol.50, No.2, pp. 477-493.
Ashton, J. K. and Hudson R. S. (2013), What does Free Banking Cost? An assessment of the costs of using
UK personal current accounts, Friends Provident Foundation.
Ashton, J.K. and Hudson, R. (2014), Do lenders cross subsidise loans by selling payment
protection insurance? International Journal of the Economics of Business, Vol.21, No.1, pp.12138.
Baker, T. and Siegelman, P. (2014), You want Insurance with That, Using Behavioural
Economics to Protect Consumers from Add-On Insurance Products, Connecticut Insurance Law
Journal, Vol.29, No.1, pp.1- 60.
Bar-Ilan, A. (1990), Overdrafts and the Demand for Money, American Economic Review, Vol. 80,
pp.1201-16.
Barron, J. M. and Staten, M. E (1995), Coercion in the Selling of Credit Life Insurance, Psychology
and Marketing, Vol.12, pp.765-787.
Boyd, J. H. (1976), Household Demand for Checking Account Money, Journal of Monetary
Economics, Vol.2, 81-98.
Burchardt, T. and Hill, J. (1998) From Public to Private: The Case of Mortgage Payment
Insurance in Great Britain, Housing Studies, Vol.13, pp.311-23.
Bucks, B. and Pence, K. (2008), Do borrowers know their mortgage terms?, Journal of Urban
Economics, Vol.64, No.2, pp. 218-33.
Central Bank of Ireland, (2012), A review of personal current account charges, Dublin.
Chuah, S. H. and Devlin, J. (2011), Behavioural economics and financial services marketing: a
review, International Journal of Bank Marketing, Vol.20, No.6, pp. 456-69.
Cunha, M. R., Lambrecht, B. M. and Pawlina, G. (2011), Household Liquidity and Incremental
Financing Decisions: Theory and Evidence, Journal of Business, Finance and Accounting, Vol.38, 1016-
52.
18
Competition Commission (2002), The Supply of Banking Services by Clearing Banks to Small and Medium-
Sized Enterprises, CM 5319, London.
Competition Commission (2007), Market Investigation into Payment Protection Insurance, Emerging
Thinking, London.
Competition Commission (2008b), Market Investigation into Payment Protection Insurance, Provisional
Findings Report, London.
Competition Commission (2009), Market Investigation into Payment Protection Insurance, London.
Competition Commission (2010), Payment Protection Insurance Market Investigation: Remittal of the Point-
of-Sale Prohibition Remedy by the Competition Appeal Tribunal, London.
Competition and Markets Authority (2015), Personal current accounts. Market study update, London.
Cruickshank, D. (2000), Competition in UK Banking: A Report to the Chancellor of the Exchequer, London.
HMSO.
Cyrnak, A. W. and Canner, G. B. (1986), Consumer Experiences with Credit Insurance: Some
New Evidence, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Economic Review, Summer, No.3, p.1-20.
DellaVigna. S. (2009), Psychology and Economics: Evidence from the Field, Journal of Economic
Literature, Vol.47, No.2, pp.315-72.
DellaVigna, S. and Malmendier, U. (2004), Contract Design and Self Control: Theory and
Evidence, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 119, No.2, pp.353-402.
Department for Environment, Transport and the Regions (2000), Quality and Choice: A Decent Home
for All. The Green Paper, HMSO, London.
Durkin, T. A. (2002), Consumers and Credit Disclosures: Credit Cards and Credit Insurance,
Federal Reserve Bulletin, April, pp. 201-213.
Durkin, T. A. and Elliehausen G. (2012), Consumers and Debt Protection Protects: Results of a
New Consumer Survey, Federal Reserve Bulletin, Vol.98, No.9, pp. 1-10.
Duxbury, D. (2015a), Behavioral finance: insights from experiments I: theory and financial
markets, Review of Behavioral Finance, Vol. 7, No. 1, pp.7896.
Duxbury, D. (2015b), Behavioral finance: insights from experiments II: biases, moods and
emotions, Review of Behavioral Finance, Vol. 7, No. 2, pp.151-175.
19
Ellison, G. (2004), A Model of Add on Pricing, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol.120, No.2, 585-
637.
Erta, K. Hunt, S., Iscenko, Z. and Brambley, W. (2013), Applying behavioural economics at the
Financial Conduct Authority, Occasional Paper, No.1, Financial Conduct Authority, London.
Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, (2008), FDIC Study of Bank Overdraft Programs, Washington.
Ferran, E. (2012), Regulatory lessons from the payment protection insurance mis-selling scandal
in the UK. European Business Organization Law Review, Vol.13, No.2, pp. 247-70.
Financial Conduct Authority. (2014), Redress for payment protection insurance (PPI) mis-sales. Update on
progress and looking ahead. Thematic Review, TR14/14, August, London.
Financial Services Authority. (2005), The sale of payment protection insurance results of thematic work,
November, London.
Financial Services Authority. (2007a), The sale of payment protection insurance. Thematic update,
September, London.
Financial Services Authority. (2007b), The sale of payment protection insurance phase III mystery shopping
results, Consumer Research, No.61, September, London.
Financial Services Authority. (2007c), Insurance selling and administration. Feedback on CP07 and final
rules, Policy Statement 07/24, December, London.
Financial Services Authority. (2008), Consumer Responsibility, Discussion Paper, 08/5, London.
Financial Services Authority. (2010), The assessment and redress of Payment Protection Insurance complaints,
Consultation Paper 10/6, London.
Financial Services Authority (2012), Packaged Bank Accounts. New ICOBS rules for the sale of non-
investment insurance contracts, Consultation Paper, CP12/17, London.
Financial Services Authority. (2013), Finalised Guidance. Payment Protection Insurance. FSA/OFT Joint
Guidance, FSA13/02/OFT1474, London.
Ford, J. and Quilgars, D. (2001), Failing Home Owners? The Effectiveness of Public and Private
Safety-nets, Housing Studies, Vol.16, No.2, pp.147-62.
Gabaix, X. and Laibson D. (2006), Shrouded Attributes, Consumer Myopia, and Information
Suppression in Competitive Markets, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 121, No.2, pp. 505-40.
20
Galariotis E. C. (2014), Contrarian and momentum trading: a review of the literature, Review of
Behavioral Finance, Vol. 6, No. 1, pp.6382.
Garling, T. Kirchler, E. Lewis, A. and van Raaij, F. (2009), Psychology, Financial Decision
making, and Financial Crises, Psychological Science in the Public Interest, Vol.10, No.1, pp. 1-47.
Gondat-Larralde, C. and Nier, E. (2006), Switching costs in the market for personal current
accounts: some evidence for the United Kingdom, Bank of England Working Paper, No.292, Bank
of England.
Gu, Y, and Wenzel, T. (2014), Strategic Obfuscation and Consumer Protection Policy, The
Journal of Industrial Economics, Vol. 62, No.4, pp.632-60.
Guibourg, G. and Segendorff. B. (2007), A note on the price- and cost structure of retail payment
services in the Swedish banking sector, Journal of Banking and Finance: Vol.31, pp.2817-27.
Grubb, M. D. (2015), Failing to Choose the Best Price: Theory Evidence and Policy, Review of
Industrial Organisation, Vol.47, pp.303-340.
Heffernan, S. A. (2002), How do UK financial institutions really price their banking products?,
Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol.26, pp.1997-2016.
House of Commons Treasury Committee (2010), Competition and choice in the banking sector, London.
Huck, S. and Zhou, J. (2011), Consumer behavioural biases in competition: A survey, Office of Fair Trading
OFT 1324, London.
Humphrey, D., Willesson, M., Lindblom, T. and Bergendahl, G. (2003). What does it cost to
make a payment, Review of Network Economics, Vol. 2, pp.159-74.
Lecko, J. M. and Pappalardo, J. K., (2007), Improving Consumer Mortgage Disclosures: An Empirical
Assessment of Current and Prototype Disclosure Forms, Federal Trade Commission, Department of
Economics Staff Report.
Lepetit, L., Nys, E., Rous, P. and Tarazi, A. (2008), The expansion of services in European
banking: Implication for loan pricing and interest margins, Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol.32,
pp.2325-35.
Mingo, J. J. (1980), The Microeconomics of Deposit Rate Ceilings: Inferences for NOW accounts
and Interest on Checking Accounts, Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol.4, pp.387-95.
Moloney N. (2010), Regulating the Retail Markets: Law, Policy, and the Financial Crisis Current
Legal Problems, Vol. 63, No.1, pp. 375-447.
21
Mullineux, A. (2009), The regulation of British retail banking utilities, Journal of Financial Regulation
and Compliance, Vol.17, No.4, pp.453-66.
Office of Fair Trading (2008), Personal Current Accounts in the UK. An OFT Market Study. London
Office of Fair Trading (2008), Personal Current Accounts in the UK. An OFT Market Study. London
Office of Fair Trading (2010a), Personal Current Accounts in the UK. Progress update. London
Office of Fair Trading (2010b), Personal Current Accounts in the UK. Unarranged overdrafts. London
Office of Fair Trading (2011), Personal Current Accounts in the UK. OFT1319. London
Office of Fair Trading (2013), Evaluating the impact of the 2008 OFT market study and UTCCR test case
into personal current accounts. OFT1005eval, London.
Osborne, D. K. and Wendel, J. (1981), A Note on Concentration and Checking Account Prices,
Journal of Finance, Vol.36, pp.181-6.
Parrish, L and Frank, L. (2011), An Analysis of Bank Overdraft Fees: Pricing, Market Structure
and Regulation, Journal of Economic Issues, Vol. 45, No.2, pp.353-61.
Piccione, M. and Spiegler, R. (2012), Price Competition under Limited Comparability, Quarterly
Journal of Economics, Vol.127, pp.97-135.
Pryce, G. (2002), Theory and Estimation of the Mortgage Payment Protection Insurance
Decision, Scottish Journal of Political Economy, Vol.49, pp.216-34.
Ranyard, R. and McHugh, S. (2012b), Defusing the risk of borrowing: The psychology of
payment protection insurance decisions, Journal of Economic Psychology, Vol.33, pp.73848.
Ross, S. L. and Tootell, G. M. B. (2004), Redlining, and the Community Reinvestment Act, and
private mortgage insurance, Journal of Urban Economics, Vol.55, No.2, pp.278-97.
Sato, Y. (2014), Opacity in Financial Markets, The Review of Financial Studies, Vol.27, No.12,
pp.3502-46.
Scitovsky, T. (1950), Ignorance as a source of oligopoly power, The American Economic Review,
Vol. 40, No. 2, pp. 48-53.
Senate Economics References Committee (2011), Competition within the Australian Banking Sector,
Canberra.
Shapiro, C. (1995), Aftermarkets and Consumer Welfare: Making Sense of Kodak, Antitrust Law
Journal, Vol.63, No.2, pp.483-511.
22
Shin, H. S. (2009), Reflections on Northern Rock: The Bank Run that Heralded the Global
Financial Crisis, Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 23, No.1, pp.101-19.
Spiegler, R. (2011), Bounded Rationality and Industrial Organization, Oxford University Press, New
York.
Spyrou, S. (2013), Herding in financial markets: a review of the literature, Review of Behavioral
Finance, Vol.5, No.2, pp.175-94
Stango, V. and Zinman, J. (2009), What do customers Really pay on their checking and Credit
card accounts? Explicit, Implicit and Avoidable costs, American Economic Review, Vol.99, No.2,
pp.424-9.
Tennant, D. and Sutherland, R. (2014), What types of banks profit most from fees charged? A
cross-county examination of bank-specific and country level determinants, Journal of Banking and
Finance, Vol.49, pp.178-90.
Whitney, N. R. (1918), The Overdraft Evil as Illustrated by Conditions in Iowa Banks, American
Economic Review, Vol.8, pp.48-61.
Whittaker, S. (2011), Unfair Contract Terms, Unfair Prices and Bank Charges, The Modern Law
Review, Vol.74, No.1, pp.106-134.
23
Table 1 Complaints received by the UK Financial Ombudsman Service 2001-2014 by product area.
(% of annual complaints received) Compiled from Annual Reports of the UK Financial Ombudsman Service.
Whole-of-
Investment- % add-
Credit Motor Mortgage life policies Total
Year PPI PCA Mortgages Pensions linked Other on
cards insurance endowments and savings complaints
products goods*
endowments
2001 2.27 2.53 7.97 0.71 6.35 10.73 28.92 6.73 8.12 25.67 31,347 5.97
2002 1.18 2.95 8.95 0.86 3.71 13.57 33.68 6.60 8.42 20.08 43,330 4.91
2003 1.29 2.58 15.18 1.39 3.82 11.63 21.83 11.13 8.06 23.10 62,170 4.28
2004 0.82 2.15 3.29 1.47 2.79 5.42 53.03 10.85 5.56 14.62 97901 3.31
2005 0.75 2.27 2.70 1.44 2.32 3.80 62.85 7.40 4.06 12.41 110,963 3.35
2006 1.16 3.14 3.49 1.88 2.99 3.59 61.24 5.15 3.69 13.68 112,923 4.78
2007 1.94 8.54 4.63 2.89 4.48 3.91 48.87 3.86 3.96 16.92 94,392 11.24
2008 8.65 31.90 5.54 11.47 4.88 4.30 11.19 2.23 2.61 17.21 123,089 41.12
2009 24.37 10.73 5.96 14.58 4.92 3.88 4.55 4.55 2.76 23.70 127,471 35.80
2010 30.18 15.49 4.58 11.29 3.34 2.20 3.31 3.88 2.58 23.14 163,012 46.34
2011 50.75 9.68 3.43 8.47 2.81 1.31 1.48 1.84 1.61 18.63 206,121 60.94
2012 59.66 5.52 3.61 7.26 2.75 1.31 1.24 1.25 1.58 15.84 264,375 65.82
2013 74.42 3.84 2.34 3.86 1.53 0.86 0.92 0.92 0.64 10.67 508,881 78.62
2014 78.09 3.88 2.46 2.04 1.40 0.85 0.70 0.61 0.48 9.48 512,167 82.49
Average 23.97 7.51 5.30 4.97 3.43 4.81 23.84 4.79 3.87 17.51 175582 32.07
* Including payment protection insurance (PPI), personal current accounts (PCA), card protection insurance, extended warrantee insurance, guaranteed asset
protection, and mobile phone insurance.
26
Table 2: Overdraft and personal current account regulatory treatment
OFT (2009) investigation into Concerns with pricing complexity, a lack of transparency and
the personal current account switching persist. Aims to enhance customer awareness of prices and
market enhancing switching procedures.
OFT (2010) - investigation as Concerns in this market persist with complexity. It is proposed to
to the unauthorised overdraft develop working groups with industry and consumer bodies to
market develop best practice. Minimum standards to be introduced.
OFT (2011) - investigation as Forwarded initiatives to address switching and improve information.
to the competitive conditions This report outlined new minimum and best practice standards for
prevailing within the firms supplying overdrafts to be prescribed in the Lending Code.
unauthorised overdraft market
OFT (2013) evaluated changes The costs of using unauthorised overdraft services and the underlying
within unsecured overdraft profitability of these services had fallen by 928m. A focus on
markets arising from past helping consumers control when they use unarranged overdraft
regulatory changes. facilities and the charges they incur. Enhanced switching procedures
and improved information provision proposed.
CMA (2015) examination of Concerns with the concentrated form of market arise with high
retail banking barriers to entry and inert customers persist in this market. A lack of
pricing transparency persists especially in regard to charging
structures. Enhance the customer journey for switching enhancing
prompts to move provider. Improved information delivered through
different media, improve comparison of personal current account
pricing amongst other proposals.
Wider examinations of UK Concerns with the level of competition in this market Have drawn
banking (e.g. HM Treasury attention to possible distributional cross subsidies in these markets.
2000, the House of Commons Proposals include the introduction of a seven-day Current Account
Treasury Committee 2011, Switch Service, a review of account number portability and a
Independent Commission on voluntary code to provide free basic bank accounts (accounts with
Banking 2011). limited services and without overdrafts).
Notes: FSA - Financial Services Authority; FCA - Financial Conduct Authority; OFT - Office of Fair
Trading; CC - Competition Commission, CMA - Competition and Markets Authority.
27
Table 3: Payment Protection Insurance (PPI) regulatory treatment
Notes: FSA - Financial Services Authority; FCA - Financial Conduct Authority; OFT - Office of Fair
Trading; CC - Competition Commission, CMA - Competition and Markets Authority.
28
Footnotes.
1 A number of abbreviations are employed for regulators and financial services. Throughout FSA refers to
Financial Services Authority; FCA refers to Financial Conduct Authority; OFT refers to Office of Fair
Trading, CC refers to Competition Commission, CMA refers to Competition and Markets Authority and
PPI refers to payment protection insurance.
2 Within the UK, redress paid to compensate customers for inappropriate sales have varied from over
10bn for pensions mis-selling in the 1990s, to 2.8bn for endowment mortgage mis-selling in the 1980s
and 1990s (see Ferran, 2012) to over 14bn paid to customers in redress for mis-sold PPI in the 2000s
(FCA, 2014).
3 The Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (2008) reported of the 86% of US banks operating overdraft
programmes, half have used external consultants to increase the levels of overdraft interest and maximise
fee income from their customers.
4 Without cross-subsidies from associated PPI sales, it was predicted the unsecured lending market would
have lost between 1bn and 2bn in 2006, generating a deadweight welfare loss on 200m annually
(Competition Commission, 2009). See also Ashton and Hudson (2014).
5 A proportion of the complaints for personal current accounts relate to concerns with ATMs and access
issues as well as overdrafts (these are recorded in the Annual Reports and are low in number).
6 In recent years the UK has observed an increase in packaged personal current accounts requiring regular
access fees and often include additional services used to differentiate personal current accounts (FSA, 2012).
29