Preliminaries: 1.1 Compound Interest
Preliminaries: 1.1 Compound Interest
Preliminaries: 1.1 Compound Interest
Preliminaries
This chapter introduces interest rates and growth rates. The two topics are closely related,
so we treat them together. The concepts discussed here are not in Barro, but they will help
you understand the graphs and statistics that he uses throughout his book.
We begin with some common terms and calculations from the realm of xed-income in-
vestments. The amount of the investment is called the principal. The xed-income from
the investments is called interest. The interest per unit of principal per unit of time is called
the interest rate. Most commonly, interest rates are quoted in dollars per year per dollar of
principal. These units can be written: $=(y $). The dollar units cancel, so this interest rate
has units of one over years. Similarly, if the interest rate is apples per day per apple bor-
rowed, the apple units will cancel, and the units of the interest rate will be one over days.
In general, the units of an interest rate are one over some unit of time.
When the unit of time is a year, we say that an interest rate is an annual interest rate. If the
unit of time is not mentioned, then it will almost always be an annual interest rate. Interest
rates that are quoted in some specic unit of time can be converted to any other unit of time
via a simple linear transformation. For example, a daily interest rate of x% corresponds to
an annual interest rate of (365)(x)%.1 (See Exercise 1.1 for an example.)
We use P for the principal of a xed-income investment and R for the annual interest rate.
Under simple interest the interest is earned on the amount of the principal only. In this case,
1 You may be wondering about leap years. These are handled according to any of a number of conventions.
For example, some interest rates are quoted using 360 days as a year; others use 365; still others use 365.25.
2 Preliminaries
Of course, this formula works only an integral numbers of years. For non-integral num-
bers, you round down to the nearest integral year n, compute Va (n), and use that in the
simple-interest formula (1.1) for the fraction of the last year. (See Exercise 1.6 for an exam-
ple.)
Lets revisit our previous example. Once again, you invest $5,000 at a 4.5% annual interest
rate, but this time interest compounds annually. After two years the value of your invest-
ment will be:
Va (2) = (1 + 0:045)2($5; 000) = $5; 460:13:
(Here and throughout, dollar amounts are rounded to the nearest cent.) Notice that the
investment is worth less under simple interest than under compound interest, since under
compounding you earn about $10 of interest on the rst years interest.
The above reasoning for compounding annually applies to compounding more frequently.
The only catch is that the interest rate needs to be quoted in terms of the same time interval
as the compounding. If R is an annual interest rate, and interest is to compound t times
per year, then the value of an investment after n years will be:
tn
R
( )=
Vt n 1+ P:
t
We return to our example again, this time supposing that interest compounds daily. After
two years, the value will be:
(365)(2)
0:045
V365 (2) = 1+ ($5; 000) = $5; 470:84:
365
1.2 Growth Rates 3
As we compound more and more frequently, we arrive at the expression for continuous
compounding:
tn
R
Vc n ( ) = lim
t !1 1+
t
P:
We can make this much more tractable by using the fact that:
x
1
e = lim
x!1 1+
x
;
where e is Eulers constant. This gives us the following formula for continuous discount-
ing:
tn " (t=R) #Rn
R 1
(1.3) Vc n
t!1
( ) = lim 1+
t
P = lim
(t=R)!1 1+
(t=R)
P = eRn P:
We return to our example one last time, this time assuming continuous compounding.
After two years, the value of the investment will be:
Vc (2) = e(0:045)(2) ($5; 000) = $5; 470:87:
Again, notice how throughout these examples the value of the investment is greater the
more often the interest compounds. Continuous compounding results in the highest value,
but the returns to more-frequent compounding fall off fairly quickly. For example, the
value is almost the same under daily versus continuous discounting.
Economists are often interested in the growth rates of economic variables. You might read,
Real Gross Domestic Product grew at a 2.3% annual rate this quarter or Ination is 4%
or The worlds population is growing 20% every decade. Each of these statements deals
with a growth rate.
An interest rate is just the growth rate of the value of an asset, and all the terminology
and formulae from the previous section apply to growth rates generally. For example, we
can calculate simple annual growth rates and annual growth rates that are compounded
annually or continuously.
Consider the following values for the Gross Domestic Product (GDP) of a hypothetical
country:
Year GDP
1991 $100,000,000
1992 $130,000,000
1993 $135,000,000
4 Preliminaries
The growth rate of GDP is just the interest rate that GDP would have had to earn if it were
a xed-income investment.
For example, the simple rate of growth of GDP between 1992 and 1993 is given by R in
equation (1.1). Starting GDP is P , ending GDP is Vs (n), and n is one year. Plugging all the
numbers in, we get:
As another example, to calculate the annual rate of growth of GDP, compounded annually,
between 1991 and 1993, we use equation (1.2). Starting GDP is P , ending GDP is Va (n), and
n is two years. This gives us:
Economists generally prefer to use continuous compounding, for two reasons. First, un-
der continuous compounding, computing the growth rate between two values of a series
requires nothing more than taking the difference of their natural logarithms, as above.
This property is useful when graphing series. For example, consider some series that is
given by V (n) = V0 e0:08n , which is depicted in Figure 1.1. By the equations above, we know
that this series grows at an 8% continuous rate. Figure 1.2 depicts the natural logarithm of
the same series, i.e., ln[V (n)] = ln(V0 ) + 0:08n. From the equation, you can see that this new
series is linear in n, and the slope (0.08) gives the growth rate. Whenever Barro labels the
vertical axis of a graph with Proportionate scale, he has graphed the natural logarithm
of the underlying series. For an example, see Barros Figure 1.1.
The second reason economists prefer continuous growth rates is that they have the follow-
ing desirable property: if you compute the year-by-year continuous growth rates of a series
and then take the average of those rates, the result is equal to the continuous growth rate
over the entire interval.
For example, consider the hypothetical GDP numbers from above: $100K , $130K , and
$135K . The continuous growth rate between the rst two is: ln($130K ) ln($100K ). The
continuous growth rate between the second two is: ln($135K ) ln($130K ). The average of
these two is:
ln($135K ) ln($130K ) + ln($130K ) ln($100K )
:
2
Exercises 5
8 2
ln[V(n)]
V(n)
4 1
0 0
0
10
15
20
25
10
15
20
25
Year (n) Year (n)
The two ln($130K ) terms cancel, leaving exactly the formula for the continuous growth
rate between the rst and third values, as we derived above.
If we carry out the same exercise under simple growth or annually compounded growth,
we will nd that the average of the individual growth rates will not equal the overall
growth rate. For example, if GDP grows by 8% this year and 4% next year, both calcu-
lated using annual compounding, then the two-year growth rate will not be 6%. (You
should verify that it will actually be 5.98%.) On the other hand, if the 8% and 4% numbers
were calculated using continuous compounding, then the continuous growth rate over the
two-year period would be 6%.
Exercises
Variable Denition
P Principal (amount invested)
R Nominal interest rate
n Number of years invested
( )
Vs n Value after n years under simple interest
Va (n) Value after n years under annual compounding
Vt (n) Value after n years when compounded t times per
year
( )
Vc n Value after n years under continuous compound-
ing
V0 Initial value of the investment
What is the growth rate of the CPI between June 1996 and September 1996? (Use a contin-
uous growth rate and annualize your answer.)
for half our current forests to be cleared? (Use annual compounding and solve for the
fewest number of whole years.)
1. What was the annual growth rate of population between 1700 and 1800? (Use con-
tinuous compounding.)
2. Suppose that the human race began with Adam and Eve and that the annual growth
rate between 1700 and 1800 prevailed in all years prior to 1700. About when must it
have been that Adam and Eve were evicted from the Garden of Eden? (Hint: What
was the population in that year?)
1. If these two growth rates remain constant at their 1965-84 levels, in what year will
per capita real income be the same in these two countries? (Again, use annual com-
pounding, and use hundredths of a year.)
2. What will be the common per capita real income of these two countries at that date?