Financing Health Improvements in India
Financing Health Improvements in India
Financing Health Improvements in India
Financing Health
Improvements In India
Resources should be focused tightly on interventions that are of
importance to the health and financial protection of the poor.
by Anil B. Deolalikar, Dean T. Jamison, Prabhat Jha, and Ramanan
Laxminarayan
ABSTRACT: India faces major challenges in sustaining the health gains achieved in the
better-performing states and ensuring that the lagging states catch up with the rest of the
country. In this paper we examine the current status of health financing in India, as well as
alternatives for realizing maximal health gains for the incremental spending. A principal
conclusion is that public expenditures of an additional US$6–US$7 per person per year
(about 1 percent of gross domestic product) would, if focused on about sixteen key inter-
ventions, provide universal access to those interventions and have a favorable affect on
population health. [Health Affairs 27, no. 4 (2008): 978–990; 10.1377/hlthaff.27.4.978]
I
n r e s p o n s e to t h e c h a l l e n g e o f sustaining the health gains in better-
performing states and ensuring that lagging states catch up with the rest of the
country, the Indian government has launched the National Rural Health Mis-
sion (NRHM). A central element of that effort is to increase public spending on
health from the current 1.1 percent of gross domestic product (GDP) to roughly
2–3 percent within five years. The NRHM focuses on rural areas, especially in the
eighteen states with weak health outcomes and infrastructure, including nine
particularly disadvantaged states referred to (using Government of India termi-
nology) as the Empowered Action Group, or EAG states.1
In this paper we examine the current status and future prospects of health fi-
nancing in India. Much has been written on this issue; we synthesize what is
known, draw attention to the benefits of public health spending, analyze why
public spending has improved health outcomes in some regions more than in oth-
ers, and apply lessons from the Disease Control Priorities Project–India (DCPP-
Anil Deolalikar is a professor of economics in the Department of Economics, University of California, Riverside.
Dean Jamison is the T & G Angelopoulos Visiting Professor of Public Health and International Development,
Kennedy School of Government and School of Public Health, Harvard University; he is located in Bethesda,
Maryland. Prabhat Jha is a professor in the Centre for Global Health Research and St. Michael’s Hospital, in
Toronto, Ontario. Ramanan Laxminarayan ([email protected]) is a senior fellow at Resources for the Future in
Washington, D.C., and a visiting scholar at the Princeton Environment Institute, Princeton University, in
Princeton, New Jersey.
978 J u l y /A u g u s t 2 0 0 8
DOI 10.1377/hlthaff.27.4.978 ©2008 Project HOPE–The People-to-People Health Foundation, Inc.
Fi nanc i ng H e alth
India) so that the resources made available by the NRHM can be applied cost-
effectively.2
The large health and institutional disparities between EAG and non-EAG
states create different financing challenges. In EAG states, such as Bihar, Madhya
Pradesh, Orissa, Rajasthan, and Uttar Pradesh, which together account for 45 per-
cent of India’s population, the health challenge is primarily high levels of infant
and child mortality and child malnutrition. In non-EAG states, such as Kerala,
Tamil Nadu, and Gujarat, noncommunicable diseases are fast replacing infectious
diseases and malnutrition as the leading causes of morbidity and mortality. We fo-
cus on the EAG states.
Health systems have two broad objectives: to improve the level (and distribu-
tion) of health outcomes, and to provide people with financial protection, from
both unanticipated high health spending and income loss. They generally have
two types of resources: financial and system capacity. The latter refers to the peo-
ple, infrastructure, and procedures available at a point in time. Some elements of
capacity cannot be increased with financial resources in the short run, so capacity
constraints can exist alongside financial ones.
The DCPP-India has collected quantitative information on the financial costs of
achieving health gains using different interventions.3 Financial protection is typi-
cally discussed without a sense of budget constraints or the cost-effectiveness of
alternative instruments for acquiring it. Nonfinancial capacity constraints are of-
ten ignored. Here we attempt, in a preliminary way, to address both shortcomings.
We review India’s progress and challenges in health, summarize the current status
of state and central government health spending, evaluate criteria for an interven-
tion package for the NRHM, and discuss the mechanics of financing these health
interventions and the implications for center-state financial responsibilities.
H E A L T H A F F A I R S ~ Vo l u m e 2 7 , N u m b e r 4 979
Pay i ng Fo r Car e
Improvements in health have not been shared equally.6 Infant mortality de-
clined by 68 percent (from 37 to 12 per 1,000) in Kerala but by only 52 percent in
Uttar Pradesh (from 150 to 72) between 1981 and 2004. Uttar Pradesh alone con-
tributes one-quarter of all infant deaths in the country and, along with Madhya
Pradesh, Bihar, and Rajasthan, accounts for slightly more than half of the total.
During 1994–1999, just 10 percent of India’s 602 districts accounted for nearly 30
percent of all infant deaths, and 23 percent of the districts accounted for approxi-
mately half of the total.7 Furthermore, there are variations across social groups.
Scheduled Tribes have an under-five mortality rate of 117 deaths per 1,000 live births,
and Scheduled Castes have a rate of 108, compared with an all-India rate of 93.8
An important policy question is whether the tremendous growth of the Indian
economy will, by itself, improve health outcomes. Recent evidence suggests that
the association between health outcomes and per capita GDP, which was rela-
tively strong in the 1980s, has weakened.9 If economic growth alone is unlikely to
bring about major health improvements, there is a need for continuing—and even
greater—public action in health.10
980 J u l y /A u g u s t 2 0 0 8
Fi nanc i ng H e alth
H E A L T H A F F A I R S ~ Vo l u m e 2 7 , N u m b e r 4 981
Pay i ng Fo r Car e
EXHIBIT 1
Total (Public Plus Private) Per Capita Spending On Health In India, In Selected States,
2001–02
Assam (69% private)
Orissa (77% private)
Rajasthan (70% private)
Karnataka (71% private)
West Bengal (77% private)
Bihar (88% private)
Gujarat (82% private)
Tamil Nadu (76% private)
Madhya Pradesh (85% private)
Maharashtra (81% private)
Sikkim (20% private)
Andhra Pradesh (83% private)
Delhi (59% private)
Jammu and Kashmir (75% private)
Uttar Pradesh (93% private)
Himachal Pradesh (62% private)
Punjab (83% private)
Haryana (90% private)
Kerala (87% private)
EXHIBIT 2
Public Spending On Health In India, Per Person, As A Percentage Of Gross State
Domestic Product, In Selected States, 2001–02
Himachal Pradesh
Jammu and Kashmir
Bihar
Assam
Rajasthan
Orissa
Kerala
Karnataka
Madhya Pradesh
West Bengal
Andhra Pradesh
Punjab
Tamil Nadu
Uttar Pradesh
Maharashtra
Gujarat
Haryana
982 J u l y /A u g u s t 2 0 0 8
Fi nanc i ng H e alth
Private spending on health is greater in states that have relatively low public
spending on health.14 Because such spending is very low in India, households gen-
erally finance health expenses themselves. The high out-of-pocket spending on
health care is an important cause of impoverishment.15 Therefore, increasing pub-
lic spending on health could directly help the poor and enhance welfare.
n Benefits of increased availability of public resources. Empirical studies on
the link between public health spending and health outcomes are inconclusive.
Some have observed a strong inverse association between public spending on health
and infant mortality; others have found no significant effect.16 Still others have found
that the inverse association between child mortality and public spending on health
is stronger for the poor than for the nonpoor.17 An econometric study based on
twenty years of data found that public spending on health has larger effects in the
EAG states than in the non-EAG states, since the high-mortality EAG states have
very low coverage—and hence much room for expansion—of low-cost child sur-
vival interventions such as immunization and oral rehydration therapy.18 In the low-
mortality non-EAG states, these basic interventions are already widespread, and
more infant mortality occurs in the first month of life. This neonatal mortality re-
quires more-costly interventions, such as deliveries in medical institutions and
postdelivery and emergency hospital-based care.
Public spending on health can be more cost-effective than private spending. In
the largely unregulated private sector, especially in the rural areas of EAG states,
health workers have an incentive to prescribe more-costly treatments instead of
the standard, recommended drug regimens, since they both prescribe and sell
drugs, as in the case of TB treatment.19
The benefits of increased public spending on health are not restricted to health
outcomes; such spending protects both poor and nonpoor households from the fi-
nancial impact of health shocks. Income redistribution to those most likely to be
impoverished by out-of-pocket payments for health is important in a country
with such a high incidence of catastrophic health payments.20 Nearly 25 percent of
Indian households report spending 5 percent or more of their total annual outlays
on out-of-pocket health payments; for 10 percent of households, out-of-pocket
health payments exceed 10 percent of total outlays.21
H E A L T H A F F A I R S ~ Vo l u m e 2 7 , N u m b e r 4 983
Pay i ng Fo r Car e
EXHIBIT 3
Expenditure On The National Rural Health Mission (NRHM) In India, By Activity,
2005–2008
Total—National Disease Control Programs 649 10.7 741 10.3 884 9.0
SOURCE: Ministry of Finance, Government of India, Union Budget 2005–06, 2006–07, and 2007–08.
NOTE: All rupees are in nominal terms.
tional Disease Control Programs have taken up 10 percent. The remaining 20 per-
cent is spread across several activities, including Information, Education, and
Communication (IEC); research; reproductive and child health; administration;
and, surprisingly, urban family welfare services.
The NRHM should focus on a smaller subset of interventions that can be fi-
nanced by the government and scaled up effectively, for several reasons.22 First,
public spending improves health typically through a few interventions. Although
the individual ranking by burden may differ slightly, similar health conditions be-
set both EAG and non-EAG states. Second, formulating a minimum package can
be more effective than paying for a large range of interventions without regard to
joint costs or shared inputs.23 Such packages have other advantages: simplifying
984 J u l y /A u g u s t 2 0 0 8
Fi nanc i ng H e alth
H E A L T H A F F A I R S ~ Vo l u m e 2 7 , N u m b e r 4 985
Pay i ng Fo r Car e
EXHIBIT 4
Share Of Central Grants In Total Government (Revenue) Spending On Health, By
Function, In Selected States, India, 1991–1992 And 1999–2000
Percent 1991–1992 1999–2000 Andhra Pradesh
60 Assam
Orissa
45 Rajasthan
Tamil Nadu
30 West Bengal
15
0
Public health and Total government Public health and Total government
family welfare health spending family welfare health spending
SOURCE: Various state budget demand documents for 1991–1992 and 1999–2000.
986 J u l y /A u g u s t 2 0 0 8
Fi nanc i ng H e alth
grants could induce states to spend more of their own resources on those activi-
ties.34 Although matching grants could create incentives for states to increase their
absolute and relative spending on communicable disease control and preventive
activities, unless carefully designed, they could disadvantage the poor high-
mortality states that cannot greatly increase their public health spending.
“Outcome budgeting” is another way to motivate states to perform better and
convert financial outlays into outcomes with measurable targets. The idea—revo-
lutionary by Government of India standards—is for ministries and state govern-
ments to be accountable for their budget allocations and to justify them by their
performance. Finance minister P. Chidambaram presented the first outcome-
contingent budget in Parliament on 25 August 2005. The Registrar-General of In-
dia can already measure health outcomes objectively and can build on plans for
district-level surveys and the ongoing Million Death Study.35
H E A L T H A F F A I R S ~ Vo l u m e 2 7 , N u m b e r 4 987
Pay i ng Fo r Car e
Government of India (and external donors) and, hence, a substantial increase in its
share in financing elementary education. Recognizing the states’ limited fiscal ca-
pacity, the center provided the bulk of incremental education funding in SSA. For
the poorer states, the percentage from the center will need to be higher still, and per-
formance-based grants may also require technical assistance from the center.
n Use centrally sponsored schemes where they are now working. Although
funding for many NRHM interventions, particularly clinical interventions, will
come from states (or flow through states from federal matching grants), several na-
tional programs already deliver immunizations, TB treatment, and AIDS prevention.
For these interventions, existing organizational and financial structures should re-
ceive additional funding and become the vehicles for NRHM implementation. To-
bacco control via higher central taxation and regulation can also avoid strain on
state health infrastructures.37
n Improve information availability and local oversight. An important way to
improve public-sector delivery performance is to generate and distribute timely, lo-
cally specific information on financial transfers, effective coverage of interventions,
and health outcomes. The Registrar-General is developing capacity for this. PRIs
and service providers should be encouraged to use this information to increase ac-
countability for performance and to monitor progress in improving it.
n Explore options for improving the quality of publicly financed services.
Increasing public-sector spending on health in India is crucial, but so is improving
the quality of additional spending. The NRHM should focus on the reason for the
low use of primary health facilities in the EAG states—such as the unavailability of
medicines and other inputs and poor incentives for personnel to report for work and
be held accountable for performance. Although some problems can respond to in-
creased finance, others must be addressed by specific capacity-building efforts, in-
cluding, initially, greater central government involvement in implementation in
weaker states. It is important to bear in mind that public finance of services need
not entail public delivery. The private and NGO sectors may each have an important
role in delivering some NRHM-financed services.
To conclude, we recommend focusing resources tightly on interventions of im-
portance to the health and financial protection of the poor. Initially, in the poorest
states and districts, all of these services would be publicly financed, because se-
lecting the poor for fee exemptions is difficult or very costly, whereas broad access
engenders political support.
Preparation of this paper was supported by the Health Financing Task Force at the Brookings Institution and the
Disease Control Priorities Project–India. In revising this paper, the authors benefited from comments by
participants at a workshop in New Delhi on 8 January 2007 (chaired by Rajiv Misra) and from comments by Anna
Abreu, Peter Berman, David de Ferranti, Meenakshi Datta Ghosh, Amanda Glassman, Charles Griffin, Satish
Jha, Rajiv Misra, William Savedoff, Julian Schweitzer, Paramita Sudharto, and Viroj Tangcharoensathien. Paolo
Belli provided detailed input, and Jeffrey Chow and Sarah Darley provided valuable research support.
988 J u l y /A u g u s t 2 0 0 8
Fi nanc i ng H e alth
NOTES
1. Empowered Action Group (EAG) states designated by the Government of India are Bihar, Chattisgarh,
Jharkhand, Madhya Pradesh, Orissa, Rajasthan, Uttar Pradesh, and Uttaranchal. The eighteen focus states
include the EAG states as well as Arunachal Pradesh, Assam, Himachal Pradesh, Jammu and Kashmir,
Manipur, Mizoram, Meghalaya, Nagaland, Sikkim, and Tripura.
2. The Disease Control Priorities Project–India follows on related but more global efforts. See D.T. Jamison et
al., eds., Disease Control Priorities in Developing Countries, 2d ed. (Oxford and New York: Oxford University
Press, 2006). See also R. Laxminarayan et al., “Advancement of Global Health: Key Messages from the Dis-
ease Control Priorities Project,” Lancet 367, no. 9517 (2006): 1193–1208.
3. The DCPP-India report, “Choosing Health: An Opportunity for India,” preliminary materials from a work-
shop in January 2007, is available from the Centre for Global Health Research at http://www.cghr.org/
dcpp.htm (accessed 20 March 2008).
4. D.E. Bloom et al., “Why Has China’s Economy Taken Off Faster than India’s?” Working Paper (Boston:
Harvard School of Public Health, 2006).
5. In Sri Lanka, infant mortality declined from 18 deaths per 1,000 live births in 1991 to 13 in 2001—a rate of
decline that exceeded the rates experienced by both Bangladesh and Nepal.
6. P. Jha, “Avoidable Mortality in India: Past Progress and Future Prospects,” National Medical Journal of India 15,
no. 1 Supp. (2002): 32–36.
7. Note that these data are merely indicative, since the NFHS data are not representative at the level of districts.
8. Scheduled Castes (SCs) and Scheduled Tribes (STs) are Indian communities that are explicitly recognized
by the Constitution of India as requiring special support to overcome centuries of discrimination.
9. A.B. Deolalikar, Attaining the Millennium Development Goals in India: Reducing Infant Mortality, Child Malnutrition,
Gender Disparities, and Hunger-Poverty and Increasing School Enrollment and Completion? (New Delhi: Oxford Uni-
versity Press, 2005).
10. T.W. Croghan, “Road Less Traveled: Four Developing Countries Blaze New Trails to Better Health,” RAND
Review 30, no. 3 (2006): 26–30.
11. Of course, public spending on health will reduce private spending by the poor only if it actually improves
service delivery to the poor. Also, it is assumed that public spending is not financed out of taxes, which fall
disproportionately on the poor.
12. Note that external assistance does constitute a sizable share of national disease control programs for TB,
HIV/AIDS, and malaria.
13. By “public spending on health,” we mean spending by the central and state governments on hospitals and
dispensaries; medical education, training, and research; public health; family welfare (family planning);
and the National Rural Health Mission (NRHM). It excludes government spending on the health care of
its own employees, including those in Railways and Defense.
14. Deolalikar, Attaining the Millennium Development Goals.
15. Nearly 25 percent of Indian households report spending 5 percent or more of their total annual expendi-
tures on out-of-pocket health payments, representing among the highest incidences of catastrophic health
payments in Asia. See E. van Doorslaer et al., “Effect of Payments for Health Care on Poverty Estimates in
Eleven Countries in Asia: An Analysis of Household Survey Data,” Lancet 368, no. 9544 (2006): 1357–1364.
16. See, for example, S. Anand and M. Ravallion, “Human Development in Poor Countries: On the Role of Pri-
vate Incomes and Public Services,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 7, no. 1 (1993): 113–150; B. Bidani and M.
Ravallion, Decomposing Social Indicators Using Distributional Data (Washington: World Bank, 1995); D. Filmer
and L. Pritchett, “The Impact of Public Spending on Health: Does Money Matter?” Social Science and Medicine
49, no. 10 (1999): 1309–1323; and V. Swaroop and A.S. Rajkumar, Public Spending and Outcomes: Does Governance
Matter? (Washington: World Bank, 2002). Rajkumar and Swaroop find that public spending on health is
significantly associated with child and infant mortality reduction, but only for countries with good gover-
nance (as measured by a corruption index and a variable reflecting the “quality of the bureaucracy”).
17. S. Gupta et al., Does Higher Government Spending Buy Better Results in Education and Health Care? (Washington: In-
ternational Monetary Fund, 1999). These authors find that the association between child deaths and pub-
lic spending on health is twice as strong for the poor as for the nonpoor.
18. R. Duggal, Cost of Health Care: A Household Survey in an Indian District (Bombay: Foundation for Research in
Community Health, 1989).
19. M. Uplekar, “Implications of Prescribing Patterns in Private Doctors in the Treatment of Pulmonary Tu-
H E A L T H A F F A I R S ~ Vo l u m e 2 7 , N u m b e r 4 989
Pay i ng Fo r Car e
berculosis in Bombay, India,” Research Paper no. 41 (Cambridge, Mass.: Takemi Program in International
Health, Harvard School of Public Health, 1989); Deolalikar, Attaining the Millennium Development Goals; K. Van
der Veen, “Government and Private Health Care: Two Competing Institutions,” in Managing Rural Develop-
ment: Health and Energy Programmes in India, ed. H. Streefkerk and T.K. Moulik (New Delhi: Sage Publications,
1991); and R. Bhat, “The Private/Public Mix in Health Care in India,” Health Policy and Planning 8, no. 1 (1993):
43–56.
20. Van Doorslaer et al., “Effect of Payments for Health Care on Poverty Estimates.”
21. Ibid.
22. DCPP-India, “Choosing Health.”
23. J.L. Bobadilla et al., “Design, Content, and Financing of an Essential National Package of Health Services,”
Bulletin of the World Health Organization 72, no. 4 (1994): 653–662.
24. J.F. Finlay et al., “A New Canadian Health Care Initiative in Tanzania,” Canadian Medical Association Journal
153, no. 8 (1995): 1081–1085; and J.L. Bobadilla et al., “National Package of Health Services,” in Macroeconom-
ics and Health: Investing in Health for Economic Development, ed. J. Sachs (Geneva: World Health Organization,
2001).
25. A. Mahal et al., “Who ‘Benefits’ from Public Sector Health Spending in India? Results of a Benefit Inci-
dence Analysis for India,” Background Paper prepared for D.H. Peters et al., Better Health Systems for India’s
Poor: Findings, Analysis, and Options (Washington: World Bank Human Development Network, 2002).
26. A. Gumber, “Burden of Disease and Cost of Ill Health in India: Setting Priorities for Health Interventions
during the Ninth Plan,” Margin 29, no. 2 (1997): 133–172.
27. The related issue of providing incentives to health care workers to work in remote areas is addressed in an-
other paper in this series.
28. A.B. Deolalikar, D.T. Jamison, and R. Laxminarayan, “India’s Health Initiative: Financing Issues and Op-
tions,” Discussion Paper no. 07-48 (Washington: Resources for the Future, October 2007).
29. There has been considerable devolution of health service delivery to panchayati raj institutions (PRIs) in
Karnataka and Kerala. In Kerala, local health workers are not only employed by local governments but also
accountable to them. In other states, PRIs receive funds to pay district- and lower-level health workers’
salaries but have little control in their hiring or termination.
30. These data are only broadly indicative, since the “public health and family welfare” category includes sev-
eral expenditures (for example, health education and drug control) unrelated to public health and ex-
cludes expenditures on water and sanitation by the PRIs. In some states, health workers’ salaries account
for nearly 90 percent of government health expenditure.
31. Deolalikar, Attaining the Millennium Development Goals; and R. Duggal, “Healthcare in India: Changing the Fi-
nancing Strategy,” Social Policy and Administration 41, no. 4 (2007): 386–394.
32. DCPP-India, “Choosing Health.”
33. Mahal et al., Who ‘Benefits’ from Public Sector Health Spending in India?”; and A. Mahal et al., “The Poor
and Health Service Use in India,” Background Paper prepared for Peters et al., Better Health Systems for India’s
Poor.
34. Some of the disease control programs are partially funded on matching grant basis, but most are fully
funded by the central government. A useful example is the Local Government Performance Program
(LGPP) in the Philippines. See M. Palabrica-Costello, N. Ogena, and A.N. Herrin, “Policy and Program Im-
plications of the Matching Grants Program in the Philippines” (Manila: Population Council, 2003).
35. Registrar-General of India and Centre for Global Health Research, “Causes of Death in India: Special Sur-
vey of Deaths 2001–3” (New Delhi: Registrar-General, 2007); and P. Jha et al., “Prospective Study of One
Million Deaths in India: Rationale, Design, and Validation Results,” PLoS Medicine 3, no. 2 (2006): e18.
36. J. Chow, S. Darley, and R. Laxminarayan, “Cost-Effectiveness of Disease Interventions in India,” Discussion
Paper no. 07-53 (Washington: Resources for the Future, December 2007).
37. R. John, “Price Elasticity Estimates for Tobacco Products in India,” Health Policy and Planning 23, no. 3 (2008):
200–209.
990 J u l y /A u g u s t 2 0 0 8