Micro1 2014 Texbrno1
Micro1 2014 Texbrno1
Micro1 2014 Texbrno1
c
Leopold Sogner
November, 2014
Course Outline (1)
Microeconomics
Learning Objectives:
1
Course Outline (2)
Microeconomics
Literature:
Supplementary Literature:
Gollier C., The Economics of Risk and Time, Mit Press, 2004.
Supplementary Literature:
3
Course Outline (4)
Microeconomics
3. General Equilibrium:
Introduction, Walrasian equilibrium (GR 12.A-D).
The Edgeworth box (GR 12.E).
One Consumer-one producer economy.
General vs. partial equilibrium.
Welfare theorems (GR 13).
5
Course Outline (6)
Microeconomics
6
Consumer Theory (1)
Rationality (1)
Microeconomics
7
Consumer Theory (1)
Rationality (2)
Microeconomics
8
Consumer Theory 1
Rationality (3)
Microeconomics
9
Consumer Theory 1
Rationality (4)
Microeconomics
13
Consumer Theory 1
Remark: Partial Order (3)
Microeconomics
14
Consumer Theory 1
Rationality (6)
Microeconomics
17
Consumer Theory 2
Budget Set (1)
Microeconomics
B X.
18
Consumer Theory 2
Budget Set (2)
Microeconomics
19
Consumer Theory 2
Competitive Budgets (1)
Microeconomics
p x = p1x1 + + pLxL M.
20
Consumer Theory 2
Competitive Budgets (2)
Microeconomics
21
Consumer Theory 2
Competitive Budgets (3)
Microeconomics
22
Consumer Theory 2
Competitive Budgets (4)
Microeconomics
23
Consumer Theory 2
Demand Functions (1)
Microeconomics
25
Correspondences (2)
Microeconomics
27
Correspondences (4)
Microeconomics
28
Consumer Theory 2
Demand Functions (2)
Microeconomics
30
Consumer Theory 2
Demand Functions (4)
Microeconomics
31
Consumer Theory 2
Demand Functions (5)
Microeconomics
Di (p,M ) M
Definition - Income Elasticity: iw = M Di (p,M ) .
piDi(p, M )
si = ,
M
Pn
where si 0 and i=1 si = 1.
32
Consumer Theory 3
The Axiomatic Approach (1)
Microeconomics
Axioms on preferences.
Walrasian/Marshallian Demand.
33
Consumer Theory 3
The Axiomatic Approach (2)
Microeconomics
34
Consumer Theory 3
The Axiomatic Approach (3)
Microeconomics
35
Consumer Theory 3
The Axiomatic Approach (4)
Microeconomics
36
Consumer Theory 3
The Axiomatic Approach (5)
Microeconomics
Discuss the differences of Axioms 3.A and 3.B (what are their
impacts on indifference sets?), e.g. by means of MWG, Figures
3.B.1 and 3.B.2, page 43.
38
Consumer Theory 3
The Axiomatic Approach (7)
Microeconomics
41
Consumer Theory 3
The Axiomatic Approach (10)
Microeconomics
By this axiom the set (x) and (x) are open sets (the
complement of a closed set is open ...). (x) is the complement
of X\ (x).
42
Consumer Theory 3
The Axiomatic Approach (11)
Microeconomics
43
Consumer Theory 3
The Axiomatic Approach (12)
Microeconomics
44
Consumer Theory 3
Utility Function (1)
Microeconomics
45
Consumer Theory 3
Utility Function (2)
Microeconomics
46
Consumer Theory 3
Utility Function (3)
Microeconomics
47
Consumer Theory 3
Utility Function (4)
Microeconomics
Proof:
48
Consumer Theory 3
Utility Function (5)
Microeconomics
Proof:
49
Consumer Theory 3
Utility Function (6)
Microeconomics
The marginal rate of substitution describes the trade-off between goods 1 and
2 that marginally keep the consumer indifferent at a given consumption bundle
(x1, x2). That is, the amount of good 2 the consumer has to obtain for
giving up one unit of good 1 while staying at the same utility level.
51
Consumer Theory 3
Utility Function (8)
Microeconomics
53
Consumer Theory 3
Consumers Problem (1)
Microeconomics
54
Consumer Theory 3
Consumers Problem (2)
Microeconomics
dM = p1dx1 + p2dx2 = 0
dx2 p1
= with other prices constant .
dx1 p2
Budget line with two goods; slope p1/p2. See Figure 2.D.1,
page 21, MWG.
55
Consumer Theory 3
Consumers Problem (3)
Microeconomics
56
Consumer Theory 3
Consumers Problem (4)
Microeconomics
57
Consumer Theory 3
Consumers Problem (5)
Microeconomics
L(x, ) = u(x) + (M p x)
L u(x)
= pi 0
xi xi
L
xi = 0
xi
L
= M px0
L
= 0
58
Consumer Theory 3
Consumers Problem (6)
Microeconomics
59
Consumer Theory 3
Consumers Problem (7)
Microeconomics
2
D u(x) u(x)
,
u(x)> 0
61
Consumer Theory 3
Consumers Problem (9)
Microeconomics
Proof:
62
Consumer Theory 3
Consumers Problem (10)
Microeconomics
Proof:
63
Consumer Theory 3
Consumers Problem (11)
Microeconomics
Proof:
64
Consumer Theory 3
Consumers Problem (12)
Microeconomics
Proof:
Now u(x ) > min{u(x), u(y)}, also for x, y. Therefore the pair
x, y cannot solve the UMP. Therefore, D(p, M ) has to be single
valued.
65
Consumer Theory 3
Offer Curves and Net Demand (1)
Microeconomics
L
X L
X
px= plxl plxl = p x
l=1 l=1
66
Consumer Theory 3
Offer Curves and Net Demand (2)
Microeconomics
To plot the budget line for the L = 2 good case, we observe that
(see [GR, Figure, 2.17, p. 38]):
The point x = (x1, x2) be consumed for all price vectors p,
p 0.
If the (relative) price changes, the budget line is rotated
around x.
Let p0 = p, > 0. Then the nominal value of x changes to
W , however the budget line is not affected.
67
Consumer Theory 3
Offer Curves and Net Demand (3)
Microeconomics
From x and the offer curve OC(p, x) we are able to obtain the
net demand D(p, x) = OC(p, x) x.
Then U
\ M P can be rewritten as follows:
69
Consumer Theory 4
Duality
Microeconomics
70
Consumer Theory 4
Indirect Utility (1)
Microeconomics
72
Consumer Theory 4
Indirect Utility (3)
Microeconomics
73
Consumer Theory 4
Indirect Utility (4)
Microeconomics
Proof:
74
Consumer Theory 4
Indirect Utility (5)
Microeconomics
Proof:
Proof:
Proof:
77
Consumer Theory 4
Indirect Utility (8)
Microeconomics
Proof:
78
Consumer Theory 4
Indirect Utility (9)
Microeconomics
Proof:
p1 x > M1 p2 x > M2
81
Consumer Theory 4
Expenditure Function (2)
Microeconomics
83
Consumer Theory 4
Expenditure Function (5)
Microeconomics
Proof:
84
Consumer Theory 4
Expenditure Function (6)
Microeconomics
Proof:
Suppose that h1 H(p, u1) and h2 H(p, u2) solve the EMP
for u2 and u1, but m(p, u2) m(p, u1). We show that this result
in a contradiction. I.e. u2 > u1 but 0 p h2 p h1.
85
Consumer Theory 4
Expenditure Function (7)
Microeconomics
Proof:
L(x, ) = p x + (u u(x)) .
86
Consumer Theory 4
Expenditure Function (8)
Microeconomics
Proof:
Proof:
88
Consumer Theory 4
Expenditure Function (10)
Microeconomics
Proof:
89
Consumer Theory 4
Expenditure Function (11)
Microeconomics
Proof:
Multiplying the first term with and the second with 1 and
taking the sum results in p1x1 + (1 )p2x2 p x .
90
Consumer Theory 4
Expenditure Function (12)
Microeconomics
Proof:
91
Consumer Theory 4
Hicksian Demand (1)
Microeconomics
92
Consumer Theory 4
Hicksian Demand (2)
Microeconomics
Proof:
93
Consumer Theory 4
Expenditure vs. Indirect Utility (1)
Microeconomics
94
Consumer Theory 4
Expenditure vs. Indirect Utility (2)
Microeconomics
95
Consumer Theory 4
Expenditure vs. Indirect Utility (3)
Microeconomics
Proof:
96
Consumer Theory 4
Expenditure vs. Indirect Utility (4)
Microeconomics
Proof:
98
Consumer Theory 4
Hicksian Demand (4)
Microeconomics
Proof:
99
Consumer Theory 4
Shephards Lemma (1)
Microeconomics
100
Consumer Theory 4
Shephards Lemma (2)
Microeconomics
101
Consumer Theory 4
Shephards Lemma (3)
Microeconomics
L u(x)
= pi 0
xi xi
L
xi = 0
xi
L
= u u(x) 0
L
= 0
102
Consumer Theory 4
Shephards Lemma (4)
Microeconomics
m(p, u) L(x, u)
= = hl(p, u)
pl pl
for l = 1, . . . , L.
103
Consumer Theory 4
Shephards Lemma (5)
Microeconomics
Proof:
104
Consumer Theory 4
Expenditure F. and Hicksian Demand (1)
Microeconomics
105
Consumer Theory 4
Expenditure F. and Hicksian Demand (2)
Microeconomics
Proof:
L
X H(p, u)
pl = rH(p, u).
pl
l=1
106
Consumer Theory 4
Walrasian vs. Hicksian Demand (1)
Microeconomics
107
Consumer Theory 4
Walrasian vs. Hicksian Demand (2)
Microeconomics
108
Consumer Theory 4
Walrasian vs. Hicksian Demand (3)
Microeconomics
The residual between the total effect and the substitution effect
is the income effect.
109
Consumer Theory 4
Walrasian vs. Hicksian Demand (4)
Microeconomics
110
Consumer Theory 4
Walrasian vs. Hicksian Demand (5)
Microeconomics
111
Consumer Theory 4
Walrasian vs. Hicksian Demand (6)
Microeconomics
Equivalently:
112
Consumer Theory 4
Walrasian vs. Hicksian Demand (7)
Microeconomics
Proof:
113
Consumer Theory 4
Walrasian vs. Hicksian Demand (8)
Microeconomics
Proof:
m(p,u)
Third: Shephards Lemma tells us that pj = Hj (p, u), this
gives
114
Consumer Theory 4
Walrasian vs. Hicksian Demand (9)
Microeconomics
Proof:
115
Consumer Theory 4
Walrasian vs. Hicksian Demand (10)
Microeconomics
D1 (p,M ) D1 (p,M ) D1 (p,M ) D1 (p,M )
p1 + D 1 (p, M ) M pL + DL (p, M ) M
S(p, M ) :=
... ... ...
D (p,M ) DL (p,M ) DL (p,M ) DL (p,M )
L + D (p, M ) + DL (p, M )
p 1 M pL M
1
116
Consumer Theory 4
Walrasian vs. Hicksian Demand (11)
Microeconomics
117
Consumer Theory 4
Walrasian vs. Hicksian Demand (12)
Microeconomics
Proof:
118
Consumer Theory 4
Roys Identity (1)
Microeconomics
1
D(p, M ) = pv(p, M ),
w v(p, M )
i.e.
v(p, M )/pl
Dl(p, M ) = .
v(p, M )/M
119
Consumer Theory 4
Roys Identity (1)
Microeconomics
Proof:
v(p, M ) L(x, )
= = xl , l = 1, . . . , L.
pl pl
v(p, M ) L(x, )
= = .
M M
120
Consumer Theory 2
Indirect Utility (11)
Microeconomics
Proof:
v(p, M ) v(p, M )
= Dl
pl M
such that
v(p, M )/pl
= Dl(p, M ).
v(p, M )/M
122
Theorem of the Maximum (1)
Microeconomics
123
Duality Theorem (1)
Microeconomics
124
Duality Theorem (2)
Microeconomics
125
Duality Theorem (3)
Microeconomics
126
Duality Theorem (4)
Microeconomics
For any closed (but not necessarily convex) set K we can define
the support function of K:
127
Duality Theorem (5)
Microeconomics
128
Consumer Theory 5
Welfare Analysis (1)
Microeconomics
Measurement of Welfare
129
Consumer Theory 5
Welfare Analysis (2)
Microeconomics
130
Consumer Theory 5
Welfare Analysis (3)
Microeconomics
Strong criterion.
131
Consumer Theory 5
Consumer Welfare Analysis (1)
Microeconomics
132
Consumer Theory 5
Consumer Welfare Analysis (2)
Microeconomics
133
Consumer Theory 5
Consumer Welfare Analysis (3)
Microeconomics
134
Consumer Theory 5
Consumer Welfare Analysis (4)
Microeconomics
135
Consumer Theory 5
Consumer Welfare Analysis (5)
Microeconomics
Discuss MWG, Figure 3.1.2, page 82; , [GR, Figure 3.6, p. 59]. if
p1 falls then the consumer is prepared to pay the amount CV ,
i.e. CV > 0.
136
Consumer Theory 5
Consumer Welfare Analysis (6)
Microeconomics
Suppose the only p1 changes, then p01 6= p11 and p0l = p1l for
l 2. With M = m(p0, u0) = m(p1, u1) and
h1(p, u) = m(p, u)/p1 we get
Z p01
EV (p0, p1, M ) = h1((p1, p), u1)dp1
p11
Z p01
CV (p0, p1, M ) = h1((p1, p), u0)dp1
p11
137
Consumer Theory 5
Consumer Welfare Analysis (7)
Microeconomics
Discuss these integrals - MWG, Figure 3.1.3, page 83; [GR, Figure 3.6, p. 59].
Here the following case is considered. p0 and p1 are L dimensional price
vectors. Only the first component p1 is changed. The other prices
p := (p2, . . . , pL) are kept constant. M is constant as well.
EV, CV increase if utility increases and vice versa.
If x1 is a normal good, then the slope of the Walrasian demand function
x1(p, M ) is smaller than the slopes of h1(p, .) (in absolute terms).
We get EV (p0, p1, M ) > CV (p0, p1, M ) if the good is normal (in
absolute value), the converse is true for inferior goods.
EV (p0, p1, M ) = CV (p0, p1, M ) with zero income effect for good 2. This
is the case with quasilinear preferences for good two (see [D 3.B.7]).
138
Consumer Theory 5
Consumer Welfare Analysis (8)
Microeconomics
Definition - Marshallian
R Consumer Surplus:
M CSl(p, M ) = p xl((pl, p), M )dpl
139
Consumer Theory 5
Area Variation Measure (1)
Microeconomics
141
Consumer Theory 5
Partial Information (2)
Microeconomics
Proof:
142
Consumer Theory 5
Partial Information (3)
Microeconomics
143
Consumer Theory 5
Partial Information (4)
Microeconomics
Proof:
Proof:
This results in m(p, u0) m(p0, u0) > 0 by the assumption that
(p p0)>pm(p0, u0) > 0 and the fact that
pm(p0, u0) = h(p0, u0) = x(p0, m(p0, u0)).
145
Consumer Theory 5
Partial Information (6)
Microeconomics
146
Production 1
Motivation
Microeconomics
Production
147
Production 1
Firms (1)
Microeconomics
148
Production 1
Production Function (1)
Microeconomics
149
Production 1
Production Function (2)
Microeconomics
150
Production 1
Production Function (3)
Microeconomics
M Pi
M RT Sij (z) =
M Pj
dz M Pi
The slope of the isoquant is given by dzji = M Pj
M Pi
Discuss: M Pj > 0 ( 0) and the concept of technical
efficiency: To remain on the same level of output at least one
input has to be increased if one input factor has been decreased;
see [GR, p. 98] 153
Production 1
Production Function (6)
Microeconomics
154
Production 1
Production Function (7)
Microeconomics
155
Production 1
Production Function (8)
Microeconomics
156
Production 1
Production Function (9)
Microeconomics
157
Production 1
Production Function (10)
Microeconomics
158
Production 1
Production Function (11)
Microeconomics
159
Production 1
Production Possibility Set (1)
Microeconomics
160
Production 1
Production Possibility Set (2)
Microeconomics
161
Production 1
Production Possibility Set (3)
Microeconomics
162
Production 1
Production Possibility Set (4)
Microeconomics
163
Production 1
Production Possibility Set (5)
Microeconomics
164
Production 1
Production Possibility Set (6)
Microeconomics
165
Production 1
Production Possibility Set (7)
Microeconomics
167
Production 1
Production Possibility Set (9)
Microeconomics
168
Production 2
Profits and Cost (1)
Microeconomics
Profit Maximization
Cost minizitation
Price taking
169
Theory of the Firm
Profits and Cost (2)
Microeconomics
Assume that the prices (p1, . . . , pL) are larger than zero and
fixed (price taking assumption).
m
X
p q yq p z z = p q yq pzizi
i=1
.
170
Production 2
Cost Function (1)
Microeconomics
On the other hand side - if the firm is not a price taker in the
output market, we cannot use the profit function, however the
results on the cost function are still valid.
171
Production 2
Cost Function (2)
Microeconomics
172
Production 2
Cost Function (3)
Microeconomics
173
Production 2
Cost Function (4)
Microeconomics
L f (z)
= p zi = pzi M Pi 0
zi zi
L
pzi = 0
zi
L L
= yq f (z) 0 , =0.
174
Production 2
Cost Function (5)
Microeconomics
175
Production 2
Cost Function (6)
Microeconomics
C(pz , yq ) L
= =
yq yq
C(pz ,yq )
Definition - Marginal Cost: LM C(yq ) = yq is called (long run)
marginal cost.
C(p ,y )
z q
Definition - Average Cost: LAC(yq ) = yq is called (long run)
average cost.
Sometimes the dependence on the prices is neglected, therefore the notion
C(yq ), etc.
Discuss the long run cost function, the marginal cost and average cost in
graphical terms. [GR, Figure 6.5, p. 120]
176
Production 2
Cost Function (7)
Microeconomics
178
Theory of the Firm
Cost Function (9)
Microeconomics
If some inputs are fixed, then we derive the so called short run
cost function .
f SC(pz ,yq ,z f )
The short run marginal cost is SM C(pz , yq , z ) = yq ,
SC(pz ,yq ,z f )
the short run average cost is SAC(pz , yq , z f ) = yq .
Discuss the long run cost function, the marginal cost and average
cost in graphical terms.
180
Production 2
Profits - Single Output Case (1)
Microeconomics
182
Production 2
Profits - Single Output Case (3)
Microeconomics
L(yq , z, ) = pq yq pz z + (f (z) yq )
f (z)
The marginal product will be abbreviated by M Pi = zi .
183
Production 2
Profits - Single Output Case (4)
Microeconomics
L L
= pq + 0 , yq = 0
yq yq
L L
= pzi M Pi 0 , zi = 0
zi zi
L L
= f (z) yq 0 , =0
184
Production 2
Profits - Single Output Case (5)
Microeconomics
This yields:
f (z)
p zi = p q , zi > 0
zi
f (z)/zi p zi
=
f (z)/zj pzj
185
Production 2
Profits - Single Output Case (6)
Microeconomics
max pq yq C(pz , yq )
yq 0
C(pz , yq )
pq 0
yq
C(pz ,yq )
with (pq yq ) = 0 if yq > 0.
SC(pz , yq , z f )
pq 0
yq
SC(pz ,yq ,z f )
with (pq yq ) = 0 if yq > 0.
Suppose that the second order conditions are met for the short
and the long run maximization problem.
188
Theory of the Firm 3
Profit Maximization & Shut Down (2)
Microeconomics
From the analysis on the last slides it follows that: Neither the
long run supply function yq (pq , pz ) nor the short run supply
function yq (pq , pz , z f ) has to be continuous in pq .
190
Theory of the Firm 3
Profit Maximization & Shut Down (4)
Microeconomics
191
Production 2
Profits (1)
Microeconomics
Assume that p = (p1, . . . , pL) are larger than zero and fixed
(price taking assumption).
192
Production 2
Profits (2)
Microeconomics
max p y s.t. y Y.
y
If Y is compact a solution (and also the max) for the profit maximization
problem exits. If this is not the case (p) = is still possible. The profit
function exists by Bergs theorem of the maximum if the constraint
correspondence is continuous.
L F (y) L
= pl 0, yl = 0
yl yl yl
L
= F (y) 0
L
= 0
195
Production 2
Profits (5)
Microeconomics
p = y F (y)
pl F/yl
= = M RTlk .
pk F/yk
196
Production 2
Profits (6)
Microeconomics
If yl, yk > 0, i.e. both goods are outputs, then yl, yk have to be
chosen such that the fraction of marginal rates of transformation
is equal to the ratio of prices.
If yl, yk < 0, i.e. both goods are inputs, then yl, yk have to be
chosen such that the fraction of marginal rates of transformation
(= marginal rate of technical substitution) is equal to the
ratio of prices.
197
Production 2
Profit Function (1)
Microeconomics
198
Production 2
Profit Function (2)
Microeconomics
Proof:
200
Production 2
Profit Function (4)
Microeconomics
Proof:
(p1) + (1 )(p2) (p )
201
Production 2
Profit Function (5)
Microeconomics
Proof:
202
Production 2
Profit Function (6)
Microeconomics
Proof:
203
Production 2
Profit Function (7)
Microeconomics
Proof:
Proof:
(p) L(y, )
= = yi(p).
pi pi
205
Production 2
Profit Function (9)
Microeconomics
Proof:
206
Production 2
Profit Function (10)
Microeconomics
We can also show that the law of supply holds also for the
non-differentiable case. (We know that p1y 1 p1y for any
y 1 y(p1) and p2y 2 p2y for any y 2 y(p1), sum up ....)
207
Production 3
Efficiency (1)
Microeconomics
208
Production 3
Efficiency (2)
Microeconomics
209
Production 3
Efficiency (3)
Microeconomics
Proof:
210
Production 3
Efficiency (4)
Microeconomics
The result also holds for nonconvex production sets - see Figure
5.F.2, page 150.
211
Production 3
Efficiency (6)
Microeconomics
212
Production 3
Efficiency (7)
Microeconomics
Proof:
213
Production 3
Efficiency (8)
Microeconomics
Proof:
214
Production 4
Objectives of the Firm (1)
Microeconomics
Until now we have assumed that the firm maximizes its profit.
215
Production 4
Objectives of the Firm (2)
Microeconomics
216
Production 4
Objectives of the Firm (3)
Microeconomics
218
Production 4
Objectives of the Firm (5)
Microeconomics
If there is a futures market the firm can sell the good before
uncertainty is resolved the consumer bears the risk. Profit
maximization can still be optimal.
219
Production 4
Objectives of the Firm (6)
Microeconomics
220
Production 4
Objectives of the Firm (7)
Microeconomics
Assume that the preferences of the owners are such that they are
only interested in good 2.
221
Production 4
Objectives of the Firm (8)
Microeconomics
Assume that the preferences of the owners are such that they
only look at good 1.
222
Production 4
Objectives of the Firm (9)
Microeconomics
Example: Let p1(f (z)) = z, then the first order conditions are
1 0 0 1
different, i.e. 2 z
f (z) + zf (z) 1 = 0 and f (z)
2 z
= 0.
223
General Equilibrium
Outline
Microeconomics
Walrasian equilibrium
Edgeworth Box
225
General Equilibrium
Motivation (2)
Microeconomics
Then we consider
A pure exchange economy: no production is possible,
commodities are ultimately consumed, the individuals are
permitted to trade the commodities among themselves. With
two consumers and two goods this can be represented in the
Edgeworth box.
One consumer - one firm economy, to get a first impression
on the impacts of production.
226
General Equilibrium
Walrasian Equilibrium (1)
Microeconomics
L goods, indexed ` = 1, . . . , L.
227
General Equilibrium
Walrasian Equilibrium (2)
Microeconomics
228
General Equilibrium
Walrasian Equilibrium (3)
Microeconomics
I
X J
X
x`i e` + y`j for ` = 1, . . . , L.
i=1 j=1
229
General Equilibrium
Walrasian Equilibrium (4)
Microeconomics
230
General Equilibrium
Walrasian Equilibrium (5)
Microeconomics
J
X
max u(xi) s.t. p xi p ei + ij (p yj ).
xi Xi
j=1
I
X J
X
x`i = e` + y`j .
i=1 j=1
231
General Equilibrium
Walrasian Equilibrium (6)
Microeconomics
232
General Equilibrium
Walrasian Equilibrium (7)
Microeconomics
233
Edgeworth Box (1)
Microeconomics
I
X J
X
x`i e` + y`j for ` = 1, . . . , L.
i=1 j=1
For a given price vector p = (p1, p2) the budget line intersects
the initial endowment point ei = (e1i, e2i). The slope is pp12 .
Note that only the relative price pp12 matters, with p 1
p2 ,
R++, we get the same Edgeworth box with the same budget
sets.
The consumers offer curve lies within the upper contour set of
ei .
238
Edgeworth Box (6)
Microeconomics
239
Edgeworth Box (7)
Microeconomics
240
Edgeworth Box (8)
Microeconomics
This happens e.g. if (i) one consumer only desires only one good
or (ii) preferences are non-convex.
241
Edgeworth Box (9)
Microeconomics
242
Edgeworth Box (10)
Microeconomics
Hence we define:
243
Edgeworth Box (11)
Microeconomics
There are two price taking agents, a single consumer and a single
firm.
There are two goods, labor (or leisure) of the consumer and the
consumption good produced by the firm.
245
One-Consumer, One-Producer (2)
Microeconomics
The firm uses labor to produce the consumption good under the
increasing and strictly concave production function yq = f (z),
where z is labor input and yq the amount of x2 produced.
max pf (z) wz
z0
given the prices (p, w). This optimization problem results in the
optimal labor demand z(p, w) and output yq (p, w). The profit is
(p, w).
246
One-Consumer, One-Producer (3)
Microeconomics
247
One-Consumer, One-Producer (4)
Microeconomics
248
One-Consumer, One-Producer (5)
Microeconomics
249
One-Consumer, One-Producer (6)
Microeconomics
250
General vs. Partial Equilibrium (1)
Microeconomics
f (M/N )
Due to price taking we get w = f 0 = (M/N ) .
252
General vs. Partial Equilibrium (3)
Microeconomics
Suppose that town 1 levies a tax on labor, the tax rate is t > 0.
253
General vs. Partial Equilibrium (4)
Microeconomics
254
General vs. Partial Equilibrium (5)
Microeconomics
w(t) denotes the equilibrium wage rate when the tax rate is t.
By symmetry z2(t) = = zN (t) = z(t). z1(t) is the labor
demand in town 1.
255
General vs. Partial Equilibrium (6)
Microeconomics
00
f (M/N )[(N 1)]z 0(0) = w0(0) + 1.
256
General vs. Partial Equilibrium (7)
Microeconomics
0 1
w (0) = .
N
Hence, the wage rates in all towns decrease due to the tax in
town 1. Only if N goes to infinity this effect becomes zero.
257
General vs. Partial Equilibrium (8)
Microeconomics
258
General Equilibrium
Microeconomics
MWG, Chapter 16
259
Notation (1)
Microeconomics
L goods, indexed ` = 1, . . . , L.
260
Notation (2)
Microeconomics
261
Notation (3)
Microeconomics
I
X J
X
x`i = e` + y`j for ` = 1, . . . , L.
i=1 j=1
PI PJ
This is i=1 xi = e` + j=1 yj . We denote the set of feasible
allocations by
I
X XJ
L(I+J)
A := {(x, y) X1 XI Y1 YJ : xi = e`+ yj } R .
i=1 j=1
262
Notation (4)
Microeconomics
263
Notation (5)
Microeconomics
PI
Suppose that consumer i initially owns e`i, where e` = i=1 e`i
for ` = 1, . . . , L, ei = (ei1, . . . , eiL).
Markets exist for all L goods and all firms are price takers; the
prices are p = (p1, . . . , pL).
264
Notation (6)
Microeconomics
J
X
{xi Xi : p xi p ei + ij p yj }.
j=1
I J I J
X X X X
x`i = e` + y`i or xi = e + yj .
i=1 j=1 i=1 j=1
265
Notation (7)
Microeconomics
{xi Xi : p xi p wi}.
PI PJ
Market clearing: i=1 i = e +
x j=1 j .
y
266
First Fundamental Theorem of Welfare
Economics (1)
Microeconomics
267
First Fundamental Theorem of Welfare
Economics (2)
Microeconomics
Recall - Local Nonsatiation: For all x X and for all > 0 there
exists some y X such that ||x y|| and y x. [D 3.B.3]
268
Second Fundamental Theorem of Welfare
Economics (1)
Microeconomics
270
Second Fundamental Theorem of Welfare
Economics (3)
Microeconomics
271
Second Fundamental Theorem of Welfare
Economics (4)
Microeconomics
272
Second Fundamental Theorem of Welfare
Economics (5)
Microeconomics
273
Second Fundamental Theorem of Welfare
Economics (6)
Microeconomics
Proposition [16.D.2]
Assume that Xi is convex and i is continuous. Suppose also
that the consumption vector xi Xi, the price vector p and
the wealth level wi are such that xi i xi implies p xiwi.
Then, if there is a consumption vector x0i Xi such that
p x0i < wi [a cheaper consumption for (p, wi)], it follows that
xi xi implies p xi>wi.
Proof: See MWG page 555. See also MWG, Figure 16.D.3
(right).
274
Second Fundamental Theorem of Welfare
Economics (7)
Microeconomics
Proposition [16.D.3]
Suppose that for every i = 1, . . . , L, Xi is convex and i is
continuous. Then, any price quasi-equilibrium with transfers
that has (w1, . . . , wL) 0 is a price equilibrium with transfers.
275
General Equilibrium
Walrasian Equilibrium - Existence (1)
Microeconomics
276
General Equilibrium
Walrasian Equilibrium - Existence (2)
Microeconomics
277
General Equilibrium
Walrasian Equilibrium - Existence (3)
Microeconomics
J
X
max u(xi) s.t. p xi ij (p yj ).
xi Xi
j=1
I
X J
X
x`i = y`j .
i=1 j=1
PJ
Note that xi = xi ei yields p xi = p (xi ei) j=1 ij (p yj )
PJ
and p xi p ei + j=1 ij (p yj ).
278
General Equilibrium
Walrasian Equilibrium - Existence (4)
Microeconomics
Questions:
Does there exist a p 0, i.e. p` 0 for ` = 1, . . . , L, such
that the requirements for a competitive equilibrium are met?
Is the solution unique?
Is the solution stable?
279
General Equilibrium
Walrasian Equilibrium - Existence (5)
Microeconomics
280
General Equilibrium
Walrasian Equilibrium - Existence (6)
Microeconomics
For more details see Rudin (1993)[Theorem 5.28], for the more
general Theorem of Kakutani see e.g. Rudin
(1993)[Theorem 5.23].
281
General Equilibrium
Walrasian Equilibrium - Existence (7)
Microeconomics
282
General Equilibrium
Walrasian Equilibrium - Existence (8)
Microeconomics
283
General Equilibrium
Walrasian Equilibrium - Existence (9)
Microeconomics
285
General Equilibrium
Walrasian Equilibrium
Microeconomics
286
Expected Utility
Uncertainty (1)
Microeconomics
MWG, Chapter 6.
287
Expected Utility
Lotteries (1)
Microeconomics
E.g. flip a coin: States {H, T } and outcomes Z = {1, 1}, with
head H or tail T.
288
Expected Utility
Lotteries (2)
Microeconomics
N
X N
X
LS = {(p1, . . . , pN )|pn 0 , pn = 1} = {L|pn 0 , pn = 1}
n=1 N =1
289
Expected Utility
Lotteries (3)
Microeconomics
290
Expected Utility
Lotteries (4)
Microeconomics
292
Expected Utility
Lotteries (6)
Microeconomics
293
Expected Utility
von Neumann-Morgenstern Utility (1)
Microeconomics
294
Expected Utility
von Neumann-Morgenstern Utility (2)
Microeconomics
295
Expected Utility
von Neumann-Morgenstern Utility (3)
Microeconomics
296
Expected Utility
von Neumann-Morgenstern Utility (4)
Microeconomics
297
Expected Utility
von Neumann-Morgenstern Utility (5)
Microeconomics
L + (1 )L L + (1 )L
if and only if .
298
Expected Utility
von Neumann-Morgenstern Utility (6)
Microeconomics
L1 L2 L1 + (1 )L3 L2 + (1 )L3 .
299
Expected Utility
von Neumann-Morgenstern Utility (7)
Microeconomics
300
Expected Utility
von Neumann-Morgenstern Utility (8)
Microeconomics
301
Expected Utility
von Neumann-Morgenstern Utility (9)
Microeconomics
302
Expected Utility
von Neumann-Morgenstern Utility (10)
Microeconomics
K
! K
X X
U k Lk = k U (Lk )
k=1 k=1
303
Expected Utility
von Neumann-Morgenstern Utility (11)
Microeconomics
Proof:
PK PK
Suppose that U ( k=1 k Lk ) = k=1 k U (Lk ) holds. We have
to P
show that U has
P expected utility form, i.e.
Pif
U ( k k Lk ) = k k U (Lk ) then U (L) = pnu(zn).
Proof:
PN
Suppose that U (L) = n=1 pnu(znP ) holds. We have to show
that
Putility is linear,
P i.e. if U (L) = pnu(zn) then
U ( k k Lk ) = k k U (Lk )
P P P k
Then
P U (P k kk Lk ) = Pn k k pn u(zn ) =
k k n pn u(zn ) = k k U (Lk ).
305
Expected Utility
von Neumann-Morgenstern Utility (13)
Microeconomics
L1 L2 if and only if
N
X N
X
U (L1) := pnu(zn) U (L2) := p0nu(zn) .
n=1 n=1
306
Expected Utility
von Neumann-Morgenstern Utility (14)
Microeconomics
Proof:
Suppose that there is a best and a worst lottery. With a finite set
of outcomes this can be easily shown by means of the
independence axiom. In addition L L.
We have to show that (i) u(zn) exists and (ii) that for any
compound lottery Lc = L1 + (1 )L2 we have
U (L1 + (1 )L2) = U (L1) + (1 )U (L2) (expected utility
structure).
307
Expected Utility
von Neumann-Morgenstern Utility (15)
Microeconomics
Proof:
308
Expected Utility
von Neumann-Morgenstern Utility (16)
Microeconomics
Proof:
309
Expected Utility
von Neumann-Morgenstern Utility (17)
Microeconomics
Proof:
Then
L + (1 )L = L + (1 )(L + (1 )L)
(L + (1 )L) + (1 )(L + (1 )L)
L + (1 )L
310
Expected Utility
von Neumann-Morgenstern Utility (18)
Microeconomics
Proof:
311
Expected Utility
von Neumann-Morgenstern Utility (19)
Microeconomics
Proof:
313
Expected Utility
Excursion: Connected Sets
Microeconomics
314
Expected Utility
Excursion: Connected Sets
Microeconomics
315
Expected Utility
von Neumann-Morgenstern Utility (20)
Microeconomics
Proof:
316
Expected Utility
von Neumann-Morgenstern Utility (21)
Microeconomics
Proof:
We show that the linear structure also holds for the compound
lottery Lc = L1 + (1 )L2.
318
Expected Utility
von Neumann-Morgenstern Utility (23)
Microeconomics
Proof:
319
Expected Utility
von Neumann-Morgenstern Utility (24)
Microeconomics
Proof:
U (L) U (L)
f1 :=
U (L) U (L)
and
V (L) V (L)
f2 := .
V (L) V (L)
Proof:
L L then f1 = f2 = 0; if L L then f1 = f2 = 1.
321
Expected Utility
von Neumann-Morgenstern Utility (26)
Microeconomics
Proof:
V (L) V (L)
= V (L) U (L)
U (L) U (L)
and
V (L) V (L)
= .
U (L) U (L)
322
Expected Utility
von Neumann-Morgenstern Utility (27)
Microeconomics
323
Expected Utility
VNM Indifference Curves (1)
Microeconomics
324
Expected Utility
VNM Indifference Curves (2)
Microeconomics
325
Expected Utility
VNM Indifference Curves (3)
Microeconomics
326
Expected Utility
Allais Paradoxon (1)
Microeconomics
327
Expected Utility
Allais Paradoxon (2)
Microeconomics
328
Expected Utility
Allais Paradoxon (3)
Microeconomics
329
Expected Utility
Allais Paradoxon (4)
Microeconomics
330
Expected Utility
Allais Paradoxon (5)
Microeconomics
Now the agents is once again willing to pay a positive amount for
receiving La
Gambler starting with La and holding at the end La has paid two
fees!
331
Expected Utility
Risk Attitude (1)
Microeconomics
For the proof of the vNM-utility function we did not place any
assumptions on the Bernoulli utility function u(z).
332
Expected Utility
Risk Attitude (2)
Microeconomics
333
Expected Utility
Risk Attitude (3)
Microeconomics
By the definition of risk aversion, we see that the utility function u(.) has to
satisfy for any non-degenerate
R distribution FR,
u(E(z)) = u( zdF (z)) E(u(z)) = u(z)dF (z).
If u(z) is a concave function and z is distributed according to F (z) (such
that the expectations exist), then
Z Z
u(z)dF (z) u( zdF (z))
R R
Jensens inequality. In addition, if u(z)dF (z) u( zdF (z)) holds
for any distribution F , then u(z) is concave.
For sums this implies:
X X
pz u(z) u( pz z) .
For strictly concave function, < has to hold whenever F is nondegenerate, for
convex functions we get ; for strictly convex functions > whenever F is
non-degenerate. 334
Expected Utility
Risk Attitude (4)
Microeconomics
335
Expected Utility
Risk Attitude (5)
Microeconomics
336
Expected Utility
Risk Attitude (6)
Microeconomics
337
Expected Utility
Risk Attitude (7)
Microeconomics
338
Expected Utility
Risk Attitude (8)
Microeconomics
Proof: (sketch)
340
Expected Utility
Comparative Analysis (1)
Microeconomics
341
Expected Utility
Comparative Analysis (2)
Microeconomics
342
Expected Utility
Comparative Analysis (3)
Microeconomics
343
Expected Utility
Comparative Analysis (4)
Microeconomics
Proof:
344
Expected Utility
Comparative Analysis (5)
Microeconomics
Proof:
Proof:
346
Expected Utility
Comparative Analysis (7)
Microeconomics
Proof:
Divide both sides by u01(z) < 0 and using u01(z) = ... yields:
347
Expected Utility
Comparative Analysis (8)
Microeconomics
Proof:
Proof:
349
Expected Utility
Stochastic Dominance (1)
Microeconomics
350
Expected Utility
Stochastic Dominance (2)
Microeconomics
351
Expected Utility
Stochastic Dominance (3)
Microeconomics
The above inequality holds since the terms inside the integral
(F (z) G(z)) 0. In addition, limt F (t) = 1 and
limt F (t) = 0 and likewise for G(.).
353
Expected Utility
Stochastic Dominance (5)
Microeconomics
Proof:
Step 2: First order, only if part: If FOSD then F (z) G(z) holds. Proof by
means of contradiction.
Assume there is a z R such that F (z) > G(z). z > by
construction. Set u(z) = 0 for z z and u(z) = 1 for z > z . Here we get
Z Z
u(z)dF (z) u(z)dG(z)
Z Z
0 0
= u(z)F (z)dz u(z)G (z)dz
Z Z
0 0
= F (z)dz G (z)dz
z z
= (1 F (z)) (1 G(z)) = F (z) + G(z) < 0
354
Expected Utility
Stochastic Dominance (6)
Microeconomics
Proof:
355
Expected Utility
Stochastic Dominance (7)
Microeconomics
Proof:
Z Z
u(z)dF (z) u(z)dG(z)
0 0
Z z Z z
= zdF (z) zdG(z) + z ((1 F (z)) (1 G(z)))
0 0
Z z
= z (F (z) G(z)) |z0 (F (z) G(z)) dz z (F (z) G(z))
0
Z z
= (F (z) G(z)) dz 0 .
0 357
Expected Utility
Stochastic Dominance (9)
Microeconomics
For x G(z)/F (z) = 1 has to hold. This and the fact that
G(z)/F (z) is non-increasing implies G(z)/F (z) 1 for all z.
358
Expected Utility
Arrow-Pratt Approximation (1)
Microeconomics
359
Expected Utility
Arrow-Pratt Approximation (2)
Microeconomics
Proof:
Use the definition of the risk premium and take the first derivate
with respect to k on both sides:
360
Expected Utility
Arrow-Pratt Approximation (3)
Microeconomics
Proof:
361
Expected Utility
Arrow-Pratt Approximation (4)
Microeconomics
Proof:
00 u00(w)
(0) = 0 E(x2) = A(w)E(x2)
u (w)
362
Expected Utility
Arrow-Pratt Approximation (5)
Microeconomics
0 00(0) 2
(k) (0) + (0)k + k
2
Thus
(k) 0.5A(w)E(x2)k 2
363
Expected Utility
Arrow-Pratt Approximation (6)
Microeconomics
(k) wu00(w) 2
0 k E(x2) = 0.5R(w)E(x2)k 2
w u (w)
365
Expected Utility
Decreasing Absolute Risk Aversion (2)
Microeconomics
366
Expected Utility
Decreasing Absolute Risk Aversion (3)
Microeconomics
Proof: (sketch)
367
Expected Utility
Decreasing Absolute Risk Aversion (4)
Microeconomics
Proof: (sketch)
This yields:
Proof: (sketch)
369
Expected Utility
Decreasing Absolute Risk Aversion (6)
Microeconomics
Proof: (sketch)
000
Step 2, (iii) (ii): Next define P (w) := uu00 which is often
called degree of absolute prudence.
Proof: (sketch)
371
Expected Utility
HARA Utility (1)
Microeconomics
1
These functions have the form u(z) = ( + z/) .
372
Expected Utility
HARA Utility (2)
Microeconomics
1
u0(z) = ( + z/)
00 1 1
u (z) = ( + z/)
(1 )( + 1) 2
u000(z) = ( + z/)
2
373
Expected Utility
HARA Utility (3)
Microeconomics
1
Risk aversion: A(z) = ( + z/)
+1 1
Absolute Prudence: P (z) = ( + z/)
1
Relative Risk Aversion: R(z) = z ( + z/)
374
Expected Utility
HARA Utility (4)
Microeconomics
375
Expected Utility
HARA Utility (5)
Microeconomics
376
Expected Utility
HARA Utility (6)
Microeconomics
377
Expected Utility
State Dependent Utility (1)
Microeconomics
I.e. the underlying cause of the consequence does not play any
role.
379
Expected Utility
State Dependent Utility (3)
Microeconomics
The set of lSDU will be called LSDU . Such lotteries are also
called horse lotteries.
380
Expected Utility
State Dependent Utility (4)
Microeconomics
1 2
lSDU lSDU
if and only if
X X
() pl1(z|)u(z, )
1
zsupp(lSDU ())
X X
() pl2(z|)u(z, ) .
2
zsupp(lSDU ())
381
Expected Utility
State Dependent Utility (4)
Microeconomics
382
Quasiconcave Functions
Motivation (1)
Microeconomics
383
Quasiconcave Functions
Concave Functions (1)
Microeconomics
f (x + z) f (x0) + (1 )f (x) .
For the univariate case this implies that the tangent line is above
the function graph of f (x); strictly for x0 6= x with strict concave
functions.
385
Quasiconcave Functions
Concave Functions (3)
Microeconomics
Proof:
f (x + z) f (x)
f (x0) = f (x + z) f (x) +
f (x + z) f (x) + f (x) z
386
Quasiconcave Functions
Concave Functions (4)
Microeconomics
Proof:
f (x + z) f (x)
f (x + z) f (x) >
387
Quasiconcave Functions
Concave Functions (5)
Microeconomics
388
Quasiconcave Functions
Concave Functions (6)
Microeconomics
Proof:
2 >
f (x + z) = f (x) + f (x) (z) + (z D2(f (x + ()z))z)
2
389
Quasiconcave Functions
Concave Functions (7)
Microeconomics
Proof:
390
Quasiconcave Functions
Quasiconcave Functions (1)
Microeconomics
If f is concave
then f is quasiconcave but not vice versa. E.g.
f (x) = x for x > 0 is concave and also quasiconcave. x3 is
quasiconcave but not concave.
391
Quasiconcave Functions
Quasiconcave Functions (2)
Microeconomics
392
Quasiconcave Functions
Quasiconcave Functions (3)
Microeconomics
393
Quasiconcave Functions
Quasiconcave Functions (4)
Microeconomics
Proof:
394
Quasiconcave Functions
Quasiconcave Functions (5)
Microeconomics
Proof:
395
Quasiconcave Functions
Quasiconcave Functions (6)
Microeconomics
396
Quasiconcave Functions
Quasiconcave Functions (7)
Microeconomics
Proof:
f (x) z 0
397
Quasiconcave Functions
Quasiconcave Functions (8)
Microeconomics
Proof:
398
Quasiconcave Functions
Quasiconcave Functions (9)
Microeconomics
399
Quasiconcave Functions
Quasiconcave Functions (10)
Microeconomics
Proof:
2 > 2
f (x + z) = f (x) + f (x)z + z D f (x + ()z)z .
2
400
Quasiconcave Functions
Quasiconcave Functions (11)
Microeconomics
Proof:
2 > 2
f (x + z) f (x) f (x)z = z D f (x + ()z)z.
2
401
Quasiconcave Functions
Quasiconcave Functions (12)
Microeconomics
Proof:
402
Envelope Theorem (1)
Microeconomics
m = 1, . . . , M .
d f (x(q); q)
v(q) = .
dq q
404
Envelope Theorem (3)
Microeconomics
[T. M.L.1] Consider the value function v(q) for the above
constrained maximization problem. Assume that v(q) is
differentiable at q RS and (1, . . . , M ) are the Lagrange
multipliers associated with the maximizer solution x(q) at q. In
addition the inequality constraints are remain unaltered in a
neighborhood of q. Then
M
v(q) f (x(q); q) X gm(x(q); q)
= m .
qs qs m=1
qs
For s = 1, . . . , S.
405
Envelope Theorem (4)
Microeconomics
Proof:
N
v(q) X f (x(q); q) xn(q) f (x(q); q)
= + .
dqs n=1
x n qs q s
M
f (x(q); q) X gm(x(q); q)
= m .
xn m=1
xn
406
Envelope Theorem (5)
Microeconomics
Proof:
In addition we observe
N
X gm(x(q); q) xn(q) gm(q)
+ = 0.
n=1
xn qs qs
407
Envelope Theorem (6)
Microeconomics
Proof:
M N
v(q) X X gm(x(q); q) xn(q) f (x(q); q)
= m + .
dqs m=1 n=1
x n qs q s
and
M
v(q) X gm(x(q); q) f (x(q); q)
= m + .
dqs m=1
qs qs
409
Consumer Theory
Abbreviations
Microeconomics
410
Theory of the Firm
Abbreviations
Microeconomics
411
Theory of the Firm
Abbreviations
Microeconomics
412
*References
414