The General Theory (Keynes)
The General Theory (Keynes)
The General Theory (Keynes)
T C
Preface
Chapter:
1. The General Theory
2. The Postulates of the Classical Economics
3. The Principle of Effective Demand
4. The Choice of Units
5. Expectation as Determining Output and Employment
6. The Definition of Income, Saving and Investment
Appendix on User Cost
7. The Meaning of Saving and Investment Further Considered
8. The Propensity to Consume: I. The Objective Factors
9. The Propensity to Consume: II. The Subjective Factors
10. The Marginal Propensity to Consume and the Multiplier
11. The Marginal Efficiency of Capital
12. The State of Long-Term Expectation
13. The General Theory of the Rate of Interest
14. The Classical Theory of the Rate of Interest
Appendix on the Rate of Interest in Marshalls Principles of
Economics, Ricardos Principles of Political Economy, And
Elsewhere
15. The Psychological and Business Incentives to Liquidity
16. Sundry Observations on the Nature of Capital
17. The Essential Properties of Interest and Money
file:///D:/keyness/contents.html 1/2
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : contents
Appendix:
1. Printing Errors in the First Edition Corrected in the Present Edition
2. Fluctuations in Net Investment in the United States
3. Relative Movements of Real Wages and Output
https://ebooks.adelaide.edu.au/k/keynes/john_maynard/k44g/contents.html
Last updated Sunday, March 27, 2016 at 11:56
file:///D:/keyness/contents.html 2/2
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : PREFACE
file:///D:/keyness/preface1.html 1/3
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : PREFACE
a line of thought which I have been pursuing for several years, may
sometimes strike the reader as a confusing change of view. This difficulty
is not made less by certain changes in terminology which I have felt
compelled to make. These changes of language I have pointed out in the
course of the following pages; but the general relationship between the two
books can be expressed briefly as follows. When I began to write my
Treatise on Money I was still moving along the traditional lines of
regarding the influence of money as something so to speak separate from
the general theory of supply and demand. When I finished it, I had made
some progress towards pushing monetary theory back to becoming a
theory of output as a whole. But my lack of emancipation from
preconceived ideas showed itself in what now seems to me to be the
outstanding fault of the theoretical parts of that work (namely, Books III
and IV), that I failed to deal thoroughly with the effects of changes in the
level of output. My so-called fundamental equations were an
instantaneous picture taken on the assumption of a given output. They
attempted to show how, assuming the given output, forces could develop
which involved a profit-disequilibrium, and thus required a change in the
level of output. But the dynamic development, as distinct from the
instantaneous picture, was left incomplete and extremely confused. This
book, on the other hand, has evolved into what is primarily a study of the
forces which determine changes in the scale of output and employment as
a whole; and, whilst it is found that money enters into the economic
scheme in an essential and peculiar manner, technical monetary detail
falls into the background. A monetary economy, we shall find, is
essentially one in which changing views about the future are capable of
influencing the quantity of employment and not merely its direction. But
our method of analysing the economic behaviour of the present under the
influence of changing ideas about the future is one which depends on the
interaction of supply and demand, and is in this way linked up with our
fundamental theory of value. We are thus led to a more general theory,
which includes the classical theory with which we are familiar, as a special
case.
The writer of a book such as this, treading along unfamiliar paths, is
extremely dependent on criticism and conversation if he is to avoid an
undue proportion of mistakes. It is astonishing what foolish things one can
temporarily believe if one thinks too long alone, particularly in economics
(along with the other moral sciences), where it is often impossible to bring
ones ideas to a conclusive test either formal or experimental. In this book,
even more perhaps than in writing my Treatise on Money, I have
file:///D:/keyness/preface1.html 2/3
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : PREFACE
https://ebooks.adelaide.edu.au/k/keynes/john_maynard/k44g/preface1.html
Last updated Sunday, March 27, 2016 at 11:56
file:///D:/keyness/preface1.html 3/3
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : PREFACE TO THE GERMAN EDITION
P G E
file:///D:/keyness/preface2.html 1/3
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : PREFACE TO THE GERMAN EDITION
J. M. KEYNES
7 September 1936
https://ebooks.adelaide.edu.au/k/keynes/john_maynard/k44g/preface2.html
Last updated Sunday, March 27, 2016 at 11:56
file:///D:/keyness/preface2.html 3/3
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : PREFACE TO THE JAPANESE EDITION
P J E
file:///D:/keyness/preface3.html 1/2
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : PREFACE TO THE JAPANESE EDITION
J. M. KEYNES
4 December 1936
https://ebooks.adelaide.edu.au/k/keynes/john_maynard/k44g/preface3.html
Last updated Sunday, March 27, 2016 at 11:56
file:///D:/keyness/preface3.html 2/2
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : PREFACE TO THE FRENCH EDITION
P F E
file:///D:/keyness/preface4.html 1/5
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : PREFACE TO THE FRENCH EDITION
file:///D:/keyness/preface4.html 2/5
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : PREFACE TO THE FRENCH EDITION
file:///D:/keyness/preface4.html 3/5
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : PREFACE TO THE FRENCH EDITION
file:///D:/keyness/preface4.html 4/5
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : PREFACE TO THE FRENCH EDITION
https://ebooks.adelaide.edu.au/k/keynes/john_maynard/k44g/preface4.html
Last updated Sunday, March 27, 2016 at 11:56
file:///D:/keyness/preface4.html 5/5
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 1
C 1
T G T
I have called this book the General Theory of Employment, Interest and
Money, placing the emphasis on the prefix general. The object of such a
title is to contrast the character of my arguments and conclusions with
those of the classical theory of the subject, upon which I was brought up
and which dominates the economic thought, both practical and
theoretical, of the governing and academic classes of this generation, as it
has for a hundred years past. I shall argue that the postulates of the
classical theory are applicable to a special case only and not to the general
case, the situation which it assumes being a limiting point of the possible
positions of equilibrium. Moreover, the characteristics of the special case
assumed by the classical theory happen not to be those of the economic
society in which we actually live, with the result that its teaching is
misleading and disastrous if we attempt to apply it to the facts of
experience.
https://ebooks.adelaide.edu.au/k/keynes/john_maynard/k44g/chapter1.html
Last updated Sunday, March 27, 2016 at 11:56
file:///D:/keyness/chapter1.html 1/1
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 2
C 2
T P C
E
file:///D:/keyness/chapter2.html 1/13
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 2
II. The utility of the wage when a given volume of labour is employed
is equal to the marginal disutility of that amount of employment.
That is to say, the real wage of an employed person is that which is
just sufficient (in the estimation of the employed persons themselves) to
induce the volume of labour actually employed to be forthcoming; subject
to the qualification that the equality for each individual unit of labour may
be disturbed by combination between employable units analogous to the
imperfections of competition which qualify the first postulate. Disutility
must be here understood to cover every kind of reason which might lead a
man, or a body of men, to withhold their labour rather than accept a wage
which had to them a utility below a certain minimum.
This postulate is compatible with what may be called frictional
unemployment. For a realistic interpretation of it legitimately allows for
various inexactnesses of adjustment which stand in the way of continuous
full employment: for example, unemployment due to a temporary want of
balance between the relative quantities of specialised resources as a result
of miscalculation or intermittent demand; or to time-lags consequent on
unforeseen changes; or to the fact that the change-over from one
employment to another cannot be effected without a certain delay, so that
there will always exist in a non-static society a proportion of resources
unemployed between jobs. In addition to frictional unemployment, the
postulate is also compatible with voluntary unemployment due to the
refusal or inability of a unit of labour, as a result of legislation or social
practices or of combination for collective bargaining or of slow response to
change or of mere human obstinacy, to accept a reward corresponding to
the value of the product attributable to its marginal productivity. But these
two categories of frictional unemployment and voluntary unemployment
are comprehensive. The classical postulates do not admit of the possibility
of the third category, which I shall define below as involuntary
unemployment.
Subject to these qualifications, the volume of employed resources is
duly determined, according to the classical theory, by the two postulates.
The first gives us the demand schedule for employment, the second gives
us the supply schedule; and the amount of employment is fixed at the
point where the utility of the marginal product balances the disutility of
the marginal employment. It would follow from this that there are only
four possible means of increasing employment:
(a) An improvement in organisation or in foresight which diminishes
frictional unemployment;
file:///D:/keyness/chapter2.html 2/13
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 2
Is it true that the above categories are comprehensive in view of the fact
that the population generally is seldom doing as much work as it would
like to do on the basis of the current wage? For, admittedly, more labour
would, as a rule, be forthcoming at the existing money-wage if it were
demanded. The classical school reconcile this phenomenon with their
second postulate by arguing that, while the demand for labour at the
existing money-wage may be satisfied before everyone willing to work at
this wage is employed, this situation is due to an open or tacit agreement
amongst workers not to work for less, and that if labour as a whole would
agree to a reduction of money-wages more employment would be
forthcoming. If this is the case, such unemployment, though apparently
involuntary, is not strictly so, and ought to be included under the above
category of voluntary unemployment due to the effects of collective
bargaining, etc.
This calls for two observations, the first of which relates to the actual
attitude of workers towards real wages and money-wages respectively and
is not theoretically fundamental, but the second of which is fundamental.
Let us assume, for the moment, that labour is not prepared to work
for a lower money-wage and that a reduction in the existing level of
money-wages would lead, through strikes or otherwise, to a withdrawal
from the labour market of labour which is now employed. Does it follow
from this that the existing level of real wages accurately measures the
marginal disutility of labour? Not necessarily. For, although a reduction in
the existing money-wage would lead to a withdrawal of labour, it does not
file:///D:/keyness/chapter2.html 3/13
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 2
follow that a fall in the value of the existing money-wage in terms of wage-
goods would do so, if it were due to a rise in the price of the latter. In other
words, it may be the case that within a certain range the demand of labour
is for a minimum money-wage and not for a minimum real wage. The
classical school have tacitly assumed that this would involve no significant
change in their theory. But this is not so. For if the supply of labour is not a
function of real wages as its sole variable, their argument breaks down
entirely and leaves the question of what the actual employment will be
quite indeterminate. They do not seem to have realised that, unless the
supply of labour is a function of real wages alone, their supply curve for
labour will shift bodily with every movement of prices. Thus their method
is tied up with their very special assumptions, and cannot be adapted to
deal with the more general case.
Now ordinary experience tells us, beyond doubt, that a situation
where labour stipulates (within limits) for a money-wage rather than a real
wage, so far from being a mere possibility, is the normal case. Whilst
workers will usually resist a reduction of money-wages, it is not their
practice to withdraw their labour whenever there is a rise in the price of
wage-goods. It is sometimes said that it would be illogical for labour to
resist a reduction of money-wages but not to resist a reduction of real
wages. For reasons given below (p. 14), this might not be so illogical as it
appears at first; and, as we shall see later, fortunately so. But, whether
logical or illogical, experience shows that this is how labour in fact
behaves.
Moreover, the contention that the unemployment which characterises
a depression is due to a refusal by labour to accept a reduction of money-
wages is not clearly supported by the facts. It is not very plausible to assert
that unemployment in the United States in 1932 was due either to labour
obstinately refusing to accept a reduction of money-wages or to its
obstinately demanding a real wage beyond what the productivity of the
economic machine was capable of furnishing. Wide variations are
experienced in the volume of employment without any apparent change
either in the minimum real demands of labour or in its productivity.
Labour is not more truculent in the depression than in the boom far
from it. Nor is its physical productivity less. These facts from experience
are a prima facie ground for questioning the adequacy of the classical
analysis.
It would be interesting to see the results of a statistical enquiry into
the actual relationship between changes in money-wages and changes in
real wages. In the case of a change peculiar to a particular industry one
file:///D:/keyness/chapter2.html 4/13
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 2
would expect the change in real wages to be in the same direction as the
change in money-wages. But in the case of changes in the general level of
wages, it will be found, I think, that the change in real wages associated
with a change in money-wages, so far from being usually in the same
direction, is almost always in the opposite direction. When money-wages
are rising, that is to say, it will be found that real wages are falling; and
when money-wages are falling, real wages are rising. This is because, in
the short period, falling money-wages and rising real wages are each, for
independent reasons, likely to accompany decreasing employment; labour
being readier to accept wage-cuts when employment is falling off, yet real
wages inevitably rising in the same circumstances on account of the
increasing marginal return to a given capital equipment when output is
diminished.
If, indeed, it were true that the existing real wage is a minimum below
which more labour than is now employed will not be forthcoming in any
circumstances, involuntary unemployment, apart from frictional
unemployment, would be non-existent. But to suppose that this is
invariably the case would be absurd. For more labour than is at present
employed is usually available at the existing money-wage, even though the
price of wage-goods is rising and, consequently, the real wage falling. If
this is true, the wage-goods equivalent of the existing money-wage is not
an accurate indication of the marginal disutility of labour, and the second
postulate does not hold good.
But there is a more fundamental objection. The second postulate
flows from the idea that the real wages of labour depend on the wage
bargains which labour makes with the entrepreneurs. It is admitted, of
course, that the bargains are actually made in terms of money, and even
that the real wages acceptable to labour are not altogether independent of
what the corresponding money-wage happens to be. Nevertheless it is the
money-wage thus arrived at which is held to determine the real wage. Thus
the classical theory assumes that it is always open to labour to reduce its
real wage by accepting a reduction in its money-wage. The postulate that
there is a tendency for the real wage to come to equality with the marginal
disutility of labour clearly presumes that labour itself is in a position to
decide the real wage for which it works, though not the quantity of
employment forthcoming at this wage.
The traditional theory maintains, in short, that the wage bargains
between the entrepreneurs and the workers determine the real wage; so
that, assuming free competition amongst employers and no restrictive
combination amongst workers, the latter can, if they wish, bring their real
file:///D:/keyness/chapter2.html 5/13
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 2
file:///D:/keyness/chapter2.html 6/13
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 2
To sum up: there are two objections to the second postulate of the
classical theory. The first relates to the actual behaviour of labour. A fall in
real wages due to a rise in prices, with money-wages unaltered, does not,
as a rule, cause the supply of available labour on offer at the current wage
to fall below the amount actually employed prior to the rise of prices. To
sthat it does is to suppose that all those who are now unemployed though
willing to work at the current wage will withdraw the offer of their labour
in the event of even a small rise in the cost of living. Yet this strange
supposition apparently underlies Professor Pigous Theory of
Unemployment, and it is what all members of the orthodox school are
tacitly assuming.
But the other, more fundamental, objection, which we shall develop in
the ensuing chapters, flows from our disputing the assumption that the
general level of real wages is directly determined by the character of the
wage bargain. In assuming that the wage bargain determines the real wage
the classical school have slipt in an illicit assumption. For there may be no
method available to labour as a whole whereby it can bring the wage-goods
equivalent of the general level of money wages into conformity with the
marginal disutility of the current volume of employment. There may exist
no expedient by which labour as a whole can reduce its real wage to a given
figure by making revised money bargains with the entrepreneurs. This will
be our contention. We shall endeavour to show that primarily it is certain
other forces which determine the general level of real wages. The attempt
to elucidate this problem will be one of our main themes. We shall argue
that there has been a fundamental misunderstanding of how in this
respect the economy in which we live actually works.
file:///D:/keyness/chapter2.html 7/13
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 2
way are not, as a rule, resisted unless they proceed to an extreme degree.
Moreover, a resistance to reductions in money-wages applying to
particular industries does not raise the same insuperable bar to an
increase in aggregate employment which would result from a similar
resistance to every reduction in real wages.
In other words, the struggle about money-wages primarily affects the
distribution of the aggregate real wage between different labour-groups,
and not its average amount per unit of employment, which depends, as we
shall see, on a different set of forces. The effect of combination on the part
of a group of workers is to protect their relative real wage. The general
level of real wages depends on the other forces of the economic system.
Thus it is fortunate that the workers, though unconsciously, are
instinctively more reasonable economists than the classical school,
inasmuch as they resist reductions of money-wages, which are seldom or
never of an all-round character, even though the existing real equivalent of
these wages exceeds the marginal disutility of the existing employment;
whereas they do not resist reductions of real wages, which are associated
with increases in aggregate employment and leave relative money-wages
unchanged, unless the reduction proceeds so far as to threaten a reduction
of the real wage below the marginal disutility of the existing volume of
employment. Every trade union will put up some resistance to a cut in
money-wages, however small. But since no trade union would dream of
striking on every occasion of a rise in the cost of living, they do not raise
the obstacle to any increase in aggregate employment which is attributed
to them by the classical school.
file:///D:/keyness/chapter2.html 8/13
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 2
are involuntarily unemployed If, in the event of a small rise in the price of
wage-goods relatively to the money-wage, both the aggregate supply of
labour willing to work for the current money-wage and the aggregate
demand for it at that wage would be greater than the existing volume of
employment. An alternative definition, which amounts, however, to the
same thing, will be given in the next chapter (Chapter 3).
It follows from this definition that the equality of the real wage to the
marginal disutility of employment presupposed by the second postulate,
realistically interpreted, corresponds to the absence of involuntary
unemployment. This state of affairs we shall describe as full employment,
both frictional and voluntary unemployment being consistent with full
employment thus defined. This fits in, we shall find, with other
characteristics of the classical theory, which is best regarded as a theory of
distribution in conditions of full employment. So long as the classical
postulates hold good, unemployment, which is in the above sense
involuntary, cannot occur. Apparent unemployment must, therefore, be
the result either of temporary loss of work of the between jobs type or of
intermittent demand for highly specialised resources or of the effect of a
trade union closed shop on the employment of free labour. Thus writers
in the classical tradition, overlooking the special assumption underlying
their theory, have been driven inevitably to the conclusion, perfectly
logical on their assumption, that apparent unemployment (apart from the
admitted exceptions) must be due at bottom to a refusal by the
unemployed factors to accept a reward which corresponds to their
marginal productivity. A classical economist may sympathise with labour
in refusing to accept a cut in its money-wage, and he will admit that it may
not be wise to make it to meet conditions which are temporary; but
scientific integrity forces him to declare that this refusal is, nevertheless, at
the bottom of the trouble.
Obviously, however, if the classical theory is only applicable to the
case of full employment, it is fallacious to apply it to the problems of
involuntary unemployment if there be such a thing (and who will deny
it?). The classical theorists resemble Euclidean geometers in a non-
Euclidean world who, discovering that in experience straight lines
apparently parallel often meet, rebuke the lines for not keeping straight
as the only remedy for the unfortunate collisions which are occurring. Yet,
in truth, there is no remedy except to throw over the axiom of parallels and
to work out a non-Euclidean geometry. Something similar is required to-
day in economics. We need to throw over the second postulate of the
file:///D:/keyness/chapter2.html 9/13
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 2
file:///D:/keyness/chapter2.html 10/13
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 2
From the time of Say and Ricardo the classical economists have taught
that supply creates its own demand; meaning by this in some
significant, but not clearly defined, sense that the whole of the costs of
production must necessarily be spent in the aggregate, directly or
indirectly, on purchasing the product.
In J.S. Mills Principles of Political Economy the doctrine is expressly
set forth:
file:///D:/keyness/chapter2.html 11/13
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 2
1. that the real wage is equal to the marginal disutility of the existing
employment;
2. that there is no such thing as involuntary unemployment in the strict
sense;
3. that supply creates its own demand in the sense that the aggregate
demand price is equal to the aggregate supply price for all levels of
output and employment.
These three assumptions, however, all amount to the same thing in the
sense that they all stand and fall together, any one of them logically
involving the other two.
https://ebooks.adelaide.edu.au/k/keynes/john_maynard/k44g/chapter2.html
Last updated Sunday, March 27, 2016 at 11:56
file:///D:/keyness/chapter2.html 13/13
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 3
C 3
T P E D
We need, to start with, a few terms which will be defined precisely later. In
a given state of technique, resources and costs, the employment of a given
volume of labour by an entrepreneur involves him in two kinds of expense:
first of all, the amounts which he pays out to the factors of production
(exclusive of other entrepreneurs) for their current services, which we
shall call the factor cost of the employment in question; and secondly, the
amounts which he pays out to other entrepreneurs for what he has to
purchase from them together with the sacrifice which he incurs by
employing the equipment instead of leaving it idle, which we shall call the
user cost of the employment in question. The excess of the value of the
resulting output over the sum of its factor cost and its user cost is the
profit or, as we shall call it, the income of the entrepreneur. The factor cost
is, of course, the same thing, looked at from the point of view of the
entrepreneur, as what the factors of production regard as their income.
Thus the factor cost and the entrepreneurs profit make up, between them,
what we shall define as the total income resulting from the employment
given by the entrepreneur. The entrepreneurs profit thus defined is, as it
should be, the quantity which he endeavours to maximise when he is
deciding what amount of employment to offer. It is sometimes convenient,
when we are looking at it from the entrepreneurs standpoint, to call the
aggregate income (i.e. factor cost plus profit) resulting from a given
amount of employment the proceeds of that employment. On the other
hand, the aggregate supply price of the output of a given amount of
employment is the expectation of proceeds which will just make it worth
the while of the entrepreneurs to give that employment.
It follows that in a given situation of technique, resources and factor
cost per unit of employment, the amount of employment, both in each
file:///D:/keyness/chapter3.html 1/8
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 3
individual firm and industry and in the aggregate, depends on the amount
of the proceeds which the entrepreneurs expect to receive from the
corresponding output. For entrepreneurs will endeavour to fix the amount
of employment at the level which they expect to maximise the excess of the
proceeds over the factor cost.
Let Z be the aggregate supply price of the output from employing N
men, the relationship between Z and N being written Z = (N), which can
be called the aggregate supply function. Similarly, let D be the proceeds
which entrepreneurs expect to receive from the employment of N men, the
relationship between D and N being written D = f(N), which can be called
the aggregate demand function.
Now if for a given value of N the expected proceeds are greater than
the aggregate supply price, i.e. if D is greater than Z, there will be an
incentive to entrepreneurs to increase employment beyond N and, if
necessary, to raise costs by competing with one another for the factors of
production, up to the value of N for which Z has become equal to D. Thus
the volume of employment is given by the point of intersection between
the aggregate demand function and the aggregate supply function; for it is
at this point that the entrepreneurs expectation of profits will be
maximised. The value of D at the point of the aggregate demand function,
where it is intersected by the aggregate supply function, will be called the
effective demand. Since this is the substance of the General Theory of
Employment, which it will be our object to expound, the succeeding
chapters will be largely occupied with examining the various factors upon
which these two functions depend.
The classical doctrine, on the other hand, which used to be expressed
categorically in the statement that Supply creates its own Demand and
continues to underlie all orthodox economic theory, involves a special
assumption as to the relationship between these two functions. For
Supply creates its own Demand must mean that f(N) and (N) are equal
for all values of N, i.e. for all levels of output and employment; and that
when there is an increase in Z ( = (N)) corresponding to an increase in N,
D ( = f(N)) necessarily increases by the same amount as Z. The classical
theory assumes, in other words, that the aggregate demand price (or
proceeds) always accommodates itself to the aggregate supply price; so
that, whatever the value of N may be, the proceeds D assume a value equal
to the aggregate supply price Z which corresponds to N. That is to say,
effective demand, instead of having a unique equilibrium value, is an
infinite range of values all equally admissible; and the amount of
file:///D:/keyness/chapter3.html 2/8
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 3
file:///D:/keyness/chapter3.html 3/8
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 3
file:///D:/keyness/chapter3.html 4/8
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 3
fill the widening gap between Z and D1 the economic system may find
itself in stable equilibrium with N at a level below full employment,
namely at the level given by the intersection of the aggregate demand
function with the aggregate supply function.
Thus the volume of employment is not determined by the marginal
disutility of labour measured in terms of real wages, except in so far as the
supply of labour available at a given real wage sets a maximum level to
employment. The propensity to consume and the rate of new investment
determine between them the volume of employment, and the volume of
employment is uniquely related to a given level of real wages not the
other way round. If the propensity to consume and the rate of new
investment result in a deficient effective demand, the actual level of
employment will fall short of the supply of labour potentially available at
the existing real wage, and the equilibrium real wage will be greater than
the marginal disutility of the equilibrium level of employment.
This analysis supplies us with an explanation of the paradox of
poverty in the midst of plenty. For the mere existence of an insufficiency of
effective demand may, and often will, bring the increase of employment to
a standstill before a level of full employment has been reached. The
insufficiency of effective demand will inhibit the process of production in
spite of the fact that the marginal product of labour still exceeds in value
the marginal disutility of employment.
Moreover the richer the community, the wider will tend to be the gap
between its actual and its potential production; and therefore the more
obvious and outrageous the defects of the economic system. For a poor
community will be prone to consume by far the greater part of its output,
so that a very modest measure of investment will be sufficient to provide
full employment; whereas a wealthy community will have to discover
much ampler opportunities for investment if the saving propensities of its
wealthier members are to be compatible with the employment of its poorer
members. If in a potentially wealthy community the inducement to invest
is weak, then, in spite of its potential wealth, the working of the principle
of effective demand will compel it to reduce its actual output, until, in spite
of its potential wealth, it has become so poor that its surplus over its
consumption is sufficiently diminished to correspond to the weakness of
the inducement to invest.
But worse still. Not only is the marginal propensity to consume
weaker in a wealthy community, but, owing to its accumulation of capital
being already larger, the opportunities for further investment are less
attractive unless the rate of interest falls at a sufficiently rapid rate; which
file:///D:/keyness/chapter3.html 6/8
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 3
brings us to the theory of the rate of interest and to the reasons why it
does not automatically fall to the appropriate level, which will occupy Book
IV.
Thus the analysis of the propensity to consume, the definition of the
marginal efficiency of capital and the theory of the rate of interest are the
three main gaps in our existing knowledge which it will be necessary to fill.
When this has been accomplished, we shall find that the theory of prices
falls into its proper place as a matter which is subsidiary to our general
theory. We shall discover, however, that money plays an essential part in
our theory of the rate of interest; and we shall attempt to disentangle the
peculiar characteristics of money which distinguish it from other things.
The idea that we can safely neglect the aggregate demand function is
fundamental to the Ricardian economics, which underlie what we have
been taught for more than a century. Malthus, indeed, had vehemently
opposed Ricardos doctrine that it was impossible for effective demand to
be deficient; but vainly. For, since Malthus was unable to explain clearly
(apart from an appeal to the facts of common observation) how and why
effective demand could be deficient or excessive, he failed to furnish an
alternative construction; and Ricardo conquered England as completely as
the Holy Inquisition conquered Spain. Not only was his theory accepted by
the city, by statesmen and by the academic world. But controversy ceased;
the other point of view completely disappeared; it ceased to be discussed.
The great puzzle of effective demand with which Malthus had wrestled
vanished from economic literature. You will not find it mentioned even
once in the whole works of Marshall, Edgeworth and Professor Pigou, from
whose hands the classical theory has received its most mature
embodiment. It could only live on furtively, below the surface, in the
underworlds of Karl Marx, Silvio Gesell or Major Douglas.
The completeness of the Ricardian victory is something of a curiosity
and a mystery. It must have been due to a complex of suitabilities in the
doctrine to the environment into which it was projected. That it reached
conclusions quite different from what the ordinary uninstructed person
would expect, added, I suppose, to its intellectual prestige. That its
teaching, translated into practice, was austere and often unpalatable, lent
it virtue. That it was adapted to carry a vast and consistent logical
superstructure, gave it beauty. That it could explain much social injustice
file:///D:/keyness/chapter3.html 7/8
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 3
https://ebooks.adelaide.edu.au/k/keynes/john_maynard/k44g/chapter3.html
Last updated Sunday, March 27, 2016 at 11:56
file:///D:/keyness/chapter3.html 8/8
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 4
C 4
T C U
In this and the next three chapters we shall be occupied with an attempt to
clear up certain perplexities which have no peculiar or exclusive relevance
to the problems which it is our special purpose to examine. Thus these
chapters are in the nature of a digression, which will prevent us for a time
from pursulng our main theme. Their subject-matter is only discussed
here because it does not happen to have been already treated elsewhere in
a way which I find adequate to the needs of my own particular enquiry.
The three perplexities which most impeded my progress in writing
this book, so that I could not express myself conveniently until I had found
some solution for them, are: firstly, the choice of the units of quantity
appropriate to the problems of the economic system as a whole; secondly,
the part played by expectation in economic analysis; and, thirdly, the
definition of income.
file:///D:/keyness/chapter4.html 1/6
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 4
file:///D:/keyness/chapter4.html 2/6
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 4
as one makes the attempt, it becomes clear, as I hope to show, that one can
get on much better without them.
The fact that two incommensurable collections of miscellaneous
objects cannot in themselves provide the material for a quantitative
analysis need not, of course, prevent us from making approximate
statistical comparisons, depending on some broad element of judgment
rather than of strict calculation, which may possess significance and
validity within certain limits.
But the proper place for such things as net real output and the general
level of prices lies within the field of historical and statistical description,
and their purpose should be to satisfy historical or social curiosity, a
purpose for which perfect precision such as our causal analysis requires,
whether or not our knowledge of the actual values of the relevant
quantities is complete or exact is neither usual nor necessary. To say
that net output to-day is greater, but the price-level lower, than ten years
ago or one year ago, is a proposition of a similar character to the statement
that Queen Victoria was a better queen but not a happier woman than
Queen Elizabeth a proposition not without meaning and not without
interest, but unsuitable as material for the differential calculus. Our
precision will be a mock precision if we try to use such partly vague and
non-quantitative concepts as the basis of a quantitative analysis.
file:///D:/keyness/chapter4.html 3/6
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 4
file:///D:/keyness/chapter4.html 4/6
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 4
file:///D:/keyness/chapter4.html 5/6
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 4
economic activity as a whole. For the aggregate supply function for a given
firm (and similarly for a given industry or for industry as a whole) is given
by
Zr = r(Nr),
where Zr is the proceeds (net of user cost) the expectation of which will
induce a level of employment Nr. If, therefore, the relation between
employment and output is such that an employment Nr results in an
output Or, where Or = r(Nr), it follows that
Zr + Ur(Nr) r(Nr) + Ur(Nr)
p= =
Or r(Nr)
is the ordinary supply curve, where Ur(Nr) is the (expected) user cost
corresponding to a level of employment Nr.
https://ebooks.adelaide.edu.au/k/keynes/john_maynard/k44g/chapter4.html
Last updated Sunday, March 27, 2016 at 11:56
file:///D:/keyness/chapter4.html 6/6
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 5
C 5
E D O
E
file:///D:/keyness/chapter5.html 1/5
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 5
file:///D:/keyness/chapter5.html 2/5
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 5
file:///D:/keyness/chapter5.html 3/5
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 5
This leads us to the relevance of this discussion for our present purpose. It
is evident from the above that the level of employment at any time
depends, in a sense, not merely on the existing state of expectation but on
the states of expectation which have existed over a certain past period.
Nevertheless past expectations, which have not yet worked themselves out,
are embodied in the to-days capital equipment with reference to which the
entrepreneur has to make to-days decisions, and only influence his
decisions in so far as they are so embodied. It follows, therefore, that, in
spite of the above, to-days employment can be correctly described as
being governed by to-days expectations taken in conjunction with to-days
capital equipment.
Express reference to current long-term expectations can seldom be
avoided. But it will often be safe to omit express reference to short-term
expectation, in view of the fact that in practice the process of revision of
short-term expectation is a gradual and continuous one, carried on largely
in the light of realised results; so that expected and realised results run
into and overlap one another in their influence. For, although output and
employment are determined by the producers short-term expectations
and not by past results, the most recent results usually play a predominant
part in determining what these expectations are. It would be too
complicated to work out the expectations de novo whenever a productive
process was being started; and it would, moreover, be a waste of time since
a large part of the circumstances usually continue substantially unchanged
from one day to the next. Accordingly it is sensible for producers to base
their expectations on the assumption that the most recently realised
results will continue, except in so far as there are definite reasons for
expecting a change. Thus in practice there is a large overlap between the
effects on employment of the realised sale-proceeds of recent output and
those of the sale-proceeds expected from current input; and producers
forecasts are more often gradually modified in the light of results than in
anticipation of prospective changes.
Nevertheless, we must not forget that, in the case of durable goods,
the producers short-term expectations are based on the current long-term
expectations of the investor; and it is of the nature of long-term
file:///D:/keyness/chapter5.html 4/5
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 5
https://ebooks.adelaide.edu.au/k/keynes/john_maynard/k44g/chapter5.html
Last updated Sunday, March 27, 2016 at 11:56
file:///D:/keyness/chapter5.html 5/5
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 6
C 6
T D I ,S
I
I. Income
During any period of time an entrepreneur will have sold finished
output to consumers or to other entrepreneurs for a certain sum which we
will designate as A. He will also have spent a certain sum, designated by
A1, on purchasing finished output from other entrepreneurs. And he will
end up with a capital equipment, which term includes both his stocks of
unfinished goods or working capital and his stocks of finished goods,
having a value G.
Some part, however, of A + G A1 will be attributable, not to the
activities of the period in question, but to the capital equipment which he
had at the beginning of the period. We must, therefore, in order to arrive
at what we mean by the income of the current period, deduct from
A + G A1 a certain sum, to represent that part of its value which has been
(in some sense) contributed by the equipment inherited from the previous
period. The problem of defining income is solved as soon as we have found
a satisfactory method for calculating this deduction.
There are two possible principles for calculating it, each of which has
a certain significance; one of them in connection with production, and
the other in connection with consumption. Let us consider them in turn.
(i) The actual value G of the capital equipment at the end of the period
is the net result of the entrepreneur, on the one hand, having maintained
and improved it during the period, both by purchases from other
entrepreneurs and by work done upon it by himself, and, on the other
hand, having exhausted or depreciated it through using it to produce
output. If he had decided not to use it to produce output, there is,
nevertheless, a certain optimum sum which it would have paid him to
file:///D:/keyness/chapter6.html 1/10
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 6
spend on maintaining and improving it. Let us suppose that, in this event,
he would have spent B on its maintenance and improvement, and that,
having had this spent on it, it would have been worth G at the end of the
period. That is to say, G B is the maximum net value which might have
been conserved from the previous period, if it had not been used to
produce A. The excess of this potential value of the equipment over G A1
is the measure of what has been sacrificed (one way or another) to produce
A. Let us call this quantity, namely
(G B) (G A1),
file:///D:/keyness/chapter6.html 2/10
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 6
file:///D:/keyness/chapter6.html 5/10
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 6
line; and to overlook (as has been usual) the concept of income proper,
which is the concept relevant to decisions concerning current production
and is quite unambiguous.
The above definitions of income and of net income are intended to
conform as closely as possible to common usage. It is necessary, therefore,
that I should at once remind the reader that in my Treatise on Money I
defined income in a special sense. The peculiarity in my former definition
related to that part of aggregate income which accrues to the
entrepreneurs, since I took neither the profit (whether gross or net)
actually realised from their current operations nor the profit which they
expected when they decided to undertake their current operations, but in
some sense (not, as I now think, sufficiently defined if we allow for the
possibility of changes in the scale of output) a normal or equilibrium
profit; with the result that on this definition saving exceeded investment
by the amount of the excess of normal profit over the actual profit. I am
afraid that this use of terms has caused considerable confusion, especially
in the case of the correlative use of saving; since conclusions (relating, in
particular, to the excess of saving over investment), which were only valid
if the terms employed were interpreted in my special sense, have been
frequently adopted in popular discussion as though the terms were being
employed in their more familiar sense. For this reason, and also because I
no longer require my former terms to express my ideas accurately, I have
decided to discard them with much regret for the confusion which they
have caused.
file:///D:/keyness/chapter6.html 7/10
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 6
file:///D:/keyness/chapter6.html 8/10
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 6
Thus any set of definitions which satisfy the above conditions leads to the
same conclusion. It is only by denying the validity of one or other of them
that the conclusion can be avoided.
The equivalence between the quantity of saving and the quantity of
investment emerges from the bilateral character of the transactions
between the producer on the one hand and, on the other hand, the
consumer or the purchaser of capital equipment.
Income is created by the value in excess of user cost which the
producer obtains for the output he has sold; but the whole of this output
must obviously have been sold either to a consumer or to another
entrepreneur; and each entrepreneurs current investment is equal to the
excess of the equipment which he has purchased from other entrepreneurs
over his own user cost. Hence, in the aggregate the excess of income over
consumption, which we call saving, cannot differ from the addition to
capital equipment which we call investment. And similarly with net saving
and net investment. Saving, in fact, is a mere residual. The decisions to
consume and the decisions to invest between them determine incomes.
Assuming that the decisions to invest become effective, they must in doing
so either curtail consumption or expand income. Thus the act of
investment in itself cannot help causing the residual or margin, which we
call saving, to increase by a corresponding amount.
It might be, of course, that individuals were so tte monte in their
decisions as to how much they themselves would save and invest
file:///D:/keyness/chapter6.html 9/10
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 6
https://ebooks.adelaide.edu.au/k/keynes/john_maynard/k44g/chapter6.html
Last updated Sunday, March 27, 2016 at 11:56
file:///D:/keyness/chapter6.html 10/10
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 6a: Appendix on User Cost
User cost has, I think, an importance for the classical theory of value which
has been overlooked. There is more to be said about it than would be
relevant or appropriate in this place. But, as a digression, we will examine
it somewhat further in this appendix.
An entrepreneurs user cost is by definition equal to
A1 + (G B) G,
with the advantage that we do not require at any stage of the analysis to
allocate the factor cost between the goods which are sold and the
equipment which is retained. Thus we can regard the employment given
by a firm, whether integrated or individual, as depending on a single
consolidated decision a procedure which corresponds to the actual
interlocking character of the production of what is currently sold with total
production.
The concept of user cost enables us, moreover, to give a clearer
definition than that usually adopted of the short-period supply price of a
unit of a firms saleable output. For the short-period supply price is the
sum of the marginal factor cost and the marginal user cost.
Now in the modern theory of value it has been a usual practice to
equate the short-period supply price to the marginal factor cost alone. It is
obvious, however, that this is only legitimate if marginal user cost is zero
or if supply price is specially defined so as to be net of marginal user cost,
just as I have defined (p. 24 above) proceeds and aggregate supply price
as being net of aggregate user cost. But, whereas it may be occasionally
convenient in dealing with output as a whole to deduct user cost, this
procedure deprives our analysis of all reality if it is habitually (and tacitly)
applied to the output of a single industry or firm, since it divorces the
supply price of an article from any ordinary sense of its price; and some
confusion may have resulted from the practice of doing so. It seems to
have been assumed that supply price has an obvious meaning as applied
to a unit of the saleable output of an individual firm, and the matter has
not been deemed to require discussion. Yet the treatment both of what is
purchased from other firms and of the wastage of the firms own
equipment as a consequence of producing the marginal output involves
the whole pack of perplexities which attend the definition of income. For,
even if we assume that the marginal cost of purchases from other firms
involved in selling an additional unit of output has to be deducted from the
sale-proceeds per unit in order to give us what we mean by our firms
supply price, we still have to allow for the marginal disinvestment in the
firms own equipment involved in producing the marginal output. Even if
all production is carried on by a completely integrated firm, it is still
illegitimate to suppose that the marginal user cost is zero, i.e. that the
marginal disinvestment in equipment due to the production of the
marginal output can generally be neglected.
The concepts of user cost and of supplementary cost also enable us to
establish a clearer relationship between long-period supply price and
short-period supply price. Long-period cost must obviously include an
file:///D:/keyness/chapter6a.html 2/7
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 6a: Appendix on User Cost
User cost constitutes one of the links between the present and the future.
For in deciding his scale of production an entrepreneur has to exercise a
choice between using up his equipment now and preserving it to be used
later on. It is the expected sacrifice of future benefit involved in present
use which determines the amount of the user cost, and it is the marginal
amount of this sacrifice which, together with the marginal factor cost and
the expectation of the marginal proceeds, determines his scale of
production. How, then, is the user cost of an act of production calculated
by the entrepreneur?
We have defined the user cost as the reduction in the value of the
equipment due to using it as compared with not using it, after allowing for
the cost of the maintenance and improvements which it would be worth
while to undertake and for purchases from other entrepreneurs. It must be
arrived at, therefore, by calculating the discounted value of the additional
prospective yield which would be obtained at some later date if it were not
used now. Now this must be at least equal to the present value of the
opportunity to postpone replacement which will result from laying up the
equipment; and it may be more.
If there is no surplus or redundant stock, so that more units of similar
equipment are being newly produced every year either as an addition or in
replacement, it is evident that marginal user cost will be calculable by
reference to the amount by which the life or efficiency of the equipment
will be shortened if it is used, and the current replacement cost. If,
however, there is redundant equipment, then the user cost will also
depend on the rate of interest and the current (i.e. re-estimated)
file:///D:/keyness/chapter6a.html 4/7
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 6a: Appendix on User Cost
The reader should notice that, where the equipment is not obsolescent but
merely redundant for the time being, the difference between the actual
user cost and its normal value (i.e. the value when there is no redundant
equipment) varies with the interval of time which is expected to elapse
before the redundancy is absorbed. Thus if the type of equipment in
question is of all ages and not bunched, so that a fair proportion is
reaching the end of its life annually, the marginal user cost will not decline
greatly unless the redundancy is exceptionally excessive. In the case of a
general slump, marginal user cost will depend on how long entrepreneurs
expect the slump to last. Thus the rise in the supply price when affairs
file:///D:/keyness/chapter6a.html 5/7
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 6a: Appendix on User Cost
begin to mend may be partly due to a sharp increase in marginal user cost
due to a revision of their expectations.
It has sometimes been argued, contrary to the opinion of business
men, that organised schemes for scrapping redundant plant cannot have
the desired effect of raising prices unless they apply to the whole of the
redundant plant. But the concept of user cost shows how the scrapping of
(say) half the redundant plant may have the effect of raising prices
immediately. For by bringing the date of the absorption of the redundancy
nearer, this policy raises marginal user cost and consequently increases
the current supply price. Thus business men would seem to have the
notion of user cost implicitly in mind, though they do not formulate it
distinctly. If the supplementary cost is heavy, it follows that the marginal
user cost will be low when there is surplus equipment. Moreover, when
there is surplus equipment, the marginal factor and user costs are unlikely
to be much in excess of their average value. If both these conditions are
fulfilled, the existence of surplus equipment is likely to lead to the
entrepreneurs working at a net loss, and perhaps at a heavy net loss.
There will not be a sudden transition from this state of affairs to a normal
profit, taking place at the moment when the redundancy is absorbed. As
the redundancy becomes less, the user cost will gradually increase; and the
excess of marginal over average factor and user cost may also gradually
increase.
file:///D:/keyness/chapter6a.html 6/7
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 6a: Appendix on User Cost
It is true that the cost of maintenance of idle plant may often, for the
reasons given above, reduce the magnitude of marginal user cost,
especially in a slump which is expected to last a long time. Nevertheless a
very low user cost at the margin is not a characteristic of the short period
as such, but of particular situations and types of equipment where the cost
of maintaining idle plant happens to be heavy, and of those disequilibria
which are characterised by very rapid obsolescence or great redundancy,
especially if it is coupled with a large proportion of comparatively new
plant.
In the case of raw materials the necessity of allowing for user cost is
obvious; if a ton of copper is used up to-day it cannot be used to-
morrow, and the value which the copper would have for the purposes of
to-morrow must clearly he reckoned as a part of the marginal cost. But the
fact has been overlooked that copper is only an extreme case of what
occurs whenever capital equipment is used to produce. The assumption
that there is a sharp division between raw materials where we must allow
for the disinvestment due to using them and fixed capital where we can
safely neglect it does not correspond to the facts; especially in normal
conditions where equipment is falling due for replacement every year and
the use of equipment brings nearer the date at which replacement is
necessary.
It is an advantage of the concepts of user cost and supplementary cost
that they are as applicable to working and liquid capital as to fixed capital.
The essential difference between raw materials and fixed capital lies not in
their liability to user and supplementary costs, but in the fact that the
return to liquid capital consists of a single term; whereas in the case of
fixed capital, which is durable and used up gradually, the return consists of
a series of user costs and profits earned in successive periods.
https://ebooks.adelaide.edu.au/k/keynes/john_maynard/k44g/chapter6a.html
Last updated Sunday, March 27, 2016 at 11:56
file:///D:/keyness/chapter6a.html 7/7
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 7
C 7
T M S
I F C
In the previous chapter saving and investment have been so defined that
they are necessarily equal in amount, being, for the community as a whole,
merely different aspects of the same thing. Several contemporary writers
(including myself in my Treatise on Money) have, however, given special
definitions of these terms on which they are not necessarily equal. Others
have written on the assumption that they may be unequal without
prefacing their discussion with any definitions at all. It will be useful,
therefore, with a view to relating the foregoing to other discussions of
these terms, to classify some of the various uses of them which appear to
be current.
So far as I know, everyone agrees in meaning by saving the excess of
income over what is spent on consumption. It would certainly be very
inconvenient and misleading not to mean this. Nor is there any important
difference of opinion as to what is meant by expenditure on consumption.
Thus the differences of usage arise either out of the definition of
investment or out of that of income.
file:///D:/keyness/chapter7.html 2/9
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 7
unsold stocks in its effect on decisions to produce; and I do not see how Mr
Hawtreys method can handle this at least equally important factor.
It seems probable that capital formation and capital consumption, as
used by the Austrian school of economists, are not identical either with
investment and disinvestment as defined above or with net investment
and disinvestment. In particular, capital consumption is said to occur in
circumstances where there is quite clearly no net decrease in capital
equipment as defined above. I have, however, been unable to discover a
reference to any passage where the meaning of these terms is clearly
explained. The statement, for example, that capital formation occurs when
there is a lengthening of the period of production does not much advance
matters.
file:///D:/keyness/chapter7.html 3/9
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 7
investment over saving was the motive force governing changes in the
volume of output. Thus the new argument, though (as I now think) much
more accurate and instructive, is essentially a development of the old.
Expressed in the language of my Treatise on Money, it would run: the
expectation of an increased excess of investment over saving, given the
former volume of employment and output, will induce entrepreneurs to
increase the volume of employment and output. The significance of both
my present and my former arguments lies in their attempt to show that the
volume of employment is determined by the estimates of effective demand
made by the entrepreneurs, an expected increase of investment relatively
to saving as defined in my Treatise on Money being a criterion of an
increase in effective demand. But the exposition in my Treatise on Money
is, of course, very confusing and incomplete in the light of the further
developments here set forth.
Mr D. H. Robertson has defined to-days income as being equal to
yesterdays consumption plus investment, so that to-days saving, in his
sense, is equal to yesterdays investment plus the excess of yesterdays
consumption over to-days consumption. On this definition saving can
exceed investment, namely, by the excess of yesterdays income (in my
sense) over to-days income. Thus when Mr Robertson says that there is an
excess of saving over investment, he means literally the same thing as I
mean when I say that income is falling, and the excess of saving in his
sense is exactly equal to the decline of income in my sense. If it were true
that current expectations were always determined by yesterdays realised
results, to-days effective demand would be equal to yesterdays income.
Thus Mr Robertsons method might be regarded as an alternative. attempt
to mine (being, perhaps, a first approximation to it) to make the same
distinction, so vital for causal analysis, that I have tried to make by the
contrast between effective demand and income.
We come next to the much vaguer ideas associated with the phrase forced
saving. Is any clear significance discoverable in these? In my Treatise on
Money (vol.1, p. 171, footnote [JMK, vol. V, p.154] I gave some references
to earlier uses of this phrase and suggested that they bore some affinity to
the difference between investment and saving in the sense in which I
there used the latter term. I am no longer confident that there was in fact
so much affinity as I then supposed. In any case, I feel sure that forced
file:///D:/keyness/chapter7.html 4/9
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 7
The prevalence of the idea that saving and investment, taken in their
straightforward sense, can differ from one another, is to be explained, I
think, by an optical illusion due to regarding an individual depositors
relation to his bank as being a one-sided transaction, instead of seeing it as
the two-sided transaction which it actually is. It is supposed that a
depositor and his bank can somehow contrive between them to perform an
operation by which savings can disappear into the banking system so that
they are lost to investment, or, contrariwise, that the banking system can
make it possible for investment to occur, to which no saving corresponds.
But no one can save without acquiring an asset, whether it be cash or a
debt or capital-goods; and no one can acquire an asset which he did not
previously possess, unless either an asset of equal value is newly produced
or someone else parts with an asset of that value which he previously had.
In the first alternative there is a corresponding new investment: in the
second alternative someone else must be dis-saving an equal sum. For his
loss of wealth must be due to his consumption exceeding his income, and
not to a loss on capital account through a change in the value of a capital-
asset, since it is not a case of his suffering a loss of value which his asset
formerly had; he is duly receiving the current value of his asset and yet is
not retaining this value in wealth of any form, i.e. he must be spending it
file:///D:/keyness/chapter7.html 6/9
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 7
file:///D:/keyness/chapter7.html 7/9
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 7
Both these propositions follow merely from the fact that there cannot
be a buyer without a seller or a seller without a buyer. Though an
individual whose transactions are small in relation to the market can safely
neglect the fact that demand is not a one-sided transaction, it makes
nonsense to neglect it when we come to aggregate demand. This is the vital
difference between the theory of the economic behaviour of the aggregate
and the theory of the behaviour of the individual unit, in which we assume
that changes in the individuals own demand do not affect his income.
https://ebooks.adelaide.edu.au/k/keynes/john_maynard/k44g/chapter7.html
Last updated Sunday, March 27, 2016 at 11:56
file:///D:/keyness/chapter7.html 9/9
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 8
C 8
T P C :
I. T O F
file:///D:/keyness/chapter8.html 2/12
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 8
file:///D:/keyness/chapter8.html 3/12
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 8
also to be taken of all kinds of risks, such as the prospect of not living to
enjoy the future goods or of confiscatory taxation. As an approximation,
however, we can identify this with the rate of interest.
The influence of this factor on the rate of spending out of a given
income is open to a good deal of doubt. For the classical theory of the rate
of interest, which was based on the idea that the rate of interest was the
factor which brought the supply and demand for savings into equilibrium,
it was convenient to suppose that expenditure on consumption is cet. par.
negatively sensitive to changes in the rate of interest, so that any rise in the
rate of interest would appreciably diminish consumption. It has long been
recognised, however, that the total effect of changes in the rate ofinterest
on the readiness to spend on present consumption is complex and
uncertain, being dependent on conflicting tendencies, since some of the
subjective motives towards saving will be more easily satisfied if the rate of
interest rises, whilst others will be weakened. Over a long period
substantial changes in the rate of interest probably tend to modify social
habits considerably, thus affecting the subjective propensity to spend
though in which direction it would be hard to say, except in the light of
actual experience. The usual type of short-period fluctuation in the rate of
interest is not likely, however, to have much direct influence on spending
either way.
There are not many people who will alter their way of living because
the rate of interest has fallen from 5 to 4 per cent, if their aggregate income
is the same as before. Indirectly there may be more effects, though not all
in the same direction. Perhaps the most important influence, operating
through changes in the rate of interest, on the readiness to spend out of a
given income, depends on the effect of these changes on the appreciation
or depreciation in the price of securities and other assets. For if a man is
enjoying a windfall increment in the value of his capital, it is natural that
his motives towards current spending should be strengthened, even
though in terms of income his capital is worth no more than before; and
weakened if he is suffering capital losses. But this indirect influence we
have allowed for already under (3) above. Apart from this, the main
conclusion suggested by experience is, I think, that the short-period
influence of the rate of interest on individual spending out of a given
income is secondary and relatively unimportant, except, perhaps, where
unusually large changes are in question. When the rate of interest falls
very low indeed, the increase in the ratio between an annuity purchasable
for a given sum and the annual interest on that sum may, however, provide
an important source of negative saving by encouraging the practice of
providing for old age by the purchase of an annuity.
The abnormal situation, where the propensity to consume may be
sharply affected by the development of extreme uncertainty concerning
file:///D:/keyness/chapter8.html 4/12
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 8
the future and what it may bring forth, should also, perhaps, be classified
under this heading.
(5) Changes in fiscal policy. In so far as the inducement to the
individual to save depends on the future return which he expects, it clearly
depends not only on the rate of interest but on the fiscal policy of the
government. Income taxes, especially when they discriminate against
unearned income, taxes on capital-profits, death-duties and the like are
as relevant as the rate of interest; whilst the range of possible changes in
fiscal policy may be greater, in expectation at least, than for the rate of
interest itself. If fiscal policy is used as a deliberate instrument for the
more equal distribution of incomes, its effect in increasing the propensity
to consume is, of course, all the greater.
We must also take account of the effect on the aggregate propensity to
consume of government sinking funds for the discharge of debt paid for
out of ordinary taxation. For these represent a species of corporate saving,
so that a policy of substantial sinking funds must be regarded in given
circumstances as reducing the propensity to consume. It is for this reason
that a change-over from a policy of government borrowing to the opposite
policy of providing sinking funds (or vice versa) is capable of causing a
severe contraction (or marked expansion) of effective demand.
(6) Changes in expectations of the relation between the present and
the future level of income. We must catalogue this factor for the sake of
formal completeness. But, whilst it may affect considerably a particular
individuals propensity to consume, it is likely to average out for the
community as a whole. Moreover, it is a matter about which there is, as a
rule, too much uncertainty for it to exert much influence.
We are left therefore, with the conclusion that in a given situation the
propensity to consume may be considered a fairly stable function,
provided that we have eliminated changes in the wage-unit in terms of
money. Windfall changes in capital-values will be capable of changing the
propensity to consume, and substantial changes in the rate of interest and
in fiscal policy may make some difference; but the other objective factors
which might affect it, whilst they must not be overlooked, are not likely to
be important in ordinary circumstances.
The fact that, given the general economic situation, the expenditure
on consumption in terms of the wage-unit depends in the main, on the
volume of output and employment is the justification for summing up the
other factors in the portmanteau function propensity to consume. For
whilst the other factors are capable of varying {and this must not be
forgotten), the aggregate income measured in terms of the wage-unit is, as
a rule, the principal variable upon which the consumption-constituent of
the aggregate demand function will depend.
file:///D:/keyness/chapter8.html 5/12
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 8
file:///D:/keyness/chapter8.html 6/12
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 8
file:///D:/keyness/chapter8.html 7/12
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 8
file:///D:/keyness/chapter8.html 8/12
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 8
( million)
file:///D:/keyness/chapter8.html 9/12
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 8
(Millions of dollars)
Gross capital
formation
(after allowing
30,706 33,571 31,157 33,934 34,491 27,538 18,721 7,780 14,879
for net change
in business
inventories)
Entrepreneurs
servicing,
repairs,
7,685 8,288 8,223 8,481 9,010 8,502 7,623 6,543 8,204
maintenance,
depreciation
and depletion
Net capital
formation (on
23,021 25,283 22,934 25,453 25,481 19,036 11,098 1,237 6,675
Mr Kuznets
definition)
Several facts emerge with prominence from this table. Net capital
formation was very steady over the quinquennium 19251929, with only a
10 percent increase in the latter part of the upward movement. The
deduction for entrepreneurs repairs, maintenance, depreciation and
depletion remained at a high figure even at the bottom of the slump. But
Mr Kuznets method must surely lead to too low an estimate of the annual
increase in depreciation, etc.; for he puts the latter at less than 1 per cent
per annum of the new net capital formation. Above all, net capital
file:///D:/keyness/chapter8.html 10/12
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 8
file:///D:/keyness/chapter8.html 11/12
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 8
https://ebooks.adelaide.edu.au/k/keynes/john_maynard/k44g/chapter8.html
Last updated Sunday, March 27, 2016 at 11:56
file:///D:/keyness/chapter8.html 12/12
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 9
C 9
T P C :
II. T S F
There remains the second category of factors which affect the amount of
consumption out of a given income namely, those subjective and social
incentives which determine how much is spent, given the aggregate of
income in terms of wage-units and given the relevant objective factors
which we have already discussed. Since, however, the analysis of these
factors raises no point of novelty, it may be sufficient if we give a catalogue
of the more important, without enlarging on them at any length.
There are, in general, eight main motives or objects of a subjective
character which lead individuals to refrain from spending out of their
incomes:
file:///D:/keyness/chapter9.html 1/5
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 9
file:///D:/keyness/chapter9.html 3/5
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 9
absolute amount than investment, it is, indeed, true that, when the rate of
interest rises, the rate of consumption will decrease. But this does not
mean that there will be a wider margin for saving. On the contrary, saving
and spending will both decrease.
Thus, even if it is the case that a rise in the rate of interest would cause
the community to save more out of a given income, we can be quite sure
that a rise in the rate of interest (assuming no favourable change in the
demand-schedule for investment) will decrease the actual aggregate of
savings. The same line of argument can even tell us by how much a rise in
the rate of interest will, cet. par., decrease incomes. For incomes will have
to fall (or be redistributed) by just that amount which is required, with the
existing propensity to consume to decrease savings by the same amount by
which the rise in the rate of interest will, with the existing marginal
efficiency of capital, decrease investment. A detailed examination of this
aspect will occupy our next chapter.
The rise in the rate of interest might induce us to save more, if our
incomes were unchanged. But if the higher rate of interest retards
investment, our incomes will not, and cannot, be unchanged. They must
necessarily fall, until the declining capacity to save has sufficiently offset
the stimulus to save given by the higher rate of interest. The more virtuous
we are, the more determinedly thrifty, the more obstinately orthodox in
our national and personal finance, the more our incomes will have to fall
when interest rises relatively to the marginal efficiency of capital.
Obstinacy can bring only a penalty and no reward. For the result is
inevitable.
Thus, after all, the actual rates of aggregate saving and spending do
not depend on Precaution, Foresight, Calculation, Improvement,
Independence, Enterprise, Pride or Avarice. Virtue and vice play no part.
It all depends on how far the rate of interest is favourable to investment,
after taking account of the marginal efficiency of capital. No, this is an
overstatement. If the rate of interest were so governed as to maintain
continuous full employment, virtue would resume her sway; the rate of
capital accumulation would depend on the weakness of the propensity to
consume. Thus, once again, the tribute that classical economists pay to her
is due to their concealed assumption that the rate of interest always is so
governed.
file:///D:/keyness/chapter9.html 4/5
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 9
https://ebooks.adelaide.edu.au/k/keynes/john_maynard/k44g/chapter9.html
Last updated Sunday, March 27, 2016 at 11:56
file:///D:/keyness/chapter9.html 5/5
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 10
C 10
T M P C
M
file:///D:/keyness/chapter10.html 1/14
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 10
The fluctuations in real income under consideration in this book are those
which result from applying different quantities of employment (i.e. of
labour-units) to a given capital equipment, so that real income increases
and decreases with the number of labour-units employed. If, as we assume
in general, there is a decreasing return at the margin as the number of
labour-units employed on the given capital equipment is increased,
income measured in terms of wage-units will increase more than in
proportion to the amount of employment, which, in turn, will increase
more than in proportion to the amount of real income measured (if that is
possible) in terms of product. Real income measured in terms of product
and income measured in terms of wage-units will, however, increase and
decrease together (in the short period when capital equipment is virtually
unchanged). Since, therefore, real income, in terms of product, may be
incapable of precise numerical measurement, it is often convenient to
regard income in terms of wage-units (Yw) as an adequate working index
of changes in real income. In certain contexts we must not overlook the
fact that, in general, Yw increases and decreases in a greater proportion
than real income; but in other contexts the fact that they always increase
and decrease together renders them virtually interchangeable.
Our normal psychological law that, when the real income of the
community increases or decreases, its consumption will increase or
decrease but not so fast, can, therefore, be translated not, indeed, with
absolute accuracy but subject to qualifications which are obvious and can
easily be stated in a formally complete fashion into the propositions that
Cw and Yw have the same sign, but Yw > Cw, where Cw is the
consumption in terms of wage-units. This is merely a repetition of the
proposition already established in Chapter 3 above. Let us define, then,
dCw/dYw as the marginal propensity to consume.
file:///D:/keyness/chapter10.html 2/14
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 10
Mr Kahns multiplier is a little different from this, being what we may call
the employment multiplier designated by k, since it measures the ratio of
the increment of total employment which is associated with a given
increment of primary employment in the investment industries. That is to
say, if the increment of investment Iw leads to an increment of primary
employment N2 in the investment industries, the increment of total
employment N = kN2.
file:///D:/keyness/chapter10.html 3/14
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 10
file:///D:/keyness/chapter10.html 4/14
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 10
prevent the nature of the malady from being obvious, whilst its severity is
such that it cannot be remedied unless its nature is understood.
When full employment is reached, any attempt to increase investment
still further will set up a tendency in money-prices to rise without limit,
irrespective of the marginal propensity to consume; i.e. we shall have
reached a state of true inflation. Up to this point, however, rising prices
will be associated with an increasing aggregate real income.
file:///D:/keyness/chapter10.html 5/14
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 10
file:///D:/keyness/chapter10.html 6/14
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 10
The discussion has been carried on, so far, on the basis of a change in
aggregate investment which has been foreseen sufficiently in advance for
the consumption industries to advance pari passu with the capital-goods
industries without more disturbance to the price of consumption-goods
than is consequential, in conditions of decreasing returns, on an increase
in the quantity which is produced.
In general, however, we have to take account of the case where the
initiative comes from an increase in the output of the capital-goods
industries which was not fully foreseen. It is obvious that an initiative of
this description only produces its full effect on employment over a period
of time. I have found, however, in discussion that this obvious fact often
gives rise to some confusion between the logical theory of the multiplier,
which holds good continuously, without time-lag, at all moments of time,
file:///D:/keyness/chapter10.html 7/14
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 10
which it previously fell below it, and eventually returns to its normal level;
whilst the restoration of stocks to their previous figure causes the
increment of aggregate investment to be temporarily greater than the
increment of investment in the capital-goods industries (the increment of
working capital corresponding to the greater output also having
temporarily the same effect).
The fact that an unforeseen change only exercises its full effect on
employment over a period of time is important in certain contexts; in
particular it plays a part in the analysis of the trade cycle (on lines such as
I followed in my Treatise on Money). But it does not in any way affect the
significance of the theory of the multiplier as set forth in this chapter; nor
render it inapplicable as an indicator of the total benefit to employment to
be expected from an expansion in the capital. goods industries. Moreover,
except in conditions where the consumption industries are already
working almost at capacity so that an expansion of output requires an
expansion of plant and not merely the more intensive employment of the
existing plant, there is no reason to suppose that more than a brief interval
of time nced elapse before employment in the consumption industries is
advancing pari passu with employment in the capital-goods industries
with the multiplier operating near its normal figure.
We have seen above that the greater the marginal propensity to consume,
the greater the multiplier, and hence the greater the disturbance to
employment corresponding to a given change in investment. This might
seem to lead to the paradoxical conclusion that a poor community in
which saving is a very small proportion of income will be more subject to
violent fluctuations than a wealthy community where saving is a larger
proportion of income and the multiplier consequently smaller.
This conclusion, however, would overlook the distinction between the
effects of the marginal propensity to consume and those of the average
propensity to consume. For whilst a high marginal propensity to consume
involves a larger proportionate effect from a given percentage change in
investment, the absolute effect will, nevertheless, be small if the average
propensity to consume is also high. This may be illustrated as follows by a
numerical example.
Let us suppose that a communitys propensity to consume is such
that, so long as its real income does not exceed the output from employing
file:///D:/keyness/chapter10.html 9/14
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 10
https://ebooks.adelaide.edu.au/k/keynes/john_maynard/k44g/chapter10.html
file:///D:/keyness/chapter10.html 13/14
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 10
file:///D:/keyness/chapter10.html 14/14
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 11
C 11
T M E C
file:///D:/keyness/chapter11.html 2/9
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 11
source, and only then can we value the asset by capitalising its
prospective yield.
which new investment will be pushed, given the schedule of the marginal
efficiency of capital. If the rate of interest is 3 per cent, this means that no
one will pay 100 for a machine unless he hopes thereby to add 3 to his
annual net output after allowing for costs and depreciation. But we shall
see in chapter 14 that in other passages Marshall was less cautious
though still drawing back when his argument was leading him on to
dubious ground.
Although he does not call it the marginal efficiency of capital,
Professor Irving Fisher has given in his Theory of Interest (1930) a
definition of what he calls the rate of return over cost which is identical
with my definition. The rate of return over cost, he writes, is that rate
which, employed in computing the present worth of all the costs and the
present worth of all the returns, will make these two equal. Professor
Fisher explains that the extent of investment in any direction will depend
on a comparison between the rate of return over cost and the rate of
interest. To induce new investment the rate of return over cost must
exceed the rate of interest. This new magnitude (or factor) in our study
plays the central rle on the investment opportunity side of interest
theory. Thus Professor Fisher uses his rate of return over cost in the same
sense and for precisely the same purpose as I employ the marginal
efficiency of capital.
file:///D:/keyness/chapter11.html 5/9
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 11
Two types of risk affect the volume of investment which have not
commonly been distinguished, but which it is important to distinguish.
The first is the entrepreneurs or borrowers risk and arises out of doubts
in his own mind as to the probability of his actually earning the
prospective yield for which he hopes. If a man is venturing his own money,
this is the only risk which is relevant.
But where a system of borrowing and lending exists, by which I mean
the ranting of loans with a margin of real or personal security, a second
type of risk is relevant which we may call the lenders risk. This may be due
either to moral hazard, i.e. voluntary default or other means of escape,
file:///D:/keyness/chapter11.html 7/9
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 11
file:///D:/keyness/chapter11.html 8/9
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 11
https://ebooks.adelaide.edu.au/k/keynes/john_maynard/k44g/chapter11.html
Last updated Sunday, March 27, 2016 at 11:56
file:///D:/keyness/chapter11.html 9/9
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 12
C 12
T S L -T E
We have seen in the previous chapter that the scale of investment depends
on the relation between the rate of interest and the schedule of the
marginal efficiency of capital corresponding to different scales of current
investment, whilst the marginal efficiency of capital depends on the
relation between the supply price of a capital-asset and its prospective
yield. In this chapter we shall consider in more detail some of the factors
which determine the prospective yield of an asset.
The considerations upon which expectations of prospective yields are
based are partly existing facts which we can assume to be known more or
less for certain, and partly future events which can only be forecasted with
more or less confidence. Amongst the first may be mentioned the existing
stock of various types of capital-assets and of capital-assets in general and
the strength of the existing consumers demand for goods which require
for their efficient production a relatively larger assistance from capital.
Amongst the latter are future changes in the type and quantity of the stock
of capital-assets and in the tastes of the consumer, the strength of effective
demand from time to time during the life of the investment under
consideration, and the changes in the wage-unit in terms of money which
may occur during its life. We may sum up the state of psychological
expectation which covers the latter as being the state of long-term
expectation; as distinguished from the short-term expectation upon the
basis of which a producer estimates what he will get for a product when it
is finished if he decides to begin producing it to-day with the existing
plant, which we examined in chapter 5.
file:///D:/keyness/chapter12.html 1/13
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 12
file:///D:/keyness/chapter12.html 2/13
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 12
file:///D:/keyness/chapter12.html 3/13
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 12
file:///D:/keyness/chapter12.html 5/13
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 12
file:///D:/keyness/chapter12.html 8/13
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 12
towards those who seek to borrow from them, sometimes described as the
state of credit. A collapse in the price of equities, which has had disastrous
reactions on the marginal efficiency of capital, may have been due to the
weakening either of speculative confidence or of the state of credit. But
whereas the weakening of either is enough to cause a collapse, recovery
requires the revival of both. For whilst the weakening of credit is sufficient
to bring about a collapse, its strengthening, though a necessary condition
of recovery, is not a sufficient condition.
These considerations should not lie beyond the purview of the economist.
But they must be relegated to their right perspective. If I may be allowed to
appropriate the term speculation for the activity of forecasting the
psychology of the market, and the term enterprise for the activity of
forecasting the prospective yield of assets over their whole life, it is by no
means always the case that speculation predominates over enterprise. As
the organisation of investment markets improves, the risk of the
predominance of speculation does, however, increase. In one of the
greatest investment markets in the world, namely, New York, the influence
of speculation (in the above sense) is enormous. Even outside the field of
finance, Americans are apt to be unduly interested in discovering what
average opinion believes average opinion to be; and this national weakness
finds its nemesis in the stock market. It is rare, one is told, for an
American to invest, as many Englishmen still do, for income; and he will
not readily purchase an investment except in the hope of capital
appreciation. This is only another way of saying that, when he purchases
an investment, the American is attaching his hopes, not so much to its
prospective yield, as to a favourable change in the conventional basis of
valuation, i.e. that he is, in the above sense, a speculator. Speculators may
do no harm as bubbles on a steady stream of enterprise. But the position is
serious when enterprise becomes the bubble on a whirlpool of speculation.
When the capital development of a country becomes a by-product of the
activities of a casino, the job is likely to be ill-done. The measure of success
attained by Wall Street, regarded as an institution of which the proper
social purpose is to direct new investment into the most profitable
channels in terms of future yield, cannot be claimed as one of the
outstanding triumphs of laissez-faire capitalism which is not surprising,
if I am right in thinking that the best brains of Wall Street have been in
fact directed towards a different object.
file:///D:/keyness/chapter12.html 9/13
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 12
file:///D:/keyness/chapter12.html 10/13
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 12
Even apart from the instability due to speculation, there is the instability
due to the characteristic of human nature that a large proportion of our
positive activities depend on spontaneous optimism rather than on a
mathematical expectation, whether moral or hedonistic or economic.
Most, probably, of our decisions to do something positive, the full
consequences of which will be drawn out over many days to come, can
only be taken as a result of animal spirits of a spontaneous urge to
action rather than inaction, and not as the outcome of a weighted average
of quantitative benefits multiplied by quantitative probabilities. Enterprise
only pretends to itself to be mainly actuated by the statements in its own
prospectus, however candid and sincere. Only a little more than an
expedition to the South Pole, is it based on an exact calculation of benefits
to come. Thus if the animal spirits are dimmed and the spontaneous
optimism falters, leaving us to depend on nothing but a mathematical
expectation, enterprise will fade and die; though fears of loss may have a
basis no more reasonable than hopes of profit had before.
It is safe to say that enterprise which depends on hopes stretching into
the future benefits the community as a whole. But individual initiative will
only be adequate when reasonable calculation is supplemented and
supported by animal spirits, so that the thought of ultimate loss which
often overtakes pioneers, as experience undoubtedly tells us and them, is
put aside as a healthy man puts aside the expectation of death.
This means, unfortunately, not only that slumps and depressions are
exaggerated in degree, but that economic prosperity is excessively
file:///D:/keyness/chapter12.html 11/13
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 12
file:///D:/keyness/chapter12.html 12/13
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 12
advantages from the investment, whatever its commercial yield may prove
to be within a wide range, and without seeking to be satisfied that the
mathematical expectation of the yield is at least equal to the current rate of
interest though the rate which the public authority has to pay may still
play a decisive part in determining the scale of investment operations
which it can afford.
Thus after giving full weight to the importance of the influence of
short-period changes in the state of long-term expectation as distinct from
changes in the rate of interest, we are still entitled to return to the latter as
exercising, at any rate, in normal circumstances, a great, though not a
decisive, influence on the rate of investment. Only experience, however,
can show how far management of the rate of interest is capable of
continuously stimulating the appropriate volume of investment.
For my own part I am now somewhat sceptical of the success of a
merely monetary policy directed towards influencing the rate of interest. I
expect to see the State, which is in a position to calculate the marginal
efficiency of capital-goods on long views and on the basis of the general
social advantage, taking an ever greater responsibility for directly
organising investment; since it seems likely that the fluctuations in the
market estimation of the marginal efficiency of different types of capital,
calculated on the principles I have described above, will be too great to be
offset by any practicable changes in the rate of interest.
https://ebooks.adelaide.edu.au/k/keynes/john_maynard/k44g/chapter12.html
Last updated Sunday, March 27, 2016 at 11:56
file:///D:/keyness/chapter12.html 13/13
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 13
C 13
T G T R
I
We have shown in chapter 11 that, whilst there are forces causing the rate
of investment to rise or fall so as to keep the marginal efficiency of capital
equal to the rate of interest, yet the marginal efficiency of capital is, in
itself; a different thing from the ruling rate of interest. The schedule of the
marginal efficiency of capital may be said to govern the terms on which
loanable funds are demanded for the purpose of new investment; whilst
the rate of interest governs the terms on which funds are being currently
supplied. To complete our theory, therefore, we need to know what
determines the rate of interest.
In chapter 14 and its Appendix we shall consider the answers to this
question which have been given hitherto. Broadly speaking, we shall find
that they make the rate of interest to depend on the interaction of the
schedule of the marginal efficiency of capital with the psychological
propensity to save. But the notion that the rate of interest is the balancing
factor which brings the demand for saving in the shape of new investment
forthcoming at a iven rate of interest into equality with the supply of
saving which results at that rate of interest from the communitys
psychological propensity to save, breaks down as soon as we perceive that
it is impossible to deduce the rate of interest merely from a knowledge of
these two factors. What, then, is our own answer to this question?
supply, and that if the rate of interest were raised, there would be a surplus
of cash which no one would be willing to hold. If this explanation is
correct, the quantity of money is the other factor, which, in conjunction
with liquidity-preference, determines the actual rate of interest in given
circumstances. Liquidity-preference is a potentiality or functional
tendency, which fixes the quantity of money which the public will hold
when the rate of interest is given; so that if r is the rate of interest, M the
quantity of money and L the function of liquidity-preference, we have
M = L(r). This is where, and how, the quantity of money enters into the
economic scheme.
At this point, however, let us turn back and consider why such a thing
as liquidity-preference exists. In this connection we can usefully employ
the ancient distinction between the use of money for the transaction of
current business and its use as a store of wealth. As regards the first of
these two uses, it is obvious that up to a point it is worth while to sacrifice
a certain amount of interest for the convenience of liquidity. But, given
that the rate of interest is never negative, why should anyone prefer to
hold his wealth in a form which yields little or no interest to holding it in a
form which yields interest (assuming, of course, at this stage, that the risk
of default is the same in respect of a bank balance as of a bond)? A full
explanation is complex and must wait for chapter 15. There is, however, a
necessary condition failing which the existence of a liquidity-preference
for money as a means of holding wealth could not exist.
This necessary condition is the existence of uncertainty as to the
future of the rate of interest, i.e. as to the complex of rates of interest for
varying maturities which will rule at future dates. For if the rates of
interest ruling at all future times could be foreseen with certainty, all
future rates of interest could be inferred from the present rates of interest
for debts of different maturities, which would be adjusted to the
knowledge of the future rates. For example, if 1dr is the value ln the present
year 1 of 1 deferred r years and it is known that ndr will be the value in the
year n of 1 deferred r years from that date, we have
1dn + r
ndr = ;
1dn
whence it follows that the rate at which any debt can be turned into cash n
years hence is given by two out of the complex of current rates of interest.
If the current rate of interest is positive for debts of every maturity, it must
always be more advantageous to purchase a debt than to hold cash as a
store of wealth.
file:///D:/keyness/chapter13.html 3/8
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 13
file:///D:/keyness/chapter13.html 4/8
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 13
seen, increase the quantity of cash which certain individuals will wish to
hold because their views as to the future of the rate of interest differ from
the market views.
Nevertheless, circumstances can develop in which even a large
increase in the quantity of money may exert a comparatively small
influence on the rate of interest. For a large increase in the quantity of
money may cause so much uncertainty about the future that liquidity-
preferences due to the precautionary-motive may be strengthened; whilst
opinion about the future of the rate of interest may be so unanimous that a
small change in present rates may cause a mass movement into cash. It is
interesting that the stability of the system and its sensitiveness to changes
in the quantity of money should be so dependent on the existence of a
variety of opinion about what is uncertain. Best of all that we should know
the future. But if not, then, if we are to control the activity of the economic
system by changing the quantity of money, it is important that opinions
should differ Thus this method of control is more precarious in the United
States, where everyone tends to hold the same opinion at the same time,
than in England where differences of opinion are more usual.
We have now introduced money into our causal nexus for the first time,
and we are able to catch a first glimpse of the way in which changes in the
quantity of money work their way into the economic system. If, however,
we are tempted to assert that money is the drink which stimulates the
system to activity, we must remind ourselves that there may be several
slips between the cup and the lip. For whilst an increase in the quantity of
money may be expected, cet. par., to reduce the rate of interest, this will
not happen if the liquidity-preferences of the public are increasing more
than the quantity of money; and whilst a decline in the rate of interest may
be expected, cet. par., to increase the volume of investment, this will not
happen if the schedule of the marginal efficiency of capital is falling more
rapidly than the rate of intere~t; and whilst an increase in the volume of
investment may be expected, cet. par., to increase employment, this may
not happen if the propensity to consume is falling off. Finally, if
employment increases, prices will rise in a degree partly governed by the
shapes of the physical supply functions, and partly by the liability of the
wage-unit to rise in terms of money. And when output has increased and
prices have risen, the effect of this on liquidity-preference will be to
file:///D:/keyness/chapter13.html 6/8
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 13
file:///D:/keyness/chapter13.html 7/8
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 13
https://ebooks.adelaide.edu.au/k/keynes/john_maynard/k44g/chapter13.html
Last updated Sunday, March 27, 2016 at 11:56
file:///D:/keyness/chapter13.html 8/8
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 14
C 14
T C T R
I
file:///D:/keyness/chapter14.html 1/8
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 14
two, though here again I have not found actual words to quote. Chapter vi
of Professor Carvers Distribution of Wealth clearly envisages interest as
the factor which brings into equilibrium the marginal disutility of waiting
with the marginal productivity of capital. Sir Alfred Flux (Economic
Principles, p. 95) writes: If there is justice in the contentions of our
general discussion, it must be admitted that an automatic adjustment
takes place between saving and the opportunities for employing capital
profitably . . . Saving will not have exceeded its possibilities of usefulness
. . . so long as the rate of net interest is in excess of zero. Professor Taussig
(Principles, vol. ii. p. 29) draws a supply curve of saving and a demand
curve representing the diminishing productiveness of the several
instalments of capital, having previously stated (p.20) that the rate of
interest settles at a point where the marginal productivity of capital
suffices to bring out the marginal instalment of saving. Walras, in
Appendix I (III) of his lments dconomie pure, where he deals with
lchange dpargnes contre capitaux neufs, argues expressly that,
corresponding to each possible rate of interest, there is a sum which
individuals will save and also a sum which they will invest in new capital
assets, that these two aggregates tend to equality with one another, and
that the rate of interest is the variable which brings them to equality; so
that the rate of interest is fixed at the point where saving, which represents
the supply of new capital, is equal to the demand for it. Thus he is strictly
in the classical tradition.
Certainly the ordinary man banker, civil servant or politician
brought up on the traditional theory, and the trained economist also, has
carried away with him the idea that whenever an individual performs an
act of saving he has done something which automatically brings down the
rate of interest, that this automatically stimulates the output of capital,
and that the fall in the rate of interest is just so much as is necessary to
stimulate the output of capital to an extent which is equal to the increment
of saving; and, further, that this is a self-regulatory process of adjustment
which takes place without the necessity for any special intervention or
grandmotherly care on the part of the monetary authority. Similarly and
this is an even more general belief, even to-day each additional act of
investment will necessarily raise the rate of interest, if it is not offset by a
change in the readiness to save.
Now the analysis of the previous chapters will have made it plain that
this account of the matter must be erroneous. In tracing to its source the
reason for the difference of opinion, let us, however, begin with the
matters which are agreed.
file:///D:/keyness/chapter14.html 2/8
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 14
file:///D:/keyness/chapter14.html 3/8
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 14
interest of (e.g.) a shift in the demand curve for capital, without abating or
modifying its assumption as to the amount of the given income out of
which the savings are to be made. The independent variables of the
classical theory of the rate of interest are the demand curve for capital and
the influence of the rate of interest on the amount saved out of a given
income; and when (e.g.) the demand curve for capital shifts, the new rate
of interest, according to this theory, is given by the point of intersection
between the new demand curve for capital and the curve relating the rate
of interest to the amounts which will be saved out of the given income. The
classical theory of the rate of interest seems to suppose that, if the demand
curve for capital shifts or if the curve relating the rate of interest to the
amounts saved out of a given income shifts or if both these curves shift,
the new rate of interest will be given by the point of intersection of the new
positions of the two curves. But this is a nonsense theory. For the
assumption that income is constant is inconsistent with the assumption
that these two curves can shift independently of one another. If either of
them shift, then, in general, income will change; with the result that the
whole schematism based on the assumption of a given income breaks
down. The position could only be saved by some complicated assumption
providing for an automatic change in the wage-unit of an amount just
sufficient in its effect on liquidity-preference to establish a rate of interest
which would just offset the supposed shift, so as to leave output at the
same level as before. In fact, there is no hint to be found in the above
writers as to the necessity for any such assumption; at the best it would be
plausible only in relation to long-period equilibrium and could not form
the basis of a short-period theory; and there is no ground for supposing it
to hold even in the long-period. In truth, the classical theory has not been
alive to the relevance of changes in the level of income or to the possibility
of the level of income being actually a function of the rate of the
investment.
The above can be illustrated by a diagram as follows:
file:///D:/keyness/chapter14.html 4/8
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 14
Thus the functions used by the classical theory, namely, the response
of investment and the response of the amount saved out of a given income
to change in the rate of interest, do not furnish material for a theory of the
file:///D:/keyness/chapter14.html 5/8
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 14
rate of interest; but they could be used to tell us what the level of income
will be, given (from some other source) the rate of interest; and,
alternatively, what the rate of interest will have to be, if the level of income
is to be maintained at a given figure (e.g. the level corresponding to full
employment).
The mistake originates from regarding interest as the reward for
waiting as such, instead of as the reward for not-hoarding; just as the rates
of return on loans or investments involving different degrees of risk, are
quite properly regarded as the reward, not of waiting as such, but of
running the risk. There is, in truth, no sharp line between these and the so-
called pure rate of interest, all of them being the reward for running the
risk of uncertainty of one kind or another. Only ln the event of money
being used solely for transactions and never as a store of value, would a
different theory become appropriate.
There are, however, two familiar points which might, perhaps, have
warned the classical school that something was wrong. In the first place, it
has been agreed, at any rate since the publication of Professor Cassels
Nature and Necessity of Interest, that it is not certain that the sum saved
out of a given income necessarily increases when the rate of interest is
increased; whereas no one doubts that the investment demand-schedule
falls with a rising rate of interest. But if the Y-curves and the X-curves both
fall as the rate of interest rises, there is no guarantee that a given Y-curve
will intersect a given X-curve anywhere at all. This suggests that it cannot
be the Y-curve and the X-curve alone which determine the rate of interest.
In the second place, it has been usual to suppose that an increase in
the quantity of money has a tendency to reduce the rate of interest, at any
rate in the first instance and in the short period. Yet no reason has been
given why a change in the quantity of money should affect either the
investment demand-schedule or the readiness to save out of a given
income. Thus the classical school have had quite a different theory of the
rate of interest in volume I dealing with the theory of value from what they
have had in volume II dealing with the theory of money. They have seemed
undisturbed by the conflict and have made no attempt, so far as I know, to
build a bridge between the two theories. The classical school proper, that is
to say; since it is the attempt to build a bridge on the part of the neo-
classical school which has led to the worst muddles of all. For the latter
have inferred that there must be two sources of supply to meet the
investment demand-schedule; namely, savings proper, which are the
savings dealt with by the classical school, plus the sum made available by
any increase in the quantity of money (this being balanced by some species
file:///D:/keyness/chapter14.html 6/8
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 14
of levy on the public, called forced saving or the like). This leads on to the
idea that there is a natural or neutral or equilibrium rate of interest,
namely, that rate of interest which equates investment to classical savings
proper without any addition from forced savings; and finally to what,
assuming they are on the right track at the start, is the most obvious
solution of all, namely, that, if the quantity of money could only be kept
constant in all circumstances, none of these complications would arise,
since the evils supposed to result from the supposed excess of investment
over savings proper would cease to be possible. But at this point we are in
deep water. The wild duck has dived down to the bottom as deep as she
can get and bitten fast hold of the weed and tangle and all the rubbish
that is down there, and it would need an extraordinarily clever dog to dive
after and fish her up again.
Thus the traditional analysis is faulty because it has failed to isolate
correctly the independent variables of the system. Saving and investment
are the determinates of the system, not the determinants. They are the
twin results of the systems determinants, namely, the propensity to
consume, the schedule of the marginal efficiency of capital and the rate of
interest. These determinants are, indeed, themselves complex and each is
capable of being affected by prospective changes in the others. But they
remain independent in the sense that their values cannot be inferred from
one another. The traditional analysis has been aware that saving depends
on income but it has overlooked the fact that income depends on
investment, in such fashion that, when investment changes, income must
necessarily change in just that degree which is necessary to make the
change in saving equal to the change in investment.
Nor are those theories more successful which attempt to make the
rate of interest depend on the marginal efficiency of capital. It is true that
in equilibrium the rate of interest will be equal to the marginal efficiency
of capital, since it will be profitable to increase (or decrease) the current
scale of investment until the point of equality has been reached. But to
make this into a theory of the rate of interest or to derive the rate of
interest from it involves a circular argument, as Marshall discovered after
he had got half-way into giving an account of the rate of interest along
these lines. For the marginal efficiency of capital partly depends on the
scale of current investment, and we must already know the rate of interest
before we can calculate what this scale will be. The significant conclusion
is that the output of new investment will be pushed to the point at which
the marginal efficiency of capital becomes equal to the rate of interest; and
what the schedule of the marginal efficiency of capital tells us, is, not what
file:///D:/keyness/chapter14.html 7/8
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 14
the rate of interest is, but the point to which the output of new investment
will be pushed, given the rate of interest.
The reader will readily appreciate that the problem here under
discussion is a matter of the most fundamental theoretical significance and
of overwhelming practical importance. For the economic principle, on
which the practical advice of economists has been almost invariably based,
has assumed, in effect, that, cet. par., a decrease in spending will tend to
lower the rate of interest and an increase in investment to raise it. But if
what these two quantities determine is, not the rate of interest, but the
aggregate volume of employment, then our outlook on the mechanism of
the economic system will be profoundly changed. A decreased readiness to
spend will be looked on in quite a different light If, instead of being
regarded as a factor which will, cet. par., increase investment, it is seen as
a factor which will, cet. par., diminish employment.
https://ebooks.adelaide.edu.au/k/keynes/john_maynard/k44g/chapter14.html
Last updated Sunday, March 27, 2016 at 11:56
file:///D:/keyness/chapter14.html 8/8
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Appendix to Chapter 14
A C 14
A R I
M P E ,
R P P
E ,A E
capital to withdraw itself partially from those uses in which its marginal
utility is lowest. It is only slowly and gradually that the rise in the rate of
interest will increase the total stock of capital (p.534).
It cannot be repeated too often that the phrase the rate of interest is
applicable to old investments of capital only in a very limited sense. For
instance, we may perhaps estimate that a trade capital of some seven
thousand millions is invested in the different trades of this country at
about 3 per cent net interest. But such a method of speaking, though
convenient and justifiable for many purposes, is not accurate. What ought
to be said is that, taking the rate of net interest on the investments of new
capital in each of those trades [i.e. on marginal investments] to be about 3
per cent; then the aggregate net income rendered by the whole of the
trade-capital invested in the various trades is such that, if capitalised at 33
years purchase (that is, on the basis of interest at 3 per cent), it would
amount to some seven thousand million pounds. For the value of the
capital already invested in improving land or erecting a building, in
making a railway or a machine, is the aggregate discounted value of its
estimated future net incomes [or quasi-rents]; and if its prospective
income-yielding power should diminish, its value would fall accordingly
and would be the capitalised value of that smaller income after allowing
for depreciation (p.593).
In his Economics of Welfare (3rd edn.), p. 163, Professor Pigou
writes: The nature of the service of waiting has been much
misunderstood. Sometimes it has been supposed to consist in the
provision of money, sometimes in the provision of time, and, on both
suppositions, it has been argued that no contribution whatever is made by
it to the dividend. Neither supposition is correct. Waiting simply means
postponing consumption which a person has power to enjoy immediately,
thus allowing resources, which might have been destroyed, to assume the
form of production instruments. The unit of waiting is, therefore, the use
of a given quantity of resources for example, labour or machinery for
a given time . . . In more general terms we may say that the unit of waiting
is a year-value-unit, or, in the simpler, if less accurate, language of Dr
Cassel, a year-pound . . . A caution may be added against the common view
that the amount of capital accumulated in any year is necessarily equal to
the amount of savings made in it. This is not so, even when savings are
interpreted to mean net savings, thus eliminating the savings of one man
that are lent to increase the consumption of another, and when temporary
accumulations of unused claims upon services in the form of bank-money
file:///D:/keyness/chapter14a.html 2/7
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Appendix to Chapter 14
are ignored; for many savings which are meant to become capital in fact
fail of their purpose through misdirection into wasteful uses.
Professor Pigous only significant reference to what determines the
rate of interest is, I think, to be found in his Industrial Fluctuations (1st
edn.), pp. 2513, where he controverts the view that the rate of interest,
being determined by the general conditions of demand and supply of real
capital, lies outside the central or any other banks control. Against this
view he argues that: When bankers create more credit for business men,
they make, in their interest, subject to the explanations given in chapter
xiii. of part i., a forced levy of real things from the public, thus increasing
the stream of real capital available for them, and causing a fall in the real
rate of interest on long and short loans alike. It is true, in short, that the
bankers rate for money is bound by a mechanical tie to the real rate of
interest on long loans; but it is not true that this real rate is determined by
conditions wholly outside bankers control.
My running comments on the above have been made in the footnotes.
The perplexity which I find in Marshalls account of the matter is
fundamentally due, I think, to the incursion of the concept interest, which
belongs to a monetary economy, into a treatise which takes no account of
money. Interest has really no business to turn up at all in Marshalls
Principles of Economics it belongs to another branch of the subject.
Professor Pigou, conformably with his other tacit assumptions, leads
us (in his Economics of Welfare) to infer that the unit of waiting is the
same as the unit of current investment and that the reward of waiting is
quasi-rent, and practically never mentions interest, which is as it should
be. Nevertheless these writers are not dealing with a non-monetary
economy (if there is such a thing). They quite clearly presume that money
is used and that there is a banking system. Moreover, the rate of interest
scarcely plays a larger part in Professor Pigous Industrial Fluctuations
(which is mainly a study of fluctuations in the marginal efficiency of
capital) or in his Theory of Unemployment (which is mainly a study of
what determines changes in the volume of employment, assuming that
there is no involuntary unemployment) than in his Economics of Welfare.
The following from his Principles of Political Economy (p. 511) puts the
substance of Ricardos theory of the rate of interest:
file:///D:/keyness/chapter14a.html 3/7
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Appendix to Chapter 14
The interest of money is not regulated by the rate at which the Bank
will lend, whether it be 5, 3 or 2 per cent., but by the rate of profit which
can be made by the employment of capital, and which is totally
independent of the quantity or of the value of money. Whether the Bank
lent one million, ten millions, or a hundred millions, they would not
permanently alter the market rate of interest; they would alter only the
value of the money which they thus issued. In one case, ten or twenty
times more money might be required to carry on the same business than
what might be required in the other. The applications to the Bank for
money, then, depend on the comparison between the rate of profits that
may be made by the employment of it, and the rate at which they are
willing to lend it. If they charge less than the market rate of interest, there
is no amount of money which they might not lend; if they charge more
than that rate, none but spendthrifts and prodigals would be found to
borrow of them.
This is so clear-cut that it affords a better starting-point for a
discussion than the phrases of later writers who, without really departing
from the essence of the Ricardian doctrine, are nevertheless sufficiently
uncomfortable about it to seek refuge in haziness. The above is, of course,
as always with Ricardo, to be interpreted as a long-period doctrine, with
the emphasis on the word permanently half-way through the passage;
and it is interesting to consider the assumptions required to validate it.
Once again the assumption required is the usual classical assumption,
that there is always full employment; so that, assuming no change in the
supply curve of labour in terms of product, there is only one possible level
of employment in long-period equilibrium. On this assumption with the
usual ceteris paribus, i.e. no change in psychological propensities and
expectations other than those arising out of a change in the quantity of
money, the Ricardian theory is valid, in the sense that on these
suppositions there is only one rate of interest which will be compatible
with full employment in the long period. Ricardo and his successors
overlook the fact that even in the long period the volume of employment is
not necessarily full but is capable of varying, and that to every banking
policy there corresponds a different long-period level of employment; so
that there are a number of positions of long-period equilibrium
corresponding to different conceivable interest policies on the part of the
monetary authority.
If Ricardo had been content to present his argument solely as
applying to any given quantity of money created by the monetary
authority, it would still have been correct on the assumption of flexible
file:///D:/keyness/chapter14a.html 4/7
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Appendix to Chapter 14
money-wages. If, that is to say, Ricardo had argued that it would make no
permanent alteration to the rate of interest whether the quantity of money
was fixed by the monetary authority at ten millions or at a hundred
millions, his conclusion would hold. But if by the policy of the monetary
authority we mean the terms on which it will increase or decrease the
quantity of money, i.e. the rate of interest at which it will, either by a
change in the volume of discounts or by open-market operations, increase
or decrease its assets which is what Ricardo expressly does mean in the
above quotation then it is not the case either that the policy of the
monetary authority is nugatory or that only one policy is compatible with
long-period equilibrium; though in the extreme case where money-wages
are assumed to fall without limit in face of involuntary unemployment
through a futile competition for employment between the unemployed
labourers, there will, it is true, be only two possible long-period positions
full employment and the level of employment corresponding to the rate
of interest at which liquidity-preference becomes absolute (in the event of
this being less than full employment). Assuming flexible money-wages, the
quantity of money as such is, indeed, nugatory in the long period; but the
terms on which the monetary authority will change the quantity of money
enters as a real determinant into the economic scheme.
It is worth adding that the concluding sentences of the quotation
suggest that Ricardo was overlooking the possible changes in the marginal
efficiency of capital according to the amount invested. But this again can
be interpreted as another example of his greater internal consistency
compared with his successors. For if the quantity of employment and the
psychological propensities of the community are taken as given, there is in
fact only one possible rate of accumulation of capital and, consequently,
only one possible value for the marginal efficiency of capital. Ricardo
offers us the supreme intellectual achievement, unattainable by weaker
spirits, of adopting a hypothetical world remote from experience as though
it were the world of experience and then living in it consistently. With
most of his successors common sense cannot help breaking in with
injury to their logical consistency.
file:///D:/keyness/chapter14a.html 5/7
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Appendix to Chapter 14
https://ebooks.adelaide.edu.au/k/keynes/john_maynard/k44g/chapter14a.html
Last updated Sunday, March 27, 2016 at 11:56
file:///D:/keyness/chapter14a.html 6/7
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Appendix to Chapter 14
file:///D:/keyness/chapter14a.html 7/7
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 15
C 15
T P B
I L
file:///D:/keyness/chapter15.html 4/12
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 15
file:///D:/keyness/chapter15.html 5/12
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 15
There is, of course, no reason for supposing that V is constant. Its value
will depend on the character of banking and industrial organisation, on
social habits, on the distribution of income between different classes and
on the effective cost of holding idle cash. Nevertheless, if we have a short
period of time in view and can safely assume no material change in any of
these factors, we can treat V as nearly enough constant.
(iii) Finally there is the question of the relation between M2 and r. We
have seen in chapter 13 that uncertainty as to the future course of the rate
of interest is the sole intelligible explanation of the type of liquidity-
preference L2 which leads to the holding of cash M2. It follows that a given
M2 will not have a definite quantitative relation to a given rate of interest
of r; what matters is not the absolute level of r but the degree of its
divergence from what is considered a fairly safe level of r, having regard to
those calculations of probability which are being relied on. Nevertheless,
there are two reasons for expecting that, in any given state of expectation,
a fall in r will be associated with an increase in M2. In the first place, if the
general view as to what is a safe level of r is unchanged, every fall in r
reduces the market rate relatively to the safe rate and therefore increases
the risk of illiquidity; and, in the second place, every fall in r reduces the
current earnings from illiquidity, which are available as a sort of insurance
file:///D:/keyness/chapter15.html 6/12
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 15
certain figure. The same policy, on the other hand, may prove easily
successful if it appeals to public opinion as being reasonable and
practicable and in the public interest, rooted in strong conviction, and
promoted by an authority unlikely to be superseded.
It might be more accurate, perhaps, to say that the rate of interest is a
highly conventional, rather than a highly psychological, phenomenon. For
its actual value is largely governed by the prevailing view as to what its
value is expected to be. Any level of interest which is accepted with
sufficient conviction as likely to be durable will be durable; subject, of
course, in a changing society to fluctuations for all kinds of reasons round
the expected normal. In particular, when M1 is increasing faster than M,
the rate of interest will rise, and vice versa. But it may fluctuate for
decades about a level which is chronically too high for full employment;
particularly if it is the prevailing opinion that the rate of interest is self-
adjusting, so that the level established by convention is thought to be
rooted in objective grounds much stronger than convention, the failure of
employment to attain an optimum level being in no way associated, in the
minds either of the public or of authority, with the prevalence of an
inappropriate range of rates of interest.
The difficulties in the way of maintaining effective demand at a level
high enough to provide full employment, which ensue from the association
of a conventional and fairly stable long-term rate of interest with a fickle
and highly unstable marginal efficiency of capital, should be, by now,
obvious to the reader.
Such comfort as we can fairly take from more encouraging reflections
must be drawn from the hope that, precisely because the convention is not
rooted in secure knowledge, it will not be always unduly resistant to a
modest measure of persistence and consistency of purpose by the
monetary authority. Public opinion can be fairly rapidly accustomed to a
modest fall in the rate of interest and the conventional expectation of the
future may be modified accordingly; thus preparing the way for a further
movement up to a point. The fall in the long-term rate of interest in
Great Britain after her departure from the gold standard provides an
interesting example of this; the major movements were effected by a
series of discontinuous jumps, as the liquidity function of the public,
having become accustomed to each successive reduction, became ready to
respond to some new incentive in the news or in the policy of the
authorities.
file:///D:/keyness/chapter15.html 8/12
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 15
We can sum up the above in the proposition that in any given state of
expectation there is in the minds of the public a certain potentiality
towards holding cash beyond what is required by the transactions-motive
or the precautionary-motive, which will realise itself in actual cash-
holdings in a degree which depends on the terms on which the monetary
authority is willing to create cash. It is this potentiality which is summed
up in the liquidity function L2. Corresponding to the quantity of money
created by the monetary authority, there will, therefore, be cet. par. a
determlnate rate of interest or, more strictly, a determinate complex of
rates of interest for debts of different maturities. The same thing, however,
would be true of any other factor in the economic system taken separately.
Thus this particular analysis will only be useful and significant in so far as
there is some specially direct or purposive connection between changes in
the quantity of money and changes in the rate of interest. Our reason for
supposing that there is such a special connection arises from the fact that,
broadly speaking, the banking system and the monetary authority are
dealers in money and debts and not in assets or consumables.
If the monetary authority were prepared to deal both ways on
specified terms in debts of all maturities, and even more so if it were
prepared to deal in debts of varying degrees of risk, the relationship
between the complex of rates of interest and the quantity of money would
be direct. The complex of rates of interest would simply be an expression
of the terms on which the banking system is prepared to acquire or part
with debts; and the quantity of money would be the amount which can
find a home in the possession of individuals who after taking account of
all relevant circumstances prefer the control of liquid cash to parting
with it in exchange for a debt on the terms indicated by the market rate of
interest. Perhaps a complex offer by the central bank to buy and sell at
stated prices gilt-edged bonds of all maturities, in place of the single bank
rate for short-term bills, is the most important practical improvement
which can be made in the technique of monetary management.
To-day, however, in actual practice, the extent to which the price of
debts as fixed by the banking system is effective in the market, in the
sense that it governs the actual market-price, varies in different systems.
Sometimes the price is more effective in one direction than in the other;
that is to say, the banking system may undertake to purchase debts at a
certain price but not necessarily to sell them at a figure near enough to its
buying-price to represent no more than a dealers turn, though there is no
file:///D:/keyness/chapter15.html 9/12
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 15
reason why the price should not be made effective both ways with the aid
of open-market operations. There is also the more important qualification
which arises out of the monetary authority not being, as a rule, an equally
willing dealer in debts of all maturities. The monetary authority often
tends in practice to concentrate upon short-term debts and to leave the
price of long-term debts to be influenced by belated and imperfect
reactions from the price of short-term debts; though here again there is
no reason why they need do so. Where these qualifications operate, the
directness of the relation between the rate of interest and the quantity of
money is correspondingly modified. In Great Britain the field of deliberate
control appears to be widening. But in applying this theory in any
particular case allowance must be made for the special characteristics of
the method actually employed by the monetary authority. If the monetary
authority deals only in short-term debts, we have to consider what
influence the price, actual and prospective, of short-term debts exercises
on debts of longer maturity.
Thus there are certain limitations on the ability of the monetary
authority to establish any given complex of rates of interest for debts of
different terms and risks, which can be summed up as follows:
(1) There are those limitations which arise out of the monetary
authoritys own practices in limiting its willingness to deal to debts of a
particular type.
(2) There is the possibility, for the reasons discussed above, that, after
the rate of interest has fallen to a certain level, liquidity-preference may
become virtually absolute in the sense that almost everyone prefers cash to
holding a debt which yields so low a rate of interest. In this event the
monetary authority would have lost effective control over the rate of
interest. But whilst this limiting case might become practically important
in future, I know of no example of it hitherto. Indeed, owing to the
unwillingness of most monetary authorities to deal boldly in debts of long
term, there has not been much opportunity for a test. Moreover, if such a
situation were to arise, it would mean that the public authority itself could
borrow through the banking system on an unlimited scale at a nominal
rate of interest.
(3) The most striking examples of a complete breakdown of stability
in the rate of interest, due to the liquidity function flattening out in one
direction or the other, have occurred in very abnormal circumstances. In
Russia and Central Europe after the war a currency crisis or flight from the
currency was experienced, when no one could be induced to retain
holdings either of money or of debts on any terms whatever, and even a
file:///D:/keyness/chapter15.html 10/12
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 15
high and rising rate of interest was unable to keep pace with the marginal
efficiency of capital (especially of stocks of liquid goods) under the
influence of the expectation of an ever greater fall in the value of money;
whilst in the United States at certain dates in 1932 there was a crisis of the
opposite kind a financial crisis or crisis of liquidation, when scarcely
anyone could be induced to part with holdings of money on any reasonable
terms.
(4) There is, finally, the difficulty discussed in section IV of chapter 11,
p. 144, in the way of bringing the effective rate of interest below a certain
figure, which may prove important in an era of low interest-rates; namely
the intermediate costs of bringing the borrower and the ultimate lender
together, and the allowance for risk, especially for moral risk, which the
lender requires over and above the pure rate of interest. As the pure rate of
interest declines it does not follow that the allowances for expense and risk
decline pari passu. Thus the rate of interest which the typical borrower
has to pay may decline more slowly than the pure rate of interest, and may
be incapable of being brought, by the methods of the existing banking and
financial organisation, below a certain minimum figure. This is
particularly important if the estimation of moral risk is appreciable. For
where the risk is due to doubt in the mind of the lender concerning the
honesty of the borrower, there is nothing in the mind of a borrower who
does not intend to be dishonest to offset the resultant higher charge. It is
also important in the case of short-term loans (e.g. bank loans) where the
expenses are heavy; a bank may have to charge its customers 1 to 2
per cent., even if the pure rate of interest to the lender is nil.
file:///D:/keyness/chapter15.html 11/12
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 15
https://ebooks.adelaide.edu.au/k/keynes/john_maynard/k44g/chapter15.html
Last updated Sunday, March 27, 2016 at 11:56
file:///D:/keyness/chapter15.html 12/12
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 16
C 16
S O N
C
would eventuate not at once but at some subsequent date, so that the
immediate effect of the saving would still be adverse to employment. In
any case, however, an individual decision to save does not, in actual fact,
involve the placing of any specific forward order for consumption, but
merely the cancellation of a present order. Thus, since the expectation of
consumption is the only raison dtre of employment, there should be
nothing paradoxical in the conclusion that a diminished propensity to
consume has cet. par. a depressing effect on employment.
The trouble arises, therefore, because the act of saving implies, not a
substitution for present consumption of some specific additional
consumption which requires for its preparation just as much immediate
economic activity as would have been required by present consumption
equal in value to the sum saved, but a desire for wealth as such, that is for
a potentiality of consuming an unspecified article at an unspecified time.
The absurd, though almost universal, idea that an act of individual saving
is just as good for effective demand as an act of individual consumption,
has been fostered by the fallacy, much more specious than the conclusion
derived from it, that an increased desire to hold wealth, being much the
same thing as an increased desire to hold investments, must, by increasing
the demand for investments, provide a stimulus to their production; so
that current investment is promoted by individual saving to the same
extent as present consumption is diminished.
It is of this fallacy that it is most difficult to disabuse mens minds. It
comes from believing that the owner of wealth desires a capital-asset as
such, whereas what he really desires is its prospective yield. Now,
prospective yield wholly depends on the expectation of future effective
demand in relation to future conditions of supply. If, therefore, an act of
saving does nothing to improve prospective yield, it does nothing to
stimulate investment. Moreover, in order that an individual saver may
attain his desired goal of the ownership of wealth, it is not necessary that a
new capital-asset should be produced wherewith to satisfy him. The mere
act of saving by one individual, being two-sided as we have shown above,
forces some other individual to transfer to him some article of wealth old
or new. Every act of saving involves a forced inevitable transfer of wealth
to him who saves, though he in his turn may suffer from the saving of
others. These transfers of wealth do not require the creation of new wealth
indeed, as we have seen, they may be actively inimical to it. The creation
of new wealth wholly depends on the prospective yield of the new wealth
reaching the standard set by the current rate of interest. The prospective
yield of the marginal new investment is not increased by the fact that
file:///D:/keyness/chapter16.html 2/9
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 16
someone wishes to increase his wealth, since the prospective yield of the
marginal new investment depends on the expectation of a demand for a
specific article at a specific date.
Nor do we avoid this conclusion by arguing that what the owner of
wealth desires is not a given prospective yield but the best available
prospective yield, so that an increased desire to own wealth reduces the
prospective yield with which the producers of new investment have to be
content. For this overlooks the fact that there is always an alternative to
the ownership of real capital-assets, namely the ownership of money and
debts; so that the prospective yield with which the producers of new
investment have to be content cannot fall below the standard set by the
current rate of interest. And the current rate of interest depends, as we
have seen, not on the strength of the desire to hold wealth, but on the
strengths of the desires to hold it in liquid and in illiquid forms
respectively, coupled with the amount of the supply of wealth in the one
form relatively to the supply of it in the other. If the reader still finds
himself perplexed, let him ask himself why, the quantity of money bcing
unchanged, a fresh act of saving should diminish the sum which it is
desired to keep in liquid form at the existing rate of interest.
Certain deeper perplexities, which may arise when we try to probe still
further into the whys and wherefores, will be considered in the next
chapter.
file:///D:/keyness/chapter16.html 3/9
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 16
course, the personal services of the entrepreneur and his assistants, as the
sole factor of production, operating in a given environment of technique,
natural resources, capital equipment and effective demand. This partly
explains why we have been able to take the unit of labour as the sole
physical unit which we require in our economic system, apart from units of
money and of time.
It is true that some lengthy or roundabout processes are physically
efficient. But so are some short processes. Lengthy processes are not
physically efficient because they are long. Some, probably most, lengthy
processes would be physically very inefficient, for there are such things as
spoiling or wasting with time. With a given labour force there is a definite
limit to the quantity of labour embodied in roundabout processes which
can be used to advantage. Apart from other considerations, there must be
a due proportion between the amount of labour employed in making
machines and the amount which will be employed in using them. The
ultimate quantity of value will not increase indefinitely, relatively to the
quantity of labour employed, as the processes adopted become more and
more roundabout, even if their physical efficiency is still increasing. Only if
the desire to postpone consumption were strong enough to produce a
situation in which full employment required a volume of investment so
great as to involve a negative marginal efficiency of capital, would a
process become advantageous merely because it was lengthy; in which
event we should employ physically inefficient processes, provided they
were sufficiently lengthy for the gain from postponement to outweigh their
inefficiency. We should in fact have a situation in which short processes
would have to be kept sufficiently scarce for their physical efficiency to
outweigh the disadvantage of the early delivery of their product. A correct
theory, therefore, must be reversible so as to be able to cover the eases of
the marginal efficiency of capital corresponding either to a positive or to a
negative rate of interest; and it is, I think, only the scarcity theory outlined
above which is capable of this.
Moreover there are all sorts of reasons why various kinds of services
and facilities are scarce and therefore expensive refatively to the quantity
of labour involved. For example, smelly processes command a higher
reward, because people will not undertake them otherwise. So do risky
processes. But we do not devise a productivity theory of smelly or risky
processes as such. In short, not all labour is accomplished in equally
agreeable attendant circumstances; and conditions of equilibrium require
that articles produced in less agreeable attendant circumstances
(characterised by smelliness, risk or the lapse of time) must be kept
file:///D:/keyness/chapter16.html 4/9
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 16
file:///D:/keyness/chapter16.html 5/9
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 16
We have seen that capital has to be kept scarce enough in the long-period
to have a marginal efficiency which is at least equal to the rate of interest
for a period equal to the life of the capital, as determined by psychological
and institutional conditions. What would this involve for a society which
finds itself so well equipped with capital that its marginal efficiency is zero
and would be negative with any additional investment; yet possessing a
monetary system, such that money will keep and involves negligible costs
of storage and safe custody, with the result that in practice interest cannot
be negative; and, in conditions of full employment, disposed to save?
If, in such circumstances, we start from a position of full employment,
entrepreneurs will necessarily make losses if they continue to offer
employment on a scale which will utilise the whole of the existing stock of
capital. Hence the stock of capital and the level of employment will have to
shrink until the community becomes so impoverished that the aggregate of
saving has become zero, the positive saving of some individuals or groups
being offset by the negative saving of others. Thus for a society such as we
have supposed, the position of equilibrium, under conditions of laissez-
faire, will be one in which employment is low enough and the standard of
life sufficiently miserable to bring savings to zero. More probably there will
be a cyclical movement round this equilibrium position. For if there is still
room for uncertainty about the future, the marginal efficiency of capital
will occasionally rise above zero leading to a boom, and in the succeeding
slump the stock of capital may fall for a time below the level which will
yield a marginal efficiency of zero in the long run. Assuming correct
file:///D:/keyness/chapter16.html 6/9
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 16
capital may be able for the time being to enjoy a higher standard of life
than the community with the larger stock; though when the poorer
community has caught up the rich as, presumably, it eventually will
then both alike will suffer the fate of Midas. This disturbing conclusion
depends, of course, on the assumption that the propensity to consume and
the rate of investment are not deliberately controlled in the social interest
but are mainly left to the influences of laissez-faire.
If for whatever reason the rate of interest cannot fall as fast as
the marginal efficiency of capital would fall with a rate of accumulation
corresponding to what the community would choose to save at a rate of
interest equal to the marginal efficiency of capital in conditions of full
employment, then even a diversion of the desire to hold wealth towards
assets, which will in fact yield no economic fruits whatever, will increase
economic well-being. In so far as millionaires find their satisfaction in
building mighty mansions to contain their bodies when alive and pyramids
to shelter them after death, or, repenting of their sins, erect cathedrals and
endow monasteries or foreign missions, the day when abundance of
capital will interfere with abundance of output may be postponed. To dig
holes in the ground, paid for out of savings, will increase, not only
employment, but the real national dividend of useful goods and services. It
is not reasonable, however, that a sensible community should be content
to remain dependent on such fortuitous and often wasteful mitigations
when once we understand the influences upon which effective demand
depends.
Let us assume that steps are taken to ensure that the rate of interest is
consistent with the rate of investment which corresponds to full
employment. Let us assume, further, that State action enters in as a
balancing factor to provide that the growth of capital equipment shall be
such as to approach saturation-point at a rate which does not put a
disproportionate burden on the standard of life of the present generation.
On such assumptions I should guess that a properly run community
equipped with modern technical resources, of which the population is not
increasing rapidJy, ought to be able to bring down the marginal efficiency
of capital in equilibrium approximately to zero within a single generation;
so that we should attain the conditions of a quasi-stationary community
where change and progress would result only from changes in technique,
file:///D:/keyness/chapter16.html 8/9
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 16
https://ebooks.adelaide.edu.au/k/keynes/john_maynard/k44g/chapter16.html
Last updated Sunday, March 27, 2016 at 11:56
file:///D:/keyness/chapter16.html 9/9
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 17
C 17
T E P I
M
It seems, then, that the rate of interest on money plays a peculiar part in
setting a limit to the level of employment, since it sets a standard to which
the marginal efficiency of a capital-asset must attain if it is to be newly
produced. That this should be so, is, at first sight, most perplexing. It is
natural to enquire wherein the peculiarity of money lies as distinct from
other assets, whether it is only money which has a rate of interest, and
what would happen in a non-monetary economy. Until we have answered
these questions, the full significance of our theory will not be clear.
The money-rate of interest we may remind the reader is nothing
more than the percentage excess of a sum of money contracted for forward
delivery, e.g. a year hence, over what we may call the spot or cash price of
the sum thus contracted for forward delivery. It would seem, therefore,
that for every kind of capital-asset there must be an analogue of the rate of
interest on money. For there is a definite quantity of (e.g.) wheat to be
delivered a year hence which has the same exchange value to-day as 100
quarters of wheat for spot delivery. If the former quantity is 105 quarters,
we may say that the wheat-rate of interest is 5 per cent per annum; and if
jt is 95 quarters, that it is minus 5 per cent per annum. Thus for every
durable commodity we have a rate of interest in terms of itself; a wheat-
rate of interest, a copper-rate of interest, a house-rate of interest, even a
steel-plant-rate of interest.
The difference between the future and spot contracts for a
commodity, such as wheat, which are quoted in the market, bears a
definite relation to the wheat-rate of interest, but, since the future contract
is quoted in terms of money for forward delivery and not in terms of wheat
file:///D:/keyness/chapter17.html 1/17
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 17
for spot delivery, it also brings in the money-rate of interest. The exact
relationship is as follows:
Let us suppose that the spot price of wheat is 100 per 100 quarters,
that the price of the future contract for wheat for delivery a year hence is
107 per 100 quarters, and that the money-rate of interest is 5 per cent;
what is the wheat-rate of interest? 100 spot will buy 105 for forward
delivery, and 105 for forward delivery will buy 105/107 100 ( = 98)
quarters for forward delivery. Alternatively 100 spot will buy 100
quarters of wheat for spot delivery. Thus 100 quarters of wheat for spot
delivery will buy 98 quarters for forward delivery. It follows that the
wheat-rate of interest is minus 2 per cent per annum.
It follows from this that there is no reason why their rates of interest
should be the same for different commodities why the wheat-rate of
interest should be equal to the copper-rate of interest. For the relation
between the spot and future contracts, as quoted in the market, is
notoriously different for different commodities. This, we shall find, will
lead us to the clue we are seeking. For it may be that it is the greatest of
the own-rates of interest (as we may call them) which rules the roost
(because it is the greatest of these rates that the marginal efficiency of a
capital-asset must attain if it is to be newly produced); and that there are
reasons why it is the money-rate of interest which is often the greatest
(because, as we shall find, certain forces, which operate to reduce the own-
rates of interest of other assets, do not operate in the case of money).
It may be added that, just as there are differing commodity-rates of
interest at any time, so also exchange dealers are familiar with the fact that
the rate of interest is not even the same in terms of two different moneys,
e.g. sterling and dollars. For here also the difference between the spot and
future contracts for a foreign money in terms of sterling are not, as a rule,
the same for different foreign moneys.
Now each of these commodity standards offers us the same facility as
money for measuring the marginal efficiency of capital. For we can take
any commodity we choose, e.g. wheat; calculate the wheat-value of the
prospective yields of any capital asset; and the rate of discount which
makes the present value of this series of wheat annuities equal to the
present supply price of the asset in terms of wheat gives us the marginal
efficiency of the asset in terms of wheat. If no change is expected in the
relative value of two alternative standards, then the marginal efficiency of
a capital-asset will be the same in whichever of the two standards it is
measured, since the numerator and denominator of the fraction which
leads up to the marginal efficiency will be changed in the same proportion.
file:///D:/keyness/chapter17.html 2/17
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 17
file:///D:/keyness/chapter17.html 4/17
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 17
file:///D:/keyness/chapter17.html 5/17
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 17
characterise money as we know it, are capable of justifying it. To the extent
that the established standard of value has these peculiarities, the summary
statement, that it is the money-rate of interest which is the significant rate
of interest, will hold good.
(i) The first characteristic which tends towards the above conclusion is
the fact that money has, both in the long and in the short period, a zero, or
at any rate a very small, elasticity of production, so far as the power of
private enterprise is concerned, as distinct from the monetary authority;
elasticity of production meaning, in this context, the response of the
quantity of labour applied to producing it to a rise in the quantity of labour
which a unit of it will command. Money, that is to say, cannot be readily
produced; labour cannot be turned on at will by entrepreneurs to
produce money in increasing quantities as its price rises in terms of the
wage-unit. In the case of an inconvertible managed currency this condition
is strictly satisfied. But in the case of a gold-standard currency it is also
approximately so, in the sense that the maximum proportional addition to
the quantity of labour which can be thus employed is very small, except
indeed in a country of which gold-mining is the major industry.
Now, in the case of assets having an elasticity of production, the
reason why we assumed their own-rate of interest to decline was because
we assumed the stock of them to increase as the result of a higher rate of
output. In the case of money, however postponing, for the moment, our
consideration of the effects of reducing the wage-unit or of a deliberate
increase in its supply by the monetary authority the supply is fixed.
Thus the characteristic that money cannot be readily produced by labour
gives at once some prima facie presumption for the view that its own-rate
of interest will be relatively reluctant to fall; whereas if money could be
grown like a crop or manufactured like a motor-car, depressions would be
avoided or mitigated because, if the price of other assets was tending to fall
in terms of money, more labour would be diverted into the production of
money; as we see to be the case in gold-mining countries, though for the
world as a whole the maximum diversion in this way is almost negligible.
(ii) Obviously, however, the above condition is satisfied, not only by
money, but by all pure rent-factors, the production of which is completely
inelastic. A second condition, therefore, is required to distinguish money
from other rent elements.
The second differentia of money is that it has an elasticity of
substitution equal, or nearly equal, to zero which means that as the
exchange value of money rises there is no tendency to substitute some
other factor for it; except, perhaps, to some trifling extent, where the
file:///D:/keyness/chapter17.html 7/17
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 17
file:///D:/keyness/chapter17.html 8/17
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 17
file:///D:/keyness/chapter17.html 9/17
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 17
analogous ways, have been on the right track; and the practical value of
their proposals deserves consideration.
The significance of the money-rate of interest arises, therefore, out of
the combination of the characteristics that, through the working of the
liquidity-motive, this rate of interest may be somewhat unresponsive to a
change in the proportion which the quantity of money bears to other forms
of wealth measured in money, and that money has (or may have) zero (or
negligible) elasticities both of production and of substitution. The first
condition means that demand may be predominantly directed to money,
the second that when this occurs labour cannot be employed in producing
more money, and the third that there is no mitigation at any point through
some other factor being capable, if it is sufficiently cheap, of doing moneys
duty equally well. The only relief apart from changes in the marginal
efficiency of capital can come (so long as the propensity towards
liquidity is unchanged) from an increase in the quantity of money, or
which is formally the same thing a rise in the value of money which
enables a given quantity to provide increased money-services.
Thus a rise in the money-rate of interest retards the output of all the
objects of which the production is elastic without being capable of
stimulating the output of money (the production of which is, by
hypothesis, perfectly inelastic). The money-rate of interest, by setting the
pace for all the other commodity-rates of interest, holds back investment
in the production of these other commodities without being capable of
stimulating investment for the production of money, which by hypothesis
cannot be produced. Moreover, owing to the elasticity of demand for liquid
cash in terms of debts, a small change in the conditions governing this
demand may not much alter the money-rate of interest, whilst (apart from
official action) it is also impracticable, owing to the inelasticity of the
production of money, for natural forces to bring the money-rate of interest
down by affecting the supply side. In the case of an ordinary commodity,
the inelasticity of the demand for liquid stocks of it would enable small
changes on the demand side to bring its rate of interest up or down with a
rush, whilst the elasticity of its supply would also tend to prevent a high
premium on spot over forward delivery. Thus with other commodities left
to themselves, natural forces, i.e. the ordinary forces of the market, would
tend to bring their rate of interest down until the emergence of full
employment had brought about for commodities generally the inelasticity
of supply which we have postulated as a normal characteristic of money.
Thus in the absence of money and in the absence we must, of course,
also suppose of any other commodity with the assumed characteristics
file:///D:/keyness/chapter17.html 10/17
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 17
of money, the rates of interest would only reach equilibrium when there is
full employment. Unemployment develops, that is to say, because people
want the moon; men cannot be employed when the object of desire (i.e.
money) is something which cannot be produced and the demand for which
cannot be readily choked off. There is no remedy but to persuade the
public that green cheese is practically the same thing and to have a green
cheese factory (i.e. a central bank) under public control.
It is interesting to notice that the characteristic which has been
traditionally supposed to render gold especially suitable for use as the
standard of value, namely, its inelasticity of supply, turns out to be
precisely the characteristic which is at the bottom of the trouble.
Our conclusion can be stated in the most general form (taking the
propensity to consume as given) as follows. No further increase in the rate
of investment is possible when the greatest amongst the own-rates of own-
interest of all available assets is equal to the greatest amongst the marginal
efficiencies of all assets, measured in terms of the asset whose own-rate of
own-interest is greatest.
In a position of full employment this condition is necessarily satisfied.
But it may also be satisfied before full employment is reached, if there
exists some asset, having zero (or relatively small) elasticities of
production and substitution, whose rate of interest declines more closely,
as output increases, than the marginal efficiencies of capital-assets
measured in terms of it.
file:///D:/keyness/chapter17.html 11/17
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 17
file:///D:/keyness/chapter17.html 12/17
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 17
file:///D:/keyness/chapter17.html 13/17
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 17
file:///D:/keyness/chapter17.html 15/17
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 17
that the system will be in equilibrium with that rate of interest and that
level of employment. Thus it was a mistake to speak of the natural rate of
interest or to suggest that the above definition would yield a unique value
for the rate of interest irrespective of the level of employment. I had not
then understood that, in certain conditions, the system could be in
equilibrium with less than full employment.
I am now no longer of the opinion that the concept of a natural rate
of interest, which previously seemed to me a most promising idea, has
anything very useful or significant to contribute to our analysis. It is
merely the rate of interest which will preserve the status quo; and, in
general, we have no predominant interest in the status quo as such.
If there is any such rate of interest, which is unique and significant, it
must be the rate which we might term the neutral rate of interest, namely,
the natural rate in the above sense which is consistent with full
employment, given the other parameters of the system; though this rate
might be better described, perhaps, as the optimum rate.
The neutral rate of interest can be more strictly defined as the rate of
interest which prevails in equilibrium when output and employment are
such that the elasticity of employment as a whole is zero.
The above gives us, once again, the answer to the question as to what
tacit assumption is required to make sense of the classical theory of the
rate of interest. This theory assumes either that the actual rate of interest
is always equal to the neutral rate of interest in the sense in which we have
just defined the latter, or alternatively that the actual rate of interest is
always equal to the rate of interest which will maintain employment at
some specified constant level. If the traditional theory is thus interpreted,
there is little or nothing in its practical conclusions to which we need take
exception. The classical theory assumes that the banking authority or
natural forces cause the market-rate of interest to satisfy one or other of
the above conditions; and it investigates what laws will govern the
application and rewards of the communitys productive resources subject
to this assumption. With this limitation in force, the volume of output
depends solely on the assumed constant level of employment in
conjunction with the current equipment and technique; and we are safely
ensconced in a Ricardian world.
file:///D:/keyness/chapter17.html 16/17
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 17
https://ebooks.adelaide.edu.au/k/keynes/john_maynard/k44g/chapter17.html
Last updated Sunday, March 27, 2016 at 11:56
file:///D:/keyness/chapter17.html 17/17
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 18
C 18
T G T E
R -S
We have now reached a point where we can gather together the threads of
our argument. To begin with, it may be useful to make clear which
elements in the economic system we usually take as given, which are the
independent variables of our system and which are the dependent
variables.
We take as given the existing skill and quantity of available labour, the
existing quality and quantity of available equipment, the existing
technique, the degree of competition, the tastes and habits of the
consumer, the disutility of different intensities of labour and of the
activities of supervision and organisation, as well as the social structure
including the forces, other than our variables set forth below, which
determine the distribution of the national income. This does not mean that
we assume these factors to be constant; but merely that, in this place and
context, we are not considering or taking into account the effects and
consequences of changes in them.
Our independent variables are, in the first instance, the propensity to
consume, the schedule of the marginal efficiency of capital and the rate of
interest, though, as we have already seen, these are capable of further
analysis.
Our dependent variables are the volume of employment and the
national income (or national dividend) measured in wage-units.
The factors, which we have taken as given, influence our independent
variables, but do not completely determine them. For example, the
schedule of the marginal efficiency of capital depends partly on the
existing quantity of equipment which is one of the given factors, but partly
file:///D:/keyness/chapter18.html 1/8
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 18
file:///D:/keyness/chapter18.html 2/8
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 18
file:///D:/keyness/chapter18.html 3/8
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 18
The above is a summary of the General Theory. But the actual phenomena
of the economic system are also coloured by certain special characteristics
of the propensity to consume, the schedule of the marginal efficiency of
capital and the rate of interest, about which we can safely generalise from
experience, but which are not logically necessary.
In particular, it is an outstanding characteristic of the economic
system in which we live that, whilst it is subject to severe fluctuations in
respect of output and employment, it is not violently unstable. Indeed it
seems capable of remaining in a chronic condition of subnormal activity
for a considerable period without any marked tendency either towards
recovery or towards complete collapse. Moreover, the evidence indicates
that full, or even approximately full, employment is of rare and short-lived
occurrence. Fluctuations may start briskly but seem to wear themselves
out before they have proceeded to great extremes, and an intermediate
situation which is neither desperate nor satisfactory is our normal lot. It is
upon the fact that fluctuations tend to wear themselves out before
file:///D:/keyness/chapter18.html 4/8
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 18
file:///D:/keyness/chapter18.html 5/8
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 18
file:///D:/keyness/chapter18.html 6/8
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 18
(iii) Our third condition accords with our experience of human nature.
For although the struggle for money-wages is, as we have pointed out
above, essentially a struggle to maintain a high relative wage, this struggle
is likely, as employment increases, to be intensified in each individual case
both because the bargaining position of the worker is improved and
because the diminished marginal utility of his wage and his improved
financial margin make him readier to run risks. Yet, all the same, these
motives will operate within limits, and workers will not seek a much
greater money-wage when employment improves or allow a very great
reduction rather than suffer any unemployment at all.
But here again, whether or not this conclusion is plausible a priori,
experience shows that some such psychological law must actually hold. For
if competition between unemployed workers always led to a very great
reduction of the money-wage, there would be a violent instability in the
price-level. Moreover, there might be no position of stable equilibrium
except in conditions consistent with full employment; since the wage-unit
might have to fall without limit until it reached a point where the effect of
the abundance of money in terms of the wage-unit on the rate of interest
was sufficient to restore a level of full employment. At no other point could
there be a resting-place.
(iv) Our fourth condition, which is a condition not so much of stability
as of alternate recession and recovery, is merely based on the presumption
that capital-assets are of various ages, wear out with time and are not all
very long-lived; so that if the rate of investment falls below a certain
minimum level, it is merely a question of time (failing large fluctuations in
other factors) before the marginal efficiency of capital rises sufficiently to
bring about a recovery of investment above this minimum. And similarly,
of course, if investment rises to a higher figure than formerly, it is only a
question of time before the marginal efficiency of capital falls sufficiently
to bring about a recession unless there are compensating changes in other
factors.
For this reason, even those degrees of recovery and recession, which
can occur within the limitations set by our other conditions of stability,
will be likely, if they persist for a sufficient length of time and are not
interfered with by changes in the other factors, to cause a reverse
movement in the opposite direction, until the same forces as before again
reverse the direction.
Thus our four conditions together are adequate to explain the
outstanding features of our actual experience; namely, that we oscillate,
avoiding the gravest extremes of fluctuation in employment and in prices
file:///D:/keyness/chapter18.html 7/8
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 18
https://ebooks.adelaide.edu.au/k/keynes/john_maynard/k44g/chapter18.html
Last updated Sunday, March 27, 2016 at 11:56
file:///D:/keyness/chapter18.html 8/8
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 19
C 19
C M -W
argue that profits will necessarily go up because wages have gone down.
But it would, I think, be more usual to agree that the reduction in money-
wages may have some effect on aggregate demand through its reducing the
purchasing power of some of the workers, but that the real demand of
other factors, whose money incomes have not been reduced, will be
stimulated by the fall in prices, and that the aggregate demand of the
workers themselves will be very likely increased as a result of the increased
volume of employment, unless the elasticity of demand for labour in
response to changes in money-wages is less than unity. Thus in the new
equilibrium there will be more employment than there would have been
otherwise except, perhaps, in some unusual limiting case which has no
reality in practice.
It is from this type of analysis that I fundamentally differ; or rather
from the analysis which seems to lie behind such observations as the
above. For whilst the above fairly represents, I think, the way in which
many economists talk and write, the underlying analysis has seldom been
written down in detail.
It appears, however, that this way of thinking is probably reached as
follows. In any given industry we have a demand schedule for the product
relating the quantities which can be sold to the prices asked; we have a
series of supply schedules relating the prices which will be asked for the
sale of different quantities on various bases of cost; and these schedules
between them lead up to a further schedule which, on the assumption that
other costs are unchanged (except as a result of the change in output),
gives us the demand schedule for labour in the industry relating the
quantity of employment to different levels of wages, the shape of the curve
at any point furnishing the elasticity of demand for labour. This
conception is then transferred without substantial modification to industry
as a whole; and it is supposed, by a parity of reasoning, that we have a
demand schedule for labour in industry as a whole relating the quantity of
employment to different levels of wages. It is held that it makes no
material difference to this argument whether it is in terms of money-wages
or of real wages. If we are thinking in terms of money-wages, we must, of
course, correct for changes in the value of money; but this leaves the
general tendency of the argument unchanged, since prices certainly do not
change in exact proportion to changes in money-wages.
If this is the groundwork of the argument (and, if it is not, I do not
know what the groundwork is), surely it is fallacious. For the demand
schedules for particular industries can only be constructed on some fixed
assumption as to the nature of the demand and supply schedules of other
file:///D:/keyness/chapter19.html 2/12
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 19
Let us, then, apply our own method of analysis to answering the problem.
It falls into two parts. (i) Does a reduction in money-wages have a direct
tendency, cet. par., to increase employment, cet. par. being taken to mean
that the propensity to consume, the schedule of the marginal efficiency of
capital and the rate of interest are the same as before for the community as
a whole? And (2) does a reduction in money-wages have a certain or
probable.tendency to affect employment in a particular direction through
its certain or probable repercussions on these three factors?
The first question we have already answered in the negative in the
preceding chapters. For we have shown that the volume of employment is
uniquely correlated with the volume ofeffective demand measured in
wage-units, and that the effective demand, being the sum of the expected
consumption and the expected investment, cannot change, if the
propensity to consume, the schedule of marginal efficiency of capital and
the rate of interest are all unchanged. If, without any change in these
file:///D:/keyness/chapter19.html 3/12
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 19
file:///D:/keyness/chapter19.html 4/12
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 19
file:///D:/keyness/chapter19.html 5/12
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 19
file:///D:/keyness/chapter19.html 9/12
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 19
file:///D:/keyness/chapter19.html 10/12
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 19
https://ebooks.adelaide.edu.au/k/keynes/john_maynard/k44g/chapter19.html
Last updated Sunday, March 27, 2016 at 11:56
file:///D:/keyness/chapter19.html 12/12
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Appendix to Chapter 19
A C 19
P P
U
Er = (x) F(x)
(x) F(x)
so that
(x) = 1 + 1
k
Thus Professor Pigous elasticity of the real demand for labour in the
aggregate is a concoction similar to some of my own, depending partly on
the physical and technical conditions in industry (as given by his function
F) and partly on the propensity to consume wage-goods (as given by his
function ); provided always that we are limiting ourselves to the special
case where marginal labour-cost is equal to marginal prime cost.
To determine the quantity of employment, Professor Pigou then
combines with his real demand for labour, a supply function for labour.
He assumes that this is a function of the real wage and of nothing else. But,
as he has also assumed that the real wage is a function of the number of
men x who are employed in the wage-goods industries, this amounts to
assuming that the total supply of labour at the existing real wage is a
function of x and of nothing else. That is to say, n = (x), where n is the
supply of labour available at a real wage F(x).
Thus, cleared of all complication, Professor Pigous analysis amounts
to an attempt to discover the volume of actual employment from the
equations
x + y = (x)
and
n = (x).
But there are here three unknowns and only two equations. It seems clear
that he gets round this difficulty by taking n = x + y. This amounts, of
course, to assuming that there is no involuntary unemployment in the
file:///D:/keyness/chapter19a.html 2/8
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Appendix to Chapter 19
strict sense, i.e. that all labour available at the existing real wage is in fact
employed. In this case x has the value which satisfies the equation
(x) = (x)
and when we have thus found that the value of x is equal to (say) n1, y
must be equal to (n1) n1, and total employment n is equal to (n1).
file:///D:/keyness/chapter19a.html 3/8
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Appendix to Chapter 19
what level of real wages will correspond to any given level of employment.
But it is not capable of telling us what determines the actual level of
employment; and on the problem of involuntary unemployment it has no
direct bearing.
If Professor Pigou were to deny the possibility of involuntary
unemployment in the sense in which I have defined it above, as, perhaps,
he would, it is still difficult to see how his analysis could be applied. For
his omission to discuss what determines the connection between x and y,
i.e. between employment in the wage-goods and non-wage-goods
industries respectively, still remains fatal.
Moreover, he agrees that within certain limits labour in fact often
stipulates, not for a given real wage, but for a given money-wage. But in
this case the supply function of labour is not a function of F(x) alone but
also of the money-price of wage-goods; with the result that the previous
analysis breaks down and an additional factor has to be introduced,
without there being an additional equation to provide for this additional
unknown. The pitfalls of a pseudo-mathematical method, which can make
no progress except by making everything a function of a single variable
and assuming that all the partial differentials vanish, could not be better
illustrated. For it is no good to admit later on that there are in fact other
variables, and yet to proceed without re-writing everything that has been
written up to that point. Thus if (within limits) it is a money-wage for
which labour stipulates, we still have insufficient data, even if we assume
that n = x + y, unless we know what determines the money-price of wage-
goods. For, the money-price of wage-goods will depend on the aggregate
amount of employment. Therefore we cannot say what aggregate
employment will be, until we know the money-price of wage-goods; and
we cannot know the money-price of wage-goods until we know the
aggregate amount of employment. We are, as I have said, one equation
short. Yet it might be a provisional assumption of a rigidity of money-
wages, rather than of real wages, which would bring our theory nearest to
the facts. For example, money-wages in Great Britain during the turmoil
and uncertainty and wide price fluctuations of the decade 19241934 were
stable within a range of 6 per cent, whereas real wages fluctuated by more
than 20 per cent. A theory cannot claim to be a general theory, unless it is
applicable to the case where (or the range within which) money-wages are
fixed, just as much as to any other case. Politicians are entitled to
complain that money-wages ought to be highly flexible; but a theorist
must be prepared to deal indifferently with either state of affairs. A
file:///D:/keyness/chapter19a.html 4/8
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Appendix to Chapter 19
definition (as we have seen above) on nothing but two factors, namely (1)
the relationship in any given environment between the total number of
men employed and the number who have to be employed in the wage-
goods industries to provide them with what they consume, and (2) the
state of marginal productivity in the wage-goods industries. Yet in Part V
of his Theory of Unemployment fluctuations in the state of the real
demand for labour are given a position of importance. The real demand
for labour is regarded as a factor which is susceptible of wide short-period
fluctuations (op. cit. Part V, chaps. vi.xii.), and the suggestion seems to
be that swings in the real demand for labour are, in combination with the
failure of wage policy to respond sensitively to such changes, largely
responsible for the trade cycle. To the reader all this seems, at first,
reasonable and familiar. For, unless he goes back to the definition,
fluctuations in the real demand for labour will convey to his mind the
same sort of suggestion as I mean to convey by fluctuations in the state of
aggregate demand. But if we go back to the definition of the real demand
for labour, all this loses its plausibility. For we shall find that there is
nothing in the world less likely to be subject to sharp short-period swings
than this factor.
Professor Pigous real demand for labour depends, by definition, on
nothing but F(x), which represents the physical conditions of production
in the wage-goods industries, and (x), which represents the functional
relationship between employment in the wage-goods industries and total
employment corresponding to any given level of the latter. It is difficult to
see a reason why either of these functions should change, except gradually
over a long period. Certainly there seems no reason to suppose that they
are likely to fluctuate during a trade cycle. For F(x) can only change slowly,
and, in a technically progressive community, only in the forward direction;
whilst (x) will remain stable, unless we suppose a sudden outbreak of thrift
in the working classes, or, more generally, a sudden shift in the propensity
to consume. I should expect, therefore, that the real demand for labour
would remain virtually constant throughout a trade cycle. I repeat that
Professor Pigou has altogether omitted from his analysis the unstable
factor, namely fluctuations in the scale of investment, which is most often
at the bottom of the phenomenon of fluctuations in employment.
I have criticised at length Professor Pigous theory of unemployment
not because he seems to me to be more open to criticism than other
economists of the classical school; but because his is the only attempt with
which I am acquainted to write down the classical theory of
unemployment precisely. Thus it has been incumbent on me to raise my
file:///D:/keyness/chapter19a.html 7/8
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Appendix to Chapter 19
https://ebooks.adelaide.edu.au/k/keynes/john_maynard/k44g/chapter19a.html
Last updated Sunday, March 27, 2016 at 11:56
file:///D:/keyness/chapter19a.html 8/8
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 20
C 20
T E F
file:///D:/keyness/chapter20.html 1/9
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 20
file:///D:/keyness/chapter20.html 2/9
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 20
Provided we can assume that the price is equal to the marginal prime cost,
we then have
1
Dwr = 1 e DPr
or
where Pr is the expected profit. It follows from this that if eor = 0, i.e. if the
output of the industry is perfectly inelastic, the whole of the increased
effective demand (in terms of wage-units) is expected to accrue to the
entrepreneur as profit, i.e. Dwr = Pr; whilst if eor = 1, i.e. if the elasticity
of output is unity, no part of the increased effective demand is expected to
accrue as profit, the whole of it being absorbed by the elements entering
into marginal prime cost.
Moreover, if the output of an industry is a function (Nr) of the labour
employed in it, we have
1 eor Nr "(Nr)
=
eer pwr{(Nr)}2
where pwr is the expected price of a unit of output in terms of the wage-
unit. Thus the condition eor = 1 means that "(Nr) = 0, i.e. that there are
constant returns in response to increased employment.
file:///D:/keyness/chapter20.html 3/9
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 20
Now, in so far as the classical theory assumes that real wages are
always equal to the marginal disutility of labour and that the latter
increases when employment increases, so that the labour supply will fall
off; cet. par., if real wages are reduced, it is assuming that in practice it is
impossible to increase expenditure in terms of wage-units. If this were
true, the concept of elasticity of employment would have no field of
application. Moreover, it would, in this event, be impossible to increase
employment by increasing expenditure in terms of money; for money-
wages would rise proportionately to the increased money expenditure so
that there would be no increase of expenditure in terms of wage-units and
consequently no increase in employment. But if the classical assumption
does not hold good, it will be possible to increase employment by
increasing expenditure in terms of money until real wages have fallen to
equality with the marginal disutility of labour, at which point there will, by
definition, be full employment.
Ordinarily, of course, eor will have a value intermediate between zero
and unity. The extent to which prices (in terms of wage-units) will rise, i.e.
the extent to which real wages will fall, when money expenditure is
increased, depends, therefore, on the elasticity of output in response to
expenditure in terms of wage-units.
Let the elasticity of the expected price pwr in response to changes in
effective demand Dwr, namely (dpwr/dDwr) (Dwr /pwr), be written epr.
or
epr + eor = 1.
That is to say, the sum of the elasticities of price and of output in response
to changes in effective demand (measured in terms of wage-units) is equal
to unity. Effective demand spends itself, partly in affecting output and
partly in affecting price, according to this law.
If we are dealing with industry as a whole and are prepared to assume
that we have a unit in which output as a whole can be measured, the same
line of argument applies, so that ep + eo = 1, where the elasticities without
a suffix r apply to industry as a whole.
Let us now measure values in money instead of wage-units and extend
to this case our conclusions in respect of industry as a whole.
file:///D:/keyness/chapter20.html 4/9
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 20
This equation is, as we shall see in the next chapter, first step to a
generalised quantity theory of money.
If eo = 0 or if ew = 1, output will be unaltered and prices will rise in the
same proportion as effective demand in terms of money. Otherwise they
will rise in a smaller proportion.
file:///D:/keyness/chapter20.html 7/9
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 20
file:///D:/keyness/chapter20.html 8/9
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 20
https://ebooks.adelaide.edu.au/k/keynes/john_maynard/k44g/chapter20.html
Last updated Sunday, March 27, 2016 at 11:56
file:///D:/keyness/chapter20.html 9/9
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 21
C 21
T T P
resources on the one hand, and the theory of output and employment as a
whole on the other hand. So long as we limit ourselves to the study of the
individual industry or firm on the assumption that the aggregate quantity
of employed resources is constant, and, provisionally, that the conditions
of other industries or firms are unchanged, it is true that we are not
concerned with the significant characteristics of money. But as soon as we
pass to the problem of what determines output and employment as a
whole, we require the complete theory of a monetary economy.
Or, perhaps, we might make our line of division between the theory of
stationary equilibrium and the theory of shifting equilibrium meaning
by the latter the theory of a system in which changing views about the
future are capable of influencing the present situation. For the importance
of money essentially flows from its being a link between the present and
the future. We can consider what distribution of resources between
different uses will be consistent with equilibrium under the influence of
normal economic motives in a world in which our views concerning the
future are fixed and reliable in all respects; with a further division,
perhaps, between an economy which is unchanging and one subject to
change, but where all things are foreseen from the beginning. Or we can
pass from this simplified propaedeutic to the problems of the real world in
which our previous expectations are liable to disappointment and
expectations concerning the future affect what we do to-day. It is when we
have made this transition that the peculiar properties of money as a link
between the present and the future must enter into our calculations. But,
although the theory of shifting equilibrium must necessarily be pursued in
terms of a monetary economy, it remains a theory of value and
distribution and not a separate theory of money. Money in its significant
attributes is, above all, a subtle device for linking the present to the future;
and we cannot even begin to discuss the effect of changing expectations on
current activities except in monetary terms. We cannot get rid of money
even by abolishing gold and silver and legal tender instruments. So long as
there exists any durable asset, it is capable of possessing monetary
attributes and, therefore, of giving rise to the characteristic problems of a
monetary economy.
file:///D:/keyness/chapter21.html 2/14
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 21
cost, and partly on the scale of output. There is no reason to modify this
conclusion when we pass to industry as a whole. The general price-level
depends partly on the rate of remuneration of the factors of production
which enter into marginal cost and partly on the scale of output as a whole,
i.e. (taking equipment and technique as given) on the volume of
employment. It is true that, when we pass to output as a whole, the costs of
production in any industry partly depend on the output of other
industries. But the more significant change, of which we have to take
account, is the effect of changes in demand both on costs and on volume.
It is on the side of demand that we have to introduce quite new ideas when
we are dealing with demand as a whole and no longer with the demand for
a single product taken in isolation, with demand as a whole assumed to be
unchanged.
file:///D:/keyness/chapter21.html 3/14
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 21
file:///D:/keyness/chapter21.html 4/14
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 21
influence the relation between the quantity of money and the quantity of
effective demand. The object of our analysis is, not to provide a machine,
or method of blind manipulation, which will furnish an infallible answer,
but to provide ourselves with an organised and orderly method of thinking
out particular problems; and, after we have reached a provisional
conclusion by isolating the complicating factors one by one, we then have
to go back on ourselves and allow, as well as we can, for the probable
interactions of the factors amongst themselves. This is the nature of
economic thinking. Any other way of applying our formal principles of
thought (without which, however, we shall be lost in the wood) will lead us
into error. It is a great fault of symbolic pseudo-mathematical methods of
formalising a system of economic analysis, such as we shall set down in
section vi of this chapter, that they expressly assume strict independence
between the factors involved and lose all their cogency and authority if this
hypothesis is disallowed; whereas, in ordinary discourse, where we are not
blindly manipulating but know all the time what we are doing and what
the words mean, we can keep at the back of our heads the necessary
reserves and qualifications and the adjustments which we shall have to
make later on, in a way in which we cannot keep complicated partial
differentials at the back of several pages of algebra which assume that
they all vanish. Too large a proportion of recent mathematical economics
are merely concoctions, as imprecise as the initial assumptions they rest
on, which allow the author to lose sight of the complexities and
interdependencies of the real world in a maze of pretentious and unhelpful
symbols.
(1) The primary effect of a change in the quantity of money on the quantity
of effective demand is through its influence on the rate of interest. If this
were the only reaction, the quantitative effect could be derived from the
three elements (a) the schedule of liquidity-preference which tells us by
how much the rate of interest will have to fall in order that the new money
may be absorbed by willing holders, (b) the schedule of marginal
efficiencies which tells us by how much a given fall in the rate of interest
will increase investment, and (c) the investment multiplier which tells us
by how much a given increase in investment will increase effective demand
as a whole.
file:///D:/keyness/chapter21.html 5/14
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 21
file:///D:/keyness/chapter21.html 6/14
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 21
file:///D:/keyness/chapter21.html 7/14
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 21
file:///D:/keyness/chapter21.html 9/14
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 21
This gives us
Mdp = e e
p d
pdM
where
ep = 1 ee eo(1 ew);
so that
e = ed (1 ew)ed eeeo = ed(1 ee eo + ee eo ew)
file:///D:/keyness/chapter21.html 10/14
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 21
where e without suffix (= (Mdp) / (pdM)) stands for the apex of this
pyramid and measures the response of money-prices to changes in the
quantity of money.
Since this last expression gives us the proportionate change in prices
in response to a change in the quantity of money, it can be regarded as a
generalised statement of the quantity theory of money. I do not myself
attach much value to manipulations of this kind; and I would repeat the
warning, which I have given above, that they involve just as much tacit
assumption as to what variables are taken as independent (partial
differentials being ignored throughout) as does ordinary discourse, whilst
I doubt if they carry us any further than ordinary discourse can. Perhaps
the best purpose served by writing them down is to exhibit the extreme
complexity of the relationship between prices and the quantity of money,
when we attempt to express it in a formal manner. It is, however, worth
pointing out that, of the four terms ed, ew, ee and eo upon which the effect
on prices of changes in the quantity of money depends, ed stands for the
liquidity factors which determine the demand for money in each situation,
ew for the labour factors (or, more strictly, the factors entering into prime-
cost) which determine the extent to which money-wages are raised as
employment increases, and ee and eo for the physical factors which
determine the rate of decreasing returns as more employment is applied to
the existing equipment.
If the public hold a constant proportion of their income in money,
ed = 1; if money-wages are fixed, ew = 0; if there are constant returns
throughout so that marginal return equals average return, ee eo = 1; and if
there is full employment either of labour or of equipment, ee eo = 0.
So far, we have been primarily concerned with the way in which changes in
the quantity of money affect prices in the short period. But in the long run
file:///D:/keyness/chapter21.html 11/14
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 21
years the long-run typical rate of interest in the leading financial centres
was about 5 per cent, and the gilt-edged rate between 3 and 3 per cent;
and that these rates of interest were modest enough to encourage a rate of
investment consistent with an average of employment which was not
intolerably low. Sometimes the wage-unit, but more often the monetary
standard or the monetary system (in particular through the development
of bank-money), would be adjusted so as to ensure that the quantity of
money in terms of wage-units was sufficient to satisfy normal liquidity-
preference at rates of interest which were seldom much below the
standard rates indicated above. The tendency of the wage-unit was, as
usual, steadily upwards on the whole, but the efficiency of labour was also
increasing. Thus the balance of forces was such as to allow a fair measure
of stability of prices; the highest quinquennial average for Sauerbecks
index number between 1820 and 1914 was only 50 per cent above the
lowest. This was not accidental. It is rightly described as due to a balance
of forces in an age when individual groups of employers were strong
enough to prevent the wage-unit from rising much faster than the
efficiency of production, and when monetary systems were at the same
time sufficiently fluid and sufficiently conservative to provide an average
supply of money in terms of wage-units which allowed to prevail the
lowest average rate of interest readily acceptable by wealth-owners under
the influence of their liquidity-preferences. The average level of
employment was, of course, substantially below full employment, but not
so intolerably below it as to provoke revolutionary changes.
To-day and presumably for the future the schedule of the marginal
efficiency of capital is, for a variety of reasons, much lower than it was in
the nineteenth century. The acuteness and the peculiarity of our
contemporary problem arises, therefore, out of the possibility that the
average rate of interest which will allow a reasonable average level of
employment is one so unacceptable to wealth-owners that it cannot be
readily established merely by manipulating the quantity of money. So long
as a tolerable level of employment could be attained on the average of one
or two or three decades merely by assuring an adequate supply of money
in terms of wage-units, even the nineteenth century could find a way. If
this was our only problem now if a sufficient degree of devaluation is all
we need we, to-day, would certainly find a way.
But the most stable, and the least easily shifted, element in our
contemporary economy has been hitherto, and may prove to be in future,
the minimum rate of interest acceptable to the generality of wealth-
owners. If a tolerable level of employment requires a rate of interest much
file:///D:/keyness/chapter21.html 13/14
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 21
below the average rates which ruled in the nineteenth century, it is most
doubtful whether it can be achieved merely by manipulating the quantity
of money. From the percentage gain, which the schedule of marginal
efficiency of capital allows the borrower to expect to earn, there has to be
deducted (1) the cost of bringing borrowers and lenders together, (2)
income and sur-taxes and (3) the allowance which the lender requires to
cover his risk and uncertainty, before we arrive at the net yield available to
tempt the wealth-owner to sacrifice his liquidity. If, in conditions of
tolerable average employment, this net yield turns out to be infinitesimal,
time-honoured methods may prove unavailing.
To return to our immediate subject, the long-run relationship between
the national income and the quantity of money will depend on liquidity-
preferences. And the long-run stability or instability of prices will depend
on the strength of the upward trend ofthe wage-unit (or, more precisely, of
the cost-unit) compared with the rate of increase in the efficiency of the
productive system.
https://ebooks.adelaide.edu.au/k/keynes/john_maynard/k44g/chapter21.html
Last updated Sunday, March 27, 2016 at 11:56
file:///D:/keyness/chapter21.html 14/14
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 22
C 22
N T C
By a cyclical movement we mean that as the system progresses in, e.g. the
upward direction, the forces propelling it upwards at first gather force and
have a cumulative effect on one another but gradually lose their strength
until at a certain point they tend to be replaced by forces operating in the
opposite direction; which in turn gather force for a time and accentuate
one another, until they too, having reached their maximum development,
wane and give place to their opposite. We do not, however, merely mean
file:///D:/keyness/chapter22.html 1/15
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 22
I can best introduce what I have to say by beginning with the later stages
of the boom and the onset of the crisis.
We have seen above that the marginal efficiency of capital depends,
not only on the existing abundance or scarcity of capital-goods and the
current cost of production of capital-goods, but also on current
expectations as to the future yield of capital-goods. In the case of durable
assets it is, therefore, natural and reasonable that expectations of the
future should play a dominant part in determining the scale on which new
investment is deemed advisable. But, as we have seen, the basis for such
expectations is very precarious. Being based on shifting and unreliable
evidence, they are subject to sudden and violent changes.
file:///D:/keyness/chapter22.html 2/15
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 22
file:///D:/keyness/chapter22.html 3/15
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 22
goods. The carrying-costs of these stocks will seldom be less than 10 per
cent. per annum. Thus the fall in their price needs to be sufficient to bring
about a restriction which provides for their absorption within a period of;
say, three to five years at the outside. Now the process of absorbing the
stocks represents negative investment, which is a further deterrent to
employment; and, when it is over, a manifest relief will be experienced.
Moreover, the reduction in working capital, which is necessarily attendant
on the decline in output on the downward phase, represents a further
element of disinvestment, which may be large; and, once the recession has
begun, this exerts a strong cumulative influence in the downward
direction. In the earliest phase of a typical slump there will probably be an
investment in increasing stocks which helps to offset disinvestment in
working-capital; in the next phase there may be a short period of
disinvestment both in stocks and in working-capital; after the lowest point
has been passed there is likely to be a further disinvestment in stocks
which partially offsets reinvestment in working-capital; and, finally, after
the recovery is well on its way, both factors will be simultaneously
favourable to investment. It is against this background that the additional
and superimposed effects of fluctuations of investment in durable goods
must be examined. When a decline in this type of investment has set a
cyclical fluctuation in motion there will be little encouragement to a
recovery in such investment until the cycle has partly run its course.
Unfortunately a serious fall in the marginal efficiency of capital also
tends to affect adversely the propensity to consume. For it involves a
severe decline in the market value of stock exchange equities. Now, on the
class who take an active interest in their stock exchange investments,
especially if they are employing borrowed funds, this naturally exerts a
very depressing influence. These people are, perhaps, even more
influenced in their readiness to spend by rises and falls in the value of their
investments than by the state of their incomes. With a stock-minded
public as in the United States to-day, a rising stock-market may be an
almost essential condition of a satisfactory propensity to consume; and
this circumstance, generally overlooked until lately, obviously serves to
aggravate still further the depressing effect of a decline in the marginal
efficiency of capital.
When once the recovery has been started, the manner in which it
feeds on itself and cumulates is obvious. But during the downward phase,
when both fixed capital and stocks of materials are for the time being
redundant and working-capital is being reduced, the schedule of the
marginal efficiency of capital may fall so low that it can scarcely be
file:///D:/keyness/chapter22.html 5/15
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 22
file:///D:/keyness/chapter22.html 6/15
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 22
file:///D:/keyness/chapter22.html 8/15
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 22
file:///D:/keyness/chapter22.html 9/15
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 22
Another school of thought finds the solution of the trade cycle, not in
increasing either consumption or investment, but in diminishing the
supply of labour seeking employment; i.e. by redistributing the existing
volume of employment without increasing employment or output.
This seems to me to be a premature policy much more clearly so
than the plan of increasing consumption. A point comes where every
individual weighs the advantages of increased leisure against increased
income. But at present the evidence is, I think, strong that the great
majority of individuals would prefer increased income to increased leisure;
and I see no sufficient reason for compelling those who would prefer more
income to enjoy more leisure.
file:///D:/keyness/chapter22.html 10/15
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 22
file:///D:/keyness/chapter22.html 11/15
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 22
can be unequal, and has, therefore, no meaning until these terms have
been defined in some special sense. Or it is sometimes suggested that the
increased saving which accompanies increased investment is undesirable
and unjust because it is, as a rule, also associated with rising prices. But if
this were so, any upward change in the existing level of output and
employment is to be deprecated. For the rise in prices is not essentially
due to the increase in investment; it is due to the fact that in the short
period supply price usually increases with increasing output, on account
either of the physical fact of diminishing return or of the tendency of the
cost-unit to rise in terms of money when output increases. If the
conditions were those of constant supply-price, there would, of course, be
no rise of prices; yet, all the same, increased saving would accompany
increased investment. It is the increased output which produces the
increased saving; and the rise of prices is merely a by-product of the
increased output, which will occur equally if there is no increased saving
but, instead, an increased propensity to consume. No one has a legitimate
vested interest in being able to buy at prices which are only low because
output is low.
Or, again, the evil is supposed to creep in if the increased investment
has been promoted by a fall in the rate of interest engineered by an
increase in the quantity of money. Yet there is no special virtue in the pre-
existing rate of interest, and the new money is not forced on anyone; it
is created in order to satisfy the increased liquidity-preference which
corresponds to the lower rate of interest or the increased volume of
transactions, and it is held by those individuals who prefer to hold money
rather than to lend it at the lower rate of interest. Or, once more, it is
suggested that a boom is characterised by capital consumption, which
presumably means negative net investment, i.e. by an excessive propensity
to consume. Unless the phenomena of the trade cycle have been confused
with those of a flight from the currency such as occurred during the post-
war European currency collapses, the evidence is wholly to the contrary.
Moreover, even if it were so, a reduction in the rate of interest would be a
more plausible remedy than a rise in the rate of interest for conditions of
under-investment. I can make no sense at all of these schools of thought;
except, perhaps, by supplying a tacit assumption that aggregate output is
incapable of change. But a theory which assumes constant output is
obviously not very serviceable for explaining the trade cycle.
file:///D:/keyness/chapter22.html 12/15
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 22
file:///D:/keyness/chapter22.html 13/15
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 22
https://ebooks.adelaide.edu.au/k/keynes/john_maynard/k44g/chapter22.html
Last updated Sunday, March 27, 2016 at 11:56
file:///D:/keyness/chapter22.html 15/15
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 23
C 23
N M , U
L ,S M T
U -C
For some two hundred years both economic theorists and practical men
did not doubt that there is a peculiar advantage to a country in a
favourable balance of trade, and grave danger in an unfavourable balance,
particularly if it results in an efflux of the precious metals. But for the past
one hundred years there has been a remarkable divergence of opinion. The
majority of statesmen and practical men in most countries, and nearly half
of them even in Great Britain, the home of the opposite view, have
remained faithful to the ancient doctrine; whereas almost all economic
theorists have held that anxiety concerning such matters is absolutely
groundless except on a very short view, since the mechanism of foreign
trade is self-adjusting and attempts to interfere with it are not only futile,
but greatly impoverish those who practise them because they forfeit the
advantages of the international division of labour. It will be convenient, in
accordance with tradition, to designate the older opinion as mercantilism
and the newer as free trade, though these terms, since each of them has
both a broader and a narrower signification, must be interpreted with
reference to the context.
Generally speaking, modern economists have maintained not merely
that there is, as a rule, a balance of gain from the international division of
labour sufficient to outweigh such advantages as mercantilist practice can
fairly claim, but that the mercantilist argument is based, from start to
finish, on an intellectual confusion.
Marshall,for example, although his references to mercantilism are not
altogether unsympathetic, had no regard for their central theory as such
file:///D:/keyness/chapter23.html 1/28
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 23
and does not even mention those elements of truth in their contentions
which I shall examine below. In the same way, the theoretical concessions
which free-trade economists have been ready to make in contemporary
controversies, relating, for example, to the encouragement of infant
industries or to the improvement of the terms of trade, are not concerned
with the real substance of the mercantilist case. During the fiscal
controversy of the first quarter of the present century I do not remember
that any concession was ever allowed by economists to the claim that
protection might increase domestic employment. It will be fairest,
perhaps, to quote, as an example, what I wrote myself. So lately as 1923, as
a faithful pupil of the classical school who did not at that time doubt what
he had been taught and entertained on this matter no reserves at all, I
wrote: If there is one thing that Protection can not do, it is to cure
Unemployment . . . There are some arguments for Protection, based upon
its securing possible but improbable advantages, to which there is no
simple answer. But the claim to cure Unemployment involves the
Protectionist fallacy in its grossest and crudest form. As for earlier
mercantilist theory, no intelligible account was available; and we were
brought up to believe that it was little better than nonsense. So absolutely
overwhelming and complete has been the domination of the classical
school.
file:///D:/keyness/chapter23.html 2/28
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 23
For this and other reasons the reader must not reach a premature
conclusion as to the practical policy to which our argument leads up.
There are strong presumptions of a general character against trade
restrictions unless they can be justified on special grounds. The
advantages of the international division of labour are real and substantial,
even though the classical school greatly overstressed them. The fact that
the advantage which our own country gains from a favourable balance is
liable to involve an equal disadvantage to some other country (a point to
which the mercantilists were fully alive) means not only that great
moderation is necessary, so that a country secures for itself no larger a
share of the stock of the precious metals than is fair and reasonable, but
also that an immoderate policy may lead to a senseless international
competition for a favourable balance which injures all alike. And finally, a
policy of trade restrictions is a treacherous instrument even for the
attainment of its ostensible object, since private interest, administrative
incompetence and the intrinsic difficulty of the task may divert it into
producing results directly opposite to those intended.
Thus, the weight of my criticism is directed against the inadequacy of
the theoretical foundations of the laissez-faire doctrine upon which I was
brought up and which for many years I taught; against the notion that
the rate of interest and the volume of investment are self-adjusting at the
optimum level, so that preoccupation with the balance of trade is a waste
of time. For we, the faculty of economists, prove to have been guilty of
presumptuous error in treating as a puerile obsession what for centuries
has been a prime object of practical statecraft.
Under the influence of this faulty theory the City of London gradually
devised the most dangerous technique for the maintenance of equilibrium
which can possibly be imagined, namely, the technique of bank rate
coupled with a rigid parity of the foreign exchanges. For this meant that
the objective of maintaining a domestic rate of interest consistent with full
employment was wholly ruled out. Since, in practice, it is impossible to
neglect the balance of payments, a means of controlling it was evolved
which, instead of protecting the domestic rate of interest, sacrificed it to
the operation of blind forces. Recently, practical bankers in London have
learnt much, and one can almost hope that in Great Britain the technique
of bank rate will never be used again to protect the foreign balance in
conditions in which it is likely to cause unemployment at home.
Regarded as the theory of the individual firm and of the distribution
of the product resulting from the employment of a given quantity of
resources, the classical theory has made a contribution to economic
file:///D:/keyness/chapter23.html 5/28
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 23
The early pioneers of economic thinking may have hit upon their maxims
of practical wisdom without having had much cognisance of the
underlying theoretical grounds. Let us, therefore, examine briefly the
reasons they gave as well as what they recommended. This is made easy by
reference to Professor Heckschers great work on Mercantilism, in which
the essential characteristics of economic thought over a period of two
centuries are made available for the first time to the general economic
reader. The quotations which follow are mainly taken from his pages.
(1) Mercantilists thought never supposed that there was a self-
adjusting tendency by which the rate of interest would be established at
the appropriate level. On the contrary they were emphatic that an unduly
high rate of interest was the main obstacle to the growth of wealth; and
they were even aware that the rate of interest depended on liquidity-
preference and the quantity of money. They were concerned both with
diminishing liquidity-preference and with increasing the quantity of
money, and several of them made it clear that their preoccupation with
increasing the quantity of money was due to their desire to diminish the
rate of interest. Professor Heckscher sums up this aspect of their theory as
follows:
file:///D:/keyness/chapter23.html 6/28
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 23
The great Locke was, perhaps, the first to express in abstract terms the
relationship between the rate of interest and the quantity of money in his
controversy with Petty. He was opposing Pettys proposal of a maximum
rate of interest on the ground that it was as impracticable as to fix a
maximum rent for land, since the natural Value of Money, as it is apt to
yield such an yearly Income by Interest, depends on the whole quantity of
file:///D:/keyness/chapter23.html 7/28
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 23
the then passing Money of the Kingdom, in proportion to the whole Trade
of the Kingdom (i.e. the general Vent of all the commodities). Locke
explains that money has two values: (i) its value in use which is given by
the rate of interest and in this it has the Nature of Land, the Income of one
being called Rent, of the other, Use, and (2) its value in exchange and in
this it has the Nature of a Commodity, its value in exchange depending
only on the Plenty or Scarcity of Money in proportion to the Plenty or
Scarcity of those things and not on what Interest shall be. Thus Locke was
the parent of twin quantity theories. In the first place he held that the rate
of interest depended on the proportion of the quantity of money (allowing
for the velocity of circulation) to the total value of trade. In the second
place he held that the value of money in exchange depended on the
proportion of the quantity of money to the total volume of goods in the
market. But standing with one foot in the mercantilist world and with
one foot in the classical world he was confused concerning the relation
between these two proportions, and he overlooked altogether the
possibility of fluctuations in liquidity-preference. He was, however, eager
to explain that a reduction in the rate of interest has no direct effect on the
price-level and affects prices only as the Change of Interest in Trade
conduces to the bringing in or carrying out Money or Commodity, and so
in time varying their Proportion here in England from what it was before,
i.e. if the reduction in the rate of interest leads to the export of cash or an
increase in output. But he never, I think, proceeds to a genuine synthesis.
How easily the mercantilist mind distinguished between the rate of
interest and the marginal efficiency of capital is illustrated by a passage
(printed in 1621) which Locke quotes from A Letter to a friend concerning
Usury: High Interest decays Trade. The advantage from Interest is greater
than the Profit from Trade, which makes the rich Merchants give over, and
put out their Stock to Interest, and the lesser Merchants Break. Fortrey
(Englands Interest and Improvement, 1663) affords another example of
the stress laid on a low rate of interest as a means of increasing wealth.
The mercantilists did not overlook the point that, if an excessive
liquidity-preference were to withdraw the influx of precious metals into
hoards, the advantage to the rate of interest would be lost. In some cases
(e.g. Mun) the object of enhancing the power of the State led them,
nevertheless, to advocate the accumulation of state treasure. But others
frankly opposed this policy:
(2) The mercantilists were aware of the fallacy of cheapness and the
danger that excessive competition may turn the terms of trade against a
country. Thus Malynes wrote in his Lex Mercatoria (1622): Strive not to
undersell others to the hurt of the Commonwealth, under colour to
increase trade: for trade doth not increase when commodities are good
cheap, because the cheapness proceedeth of the small request and scarcity
of money, which maketh things cheap: so that the contrary augmenteth
trade when there is plenty of money, and commodities become dearer
being in request. Professor Heckscher sums up as follows this strand in
mercantilist thought:
In the course of a century and a half this standpoint was formulated again
and again in this way, that a country with relatively less money than other
countries must sell cheap and buy dear . . .
Even in the original edition of the Discourse of the Common Weal,
that is in the middle of the 16th century, this attitude was already
manifested. Hales said, in fact, And yet if strangers should be content to
take but our wares for theirs, what should let them to advance the price of
other things (meaning: among others, such as we buy from them), though
ours were good cheap unto them? And then shall we be still losers, and
they at the winning hand with us, while they sell dear and yet buy ours
good cheap, and consequently enrich themselves and impoverish us. Yet
had I rather advance our wares in price, as they advance theirs, as we now
do; though some be losers thereby, and yet not so many as should be the
other way. On this point he had the unqualified approval of his editor
several decades later (1581). In the 17th century, this attitude recurred
again without any fundamental change in significance. Thus, Malynes
believed this unfortunate position to be the result of what he dreaded
above all things, i.e. a foreign under-valuation of the English exchange . . .
The same conception then recurred continually. In his Verbum Sapienti
(written 1665, published 1691), Petty believed that the violent efforts to
increase the quantity of money could only cease when we have certainly
more money than any of our Neighbour States (though never so little),
file:///D:/keyness/chapter23.html 9/28
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 23
(3) The mercantilists were the originals of the fear of goods and the
scarcity of money as causes of unemployment which the classicals were to
denounce two centuries later as an absurdity:
file:///D:/keyness/chapter23.html 10/28
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 23
new supplies of gold and silver were comparatively abundant, the struggle
might be somewhat abated. But with the growth of wealth and the
diminishing marginal propensity to consume, it has tended to become
increasingly internecine. The part played by orthodox economists, whose
common sense has been insufficient to check their faulty logic, has been
disastrous to the latest act. For when in their blind struggle for an escape,
some countries have thrown off the obligations which had previously
rendered impossible an autonomous rate of interest, these economists
have taught that a restoration of the former shackles is a necessary first
step to a general recovery.
In truth the opposite holds good. It is the policy of an autonomous
rate of interest, unimpeded by international preoccupations, and of a
national investment programme directed to an optimum level of domestic
employment which is twice blessed in the sense that it helps ourselves and
our neighbours at the same time. And it is the simultaneous pursuit of
these policies by all countries together which is capable of restoring
economic health and strength internationally, whether we measure it by
the level of domestic employment or by the volume of international trade.
If, then, the underlying attitude towards money and the material from
which money was created did not alter in the period between the Crusades
and the 18th century, it follows that we are dealing with deep-rooted
notions. Perhaps the same notions have persisted even beyond the 500
years included in that period, even though not nearly to the same degree as
the fear of goods. With the exception of the period of laissez-faire, no age
has been free from these ideas. It was only the unique intellectual tenacity
of laissez-faire that for a time overcame the beliefs of the natural man on
this point.
It required the unqualified faith of doctrinaire laissez-faire to wipe
out the fear of goods . . . [which] is the most natural attitude of the
file:///D:/keyness/chapter23.html 12/28
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 23
There remains an allied, but distinct, matter where for centuries, indeed
for several millenniums, enlightened opinion held for certain and obvious
a doctrine which the classical school has repudiated as childish, but which
deserves rehabilitation and honour. I mean the doctrine that the rate of
interest is not self-adjusting at a level best suited to the social advantage
but constantly tends to rise too high, so that a wise government is
concerned to curb it by statute and custom and even by invoking the
sanctions of the moral law.
Provisions against usury are amongst the most ancient economic
practices of which we have record. The destruction of the inducement to
invest by an excessive liquidity-preference was the outstanding evil, the
prime impediment to the growth of wealth, in the ancient and medieval
worlds. And naturally so, since certain of the risks and hazards of
economic life diminish the marginal efficiency of capital whilst others
serve to increase the preference for liquidity. In a world, therefore, which
no one reckoned to be safe, it was almost inevitable that the rate of
interest, unless it was curbed by every instrument at the disposal of
society, would rise too high to permit of an adequate inducement to invest.
I was brought up to believe that the attitude of the Medieval Church to
the rate of interest was inherently absurd, and that the subtle discussions
aimed at distinguishing the return on money-loans from the return to
active investment were merely jesuitical attempts to find a practical escape
from a foolish theory. But I now read these discussions as an honest
intellectual effort to keep separate what the classical theory has
inextricably confused together, namely, the rate of interest and the
file:///D:/keyness/chapter23.html 13/28
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 23
marginal efficiency of capital. For it now seems clear that the disquisitions
of the schoolmen were directed towards the elucidation of a formula which
should allow the schedule of the marginal efficiency of capital to be high,
whilst using rule and custom and the moral law to keep down the rate of
interest.
Even Adam Smith was extremely moderate in his attitude to the usury
laws. For lie was well aware that individual savings may be absorbed either
by investment or by debts, and that there is no security that they will find
an outlet in the former. Furthermore, he favoured a low rate of interest as
increasing the chance of savings finding their outlet in new investment
rather than in debts; and for this reason, in a passage for which he was
severely taken to task by Bentham, he defended a moderate application of
the usury laws. Moreover, Benthams criticisms were mainly on the ground
that Adam Smiths Scotch caution was too severe on projectors and that a
maximum rate of interest would leave too little margin for the reward of
legitimate and socially advisable risks. For Bentham understood by
projectors all such persons, as, in the pursuit of wealth, or even of any
other object, endeavour, by the assistance of wealth, to strike into any
channel of invention . . . upon all such persons as, in the line of any of their
pursuits, aim at anything that can be called improvement . . . It falls, in
short, upon every application of the human powers, in which ingenuity
stands in need of wealth for its assistance. Of course Bentham is right in
protesting against laws which stand in the way of taking legitimate risks.
A prudent man, Bentham continues, will not, in these circumstances,
pick out the good projects from the bad, for he will not meddle with
projects at all.
It may be doubted, perhaps, whether the above is just what Adam
Smith intended by his term. Or is it that we are hearing in Bentham
(though writing in March 1787 from Crichoff in White Russia) the voice of
nineteenth-century England speaking to the eighteenth? For nothing short
of the exuberance of the greatest age of the inducement to investment
could have made it possible to lose sight of the theoretical possibility of its
insufficiency.
file:///D:/keyness/chapter23.html 14/28
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 23
In the post-war years his devotees bombarded me with copies of his works;
yet, owing to certain palpable defects in the argument, I entirely failed to
discover their merit. As is often the case with imperfectly analysed
intuitions, their significance only became apparent after I had reached my
own conclusions in my own way. Meanwhile, like other academic
economists, I treated his profoundly original strivings as being no better
than those of a crank. Since few of the readers of this book are likely to be
well acquainted with the significance of Gesell, I will give to him what
would be otherwise a disproportionate space.
Gesell was a successful German merchant in Buenos Aires who was
led to the study of monetary problems by the crisis of the late eighties,
which was especially violent in the Argentine, his first work, Die
Reformation im Mnzwesen als Brcke zum socialen Staat, being
published in Buenos Aires in 1891. His fundamental ideas on money were
published in Buenos Aires in the same year under the title Nervus rerum,
and many books and pamphlets followed until he retired to Switzerland in
1906 as a man of some means, able to devote the last decades of his life to
the two most delightful occupations open to those who do not have to earn
their living, authorship and experimental farming.
The first section of his standard work was published in 1906 at Les
Hauts Geneveys, Switzerland, under the title Die Verwirklichung des
Rechtes auf dem vollen
Arbeitsertrag, and the second section in 1911 at Berlin under the title
Die neue Lehre vom Zins. The two together were published in Berlin and
in Switzerland during the war (1916) and reached a sixth edition during his
lifetime under the title Die natrliche Wirtschaftsordnung durch Freiland
und Freigeld, the English version (translated by Mr Philip Pye) being
called The Natural Economic Order. In April 1919 Gesell joined the short-
lived Soviet cabinet of Bavaria as their Minister of Finance, being
subsequently tried by court-martial. The last decade of his life was spent in
Berlin and Switzerland and devoted to propaganda. Gesell, drawing to
himself the semi-religious fervour which had formerly centred round
Henry George, became the revered prophet of a cult with many thousand
disciples throughout the world. The first international convention of the
Swiss and German FreilandFreigeld Bund and similar organisations from
many countries was held in Basle in 1923. Since his death in 1930 much of
the peculiar type of fervour which doctrines such as his are capable of
exciting has been diverted to other (in my opinion less eminent) prophets.
Dr Buchi is the leader of the movement in England, but its literature seems
to be distributed from San Antonio, Texas, its main strength lying to-day
file:///D:/keyness/chapter23.html 15/28
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 23
file:///D:/keyness/chapter23.html 17/28
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 23
attached to it, but differed only in degree from many other articles,
deriving its importance from having a greater liquidity-premium than any
other article. Thus if currency notes were to be deprived of their liquidity-
premium by the stamping system, a long series of substitutes would step
into their shoes bank-money, debts at call, foreign money, jewellery and
the precious metals generally, and so forth. As I have mentioned above,
there have been times when it was probably the craving for the ownership
of land, independently of its yield, which served to keep up the rate of
interest; though under Gesells system this possibility would have been
eliminated by land nationalisation.
file:///D:/keyness/chapter23.html 18/28
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 23
The text of the Fable of the Bees is an allegorical poem The Grumbling
Hive, or Knaves turned honest, in which is set forth the appalling plight of
a prosperous community in which all the citizens suddenly take it into
their heads to abandon luxurious living, and the State to cut down
armaments, in the interests of Saving:
file:///D:/keyness/chapter23.html 19/28
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 23
Two extracts from the commentary which follows the allegory will show
that the above was not without a theoretical basis:
file:///D:/keyness/chapter23.html 20/28
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 23
The great art to make a nation happy, and what we call flourishing,
consists in giving everybody an opportunity of being employed; which to
compass, let a Governments first care be to promote as great a variety of
Manufactures, Arts and Handicrafts as human wit can invent; and the
second to encourage Agriculture and Fishery in all their branches, that the
whole Earth may be forced to exert itself as well as Man. It is from this
Policy and not from the trifling regulations of Lavishness and Frugality
that the greatness and felicity of Nations must be expected; for let the
value of Gold and Silver rise or fall, the enjoyment of all Societies will ever
depend upon the Fruits of the Earth and the Labour of the People; both
which joined together are a more certain, a more inexhaustible and a more
real Treasure than the Gold of Brazil or the Silver of Potosi.
We see in almost every part of the world vast powers of production which
are not put into action, and I explain this phenomenon by saying that from
the want of a proper distribution of the actual produce adequate motives
are not furnished to continued production . . . I distinctly maintain that an
attempt to accumulate very rapidly, which necessarily implies a
considerable diminution of unproductive consumption, by greatly
impairing the usual motives to production must prematurely check the
progress of wealth . . . But if it be true that an attempt to accumulate very
rapidly will occasion such a division between labour and profits as almost
to destroy both the motive and the power of future accumulation and
consequently the power of maintaining and employing an increasing
population, must it not be acknowledged that such an attempt to
file:///D:/keyness/chapter23.html 21/28
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 23
Ricardo, however, was stone-deaf to what Malthus was saying. The last
echo of the controversy is to be found in John Stuart Mills discussion of
his wages-fund theory, which in his own mind played a vital part in his
rejection of the later phase of Malthus, amidst the discussions of which he
file:///D:/keyness/chapter23.html 22/28
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 23
had, of course, been brought up. Mills successors rejected his wages-fund
theory but overlooked the fact that Mills refutation of Malthus depended
on it. Their method was to dismiss the problem from the corpus of
economics not by solving it but by not mentioning it. It altogether
disappeared from controversy. Mr Cairncross, searching recently for traces
of it amongst the minor Victorians, has found even less, perhaps, than
might have been expected. Theories of under-consumption hibernated
until the appearance in 1889 of The Physiology of Industry, by J. A.
Hobson and A. F. Mummery, the first and most significant of many
volumes in which for nearly fifty years Mr Hobson has flung himself with
unflagging, but almost unavailing, ardour and courage against the ranks of
orthodoxy. Though it is so completely forgotten to-day, the publication of
this book marks, in a sense, an epoch in economic thought.
The Physiology of Industry was written in collaboration with A. F.
Mummery. Mr Hobson has told how the book came to be written as
follows:
It was not until the middle eighties that my economic heterodoxy began to
take shape. Though the Henry George campaign against land values and
the early agitation of various socialist groups against the visible oppression
of the working classes, coupled with the revelations of the two Booths
regarding the poverty of London, made a deep impression on my feelings,
they did not destroy my faith in Political Economy. That came from what
may be called an accidental contact. While teaching at a school in Exeter I
came into personal relations with a business man named Mummery,
known then and afterwards as a great mountaineer who had discovered
another way up the Matterhorn and who, in 1895, was killed in an attempt
to climb the famous Himalayan mountain Nanga Parbat. My intercourse
with him, I need hardly say, did not lie on this physical plane. But he was a
mental climber as well, with a natural eye for a path of his own finding and
a sublime disregard of intellectual authority. This man entangled me in a
controversy about excessive saving, which he regarded as responsible for
the under-employment of capital and labour in periods of bad trade. For a
long time I sought to counter his arguments by the use of the orthodox
economic weapons. But at length he convinced me and I went in with him
to elaborate the over-saving argument in a book entitled The Physiology of
Industry, which was published in 1889. This was the first open step in my
heretical career, and I did not in the least realise its momentous
consequences. For just at that time I had given up my scholastic post and
was opening a new line of work as University Extension Lecturer in
Economics and Literature. The first shock came in a refusal of the London
Extension Board to allow me to offer courses of Political Economy. This
was due, I learned, to the intervention of an Economic Professor who had
read my book and considered it as equivalent in rationality to an attempt
file:///D:/keyness/chapter23.html 23/28
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 23
to prove the flatness of the earth. How could there be any limit to the
amount of useful saving when every item of saving went to increase the
capital structure and the fund for paying wages? Sound economists could
not fail to view with horror an argument which sought to check the source
of all industrial progress. Another interesting personal experience helped
to bring home to me the sense of my iniquity. Though prevented from
lecturing on economics in London, I had been allowed by the greater
liberality of the Oxford University Extension Movement to address
audiences in the Provinces, confining myself to practical issues relating to
working-class life. Now it happened at this time that the Charity
Organisation Society was planning a lecture campaign upon economic
subjects and invited me to prepare a course. I had expressed my
willingness to undertake this new lecture work, when suddenly, without
explanation, the invitation was withdrawn. Even then I hardly realised
that in appearing to question the virtue of unlimited thrift I had
committed the unpardonable sin.
In this early work Mr Hobson with his collaborator expressed himself with
more direct reference to the classical economics (in which he had been
brought up) than in his later writings; and for this reason, as well as
because it is the first expression of his theory, I will quote from it to show
how significant and well-founded were the authors criticisms and
intuitions. They point out in their preface as follows the nature of the
conclusions which they attack:
Saving enriches and spending impoverishes the community along with the
individual, and it may be generally defined as an assertion that the
effective love of money is the root of all economic good. Not merely does it
enrich the thrifty individual himself, but it raises wages, gives work to the
unemployed, and scatters blessings on every side. From the daily papers to
the latest economic treatise, from the pulpit to the House of Commons,
this conclusion is reiterated and re-stated till it appears positively impious
to question it. Yet the educated world, supported by the majority of
economic thinkers, up to the publication of Ricardos work strenuously
denied this doctrine, and its ultimate acceptance was exclusively due to
their inability to meet the now exploded wages-fund doctrine. That the
conclusion should have survived the argument on which it logically stood,
can be explained on no other hypothesis than the commanding authority
of the great men who asserted it. Economic critics have ventured to attack
the theory in detail, but they have shrunk appalled from touching its main
conclusions. Our purpose is to show that these conclusions are not
tenable, that an undue exercise of the habit of saving is possible, and that
such undue exercise impoverishes the Community, throws labourers out of
work, drives down wages, and spreads that gloom and prostration through
the commercial world which is known as Depression in Trade . . .
file:///D:/keyness/chapter23.html 24/28
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 23
In the last sentence of this passage there appears the root of Hobsons
mistake, namely, his supposing that it is a ease of excessive saving causing
the actual accumulation of capital in excess of what is required, which is,
in fact, a secondary evil which only occurs through mistakes of foresight;
whereas the primary evil is a propensity to save in conditions of full
employment more than the equivalent of the capital which is required,
thus preventing full employment except when there is a mistake of
foresight. A page or two later, however, he puts one half of the matter, as it
seems to me, with absolute precision, though still overlooking the possible
rle of changes in the rate of interest and in the state of business
confidence, factors which he presumably takes as given:
We are thus brought to the conclusion that the basis on which all economic
teaching since Adam Smith has stood, viz. that the quantity annually
produced is determined by the aggregates of Natural Agents, Capital, and
Labour available, is erroneous, and that, on the contrary, the quantity
produced, while it can never exceed the limits imposed by these
aggregates, may be, and actually is, reduced far below this maximum by
the check that undue saving and the consequent accumulation of over-
supply exerts on production; i.e. that in the normal state of modern
industrial Communities, consumption limits production and not
production consumption.
Finally he notices the bearing of his theory on the validity of the orthodox
Free Trade arguments:
the propensity to save but in response to the demand resulting from actual
and prospective consumption. The following portmanteau quotation
indicates the line of thought:
Hobson and Mummery were aware that interest was nothing whatever
except payment for the use of money. They also knew well enough that
their opponents would claim that there would be such a fall in the rate of
interest (or profit) as will act as a check upon Saving, and restore the
proper relation between production and consumption. They point out in
reply that if a fall of Profit is to induce people to save less, it must operate
in one of two ways, either by inducing them to spend more or by inducing
them to produce less. As regards the former they argue that when profits
fall the aggregate income of the community is reduced, and we cannot
suppose that when the average rate of incomes is falling, individuals will
file:///D:/keyness/chapter23.html 26/28
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 23
file:///D:/keyness/chapter23.html 27/28
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 23
https://ebooks.adelaide.edu.au/k/keynes/john_maynard/k44g/chapter23.html
Last updated Sunday, March 27, 2016 at 11:56
file:///D:/keyness/chapter23.html 28/28
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 24
C 24
C N S
P T
G T M L
The outstanding faults of the economic society in which we live are its
failure to provide for full employment and its arbitrary and inequitable
distribution of wealth and incomes. The bearing of the foregoing theory on
the first of these is obvious. But there are also two important respects in
which it is relevant to the second.
Since the end of the nineteenth century significant progress towards
the removal of very great disparities of wealth and income has been
achieved through the instrument of direct taxation income tax and
surtax and death duties especially in Great Britain. Many people would
wish to see this process carried much further, but they are deterred by two
considerations; partly by the fear of making skilful evasions too much
worth while and also of diminishing unduly the motive towards risk-
taking, but mainly, I think, by the belief that the growth of capital depends
upon the strength of the motive towards individual saving and that for a
large proportion of this growth we are dependent on the savings of the rich
out of their superfluity. Our argument does not affect the first of these
considerations. But it may considerably modify our attitude towards the
second. For we have seen that, up to the point where full employment
prevails, the growth of capital depends not at all on a low propensity to
consume but is, on the contrary, held back by it; and only in conditions of
full employment is a low propensity to consume conducive to the growth
of capital. Moreover, experience suggests that in existing conditions saving
by institutions and through sinking funds is more than adequate, and that
measures for the redistribution of incomes in a way likely to raise the
file:///D:/keyness/chapter24.html 1/10
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 24
task of transmuting human nature must not be confused with the task of
managing it. Though in the ideal commonwealth men may have been
taught or inspired or bred to take no interest in the stakes, it may still be
wise and prudent statesmanship to allow the game to be played, subject to
rules and limitations, so long as the average man, or even a significant
section of the community, is in fact strongly addicted to the money-making
passion.
There is, however, a second, much more fundamental inference from our
argument which has a bearing on the future of inequalities of wealth;
namely, our theory of the rate of interest. The justification for a
moderately high rate of interest has been found hitherto in the necessity of
providing a sufficient inducement to save. But we have shown that the
extent of effective saving is necessarily determined by the scale of
investment and that the scale of investment is promoted by a low rate of
interest, provided that we do not attempt to stimulate it in this way beyond
the point which corresponds to full employment. Thus it is to our best
advantage to reduce the rate of interest to that point relatively to the
schedule of the marginal efficiency of capital at which there is full
employment.
There can be no doubt that this criterion will lead to a much lower
rate of interest than has ruled hitherto; and, so far as one can guess at the
schedules of the marginal efficiency of capital corresponding to increasing
amounts of capital, the rate of interest is likely to fall steadily, if it should
be practicable to maintain conditions of more or less continuous full
employment unless, indeed, there is an excessive change in the
aggregate propensity to consume (including the State).
I feel sure that the demand for capital is strictly limited in the sense
that it would not be difficult to increase the stock of capital up to a point
where its marginal efficiency had fallen to a very low figure. This would
not mean that the use of capital instruments would cost almost nothing,
but only that the return from them would have to cover little more than
their exhaustion by wastage and obsolescence together with some margin
to cover risk and the exercise of skill and judgment. In short, the aggregate
return from durable goods in the course of their life would, as in the case
of short-lived goods, just cover their labour-costs of production plus an
allowance for risk and the costs of skill and supervision.
file:///D:/keyness/chapter24.html 3/10
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 24
Now, though this state of affairs would be quite compatible with some
measure of individualism, yet it would mean the euthanasia of the rentier,
and, consequently, the euthanasia of the cumulative oppressive power of
the capitalist to exploit the scarcity-value of capital. Interest to-day
rewards no genuine sacrifice, any more than does the rent of land. The
owner of capital can obtain interest because capital is scarce, just as the
owner of land can obtain rent because land is scarce. But whilst there may
be intrinsic reasons for the scarcity of land, there are no intrinsic reasons
for the scarcity of capital. An intrinsic reason for such scarcity, in the sense
of a genuine sacrifice which could only be called forth by the offer of a
reward in the shape of interest, would not exist, in the long run, except in
the event of the individual propensity to consume proving to be of such a
character that net saving in conditions of full employment comes to an end
before capital has become sufficiently abundant. But even so, it will still be
possible for communal saving through the agency of the State to be
maintained at a level which will allow the growth of capital up to the point
where it ceases to be scarce.
I see, therefore, the rentier aspect of capitalism as a transitional phase
which will disappear when it has done its work. And with the
disappearance of its rentier aspect much else in it besides will suffer a sea-
change. It will be, moreover, a great advantage of the order of events which
I am advocating, that the euthanasia of the rentier, of the functionless
investor, will be nothing sudden, merely a gradual but prolonged
continuance of what we have seen recently in Great Britain, and will need
no revolution.
Thus we might aim in practice (there being nothing in this which is
unattainable) at an increase in the volume of capital until it ceases to be
scarce, so that the functionless investor will no longer receive a bonus; and
at a scheme of direct taxation which allows the intelligence and
determination and executive skill of the financier, the entrepreneur et hoc
genus omne (who are certainly so fond of their craft that their labour could
be obtained much cheaper than at present), to be harnessed to the service
of the community on reasonable terms of reward.
At the same time we must recognise that only experience can show
how far the common will, embodied in the policy of the State, ought to be
directed to increasing and supplementing the inducement to invest; and
how far it is safe to stimulate the average propensity to consume, without
foregoing our aim of depriving capital of its scarcity-value within one or
two generations. It may turn out that the propensity to consume will be so
easily strengthened by the effects of a falling rate of interest, that full
file:///D:/keyness/chapter24.html 4/10
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 24
file:///D:/keyness/chapter24.html 5/10
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 24
file:///D:/keyness/chapter24.html 6/10
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 24
that the world will not much longer tolerate the unemployment which,
apart from brief intervals of excitement, is associated and, in my
opinion, inevitably associated with present-day capitalistic
individualism. But it may be possible by a right analysis of the problem to
cure the disease whilst preserving efficiency and freedom.
file:///D:/keyness/chapter24.html 8/10
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 24
repulse the offerings of its neighbour, not because this was necessary to
enable it to pay for what it wished to purchase, but with the express object
of upsetting the equilibrium of payments so as to develop a balance of
trade in its own favour. International trade would cease to be what it is,
namely, a desperate expedient to maintain employment at home by forcing
sales on foreign markets and restricting purchases, which, if successful,
will merely shift the problem of unemployment to the neighbour which is
worsted in the struggle, but a willing and unimpeded exchange of goods
and services in conditions of mutual advantage.
file:///D:/keyness/chapter24.html 9/10
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Chapter 24
https://ebooks.adelaide.edu.au/k/keynes/john_maynard/k44g/chapter24.html
Last updated Sunday, March 27, 2016 at 11:56
file:///D:/keyness/chapter24.html 10/10
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Appendix 1
A 1
P E F E
C P E
Page Line Correction
[Chapter 6] 6 For possession read possessions
[Chapter 7] 12 For has read had
[Chapter
13 For 23 read 19
10]
[Chapter footnote I, line
For th read the
10] 2
[Chapter
21 For security read precautionary
13]
[Chapter
9 For than read that
16]
[Chapter For output read the stock of assets in
32
17] general
[Chapter
25 For their read its
17]
[Chapter
31 For or read of
17]
[Chapter
28 For three read four
19]
[Chapter
4 For technique read techniques
19]
[Chapter
23 For income read incomes
22]
[Chapter
7 For Mercantilist read Mercantilists
23]
file:///D:/keyness/appendix1.html 1/2
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Appendix 1
https://ebooks.adelaide.edu.au/k/keynes/john_maynard/k44g/appendix1.html
Last updated Sunday, March 27, 2016 at 11:56
file:///D:/keyness/appendix1.html 2/2
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Appendix 2
A 2
From The Economic Journal, September 1936
F N U
S
(Millions of dollars.)
Consumers
durable 8,664 9,316 8,887 9,175 10,058 7,892 5,885 4,022 3,737
commodities
The above figure for 1929 includes 3,400 million dollars for motor-cars,
whilst the depreciation in respect of the same item for that year is
estimated at 2,500 million dollars.
(2) Residential Construction
This is an important and highly fluctuating item which should
undoubtedly be included in investment, and not in consumption
expenditure, since houses are usually regarded as purchased out of savings
and not out of income, and are often owned by others than the occupiers.
In the Bulletin from which these figures are taken Mr Kuznets gives no
estimate for the annual rate of depreciation, etc. More recently, however,
his colleague, Mr Solomon Fabricant, has published such estimates, which
I have used in the following table:
(Millions of dollars.)
file:///D:/keyness/appendix2.html 2/9
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Appendix 2
Residential 3,050 2,965 2,856 3,095 2,127 1,222 900 311 276
construction
Depreciation* 1,554 1,676 1,754 1,842 1,911 1,901 1,698 1,460 1,567
Net
1,496 1,289 1,102 1,253 216 679 798 1,149 1,291
investment
(Millions of dollars.)
Gross
business
capital 9,070 9,815 9,555 10,019 11,396 9,336 5,933 3,205 2,894
formation
(as above)
Depreciation
and 5,685 6,269 6,312 6,447 7,039 6,712 6,154 5,092 4,971
depletion*
file:///D:/keyness/appendix2.html 3/9
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Appendix 2
Net 3,385 3,546 3,243 3,572 4,357 2,624 221 1,887 2,077
investment
* These figures are not taken from Mr Kuznets memoranda, hut from Mr
Fabricants later and revised estimates. As before they are in terms of current
(replacement) cost. In terms of original cost they are appreciably lower prior
to 1931 and higher subsequently.
(Millions of dollars.)
Net gain or
loss in
916 2,664 176 511 1,800 100 500 2,250 2,250
business
inventories
This table covers not only manufacturers stocks but also stocks of farmers,
mines, traders, government agencies, etc. From 1929 onwards the figures
given in Mr Kuznets memorandum of 1934 proved to require correction.
Those given above are provisional and approximate estimates, pending the
publication of revised figures by the National Bureau.
(5) Public Construction and Borrowing
The relevant figure in this context is not so much the gross (or net)
expenditure on construction, as the amount of expenditure met out of a
net increase in borrowing. That is to say in the case of public authorities
and the like, their net investment may be best regarded as being measured
by the net increase in their borrowing. In so far as their expenditures are
met by compulsory transfer from the current income of the public, they
have no correlative in private saving; whilst public saving, if we were to
find a satisfactory definition for this concept, would be subject to quite
different psychological influences from private saving. I have touched on
the problem in my General Theory, footnote. I propose, therefore, to
insert in place of the figures of public construction the loan expenditure
of public bodies.
Mr Kuznets has very kindly supplied me with figures for the net
changes in the amount of public debt (Federal, State and local)
outstanding in the United States, which, except for minor changes in the
Governments cash balances, represent the amount of public expenditure
file:///D:/keyness/appendix2.html 4/9
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Appendix 2
not covered by taxes and other revenues. This is given below in parallel
with his estimates of the amount of construction by public authorities. The
interesting result emerges that up to 1928 there was a net reduction in the
public debt in spite of a large expenditure on public construction, and that
even up to 1931 some part of public construction was met out of revenue.
The excess of borrowing over construction in 1932 and 1933 represents, of
course, various measures of public relief.
(Millions of dollars.)
Public
2,717 2,612 3,045 3,023 2,776 3,300 2,906 2,097 1,659
construction
Net change
in
outstanding 43 280 244 50 +441 +1,712 +2,822 +2,565 +2,796
public
debt**
* See Mr Kuznets Bulletin, Table II, line 22, brought up to date on the basis
of more recent data.
(Millions of dollars.)
(Millions of dollars.)
Residential
1,496 1,289 1,102 1,253 216 679 798 1,149 1,291
construction
file:///D:/keyness/appendix2.html 5/9
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Appendix 2
Business 3,385 3,546 3,243 3,572 4,357 2,624 221 1,887 2,077
fixed capital
Business
916 2,664 176 511 1,800 100 500 2,250 2,250
inventories
Net loan
expenditures
43 280 244 10 441 1,712 2,822 2,565 2,796
by public
authorities
Foreign
428 44 606 957 312 371 326 40 293
investment
Aggregate
net 6,182 7,263 4,531 6,283 7,126 4,128 1,629 2,681 2,529
investment
AN A 2
T N O I P
D
(Millions of dollars.)
file:///D:/keyness/appendix2.html 7/9
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Appendix 2
(Source: Report of the Secretary of the Treasury for year ended 30 June
1935, p. 424.)
Total outstanding issues exclude a small volume of matured and non-
interest bearing obligations (see ibid., p. 379).
Net outstanding issues are equal to total outstanding issues less those
held in U.S. Government trust funds, or owned by U.S. Government or by
governmental agencies and held in sinking funds.
The table above does not include the contingent debt of the Federal
Government, i.e. obligations guaranteed by the United States. These,
comprising largely debt issues of the Federal Farm Mortgage Corporation,
Home Owners Loan Corporation and the Reconstruction Finance
Corporation, were as follows:
file:///D:/keyness/appendix2.html 8/9
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Appendix 2
https://ebooks.adelaide.edu.au/k/keynes/john_maynard/k44g/appendix2.html
Last updated Sunday, March 27, 2016 at 11:56
file:///D:/keyness/appendix2.html 9/9
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Appendix 3
A 3
From The Economic Journal, March 1939
R M R W
O
You know, my views on this matter are (a) not very confident, (b) not very
warmly advocated by me, (c) not very old, (d) based entirely on non-
academic arguments & observation.
In the years 68 to 77 I was strongly on the side you now advocate. The
observation of events in Bristol made me doubt. In 85, or 86 I wrote a
Memn for the Comn on Depression showing a slight preference for rising
prices. But in the following two years I studied the matter closely, I read
and analysed the evidence of business men before that Commission; & by
the time the Gold & Silver Commission came, I had just turned the corner.
Since then I have read a great deal, but almost exclusively of a non-
academic order on the subject: & was thinking about it duhng a great part
of the evidence given by business men & working men before the Labour
Commission. I have found a good deal that is new to strengthen my new
conviction, nothing to shake it. I am far from certain I am right. I am
absolutely certain that the evidence brought forward in print to the
contrary in England and America (I have not read largely for other
countries) does not prove what it claims to, & does not meet or anticipate
my arguments, in the simple way you seem to imagine.
I will confess that, for ten or fifteen years after I began to study political
economy, I held the common doctrine, that a rise of prices was generally
beneficial to business men directly, and indirectly to the working classes.
file:///D:/keyness/appendix3.html 3/17
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Appendix 3
But, after that time, I changed my views, and I have been confirmed in my
new opinions by finding that they are largely held in America, which has
recently passed through experiences somewhat similar to those of England
early in the century. The reasons for the change in my opinion are rather
long, and I gave them at some length before the Gold and Silver
Commission. I think, perhaps, I had better content myself now with calling
your attention to the fact that the statistical aspect of the matter is in a
different position now. The assertions that a rise in prices increased the
real wages of the worker were so consonant with the common opinion of
people who had not specially studied the matter, that it was accepted
almost as an axiom; but, within the last ten years, the statistics of wages
have been carried so far in certain countries, and especially in England and
America, that we are able to bring it to the test. I have accumulated a great
number of facts, but nearly everything I have accumulated is implied in
this table. It is copied from the article by Mr Bowley in the Economic
Journal for last December. It is the result of work that has been going on
for a number of years, and seems to me to be practically decisive. It
collects the average wages in England from the year 1844 to the year 1891,
and then calculates what purchasing power the wages would give at the
different times, and it shows that the rise of real wages after 1873 when
prices were falling was greater than before 1873 when prices were rising.
Here follows a table from Prof. Bowleys article in this Journal for
December 1898. Marshalls final conclusion was crystallised in a passage
in the Principles (Book VI, ch. VIII, 6):
[When prices rise the employer] will therefore be more able and more
willing to pay the high wages; and wages will tend upwards. But
experience shows that (whether they are governed by sliding scales or not)
they seldom rise as much in proportion as prices; and therefore they do
not rise nearly as much in proportion as profits.
Real wages
18801884 Recovery Falling
18841886 Depression Rising
18861890 Recovery Rising
18901896 Depression Falling
18961899 Recovery Rising
file:///D:/keyness/appendix3.html 4/17
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Appendix 3
About that time M. Rueff had attracted much attention by the publication
of statistics which purported to show that a rise in real wages tended to go
with an increase in unemployment, Prof. Pigou points out that these
statistics are vitiated by the fact that M. Rueff divided money wages by the
wholesale index instead of by the cost-of-living index, and he does not
agree with M. Rueff that the observed rise in real wages was the main
cause of the increased unemployment with which it was associated. But he
file:///D:/keyness/appendix3.html 5/17
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Appendix 3
file:///D:/keyness/appendix3.html 6/17
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Appendix 3
First of all, are the statistics on which Mr Dunlop and Mr Tarshis are
relying sufficiently accurate and sufficiently uniform in their indications to
form the basis of a reliable induction?
For example, in so recent a compilation as the League of Nations
World Economic Survey 193738, prepared by Mr J. E. Meade, the
traditional conclusion receives support, not on priori recently available
statistics. I quote the following from pp. 5455:
During the great depression after 1929, the demand for goods and services
diminished, and in consequence the price of commodities fell rapidly. In
most countries, as can be seen from the graph on p. 52, hourly money
wages were reduced as the demand for labour fell; but in every case there
file:///D:/keyness/appendix3.html 7/17
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Appendix 3
was a greater fall in prices, so that hourly real wages rose. . .[It is then
explained that the same was not true of weekly wages.]. . .Since the
recovery, the opposite movements may be observed. In most countries,
increased demand for goods and services has caused commodity prices to
rise more rapidly than hourly money wages, and the hourly real wage has
fallen. . .In the United States and France, however, the rise in money
wages was so rapid between 1936 and 1937 that the hourly real wage
continued to rise. . .When real hourly wages are raised i.e. when the
margin between commodity prices and the money-wage cost becomes less
favourable employers are likely to diminish the amount of employment
which they offer to labour. While there were, no doubt, other influences
affecting the demand for labour, the importance of this factor is well
illustrated by the graph on p. 53. In the case of all the countries
represented for which information is available, the fall in commodity
prices between 1929 and 1932 caused a rise in the hourly real wage, and
this was accompanied by a diminution in employment. . .(it is shown that
on the recovery there has been a greater variety of experience). . .
This authoritative study having international scope indicates that the new
generalisations must be accepted with reserve. In any case Mr Tarshiss
scatter diagram printed below [in the Economic Journal, March 1939] (p.
150), whilst it shows a definite preponderance in the south-west and
north-east compartments and a high coefficient of association, includes a
considerable number of divergent cases, and the absolute range of most of
the scatter is extremely small, with a marked clustering in the
neighbourhood of the zero line for changes in real wages; and much the
same is true of Mr Dunlops results. The great majority of Mr Tarshiss
observations relate to changes of less than 1.5 per cent. In the introduction
to his Wages and Income in the United Kingdom since 1860, Prof. Bowley
indicates that this is probably less than the margin of error for statistics of
this kind. This general conclusion is reinforced by the fact that it is hourly
wages which are relevant in the present context, for which accurate
statistics are not available. Moreover, in the post-scriptum to his note, Mr
Tarshis explains that whilst real wages tend to move in the same direction
as money wages, they move in the opposite direction, though only slightly,
to the level of output as measured by man-hours of employment; from
which it appears that Mr Tarshiss final result is in conformity with my
original assumption, which is, of course, concerned with hourly wages. It
seems possible, therefore, taking account of Mr Meades results, that I may
not, after all, have been seriously wrong.
Furthermore, for reasons given below, it is important to separate the
observations according as the absolute level of employment is distinctly
good or only mediocre. It may be that we can analyse our results so as to
file:///D:/keyness/appendix3.html 8/17
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Appendix 3
file:///D:/keyness/appendix3.html 9/17
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Appendix 3
Has the identification of marginal cost with marginal wage cost introduced
a relevant error? In my General Theory of Employment, I have argued
that this identification is dangerous in that it ignores a factor which I have
called marginal user cost. It is unlikely, however, that this can help us in
the present context. For marginal user cost is likely to increase when
output is increasing, so that this factor would work in the opposite
direction from that required to explain our present problem, and would be
an additional reason for expecting prices to rise more than wages. Indeed,
one would, on general grounds, expect marginal total cost to increase
more, and not less, than marginal wage cost.
There remains the question whether the mistake lies in the approximate
identification of marginal cost with price, or rather in the assumption that
for output as a whole they bear a more or less proportionate relationship
to one another irrespective of the intensity of output. For it may be the
case that the practical workings of the laws of imperfect competition in the
modern quasi-competitive system are such that, when output increases
and money wages rise, prices rise less than in proportion to the increase in
marginal money cost. It is scarcely likely, perhaps, that the narrowing gap
could be sufficient to prevent a decline in real wages in a phase in which
marginal real cost was increasing rapidly. But it might be sufficient to
offset the effect on real wages of a modest rise in marginal real cost, and
even to dominate the situation in the event of the marginal real cost curve
proving to be almost horizontal over a substantial portion of its relevant
length.
It is evidently possible that some such factor should exist. It might be,
in a sense, merely an extension of the stickiness of prices of which we have
already taken account in II above. Apart from those prices which are
virtually constant in the short period, there are obviously many others
which are, for various reasons, more or less sticky. But this factor would be
particularly likely to emerge when output increases, in so far as producers
are influenced in their practical price policies and in their exploitation of
the opportunities given them by the imperfections of competition, by their
long-period average cost, and are less attentive than economists to their
short-period marginal cost. Indeed, it is rare for anyone but an economist
to suppose that price is predominantly governed by marginal cost. Most
business men are surprised by the suggestion that it is a close calculation
of short-period marginal cost or of marginal revenue which should
dominate their price policies. They maintain that such a policy would
rapidly land in bankruptcy anyone who practised it. And if it is true that
they are producing more often than not on a scale at which marginal cost
is falling with an increase in output, they would clearly be right; for it
would be only on rare occasions that they would be collecting anything
whatever towards their overhead. It is, beyond doubt, the practical
assumption of the producer that his price policy ought to be influenced by
the fact that he is normally operating subject to decreasing average cost,
even if in the short-period his marginal cost is rising. His effort is to
maintain prices when output falls and, when output increases, he may
raise them by less than the full amount required to offset higher costs
file:///D:/keyness/appendix3.html 12/17
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Appendix 3
including higher wages. He would admit that this, regarded by him as the
reasonable, prudent and far-sighted policy, goes by the board when, at the
height of the boom, he is overwhelmed by more orders than he can supply;
but even so he is filled with foreboding as to the ultimate consequences of
his being forced so far from the right and reasonable policy of fixing his
prices by reference to his long-period overhead as well as his current costs.
Rightly ordered competition consists, in his opinion, in a proper pressure
to secure an adjustment of prices to changes in long-period average cost;
and the suggestion that he is becoming a dangerous and anti-social
monopolist whenever, by open or tacit agreement with his competitors, he
endeavours to prevent prices from hollowing short-period marginal cost,
however much this may fall away from long-period average cost, strikes
him as disastrous. (It is the failure of the latest phase of the New Deal in
the United States, in contrast to the earliest phase, of which the opposite is
true, to distinguish between price agreements for maintaining prices in
right relation to average long-period cost and those which aim at obtaining
a monopolistic profit in excess of average long-period cost which strikes
him as particularly unfair.)
Thus, since it is the avowed policy of industrialists to be content with
a smaller gross profit per unit of output when output increases than when
it declines, it is not unlikely that this policy may be, at least partially,
operative. It would be of great interest if the statisticians could show in
detail in what way gross profit per unit of output changes in different
industries with a changing ratio between actual and capacity output. Such
an investigation should distinguish, if possible, between the effect of
increasing output on unit-profit and that of higher costs in the shape of
higher money wages and other expenses. If it should appear that
Increasing output as such has a tendency to decrease unit-profit, it would
follow that the policy suggested above is actual as well as professed. If,
however, the decline in unit-profit appears to be mainly the result of a
tendency of prices to offset higher costs incompletely, irrespective of
changes in the level of output, then we have merely an example of the
stickiness of prices arising out of the imperfection of competition intrinsic
to the market conditions. Unfortunately it is often difficult or impossible to
distinguish clearly between the effects of the two influences, since higher
money costs and increasing output will generally go together.
A well-known statistical phenomenon which ought to have put me on
my guard confirms the probability of constant or diminishing, rather than
increasing, profit per unit of output when output increases. I mean the
stability of the proportion of the national dividend accruing to labour,
file:///D:/keyness/appendix3.html 13/17
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Appendix 3
. . .
file:///D:/keyness/appendix3.html 14/17
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Appendix 3
file:///D:/keyness/appendix3.html 15/17
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Appendix 3
And it appears that, for reasons which are not yet clear, these factors taken
in conjunction have no significant influence on the distribution between
labour and capital of the income resulting from the output. Whatever a
more complete inquiry into the problem may bring forth, it is evident that
Mr Dunlop, Mr Tarshis and Dr Kalecki have given us much to think about,
and have seriously shaken the fundamental assumptions on which the
short-period theory of distribution has been based hitherto; it seems
that for practical purposes a different set of simplifications from those
adopted hitherto are preferable. Meanwhile I am comforted by the fact
that their conclusions tend to confirm the idea that the causes of short-
period fluctuation are to be found in changes in the demand for labour,
and not in changes in its real-supply price; though I complain a little that I
in particular should be criticised for conceding a little to the other view by
admitting that, when the changes in effective demand to which I myself
attach importance have brought about a change in the level of output, the
real-supply price for labour would in fact change in the direction assumed
by the theory I am opposing as if I was the first to have entertained the
fifty-year-old generalisation that, trend eliminated, increasing output is
usually associated with a falling real wage.
I urge, nevertheless, that we should not be too hasty in our revisions,
and that further statistical enquiry is necessary before we have a firm
foundation of fact on which to reconstruct our theory of the short period.
In particular we need to know:
i. How the real hourly wage changes in the short period, not merely in
relation to the money wage, but in relation to the percentage which
actual output bears to capacity output;
file:///D:/keyness/appendix3.html 16/17
8/18/2017 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, by Keynes : Appendix 3
ii. How the purchasing power of the industrial money wage in terms of
its own product changes when output changes; and
iii. How gross profit per unit of output changes (a) when money costs
change, and (b) when output changes.
J. M. KEYNES
https://ebooks.adelaide.edu.au/k/keynes/john_maynard/k44g/appendix3.html
Last updated Sunday, March 27, 2016 at 11:56
file:///D:/keyness/appendix3.html 17/17