Continuous Time Pension Fund Modelling
Continuous Time Pension Fund Modelling
Continuous Time Pension Fund Modelling
Abstract
This paper considers stochastic pension fund models which evolve in continuous
time and with continuous adjustments to the contribution rate and to the asset mix.
A generalization of constant proportion portfolio insurance is considered and an an-
alytical solution is derived for the stationary distribution of the funding level. In the
case where a risk-free asset exists this is a translated-inverse-gamma distribution.
Numerical examples show that the continuous-time model gives a very good ap-
proximation to more widely used discrete time models, with, say, annual contribu-
tion rate reviews, and using a variety of models for stochastic investment returns.
Keywords: continuous time; stochastic differential equation; risk-free rate; contin-
uous proportion portfolio insurance.
1 E-mail:
[email protected]
2
WWW: http://www.ma.hw.ac.uk/ andrewc/
1 Introduction
In this paper we consider continuous time stochastic models for pension fund dy-
namics. The general form of this simple model is:
dXt Xt d t Xt N D Xt B dt
where Xt funding level at time t
Assets/Liabilities at time t
d t Xt real return between t and t dt
over salary growth
N normal contribution rate
D t Xt adjustment to the contribution rate
for surplus or deficit
and B rate of benefit outgo (as a proportion
of the actuarial liability)
(Note that the description of the model given here allows for the distribution of
investment returns to depend upon the funding level.)
Here, it is assumed that the level of benefit outgo is constant through time relative
to the actuarial liability.
Related to the funding level is the target funding level, L, which will normally be
equal to 1 but this need not be the case. This reserve is related to the normal contri-
bution rate, the level of benefit outgo and the valuation rate of interest in excess of
salary growth, v , in the following way:
dL
vL N B 0
dt
That is, if the experience of the fund is precisely as expected then interest on the
fund plus the normal contribution rate will be precisely sufficient to pay the benefits.
Thus B N v L.
Similar continuous time models have been considered by Dufresne (1990). A dis-
crete time version version of the model has been considered in more detail and
in various forms by Cairns and Parker (1996), Dufresne (1988, 1989, 1990) and
Haberman (1992, 1994).
This paper will discuss various special cases of the model. The first case is where
d t Xt does not depend upon Xt and, in effect, reflects a static investment pol-
icy with independent and identically distributed returns. This case has previously
been considered by Dufresne (1990) who showed that the stationary distribution
of the fund size was Inverse Gaussian and here we verify his result using different
techniques.
The second case will consider Continuous Proportion Portfolio Insurance. This is a
special type of investment strategy which holds a greater proportion of its assets in
low risk stocks when the funding level Xt is low. Several sub-cases are investigated
including one in which a risk-free asset exists and one in which it does not. The
latter indicates that selling a particular asset class short could be a problem and as a
consequence certain constraints are put in place. These constraints prevent the fund
from going short on the higher risk assets when the funding level is low and place
an upper limit on the amount by which the fund can go short on low risk assets
when the funding level is high. In all cases, a closed form solution can be found for
the limiting (stationary) density function of Xt . When there exists a risk-free asset,
this distribution is Translated-Inverse-Gaussian (TIG).
Much of the analysis relies on the following result:
Theorem 1.1
Let the continuous-time stochastic process Xt satisfy the stochastic differential equa-
tion
dXt Xt Xt2 1 2
dZt t Xt dt
1 x b
fX x k exp 2a tan x x2 1
c
for x
1
where a 2
4 2
b
2
4 2
c
2
fX x k x b exp x b for b x
where b
2
2 1
2
2
d t Xt d t dt dZt
D Xt k L Xt
where k and k v L.
2.1 Properties of X
Let X be a random variable with the stationary distribution of Xt . (Cairns and Parker,
1996, show that such processes are stationary and ergodic.)
Now Xt falls into the collection of stochastic processes covered in Theorem 1.1 Thus
by Theorem 1.1(b) X has an Inverse Gamma distribution with parameters 1 and
2 2 1
where 2 1 2 and 4 (that is, X Gamma 1 ). For this
to be a proper distribution (that is, one which has a density which integrates to 1)
1 2
we require that 1. This therefore imposes the further condition that k 2 .
Stronger conditions on k are required to ensure that X has finite moments.
The stationary distribution of Xt was found by Dufresne (1990), Proposition 4.4.4,
but here we have derived it in a different way by making use of Theorem 1.1.
Let M j E X j where j is a non-negative integer. Then it is easy to show that for
j 1
j
Mj
2 3 j 1
For j 1, M j is infinite.
Using these equations we see that
k v
E X L
k
k 2
v
E X2 1 2
L2
k k 2
k 21 2
v 2
Var X 1 2
L2
k 2 k 2
Note that it is possible for the process to be stationary but to have an infinite mean.
Using this information we can calculate, for example, Pr X x0 where x0 is the
government statutory limit of 105% of the actuarial liability calculated on the UK
statutory valuation basis. This figure gives a guide to the frequency in the long run
of breaches of this upper limit.
2.2 Hitting Times
The problems described below are included as open problems.
Suppose T inf t : Xt x . Since Xt is stationary it cannot be true that E s XT
E s X0 . If, on the other hand, 0 x X0 y and T inf t : Xt x or y then
E s XT s x Pr XT x s y Pr XT y E s X0 .) Since no closed form
for s x exists this problem must be solved numerically.
The problem can be generalized to allow us to gain further information about a
stopping time T . Suppose we are interested in the first time, T , that the process Xt
reaches some level x or hits an upper or a lower bound (y or x). We can at least in
principle obtain the moment generating function for T by generalizing the approach
described in Section 2.1.
Let Yt f t Xt F t G Xt , which we wish to be a martingale.
Then by Itos formula we have
1
dY FGdt FG dX FG dX 2
2
1 2 2
FG XdZ FG X FG XFG G dt
2
and G x satisfies:
x2 G x x G x Gx 0
where 2 2, 2 2 and 2 2.
d Xt M c dt a Xt M dt 2 Xt M dZt
where a k 2
c k v L k 1 M
Xt M Inverse-Gamma 1
a
where 21 2
2
2c
2
2
E Xt M
2
2
Var Xt M 2
2 3
Therefore we have
k v L k 1 M
E Xt M
k 2
2 2
k v L k 1 M 2
Var Xt 2
k 2 2k 2 2
1 2
provided k 2 2 2
From these equations, we see that we require c 0 to ensure that Xt M for all
t almost surely (that is, the risk-free interest plus the amortization effort must be
sufficient to keep the funding level above M). We also require a 0 (that is, k 2)
to ensure that Xt does not tend to infinity almost surely. Finally we can see that the
1 2
variance will be infinite if k 2 2 2.
V exp s C t 2ds
0
CPPI
Probability Density
1.5
Static
1.0
0.5
0.0
Funding Level
Figure 1: Comparison of the stationary densities for the Static and CPPI asset allo-
cation strategies. Static (solid curve): E Xt 1 28, Var Xt 0 2432. CPPI (dotted
curve): E Xt 1 28, Var Xt 0 3132 .
approaches the minimum or if the funding level gets quite high and into more risky
assets if the funding level lies between these two extremes.
n n
A
d A t j j dt c jk dZk t
j 1 k 1
similarly for portfolio B the return in the time interval [t, t+dt) is
n n
B
d B t j j dt c jk dZk t
j 1 k 1
The matrix C c jk is somewhat arbitrary but has the constraint that CCT V
where V is the symmetric convariance matrix for the n assets.
These equations can be condensed into the following forms:
d A t A dt AA dZA t AB dZB t
d B t B dt BA dZA t BB dZB t
n
A
where A j j
j 1
n
B
B j j
j 1
AA AB
and if S
BA BB
TV TV
A B
then SST A
TV
A
TV
B A B B
Thus without loss of generality we may work with two assets 1 and 2 instead of the
two portfolios A and B.
At any time a proportion of the fund p t is invested in asset 2. Thus the return in
the time interval [t, t+dt) is
d t 1 pt d 1t pt d 2t
where d 1 t 1 dt 11 dZ1 t 12 dZ2 t
d 2 t 2 dt 21 dZ1 t 22 dZ2 t
dX t X t d t N B k L X t dt
Note that if v is the valuation force of interest then N, B and L are related by the
balance equation 0 dL v Ldt N B dt which implies that N B v L.
Hence
dX t X t d t k v L kX t dt
p0 p1 X t
pt
X t
p20 21 11
2
22 12
2
2p0 21 11 1 p1 11 p1 21
22 12 1 p1 12 p1 22
1 p1 11 p1 21 2 1 p1 12 p1 22
2
p0 2 1 k v L
k 1 p1 1 p1 2
This stochastic differential equation for X t is therefore in the correct form for
Theorem 1.1. Thus the stationary distribution of X t is
1 x b
fX x k exp 2a tan x x2 1
c
for x
1
where a 2
4 2
b
2
4 2
c
2
This is true provided that it is not possible to synthesize a risk-free asset out of the
two portfolios. If that is the case then we will have 4 2 0.
An example of this is given in Figure 2. Here we have 1 0 02, 2 0 05,
v 0 02, k 0 1, L 1, 11 0 04, 12 21 0 08 and 22 0 15. The
asset allocation strategy uses p0 0 8 and p1 1. This gives E Xt 1 11 and
Var Xt 0 4392. Figure 2 also plots the density for the equivalent static strategy.
This strategy used a linear combination of portfolios 1 and 2 (with p 0 275) and
gives E Xt 1 11 and Var Xt 0 3432. We see that generalized CPPI appears
to have a similar effect to the more basic form: that is, the distribution has lower
probabilities of low funding levels, a fat tail and is more skewed than the static
strategy.
It should be noted that below a funding level of M p0 p1 the new CPPI strategy
goes short in asset 2 and long in asset 1. Furthermore, there is nothing to stop the
funding level going negative (although the probability that this happens in any one
year is very small). This is because at that point the fund is long in asset 1 and
short in asset 2. If asset 2 performs much better than asset 1 then the funding level
will continue to move in a negative direction. In effect, when the funding level goes
below M, the level of risk increases again. To avoid this problem, Cairns (1996)
considers the case
p0 p1 Xt
Xt whenXt p0 p1
pt
0 whenXt p0 p1
This strategy remains wholly in asset 1 below the minimum and means that Xt will
remain positive with probablity 1.
1.5
Gen.CPPI
Probability Density
1.0
Static
0.5
0.0
Funding Level
Figure 2: Comparison of the stationary densities for the Static and Generalized
CPPI asset allocation strategies. Static (solid curve): E Xt 1 11, Var Xt
2
0 343 . Generalized CPPI (dotted curve): E Xt 1 11, Var Xt 0 4392.
6 References
Black, F. and Jones, R. (1988) Simplifying portfolio insurance for corporate pen-
sion plans. Journal of Portfolio Management 14(4), 33-37.
Black, F. and Perold, A. (1992) Theory of constant proportion portfolio insurance.
Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 16, 403-426.
Boulier, J-F., Trussant, E. and Florens, D. (1995) A dynamic model for pension
funds management. Proceedings of the 5th AFIR International Colloquium 1,
361-384.
Cairns, A.J.G. (1996) Continuous-time stochastic pension fund models. In prepa-
ration.
Cairns, A.J.G. and Parker, G. (1996) Stochastic pension fund modelling. Submit-
ted.
Dufresne, D. (1988) Moments of pension contributions and fund levels when rates
of return are random. Journal of the Institute of Actuaries 115, 535-544.
Dufresne, D. (1989) Stability of pension systems when rates of return are random.
Insurance: Mathematics and Economics 8, 71-76.
Dufresne, D. (1990) The distribution of a perpetuity, with applications to risk
theory and pension funding. Scandinavian Actuarial Journal 1990, 39-79.
Haberman, S. (1992) Pension funding with time delays: a stochastic approach.
Insurance: Mathematics and Economics 11, 179-189.
Haberman, S. (1994) Autoregressive rates of return and the variability of pension
fund contributions and fund levels for a defined benefit pension scheme. Insurance:
Mathematics and Economics 14, 219-240.
Oksendal, B. (1992) Stochastic Differential Equations. Springer Verlag, Berlin.
Parker, G. (1994) Limiting distribution of the present value of a portfolio of poli-
cies. ASTIN Bulletin 24, 47-60.