C00 1057 - 00A 008E c1

Download as doc, pdf, or txt
Download as doc, pdf, or txt
You are on page 1of 69

Decision No.

C00-1057

BEFORE THE PUBLIC UTILITIES COMMISSION OF THE STATE OF COLORADO

DOCKET NO. 00A-008E

IN THE MATTER OF THE APPLICATION OF PUBLIC SERVICE COMPANY OF


COLORADO FOR AN ORDER DETERMINING WHETHER THE SIZE AND LOAD
IMPACT OF THE DEMAND SIDE MANAGEMENT AND RENEWABLES SEGMENTS OF
ITS 1999 INTEGRATED RESOURCE PLAN MAXIMIZE THE PUBLIC INTEREST.

INITIAL COMMISSION DECISION REGARDING THE


DEMAND SIDE MANAGEMENT AND RENEWABLES
SEGMENTS OF PUBLIC SERVICE COMPANY OF
COLORADOS 1999 INTEGRATED RESOURCE PLAN

Mailed Date: September 26, 2000


Adopted Date: July 13, 2000

TABLE OF CONTENTS
I. BY THE COMMISSION:...........................................2
A. Statement.................................................2
B. Discussion................................................5
II. RENEWABLES SEGMENT OF PUBLIC SERVICE 1999 IRP.............5
A. Introduction..............................................5
a. Parties Positions..................................6
(1)....................................Public Service
.................................................6
(2)...............................................OCC
.................................................7
(3)........................Commission Staff (Staff)
.................................................8
(4)..............................................CRES
.................................................9
(5)..............................................CORE
.................................................9
(6)..........................................LAW Fund
................................................10
(7)................City and County of Denver (City)
................................................10
III. COMMISSION DECISION......................................11
IV. THE DSM STIPULATION AND SETTLEMENT AGREEMENT.............13
A. Introduction.............................................13
B. Paragraph M of Stipulation...............................18
V. Legality of DSM.............................................20
A. Commission Authority to Adopt DSM........................20
B. DSM and Cost of Service..................................24
C. Rate Discrimination......................................26
D. Other Objections to DSM..................................32
E. Conclusion...............................................35
VI. CONCLUSION...............................................35
VII. ORDER....................................................36
VIII. CHAIRMAN RAYMOND L. GIFFORD CONCURRING, IN PART, AND
DISSENTING, IN PART:........................................37
A. Introduction.............................................37
B. DSM Lacks Statutory Authorization........................38
1. Background............................................38
2. Ratemaking............................................38
C. The DSM Stipulation Violates 40-3-106(1)(a), C.R.S.....44
2. Case Law: Mountain States Legal Foundation v. PUC.....49
3. The DSM Stipulation is Necessary to Avoid Interruptions
in Service............................................57
D. The Big Picture..........................................59
The Real Problem......................................59
E. The Real Solution: Accurate Cost-Based Rates.............61
F. Conclusion...............................................63
G. Postlude.................................................64
IX. COMMISSIONER ROBERT J. HIX DISSENTING, IN PART:..........67

A. BY THE COMMISSION:

2
1. Statement

.1 This matter comes before the Commission for entry

of an initial decision, pursuant to the provisions of

40-6-109(6), C.R.S., regarding the demand side management

(DSM) and renewables segments of Public Service Company of

Colorados (Public Service or Company) 1999 Integrated

Resources Plan (IRP). In accordance with the Commissions

Integrated Resource Planning Rules, 4 Code of Colorado

Regulations 723-21, Public Service previously filed its proposed

1999 IRP. The Commission is considering that plan in Docket No.

99A-549E. In that docket, by Decision No. C00-38, we decided

that the DSM and the renewables portions of the Companys plan

should be considered in a separate proceeding. The instant

docket was opened for that purpose.

In the order initiating this proceeding (Decision No. C00-40,

Mailed Date of January 10, 2000), we assigned this matter to an

Administrative Law Judge (ALJ) for hearing.1 We directed that

in the proceedings before the ALJ the parties address certain

issues including: Public Services proposal to recover through

1
Because this case originated from Docket No. 99A-549E, the parties in
that case were made parties to the instant proceeding by order of the
Commission (Decision No. C00-40, pages 3 and 4. Intervenors to the present
case include: the Arkansas River Power Authority; the City and County of
Denver; the Office of Energy Management and Conservation; the Colorado
Independent Energy Association; Colorado Interstate Gas Company; the Colorado
Mining Association; the Colorado Office of Consumer Counsel; the Colorado
Renewable Energy Society; Holy Cross Electric Association, Inc.; the Land and
Water Fund of the Rockies; the North American Power Group, Ltd.; Staff of the
Commission; and Tri-State Generation and Transmission Association, Inc.

3
rates the costs associated with the anticipated acquisition of an

additional 25 MWs of wind power; Public Services corporate

policy toward DSM measures; Public Services position that DSM

4
resources should not be used to offset supply-side resources to

be acquired under the 1999 IRP; and Public Services advocacy

that DSM acquisitions in an amount of $10 million properly

balances the eight goals set forth in the Basis and Purpose of

the IRP Rules.

.2 The ALJ conducted a hearing on the renewables

portion of this proceeding on April 12 and 13, 2000.

Additionally, on May 17, 2000, the parties submitted the

Stipulation and Settlement Agreement (Stipulation) which

proposes to resolve all outstanding issues related to the DSM

segment of the Companys 1999 IRP. In order to investigate the

acceptability of the Stipulation we conducted a hearing on

June 22, 2000. The parties presented a number of witnesses who

supported the Stipulation.

.3 In Decision No. C00-40, we anticipated that, given

the Companys need for timely decisions on its proposed IRP, the

Commission may be required to issue the initial decision in this

proceeding pursuant to 40-6-109(6), C.R.S. We now conclude

that due and timely execution of our functions imperatively and

unavoidably requires that we issue the initial decision in this

matter. In particular, we find that Public Service requires

timely decisions on these aspects of its IRP, in order to enable

it to take appropriate actions to acquire resources to meet

customers future electric needs.

5
.4 Now being duly advised in the premises, we enter

the instant decision. In part, we approve Public Services

proposal to expand its voluntary Wind Source Program by a minimum

of 35 MWs over the 2002 through 2005 time period. We also

approve the Stipulation, which, in part, calls for Public Service

to attempt to acquire up to 124 MWs of cost-effective DSM

resources through the period ending December 31, 2005 at a cost

not to exceed $75 million total capital and expense (in year 2000

dollars).

2. Discussion

We first address the renewables segment and then

consider the DSM Stipulation and Settlement Agreement.

B. RENEWABLES SEGMENT OF PUBLIC SERVICE 1999 IRP

1. Introduction

.1 The Commission must decide how much renewable

resources are optimal given the eight goals set forth in the

IRP Rules. Parties have suggested a number of options. For

example, Public Service proposes to expand its voluntary Wind

Source Program by a minimum of 35 MWs over the 2002 through 2005-

time period. Environmental groups such as the Colorado

Renewable Energy Society (CRES), Community Office for Resource

Efficiency (CORE), and the Land and Water fund of the Rockies

(LAW Fund) suggest that ratepayers match the amount of wind

6
power provided by the voluntary Wind Source Program up to a total

of 100 MWs over the same period.

.2 The history of the WindSource Program is described

in Chapter 4, page 4, of Public Services 1999 Draft IRP. In

January 1996, Public Service began investigating product

opportunities that would meet customers needs in the general area

of green pricing (i.e., offering customers renewable generation

as a premium priced option). A business case was developed that

supported the concept of a voluntary wind subscription program.

On September 3, 1996, Public Service filed an application with

the Commission for a Renewable Energy Service Adjustment. On

February 3, 1997, Public Service and intervenors in that case

filed a settlement resolving all issues. On February 19, 1997,

the Commission issued Decision No. C97-203, approving the

settlement and authorizing Public Service to proceed with

offering an optional product to customers at a price of 2.5

cents/kWh above base rates.

.a Parties Positions

()1 Public Service

In his Direct Testimony, page 6,

Mr. Stoffel, originally proposed a special electric rider charged

to all electric customers. Under that proposal the Company would

have been allowed to recover any wind energy costs that were in

excess of the 2.5 cents per kilowatt-hour Public Service is

7
allowed to charge above the base rates under its current

WindSource tariff. This was opposed by the Office of Consumer

Counsel (OCC) in the Answer Testimony of P. B. Schechter. In

the Rebuttal Testimony of Mr. Stoffel, page 2, Public Service

withdrew its request for a special wind rate rider to apply to

all retail electric rates. Instead, the Company agreed to

attempt to acquire the equivalent of 35 additional MWs of

Colorado wind generation over the resource acquisition period,

and to market that power to retail customers through the

Companys WindSource program at shareholder risk. At the June

22, 2000 hearing in defense of the DSM Stipulation, Mr. Stoffel

stated that the Company traded off the settlements larger

investment in DSM for lower levels of renewables, because DSM is

a known and preferable solution to diversity and environmental

quality goals than renewables.

()2 OCC

The OCCs position is contained in the

Answer Testimony of Witness Schechter. As mentioned above, the

OCC opposed Public Services original proposal to implement a

rate rider to recover any potential unrecovered costs from Public

Services WindSource Program. Mr. Schechter suggested that as

long as customers are free to choose whether or not they wish to

pay extra for wind energy, the OCC is not opposed to Public

Service making wind energy available to its customers even if the

8
cost of producing energy for wind is higher than other resources.

He added that the OCC is opposed to requiring all customers to

pay additional charges for wind energy. He maintained that

Commission rules do not require the acquisition of wind power.

Mr. Schechter pointed out that, presumably, Public Service is

proposing to acquire wind energy to promote diversity and

environmental quality (IRP Rules, goals 4 and 6). However, he

maintained that Public Service could promote diversity and

environmental quality at least cost by acquiring cost effective

DSM.

()3 Commission Staff (Staff)

Ms. Sharon Podein testified for Staff on

this issue. Staffs position is that cost recovery for renewable

resources should be limited to a program based on voluntary

participation. Ms. Podein stated that the Green Electric Study

prepared for Public Service by Insight Research, Inc., led her to

conclude that, while a majority of customers polled supported

Public Service putting forth an effort to develop renewable

energy, most were unwilling to pay for it directly. According to

Ms. Podein, rate-basing wind resources raises fairness issues

inasmuch as market studies show that the customers most likely to

purchase green products have higher incomes and belong to

environmental organizations in greater numbers than ratepayers in

general. She claimed that the market research conducted by

9
Public Service determined that the majority of the ratepayers do

not value renewable resources enough to choose funding them.

()4 CRES

CRES filed the Answer Testimony of

Karl Rabago and Harold Hubbard. These witnesses suggested that

balancing the IRP goals, including diversity, environmental

quality, and public health, calls for placing more renewables in

rate base. These witnesses argued that Public Services wind

power proposal is too small to take advantage of economies of

scale. Therefore, they recommended that Public Service acquire a

minimum of 100 MW of wind. Finally, they contended that if

Public Service is not willing to meet customer demand for

renewables, the Commission should consider allowing alternative

providers to enter the market.

()5 CORE

CORE filed the Answer Testimony of Mr.

Randy Udall. According to Mr. Udall, Public Services wind

proposal is too little too late. He maintained that given

Colorados severe capacity constraints, the Company needs more

wind power now. He specifically suggested building 100 MWs of

wind resources by 2005. Furthermore, he argued that non-wind

customers are free riders, receiving the benefits that voluntary

Wind Source customers provide. He contended that these benefits

include environmental quality, public health, and resource

10
diversity. Mr. Udall concluded that Public Service should be

ordered to match with equal amounts of wind in rate base the

amounts of wind generation to which WindSource customers

subscribe.

()6 LAW Fund

The Law Funds position is contained in

the Direct Testimony of James F. Gilliam. Mr. Gilliam is

generally supportive of additional acquisitions of wind energy

such as those advocated by CRES and CORE.

()7 City and County of Denver (City)

Mr. Steve Foute filed testimony on

behalf of the City. Mr. Foute is employed by the City as the

Director of the Environmental Protection Division of the Denver

Department of Environmental Health. Mr. Foute testified that the

City is a proponent of utility development of renewable energy.

The City is a WindSource subscriber and encourages Public Service

to expand its purchase of electricity generated from renewable

resources. According to Mr. Foute, the City prefers that

renewables be developed through a rate-base approach. Mr. Foute

noted that the study conducted by Stone and Webster and

commissioned by the Colorado Electricity Advisory Panel concluded

that adding 50 MWs of wind power a year would have a rate impact

of less than 1 percent on the average residential ratepayer.

According to Mr. Foute, the City recommends that Public Service

11
work with interested parties to evaluate the accuracy of the

Stone and Webster rate impact projection. If the modeling of the

rate impact of wind development confirms that there is only a

slight rate impact on customers, the Company should come forward

with a sustained rate-based wind development proposal in the

range of 20 through 30 MWs a year.

C. COMMISSION DECISION

.A The Company asserts that wind power is approximately

twice as expensive as conventional resources.2 On the other

hand, supporters of wind assert that Public Services proposals

do not take advantage of potential economies of scale that could

make wind more price competitive. The record here contains

conflicting assertions concerning the consumer demand for wind

power. Given the relatively weak factual record in this docket,

it is difficult to overcome the objections of the OCC and the

Staff to rate basing more wind resources.

The overall record in this docket does reveal that the DSM

2
All the parties agreed that the Companys voluntary WindSource Program
has been successful. Mr. Rabago, testifying on behalf of CRES, pointed out
that the WindSource Program is the largest selling green pricing service
offered by a regulated utility in a non-competitive market in the world.

12
proposed in the Stipulation and Settlement Agreement (discussion

below) is likely to be less expensive than wind resources.

Certainly the decision by Public Service and the parties, in the

Stipulation, to pursue 124 MWs of DSM reduces the need to acquire

additional wind resources beyond the new 35 MWs the Company

agrees to pursue through its voluntary WindSource Program.

Further, the Commission agrees with the OCC that the Commission

can advance the preservation of environmental quality and the

development of a diversified electric resource portfolio (goals 4

and 6 of IRP Rules), for less cost, by directing Public Service

to promote cost effective DSM.

.B Therefore, given the current economics of wind power,

and in the context of an IRP period characterized by an attempt

to pursue unprecedented amounts of DSM, we agree with the parties

who opposed the rate-basing of more wind resources. The

Commission finds that the Companys proposal to expand its

voluntary Wind Source Program by a minimum of 35 megawatts over

the 2002 through 2005 time period is in the public interest and

is consistent with optimizing the eight goals set forth in the

IRP Rules.

.C We reject as unlawful the suggestion by some of the

parties that other providers be permitted to offer wind power to

Public Services customers. The regulation of the electric

utility industry in Colorado is currently based upon the doctrine

13
of regulated monopoly. Public Service Company v. Trigen-Nations,

982 P.2d 316 (Colo. 1999); Public Service Company v. Public

Utilities Commission, 765 P.2d 1015 (Colo. 1988). Under the

regulated monopoly doctrine, when an area is certificated to one

utility, it and it alone has the right to serve the future needs

of that area provided it can do so. Public Service Company v.

PUC, supra, at 1021. There is no evidence here that the Company

is unable or unwilling to meet the electricity needs of end-users

within its service territory. Therefore, it would be unlawful to

permit other providers to offer wind power to Public Services

end-users.

D. THE DSM STIPULATION AND SETTLEMENT AGREEMENT

1. Introduction

.1 Several of the parties3 recommended that the

Commission approve the Stipulation as a just and reasonable

conclusion to that portion of the Companys 1999 IRP dealing with

the DSM resources to be pursued by the Company in its 1999 IRP.

The parties specifically agree that the terms are reasonable and

in the public interest. No party to this case opposed the

Stipulation.

.2 We find that the Stipulation is in the public

interest and should be approved. We do not discuss here each

3
The parties to the settlement are: Public Service; Staff; the City;
the Colorado Governors Office of Energy Management and Conservation; the OCC;
and The LAW Water Fund.

14
specific provision in the Stipulation, although we do approve the

Stipulation in its entirety.

.3 In our view, the Stipulation does reflect an

appropriated balancing of the eight goals set forth in the Basis

and Purpose to the IRP Rules. According to all the witnesses who

testified at the hearing, DSM is the least expensive and easiest

way to satisfy Colorados growing demand for electricity. These

witnesses suggested that the proposed DSM acquisition in the

Stipulation would advance all eight IRP goals.

.4 At the June 22, 2000 hearing, the witnesses

testified that Colorados unprecedented growth creates a

tremendous challenge for Public Service and its suppliers.

Specifically, adding 1200 MWs of new supply-side power during the

next five years, as the Company proposes, will require overcoming

numerous and substantial barriers. These include transmission

constraints, concerns associated with siting new generation

facilities, more stringent Environmental Protection Agency

(EPA) air quality standards, and reserve margin uncertainties.

Public Service witness Stoffel testified that, based on an

analysis the Company performed in preparation for the hearing on

the Stipulation, the costs of new supply-side resources range

from $550/kW to $1100/kW, with the majority being above $700/kW.4

4
In contrast, under the terms of the Stipulation DSM costs would
average $605/kW ($75 million divided by 124 MWs).

15
He also testified that although DSM has its own implementation

challenges and uncertainties, these are less serious than the

uncertainties and challenges the Company faces in delivering

supply-side resources. OCC witness Reif, Director of the OCC,

testified that prior to this proceeding he had not been an

enthusiastic supporter of DSM because, in the past, Public

Service has had excess capacity. This excess capacity

environment meant that DSM benefits were primarily non-economic

ones. However, according to Mr. Reif, circumstances are now

different inasmuch as the Company now faces serious capacity

constraints. In light of these new circumstances, Mr. Reif is

now convinced that DSM is justified on economic grounds as the

least expensive way to meet future demand.

.5 We note that cost effective DSM programs are, by

definition, reductions in the demand for power and/or usage of

energy that are less expensive to achieve than the supply-side

resources they replace. Such programs lower Public Services

cost of acquiring power and lower the costs to the average

customer. Cost effective DSM is supported by the Company,

Commission Staff, parties representing consumer and environmental

interests, and has been supported by this Commission in previous

dockets. We note that, as a regulated monopoly, Public Service

is obligated to acquire resources in the least cost manner.

16
.6 The Stipulation contains numerous safeguards to

assure that only cost effective DSM is pursued. These include

Paragraph F, which requires the Company to use the Total

Resource Cost test5 in evaluating specific DSM proposals, and

Paragraph H which requires verification of installation

effectiveness in addition to impact and process evaluations. The

fact that DSM will be acquired by competitive bid creates another

level of protection. Ms. Haines, Director of Commercial and

Industrial Marketing for Public Service, testified that Public

Services acquisition of 124 MWs of DSM over the next five years

will attract interest from national energy service companies and

will accelerate the markets ability to take over the provision

of DSM. Finally, at the June 22, 2000 hearing, Public Service

introduced Exhibit 22 which contains the results of several cost-

effectiveness tests evaluated in support of the proposed 124 MWs

of DSM. Several witnesses, including

5
The Total Resource Cost Test (TRC) is designed to ensure that the
utility, target customers and the general ratepayers all benefit. The intent
of the TRC test is to minimize the total economic cost of meeting customer
needs for electricity (i.e., to maximize economic welfare). At the June 22,
2000 hearing, Ms. Haines testified to the conservative nature of the Companys
avoided cost method. She stated that the Company employs a short estimate of
measured lifetimes and conservative estimates of avoided transmission and
distribution costs. This increases the likelihood that DSM programs will have
measured cost/benefit ratios greater than one.

17
Ms. Haines and Staff witness Winger, testified that these results

were positive. Mr. Winger stated that Exhibit 22s cost-

effectiveness tests changed his mind about the desirability of

DSM. (Mr. Winger had originally questioned the need for DSM

resources.)

.7 We recognize that there are reasons for caution

when acquiring DSM (or any resource for that matter) including

the possibility of higher bills for non-participants.6 However,

the Stipulation is designed to minimize this problem. It creates

program options for all customer classes thereby allowing all

customers who are paying for DSM the opportunity to participate.

In an era of growing peak demand, the proposed DSM programs are

focused on reductions in peak demand with only minimal reduction

in energy consumption, and, therefore, rates are unlikely to be

significantly affected.

The Commission agrees with the parties that Colorados

unprecedented growth has created serious and historically

6
As several witnesses pointed out, distributional issues are often more
visible on the demand side than on the supply-side. To put things in
perspective, Public Service has identified a need for 1,200 MWs of new
capacity between 2002 and 2005. It has been estimated that ratepayers will
pay over $1 billion for this new capacity, over the ten-year lives of the
contracts Public Service is soliciting in its supply-side request for
proposal. This new capacity will have a rate impact on all customers, and on
all customer classes, not just customers causing the load growth that requires
the acquisition of new capacity. When a utility adds generation,
transmission, or distribution capacity, the costs of that new plant investment
are seldom allocated only to those customers whose load growth created the
need for new capacity. Rather the costs are rolled into rates in ways that
spread the incremental costs among all customers.

18
unprecedented capacity constraints. Further, the record

demonstrates that there are significant barriers to acquiring

sufficient supply-side resources over the next six years. In

this environment it is both prudent and in the public interest to

approve the Stipulation.

2. Paragraph M of Stipulation

In Decision No. C00-40, we directed the ALJ to investigate Public

Services position that the savings attributable to DSM measures

should not be used to offset the potential supply-side resource

additions to be selected through its 1999 IRP. In light of the

Commissions explicit interest in this issue we comment

specifically about the terms contained in Paragraph M.

.1 That paragraph provides that Public Service shall

not be required to reduce the amount of supply-side resources to

be acquired through the 1999 IRP as a result of the Stipulation.

The Commission agrees with parties who contended that, in theory,

it is inappropriate to acquire both DSM and supply-side resources

for the same demand. However, we believe that the parties to the

settlement agreement provided sufficient reasons to support

Paragraph M. Mr. Reif testified at the hearing that there were

good and adequate reasons why Public Service should acquire DSM

without offsetting the need to acquire supply-side resources. He

suggested that Public Services capacity forecasts may be low by

as much as 300 MWs. He added that, because of the uncertainty

19
and barriers to acquiring sufficient supply-side resources, the

risks of paying for 124 MWs of DSM that Public Services

customers may not need are overridden by the risk of not having

sufficient power to meet future demand.7

.2 Mr. Winger testified that DSM should be viewed as

a cushion. He based this on the uncertainty about how Public

Service will meet its supply-side objectives, citing the

uncertainties regarding transmission constraints, reserve

margins, EPA requirements and Public Services ability to acquire

sufficient power from its suppliers.

.3 At the June 22, 2000 hearing, Mr. Stoffel

acknowledged that the acquisition of this DSM could offset the

need to acquire supply-side resources going forward, for example

in the next IRP. He explained that the actual new installed DSM

should be reflected in a capacity reduction, and, therefore,

reduce the need for new supply-side resources.

.4 The Commission agrees with the rationales offered

by the parties and finds Paragraph M to be in the public

interest.

7
Even when the OCC was arguing that Public Service should be required
to offset supply-side resources in its March 15th Answer Testimony, it stated
its belief that it was more likely that Public Service would acquire more
expensive capacity by failing to solicit DSM resources, than it was that
Public Service would acquire too much capacity by soliciting DSM resources in
addition to supply-side resources.

20
E. LEGALITY OF DSM

The dissents (by Chairman Gifford) conclusion, that DSM

generally and the Stipulation specifically are unlawful, is

incorrect. We note that DSM is a well-established regulatory

practice, not only in Colorado, but nationally as well. 8 At this

late date, the claim that DSM is illegal is extraordinary and

should be accompanied by clear and strong support. The

dissenting opinion disappoints. Notably, the opinion cites not a

single case specifically related to DSM, even though DSM has been

considered by many regulatory and judicial bodies in the past.

There is no legal basis for concluding that DSM in general is

unlawful. Furthermore, there is no legal or factual basis for

concluding that the Stipulation here should be rejected.

1. Commission Authority to Adopt DSM

The dissent first argues that no statute specifically authorizes

the Commission to approve DSM programs in its regulation of

public utilities. Assuming specific statutory authorization

8
For example: Industrial Customers of Idaho Power v. Idaho Public
Utilities Commission, 200 PUR 4th 371 (Idaho, 2000); Porter v. South Caroline
Public Service Commission, 504 S.E.2d 320 (S.C., 1998); Potomac Electric
Power Company v. Public Service Commission, 661 A.2d 131 (D.C. App, 1995);
Association of Businesses Advocating Tariff Equity v. Michigan Public Service
Commission, 522 N.W. 2d 140 (Mich. App., 1994); In re Green Mountain Power
Corp., 648 A.2d 374 (Vermont, 1994).

21
were necessary-an assumption we reject9this argument is

inaccurate. Sections 40-3-111(1) and 40-6-111(2)(a), C.R.S.,

expressly authorize the Commission to establish utility rates

and practices that, in part, influence an adequate supply of

energy and encourage energy conservation. DSM is intended to

accomplish these purposes.10 See Porter v. South Carolina Public

Service Commission, supra, at 322 (DSM characterized as energy

conservation program); Potomac Electric Power v. Public Service

Commission, supra, at 133 , footnote 1 (DSM defined as programs

undertaken by utilities to encourage conservation...and thus to

reduce the demand for electricity); Association of Businesses

Advocating Tariff Equity v. Michigan Public Service Commission,

supra, at 143 (DSM defined as activities designed to influence

customer use of electricity and programs that may include

conservation measures). Sections 40-3-111(1) and 40-6-111(2)

(a) specifically authorize the Commission to adopt DSM programs

in its regulation of public utilities. The existence of these

9
The dissenting opinion itself notes that the Commission is a
constitutionally created agency and, as such, possesses authority equal to
that of the Legislature except where limited by statute. Colorado Energy
Advocacy Office v. Public Service Company, 704 P.2d 298 (Colo. 1985).
Therefore, no specific affirmative statutory authorization is necessary for
the Commission to adopt DSM programs. The dissent, for unexplained reasons,
finds that invocation of the Commissions broad constitutional authority is a
sign that the Commission is exceeding its authority. This is curious
reasoning. The Commissions broad power to regulate public utilities is a
principle specifically established by the Colorado Supreme Court in various
contexts.
10
The dissent may disagree that DSM is an effective method for
influencing an adequate supply of energy and for encouraging energy
conservation. However, this objection relates to the specifics of particular
DSM programs, not to the legality of DSM in general.

22
statutory provisions refutes the dissents assertion that the

Commission lacks legal authority to approve the Stipulation.11

.1 The dissenting opinion (paragraph VIII.B.2.b.)

interprets a statement in Office of Consumer Counsel v. Public

Service Co., 877 P.2d 867, at 874, n. 10 (Colo. 1994) as an

intimation that the Court questions the legality of DSM. This

interpretation is misguided for various reasons. In the first

place, a statement by the Court that the legality of DSM has

never been addressed by a court of law cannot be taken for

anything more than an observation that the legality of DSM has

never been addressed by a court of law. We should assume that

the Court meant exactly what it said, and not speculateand

speculation it is-- that the Court meant anything more. Second,

we note that, contrary to the dissents interpretation, the

Courts statement did not even concern the legality of DSM

generally. Rather, the Courts statement primarily related to an

incentive payment to Public Service that was merely one

component of the DSM program approved by the Commission in 1993.

Specifically, the incentive component of the previously approved

DSM plan was intended to allow Public Service to recover some of

the revenues lost as a result of energy conservation. That

11
These statutory provisions also answer the dissents contention that
DSM constitutes an illegal preference under 40-3-106, inasmuch as, in these
statutes, the Legislature specifically authorized the Commission to adopt DSM.
See discussion infra.

23
incentive payment is eliminated in the proposed Stipulation here.

See paragraph B, pages 2-3 of Stipulation.

.2 In any event, the comment in footnote 10, Office

of Consumer Counsel v. Public Service Company, did not concern

DSM programs generally; the case itself did not involve DSM in

any way. As such, the dissents speculation that the Court has

questioned the legality of DSM and has invited the Commission

to justify the lawfulness of DSM is groundless.

.3 The dissent, moreover, ignores a subsequent

decision by the Colorado Supreme Court in which it affirmed the

legality of certain Commission ratemaking decisions related to a

specific DSM practice (i.e. interruptible rates for industrial

and large commercial customers). See CFI Steel , L.P. v. Public

Utilities Commission, 949 P.2d 577 (Colo. 1997). On review of a

Commission decision setting rates for interruptible electric

service, a service expressly characterized by the Commission and

the Court as a DSM measure, the Court affirmed the Commissions

ratemaking determinations for this DSM method. Notably, the

Court addressed some of the arguments asserted by the dissent

here (e.g. that DSM constitutes an unlawful preference). See

discussion infra. There is no need to speculate, as the dissent

does, that the Colorado Supreme Court questions the legality of

DSM programs as a result of an off-hand comment in one of its

decisions. The Court specifically considered a DSM program in

24
CF&I and affirmed a Commission ratemaking decision relating to

that program.

2. DSM and Cost of Service

.1 The dissenting opinion then contends that DSM is

unlawful because it results in rates not based upon actual cost

of service. That is, all customers will pay DSM-related costs

even though some do not participate in DSM programs, and,

therefore, do not benefit from DSM (or, in the words of the

dissent, benefit far less so than others). According to the

dissenting opinion, consumers have a right to pay rates based

upon cost-of-service only.12 We disagree.13

.2 In the first place, the dissent is incorrect in

its assertion that non-participants in a DSM program will not

benefit. The purpose of DSM practices, as explained above, is to

avoid or delay new supply-side resources and the costs associated

with those resources. Appropriate, cost-effective DSM14 will

benefit all ratepayers, including those who are not direct

12
In part, the dissent cites Consumers League of Colorado v. Colorado
& Southern Railway, 172 P. 1064 (Colo. 1918) in support of this argument,
suggesting that this case represents the foundation of the Commissions
authority. This statement is certainly hyperbolic. We note that this 1918
case, which involved ratemaking for a railroad instead of a fixed utility like
Public Service, has never been cited in another Colorado court opinion.
13
We note that the dissent itself appears to diverge from its theory
by its statement that rates may also be based upon value of service
considerations.
14
We point out that approval of the Stipulation here does not result
in Commission approval of any specific program. The dissenting opinion
suggests that all DSM programs are always cost-ineffective. However, as
discussed infra, this remarkable premise is a factual one that lacks support
in this record.

25
participants in a specific program, by avoiding the costs of

building new capacity. The parties pointed out that cost-

effective DSM resources(i.e. less costly than new supply-side

resources) currently exist. As for the dissents concern that

the selected DSM resources will not, in fact, benefit ratepayers,

we note that the Stipulation establishes numerous safeguards for

ensuring that only cost-effective DSM is acquired by the Company

in the future. In general, therefore, it is inaccurate to

suggest that DSM practices are unrelated to cost of service.

Furthermore, the dissents contention that ratepayers (e.g. non-

participants in DSM) are legally entitled to pay rates based only

on cost-of-service is contrary to clearly established law. The

CF&I case (pages 588-589) points out that while cost of service

is an important consideration in setting utility rates, this is

not the exclusive factor; the Commission has discretion to

consider other factors related to legitimate utility purposes.

Accord Integrated Network Services, Inc. v. Public Utilities

Commission, 875 P.2d 1373 (Colo. 1994). Influencing

26
consumer demand for electricity and the promotion of energy

conservation are legitimate ratemaking considerations

particularly in light of the provisions of 40-3-111(1) and 40-

6-111(2)(a).

.3 The DSM that may be acquired pursuant to the

Stipulation will likely promote the public interest. It offers

the promise of providing resources to ratepayers at lesser costs

than new supply-side resources. Furthermore, at a time when

Public Service is projecting a need to acquire approximately 1200

MWs of power over the next few years, DSM will promote system

reliability, reducing the possibility of electric service

interruptions in the future. These are valid ratemaking

considerations. Nothing in current law even remotely suggests

that the Commission must ignore these aspects of the public

interest, simply because not all ratepayers will participate

directly in a DSM program.

3. Rate Discrimination

.1 The dissent reasons that DSM in general

constitutes an illegal preference under 40-3-106(1), C.R.S. (no

public utility, as to rates, charges, service, or facilities,

shall grant any preference to any person). According to the

dissenting opinion, DSM programs result in improper inter- and

intraclass rate discrimination for various reasons: As to

interclass discrimination, DSM programs are heavily weighted

27
towards industrial and large commercial ratepayers. Other

customer classes (e.g. residential) do not have the opportunity

to participate in DSM programs to the same degree as industrial

and large commercial customers. This, the dissent concludes,

amounts to unreasonable interclass discrimination.

.2 With respect to intraclass discrimination, the

dissent observes: Not everyone in the class (e.g. residential

ratepayers who do not have air conditioning15) directly

participates in specific DSM programs, and, therefore, not

everyone in the class benefits equally. Section 40-3-106(1)

prohibits any intraclass preference, not only unreasonable ones.

Therefore, the failure of everyone within specific rate classes

to directly participate in DSM programs constitutes an unlawful

preference.

.3 Lastly, the dissent concludes that DSM is unlawful

under Mountain States Legal Foundation v. Public Utilities

Commission, 590 P.2d 495 (Colo. 1979). Under this theory, DSM

amounts to ratemaking to implement social policy; such

ratemaking is prohibited by Mountain States.

.4 We disagree with all these arguments. First, as

noted above, the Legislature ( 40-3-111(1) and 40-6-111(2)(a))

has expressly authorized the Commission to adopt DSM practices in

15
One of the Companys DSM programs for the residential class provides
a $25 payment to customers who allow Public Service to place a load control
device on their air conditioning units.

28
ratemaking proceedings. This is dispositive of all contentions

that DSM methods are unlawfully discriminatory under 40-3-

106(1). However narrowly and formalistically one wishes to

interpret 40-3-106(1), the fact remains that the Legislature

has already spoken regarding the permissibility of DSM in public

utility ratemaking.

.5 Moreover, the CF&I case directly addresses this

aspect of the dissents objection to DSM. After acknowledging

that adoption of interruptible electric rates constituted a

demand side resource,16 the Court observed:

....With regard to interruptible rates, Public Service had


proposed to create six subclasses of a very few users of
electricity who would receive a substantial price advantage over
firm service that was not available to the vast majority of the
companys customers. Only the largest users of electrical
service could qualify. The rational basis for such a proposal,
which otherwise might appear to discriminate against smaller
customers who have no choice but to accept firm service and pay
firm service rates, is that these large commercial and
industrial accounts can provide Public Service with a
substantial load management capability by declining service
during occasional maximum demand periods.

(emphasis added) CF&I, at 586. The dissent itself suggests that,

with respect to rates applicable to different customer classes,

it is unreasonable rate differences that are prohibited by the

statute. According to the dissenting opinion, DSM is

unreasonable because the programs are primarily directed at

industrial and commercial customers. However, CF&I refutes the

16
See CF& I, at 580, and footnote 3.

29
dissents conclusion. That most DSM programs involve industrial

and commercial customers simply reflects the fact that these are

the programs that carry the greatest potential for cost-effective

demand side savings. In short, whatever interclass differences

exist under the Stipulation are reasonable. And, in any event,

the Stipulation is intended to provide the opportunity for all

customer classes to participate in DSM measures in the future.

.6 With respect to the suggestion that DSM involves

illegal intraclass discrimination, in addition to the above

comments we note: The dissents interpretation of 40-3-106(1)

is overly simplistic and narrow. It emphasizes the statutes use

of the word any and concludes that any difference in treatment

of customers within the same class (i.e. some ratepayers

participate directly in a DSM program and some do not) is

unlawful. However, this reasoning assumes the conclusion

reached. What is proscribed by the statute is the grant of a

preference (or advantage). The dissent assumes, without

support, that any difference amounts to a preference

30
as that term is used in the statute. That a particular

ratemaking practice such as DSM may benefit all ratepayers is

irrelevant in the dissents view, because some customers benefit

more than others. Every difference is an illegal preference.

.7 We disagree with this interpretation of the

statute. The statute does not define preference. Therefore,

as the agency with authority to administer the Public Utilities

Law, it is the Commissions obligation to apply the statute and

decide whether particular practices are preferences within the

legal contemplation. The Legislature, in 40-3-106(1), has not

stated that every ratemaking difference constitutes an illegal

preference. In fact, the last directive in 40-3-106(1) is

that, The commission has the power to determine any question of

fact arising under this section. We conclude that the

Legislature intended that the Commission examine the factual

circumstances involved in specific cases to determine whether a

particular ratemaking practice is an illegal preference. For the

reasons discussed in this decision, we conclude that the

Stipulation is reasonable and will result in just and reasonable

rates.

.8 We note that the Stipulation will not result in

any difference in the DSM-related rates paid by customers within

the same rate class. Therefore, the dissents argument here

(that a preference exists) is solely based upon the observation

31
that not all ratepayers will benefit equally through the DSM

programs. See paragraph VIII.C.2. of dissent (intraclass

preference will exist because some ratepayers, the non-

participants in DSM programs, will benefit far less so than

others). This reasoning, however, implies that rates must be set

for each individual customer, accounting for that individuals

specific cost of service and the precise benefits that customer

will obtain, not only from DSM, but all other utility services.

Of course, under this interpretation of preference virtually no

rates or ratemaking practices would be lawful.

.9 The dissent itself observes that rate averaging

(i.e. establishing identical rates to be paid by all customers

within a class) is a common and well-established practice. With

rate averaging, customers within a rate class pay the same rates

regardless of the costs of serving individual customers and

regardless of the particular benefits derived by those individual

customers. At least for reasons of practicality, the fact that

not all customers in a rate class will benefit equally from DSM

does not mean that an illegal preference exists. Cf. CF&I, at

588-89 (Commission cannot determine with precision how

interruptible customers individual costs will be affected by

interruptible service).

.10 The dissent is also mistaken in its assertion that

DSM is discriminatory under the principles established by the

32
Mountain States case. That case essentially holds that in the

absence of a specific statute, the Commissions authority to

engage in ratemaking to effect social policy (i.e. ratemaking

unrelated to the cost or type of the service provided

(Mountain States, at 498)) is restricted. However, as discussed

above, the Legislature has empowered the Commission to adopt DSM

methods. Moreover, DSM is related to cost and reliability of

utility service, and, therefore, is not ratemaking for the

purpose of effecting social policy.

.11 The Stipulation (paragraph G) establishes the

principle that, to the extent practicable, all customer classes

will be provided an opportunity to participate in DSM programs.

Further, the Stipulation contains procedures for ensuring that

cost-effective DSM is acquired by the Company, to the benefit of

all ratepayers. We conclude that the DSM entailed in the

Stipulation is not discriminatory or preferential in any respect.

4. Other Objections to DSM

We note that in its rejection of the Stipulation the dissent

relies upon a number of factual premises. For example, the

dissent asserts that the cost effectiveness of DSM programs is

difficult to quantify; that DSM programs are always wasteful and

ineffective; that the Stipulation is not necessary to avoid

future interruptions in service; that the more appropriate

solution to potential power shortages in the future is to adopt

33
more cost-based rates;17 and that the Stipulation was agreed to by

the parties for political reasons. None of these assertions is

supported in the record here. In their testimony, the parties

supported the Stipulation as being in the public interest for

reasons directly related to the cost and reliability of service

on Public Services system. We find those reasons to be

credible.

.1 We further note that some of the factual

assertions in the dissent (e.g. objections to the cost

effectiveness of DSM) are misdirected inasmuch as the Stipulation

does not even call for approval of specific DSM programs at this

time. The Stipulation simply establishes the principles to guide

future selection of specific programs. The time for objecting to

specific DSM programs on the grounds that those measures are not

cost effective is when rate recovery is sought.

.2 The dissent advances other legal arguments that

are plainly and clearly wrong. Specifically, the dissenting

opinion claims that any DSM-related rate constitutes a tax,

citing Thrifty Rent-a-Car v. Denver, 833 P.2d 852 (Colo. App.

17
The dissent is mistaken in its assertion that current rates are not
reflective of system peaking costs. The electric rates for the Company were
approved by the Commission and were based, in part, upon the average and
excess demand cost allocation method. This method does reflect the costs of
serving various customer classes at the time of system peak. There is nothing
in this record that indicates that the solution to the growth in demand for
electricity is simple modification of the electric rate design. Given the
growth in demand on Public Services system, it would be reckless for the
Commission to reject the Stipulation, in part, in the unsupported and
unexamined hope that future adjustments to rates will decrease future demand
for electricity at times of system peak.

34
1992). However, the Thrifty case (page 855) itself points out

that a tax provides revenues to defray general expenses of

government. No DSM revenues will be used for this purpose.

Rather, the DSM rates entailed in the Stipulation (and, for that

matter, in past DSM programs approved by the Commission) are

strictly related to the provision of utility service provided by

Public Service, a private entity. Approval of DSM rates is a

public utility ratemaking function, not imposition of a tax.

.3 The dissenting opinion also suggests that the

Stipulation violates the anti-donation clause of the State

Constitution, Article XI, 2. That clause prohibits grants or

donations from State and local governments to private

corporations. In re Interrogatory Propounded by Governor Roy

Romer on House Bill 91S-10005, 814 P.2d 875 (Colo. 1991). As

explained above, however, public utility rates that recover DSM-

related costs do not involve a donation of public monies to

private entities. On its face, Article XI, 2 is inapplicable

here.

5. Conclusion

As we stated above, DSM is a well-established regulatory

practice. The arguments directed against DSM by the dissent are

not new, and have been rejected by various courts in the past.

Ford Motor Company v. Michigan Public Service Commission, 562

N.W.2d 224, 233-234 (Mich. App. 1997) (DSM surcharge applicable

35
to all customers, including non-participants in DSM programs, was

legal; setting rates to recover DSM costs is traditional public

utility ratemaking function); Multiple Intervenors v. Public

Service Commission, 569 N.Y.S. 2d 522, at 524 (N.Y. App. 1991)

(DSM is valid energy conservation measure, not social

policymaking; setting rates to recover DSM costs is ratemaking

function of state commission). We reject all assertions that DSM

is illegal.

F. CONCLUSION

For the foregoing reasons, we find the Stipulation to be in

the public interest. As such, we approve the Stipulation. Our

approval of the Stipulation makes moot the Motion to Amend

Settlement Agreement filed by the Company on March 14, 2000 in

Docket No. 97A-297E. See paragraph E, page 4 of the Stipulation.

An appropriate order will issue in Docket No. 97A-297E.

G. ORDER

1. The Commission Order That:

.1 The demand side management and renewables segments

of Public Service Company of Colorados 1999 Integrated Resource

Plan are approved consistent with the above discussion.

.2 The Stipulation and Settlement Agreement on

Demand-Side Management submitted by the parties on May 17, 2000

is approved.

36
.3 The 20-day period provided for in 40-6-114(1),

C.R.S., within which to file applications for rehearing,

reargument, or reconsideration begins of the first day following

the Mailed Date of this Decision.

.4 This Order is effective on its Mailed Date.

2. ADOPTED IN COMMISSIONERS DELIBERATIONS MEETING


July 13, 2000.

37
THE PUBLIC UTILITIES COMMISSION
OF THE STATE OF COLORADO

________________________________

________________________________

________________________________

Commissioners

CHAIRMAN RAYMOND L. GIFFORD


CONCURRING, IN PART,
AND DISSENTING, IN PART.

COMMISSIONER ROBERT J. HIX


CONCURRING, IN PART,
AND DISSENTING, IN PART.

H. CHAIRMAN RAYMOND L. GIFFORD CONCURRING, IN PART, AND


DISSENTING, IN PART:

1. Introduction

The Demand Side Management (DSM) Stipulation approved

by the Commission combines an illegal tax with a $75 million

corporate welfare program. DSM is not authorized by Colorado

law. DSM constitutes an illegal preference that is forbidden by

statute. Moreover, the parties agreed to the DSM Stipulation not

because they believe in it, but rather out of fear. The record

illustrates that DSM is wasteful, always falls short of

38
expectations, and imposes costs upon the body of ratepayers as a

whole to benefit a few, usually large commercial and industrial,

customers. DSM should have been rejected, and other alternatives

explored.

2. DSM Lacks Statutory Authorization

a. Background

The first question the Commission must answer

before approving this Stipulation is where it derives authority

to approve a utility-sponsored DSM program. The majoritys

syllogism is simple: The Commission has broad discretion in

ratemaking. DSM involves ratemaking. Therefore, DSM is a lawful

exercise of our ratemaking authority. Both the major and minor

premise of this argument are false.18

b. Ratemaking

.a A first sign of the Commission going beyond

its statutory bounds is the invocation of the Commissions

broad legal authority under article XXV of the Colorado

Constitution. Colo. Const. Art. XXV. The Commissions legal

authority is equal to that of the legislature before enactment of

article XXV, except where it is defined or limited by statute.


18
The majoritys epithets of my disappoint[ing] [ V.], incorrect
[V(B)(2)], narrow[], formalistic[], [ V(C)(4)], overly simplistic and
narrow, [ V(C)(6)] and plainly and clearly wrong, [ V(D)(3)] analysis fail
to convince me of the apparent manifest stupidity of my position.
Fortunately, the majoritys rhetorical vehemence is meant to obscure its
pallid analysis. Near as I can tell, the majoritys position boils down to
three points: 1) everyone else is doing it, so why cant we?; 2) this is
reasonable despite any statutory limits on our authority; and, 3) a
preference is not a preference if we say it is not a preference.

39
See, Colorado Energy Advocacy Office v. Public Service Co. of CO,

704 P.2d 298, 306 (Colo. 1985) (citing Miller Bros., Inc. v.

Public Utilities Commission, 525 P.2d 443, 451 (Colo. 1974); OCC

v. Mountain States Telephone and Telegraph, 816 P.2d 278 (Colo.

1991); City of Montrose v. Public Utilities Commission, 629 P.2d

619, 622 (Colo. 1981). The Commissions broad legal authority

with regard to rate making has been given based on the idea that

rate making is at best an inexact science. See, City of

Montrose v. PUC, 629 P.2d 619, 622 (Colo. 1981). This plenary

legislative authority over ratemaking is not carte blanche for

the Commission to do what it wants, and then call it ratemaking,

however.

.b A signal that DSM is not a slam dunk comes

from the Colorado Supreme Court. The Court has noted that:

[t]he Demand Side Management Program was approved by the Public

Utilities Commission after extensive hearings, but its legality

has never been addressed by a court of law. Office of Consumer

Counsel v. Public Service Co. of Colorado, 877 P.2d 867, 874 n.10

(Colo. 1994). While this statement makes no conclusions about

the legality of DSM, it is also rare for a court gratuitously to

note that the legality of a program has not been decided. It

suggests, at least, that the court wondered about DSMs legality.

.c Taking up the courts invitation, it is

incumbent on the Commission to justify DSMs legality. Though

40
the Commission has approved DSM programs for over ten years,

efforts to ground them in statute have been scant, or worse yet,

unconvincing.

.d Ratemaking involves the . . .right of

consumers to pay a rate which reflects the cost of service

rendered. See, Public Service Co. v. PUC 644 P.2d 933, 939

(Colo. 1982); accord Cottrell v. City and County of Denver, 636

P.2d 703 (Colo. 1981) (purpose of utility regulation is to insure

that rates are not excessive . . .). A utility rate must

represent the actual cost for providing the service to the

consumer. Public Service Co., 644 P.2d at 939. Under the DSM

stipulation, consumers pay more than the actual cost of service.

The DSMCA-rider has no relation to the cost of service; rather it

operates solely as a transfer payment from the body of ratepayers

to DSM program beneficiaries. Therefore, the Commission violates

state law by authorizing a rate which is unrelated to the actual

cost of service. Id. Furthermore, it has long been a part of

Colorado law that extra utilities services provided to a few

customers can not be paid for by averaging the cost over all of

the customers. Consumers League of Colorado v. Colorado &

Southern Railway, 172 P. 1064, 1066 (Colo. 1918). As far back as

1918, the Colorado Supreme Court stated:

In fixing a rate, neither the carrier nor the Commission has the
right to consider any extra terminal services, that is to say
terminal services which do not appertain to the traffic as a

41
whole, but which are to be rendered in connection with certain
parts of the traffic only . . . . The Public Utility Commission
has the power to fix rates for service performed, or to be
performed, but it has no power to fix a charge for a service not
to be rendered.

Id. at 1066. The Consumers League case represents the

foundation of the Commissions authority and still represents the

law in Colorado. Therefore, to the extent that the DSM

stipulation results in a rate in which ratepayers pay more than

the actual cost of what they receive, the Commission is not

legally authorized to accept the DSM stipulation. 19

.e Indeed, the money collected through the DSMCA

has nothing to do with a rate. DSM money is not spent on

providing any resources or services for the ratepayer. It is a

transfer payment from one ratepayer to another. There is no

relation to the cost of service or the value of service. The

bottom line is that DSM programs are simply not part of the

Commissions ratemaking duties, or authority.

.f Past Commission attempts to justify DSMs

legality reinforce the point that there is scant statutory

authorization for the program. Decision No. C90-1551 accepted

the first DSM settlement stipulation in Colorado.

See The Application of Public Service Company of Colorado to

19
The Commission recently cited Public Service Co., supra, as limiting
our ability to approve a competitive rate scheme without looking to the cost
of service. See In the Matter of the Petition of Totem Gas Storage LLC For A
Declaratory Order, Decision No. C99-1376, 7, Docket No. 99D-415G (Dec. 20,
1999).

42
Place into Effect a Demand Side Management Clause Cost Adjustment

Clause, Docket No. 90A-147E, (December 7, 1990). Neither the

Commissions order nor the Stipulation and Settlement Agreement

discuss the statutory authority for DSM. Subsequent DSM-related

dockets continued this tradition of silent acceptance of DSMs

legal premises. See, Re: Investigation and Suspension of Tariff

Sheets Filed by the Public Service Company of Colorado with

Advice Letter No. 453-Gas and Advice Letter No. 1133-Electric,

Decision No. 91-918, Docket Nos. 91S-091EG, 90F-226E (July 17,

1991)(authorizing DSM collaborative process).

.g A never-adopted policy statement citing the

broad authority of the article XXV and 40-3-101, 102 and 111,

C.R.S., is the only attempt to ground DSM in law. See Dec. No.

C90-1641, Dkt. No. 90I-227EG. None of these statutory provisions

expressly authorizes the Commission to create a

43
preferential rate structure to fund DSM programs.20 At best,

40-3-111, C.R.S., states that the Commission may consider

. . .any factors which encourage energy conservation in setting

rates, and 40-3-102 states that the Commission has a

. . .duty . . .to do all things, . . .which are necessary or

convenient in the exercise of . . .[its power] . . . Neither of

these provisions authorize ratemaking unrelated to the cost of

service, much less preferential rates.

.h Under the policy statement and the majoritys

construction, it is difficult to discern a limiting principle

that would not bring the entire redistributive power of the state

of Colorado within the ambit of the Commissions ratemaking

authority. So long as the Commission attaches a rate-rider to a

utility bill, it would seem, what happens to the money from then-

on is wholly within our ratemaking discretion. The Commissions

construction unmoors ratemaking from its basis in cost of

20
The majority seems to think that if they repeatedly say 40-3-111(1) and
40-6-111(2)(a), C.R.S., expressly authorize utility-sponsored DSM, then it
will be so. See pp. 21, 27. Express authority means:
Confer[ring] power to do a particular identical thing set forth and declared exactly,
plainly, and directly with well-defined limits. An authority given in direct terms,
definitely and explicitly, and not left to inference or implication,
Blacks Law Dictionary 521 (5th Ed. 1979). Sections 40-3-111(1) and 40-6-
111(2)(a) C.R.S., confer no such express authority. Allowing the Commission
to consider factors which influence adequate energy supply and encourage
energy conservation may allow the Commission to infer, imply, interpolate, or
find DSM authority emanating from a penumbra of these sections, but surely
this is not express authority. To my overly simplistic and narrow way of
thinking, express authority from the legislature would read something on the
order of: The Commission is authorized to implement utility-sponsored demand
side management programs.

44
service.21 This makes the term ratemaking meaningless, and sets

the Commission on a course to act like a general utility taxing

authority.22 None of this is contemplated in statute.

3. The DSM Stipulation Violates 40-3-106(1)(a),


C.R.S.

.1 DSM constitutes an illegal intra-rate class

preference and unreasonable inter-rate class difference. Such

preferences and unreasonable differences are forbidden by 40-3-

106(1)(a), C.R.S., which prohibits both intra- and inter-rate

class discrimination:

[N]o public utility, as to rates, charges, service or facilities,


or in any other respect, shall make or grant any preference or
advantage to any corporation or person or subject any corporation
or person to any prejudice or disadvantage. No public utility
shall establish or maintain any unreasonable difference as to
rates, charges service, facilities or, in any respect, either
between localities or as between any class of service.

The first sentence absolutely prohibits granting any preference

within a rate class. The second sentence prohibits unreasonable

differences between classes of service.23 DSM undeniably results

21
Using cost of service as the lodestar for ratemaking does not forbid
rate averaging. It is inherent in the notion of classes of service that costs
of service be averaged. However, Colorado law sets up a formalized structure
for when rates can be averaged and differentiated. Different classes of
service are allowed based on commonality of cost of service, value of service
and demand elasticity. The respective classes, according to 106(1)(a),
cannot be based on unreasonable differences. Once the class is set, however,
no discrimination within the class is allowed.
22
Though the state never formally touches the money, the DSM and the
funds derived from it are indistinguishable from a tax. See Thrifty Rent-a-
Car v. Denver, 833 P.2d 852, 855 (Colo. App. 1992). Instead of a fee, which
would go to a particular purpose, the DSMCA money is transferred to a variety
of yet-to-be-named program beneficiaries.
23
It is notable that any discrimination within a class of service is
forbidden; whereas unreasonable discrimination between classes of service is

45
in prohibited preferences within a rate class. It likewise

causes unreasonable differences between rate classes because, to

even begin to succeed, DSM must be heavily weighted toward

industrial and large commercial customers.

.2 DSM programs are funded through a rate-rider paid

by all ratepayers. The resulting pool of money from this rate-

rider is then apportioned out to benefit a deserving subset of

ratepayers. This results in both intra- and inter-rate class

preferences. The beneficiaries of DSM are typically large,

consumers, which are given money to change energy consumption, or

capital improvements to reduce energy consumption (a two-fold

benefit, the improvements themselves and the reduced future

energy costs). Therefore, the DSM rate is clearly preferential;

everyone pays the same amount while some benefit and others do

forbidden. The latter standard gives the Commission some discretion factually
to justify differences; the former does not.

46
not (or at least far less so). 24 The stipulation favors those

ratepayers that are participants in DSM projects at the expense

of those who can not or do not participate.25

.3 Section 40-3-106(1)(a), C.R.S., prohibits granting

any preference in rates, charges, service, facilities, or in any

other respect. Thus, even if the majority is correct and DSM is

ratemaking, it is still prohibited because it is

24
The DSM rate preference goes beyond the averaging that is
traditionally involved in utility rate design. Price-averaging as reflected
in the existence of different rate classes evolves from both cost of service
and value of service considerations. The averaging at the rate class level
should end where the expense of further definition of the exact costs of
providing a service or product outweighs the benefits of accurate pricing.
Price averaging occurs in competitive markets, i.e., ten cents per minute long
distance calling plans, and the Commission is justified in price-averaging to
the extent the Commission simulates competitive market pressures. The DSM
rate-rider is neither a part of the cost of providing utilities service; nor
does DSM have any relation to value of service. It is simply in a direct,
quantifiable and substantial benefit to some ratepayers at the expense of
others. Therefore, the DSM rate-rider is not simply a part of rate design
averaging of costs.
25
Proponents of the DSM stipulation may argue that all ratepayers do in
fact have the opportunity to participate. This is simply not true. First,
the DSM stipulation is capped at $75 million, meaning that there is a set
limit on the number of participants. Furthermore, DSM is premised on the
concept of a larger group paying for energy efficiency of a smaller group. If
everyone could or did participate in DSM programs (in effect equaling the
economic incentives of accurate pricing signals), DSM would simply collapse
for lack of funding. In addition, some ratepayers may have already taken
energy conservation measures or are not consumers of excess energy in the
first place. These ratepayers are simply not candidates for participation in
DSM programs (i.e. if an individual does not own an air conditioner they can
not be paid to turn it off), and will be victims of their own foresight. The
parties to the DSM stipulation appear to recognize this situation, however,
they apparently fail to understand its implications.

47
preferential. 26
To the extent DSM programs confer special

service, facilities and in other respects preference some

customers within a rate class over others, it is prohibited by

this statute. Furthermore, there is no other statutory authority

that overrides this blanket ban on preferences to allow this DSM

Stipulation. See, C.J.S. 73 B Public Utilities 43, pg. 253

(It is as improper to discriminate in favor of a municipality,

or a benevolent, religious, or eleemosynary institution, as in

favor of any other customer of a utility, unless the statute

expressly provides therefor. (emphasis added). The lack of

statutory authorization for a preferential rate for DSM can be

contrasted with 40-15-208, C.R.S., which created the high cost

support mechanism (HCSM) for telephone service. Section 40-15-

208, C.R.S., expressly authorizes the Commission to create

preferential rates and charges to subsidize telephone service in

26
The majority ignores the dictum generalia specialibus non derogant.
See Ex parte Crow Dog, 109 U.S. 556, 570 , 571 S., 3 S.Ct. 396, 405 (1883).
It is an interpretive canon so time-honored that it is in latin, and, what is
more, is codified at 2-4-205, C.R.S.:
If a general provision conflicts with a special or local provision, it shall be
construed, if possible, so that effect is given to both. If the conflict between the
provisions is irreconcilable, the special or local provision prevails as an exception
to the general provision, unless the general provision is the later adoption and the
manifest intent is that the general provision prevail.

Here, the Commissions plenary legislative authority over ratemaking is


limited by the more specific provision of 40-3-106(1)(a), C.R.S. Thus,
proper statutory interpretation would read even our plenary ratemaking
authority to be limited by the more specific statute forbidding any intraclass
preference or advantage. The majoritys reading inverts the traditional canon
and has the Commissions energy conservation and supply adequacy considering
authority override the specific, clear prohibition on preferences and
advantages in 40-3-106(1)(a), C.R.S.

48
high cost areas.27 Section 40-15-208 C.R.S. The resulting

subsidy from the HCSM rate element is used to reduce the price of

basic telephone service below the actual costs. Id. The direct

authorization to create a preferential rate in one situation but

not in another, further evidences the lack of legislative intent

to give the Commission the legal authority to authorize DSM.28

.4 Contrast also Colorados flat out prohibition of

any preference or advantage or prejudice or disadvantage to

other states, whose legislatures have adopted different

standards:

No [public utility] shall make or grant any undue preference or


advantage to any person, corporation or locality or any
particular description of service in any respect whatsoever, or
subject any particular person, corporation or locality or any
particular description of service to any undue or unreasonable
prejudice or disadvantage in any respect whatsoever.

N.Y. Pub. Serv. Law Art. 4 65(3) (Consol. 1999).

(c) An electric utility may not:

27
Section 40-15-208, C.R.S.: The commission is hereby authorized to
establish a mechanism for the support of universal service. The purpose of
the high cost support mechanisms is to provide financial assistance to local
exchange providers to help make basic local exchange service affordable.
28
In addition, the current DSM stipulation violates at least the plain
language of several other provisions of Colorado state law. For example, 2,
Article XI of the Colorado Constitution states: Neither the stateshall make
any donation or grant to, or in aid of,any corporation or company (emphasis
added). This section of the constitution was intended to prohibit all public
aid to railroad companies no matter what might be the public benefit
Colorado Cent. R.R. v. Lea, 5 Colo. 192 (1879). While subsequent cases have
brought into question the exact nature of 2 of Article XI, at least on its
face DSM would be in violation of such a provision. See, In re Interrogatory
Propounded by Governor Roy Romer on House Bill 91S-1005, 814 P.2d 875, 882
(Colo. 1991). Finally, the Taxpayers Bill of Rights, Art. X, 20 states
that all new taxes must be approved through a popular vote of the people.
Again, to the extent that DSM represents a tax, see Thrify Rent-a-Car, supra,
it would also violate Art. X, 20.

49
(1) grant an unreasonable preference or advantage concerning
rates to a person in a classification;

(2) subject a person in a classification to an unreasonable


prejudice or disadvantage concerning rates; or

(3) establish or maintain an unreasonable difference concerning


rates between localities or between classes of service.

Tex. Util. Code Ann. 36.003. The New York and Texas statutes

represent a different standard than applies in Colorado.

Substituting the word undue or unreasonable for any makes

all the difference in the world. Those states commissions

possess the discretion to determine whether intra-class

discrimination is due or not, reasonable or not. The Colorado

legislature by its choice of the word "any" did not give this

Commission that same discretion. See also, for example, Utah

Code Ann. 54-3-8; Idaho Code 61-315 (identical to Colorados

language).

2. Case Law: Mountain States Legal Foundation v. PUC

.a To the extent there remain any doubts about

the illegality of DSM, the Colorado Supreme Court dispels them in

Mountain States Legal Foundation v. Public Utilities Commission

of the State of Colorado, 590 P.2d 495 (Colo. 1979). There, the

Court construed 40-3-106(1)(a) and held that the Commissions

authorization of a preferential rate without direct statutory

authorization was illegal. In Mountain States Legal Foundation,

the court overturned the Commissions effort to set up a

preferential utility rate in order to benefit low-income elderly

50
and low-income disabled customers. Id. at 497. The court

states:

It is clear in the case before us that the PUCs authority to


order preferential utility rates to effect social policy has, in
fact, been restricted by the legislatures enactment of section
40-3-106(1), C.R.S. 1973 and section 40-3-102, C.R.S. 1973.

Id. at 497. The court went on to state:

When the PUC ordered the utility companies to provide a lower


rate to selected customers unrelated to the cost or type of the
service provided, it violated section 40-3-106(1)s prohibition
against preferential rates. In this instance, the discount rate
benefits an unquestionably deserving group . . . . This
unfortunately, does not make the rate less preferential . . . .
The legislature clearly provided against such discretionary power
when it prohibited public utilities from granting any
preference.(emphasis added)

Id. at 498. The courts direct reference to any preference

provides a clear statement of the 106(1)(a)'s proper

construction. The Commission violates that law by authorizing

the DSM stipulation, which creates preferential rates,

preferential services and preferential facilities.

.b The DSM Stipulation is not distinguishable

from the Mountain States Legal Foundation. First, the reasoning

behind Mountain States Legal Foundation case is simple: the

Commission can not create preferences unless directly authorized

by statute. Id. A lower rate for low-income elderly and

handicap customers is preferential in that all ratepayers pay for

the benefit of a few ratepayers. An energy consumption reduction

incentive or capital improvement to a specific ratepayer is

51
preferential in exactly the same manner, everyone pays for the

greater benefit of a few. Mountain States Legal Foundation

underscores the flat out prohibition on intra-class

discrimination in 40-3-106(1)(a), C.R.S.29 Furthermore, DSM

constitutes social policy just as a preference for low income

elderly or disabled does. DSM represents an attempt to provide

overall benefit to the utilities system as a whole. In addition,

DSM is a conscious decision to consider the demand side of the

utilities regulation equation in addition to the supply side.

Such consideration is not necessary for utilities regulation.

The consideration of DSM is influenced by various concerns, i.e.

the environment, international politics, etc., rather than the

simple competitive market pressures simulation of fundamental

utilities regulation, making DSM a social policy. 30

29
Residential class customers are projected to receive approximately
20% of the DSM funds (although, historically Residential customers have
received less than 10% of DSM funds) while Commercial and Industrial class
customers will receive the remaining 80%, resulting in inter- class
discrimination. Furthermore, not all members of any of the three customer
classes will be able to participate in the DSM programs resulting in intra-
class discrimination, i.e. some residents will benefit by participation while
other residents will not.
30
The Commissions never-adopted policy statement in Decision No.
C90-1641, Docket No. 90I-227EG stated:
We will hereafter consider at least the following influences and considerations in
setting and implementing our regulatory objectives:
a. An inter-dependent, but competitive global economy with increasing income
disparities within and among nations;
b. A physical environment at risk;
c. An opportunity for society to reduce present and future risk and discontinuities
by pursuing diversity of energy supply sources, developing renewable energy resources,
and investing in efficiency; and
d. A regulatory process among the Commission, Colorado utilities, the legislature,
and Colorado consumers, which integrates the strengths of democracy, free markets, and
technology towards a sustainable society.

52
.c Proponents of DSM may argue that DSM provides

benefits to all ratepayers and, therefore, is not preferential.

The argument is that the energy savings across the entire energy

system results in benefits for all ratepayers, i.e. avoided costs

of supply side resources. This argument does not hold up for

three reasons.

.d First, regardless of the potential overall

cost benefit analysis to the general ratepayer, some consumers

still receive disproportionately large benefits. In the

Mountain States Legal Foundation opinion the court did not even

Dec. No. C90-1641, Dec. 5, 1990, pg. 5. This statement clearly indicates that
DSM is in fact a social policy. In addition, the statement illustrates that
DSM is a broad expansion of the Commissions duties and authority beyond the
traditional scope of utilities regulation.

53
consider whether the preferential rate would be cost effective. 31

Mountain States Legal Foundation, supra. Even if everyone

benefits, some will receive much larger benefits and therefore

the stipulation creates an illegal preference. 32

.e Second, there is reason to question the

economic tests that suggest the overall benefits of DSM. The DSM

stipulation relies on the Total Resource Cost (TRC) test to

determine DSM program cost effectiveness. However, the TRC test

disregards the costs incurred by the general ratepayer.33 Under

the TRC test, DSM can go forward even if the outcome in not

31
Actually the court in Mountain States Legal Foundation does state
that the low income elderly and disabled are an unquestionably deserving
group which suggests recognition of the idea that all rate payers would in
some way benefit from the preference. However, the court nonetheless flat out
rejected the preferential rate. Mountain States Legal Foundation, 590 P.2d 495
32
The Commissions sophisticated--as opposed to my overly simplistic
and narrow--construction of 40-3-106(1), C.R.S., is a tad opaque, but I will
try to respond to this novel hermeneutic technique. The majority begins with
the unobjectionable proposition that the Commission must define the term
preference as used in 40-3-106(1)(a). Orthodox statutory interpretation
and Colorado law, 2-4-101, C.R.S., would have the Commission construe the
term according to its familiar and accepted meaning. Preference means the
granting of precedence or advantage to one over others. American Heritage
Dictionary 976 (2d Ed. 1982). Advantage means a relatively favorable
position. Id. at 81. I conclude that taxing all members within a rate class
and then disbursing those rents to specific members of that same rate class
gives precedence to and a relatively favorable position to the recipients of
DSM funds as opposed to the rest of the rate class. By contrast, the majority
reads 40-3-106(1)(a) as a legislative invitation to decide what constitutes
a preference based on given factual circumstances, and if the intraclass
differences are reasonable, then the Commission may allow them. In other
words, 40-3-106(1)(a) only prohibits unreasonable intraclass differences.
The majority arrives at this construction notwithstanding that the very next
sentence of 403106(1)(a), C.R.S., explicitly says just that: no
unreasonable differenceas between any class of service. Therefore,
according to the majority, the legislature meant the very same thing as to
intraclass and interclass preferences. This is truly a Through the Looking
Glass moment that, were in not so hackneyed, would warrant full quotation of
Humpty Dumptys word game. The majoritys position boils down to this: an
intraclass preference is not a preference if we say it is not a preference.
Mr. Dumpty could not have said it better. See Lewis Carroll, Through the
Looking Glass, Ch. VI.

54
Pareto-optimal for all ratepayers. The Rate Payer Impact Measure

(RIM) test, on the other hand takes into account the increased

rates and costs to the general rate payer. 34 While the TRC test

projects an overall cost effectiveness to DSM programs, the same

programs largely fail under the RIM test.

.f To make matters worse, DSM programs are

generally more effective when directed at the Commercial and

Industrial (C & I) classes of customers (they are larger and more

concentrated users of energy). As a result, DSM packages

33
Total Resource Cost Test (TRC): This test examines the program
benefits and costs from Public Services and Public Service customers
perspectives. On the benefit side, it includes reduction in generation costs
as well as non-energy and tax benefits. On the cost side, it includes costs
incurred by both Public Service and the participants. Public Service Company
of Colorado Economic Analysis of DSM Measures, June 15, 2000, pg. 2.
34
Ratepayer Impact Test (RIM): All ratepayers (participants and non-
participants) may experience an increase in rates to recover lost revenue.
This test includes all Public Service program costs as well as lost revenues.
On the benefits side, this test includes all avoided energy and capacity
costs. Public Service Company of Colorado Economic Analysis of DSM Measures,
June 15, 2000, pg. 2. Even if Mountain States Legal Foundation permitted
discrimination under 106(1)(a) if the preference met some overall
cost/benefit analysis test, the RIM test would be the only permissible
measure. Notably, none of the tests in this DSM Stipulation meet the RIM
test.

55
are generally weighted in favor of these customers.35 Public

Service testified that of the $75 million proposed DSM package

80% of it would be targeted to the C& I classes of customers.

However, the stipulation itself does not contain such a

stipulation. Historically, residential DSM programs have

accounted for only 7% of all DSM programs. Given Public

Services incentive to make the DSM programs as cost effective as

possible they will have every incentive to limit the residential

DSM programs. In other words, there is no guarantee that the

residential ratepayer will get even as little as 20% of the total

DSM package that is cost effective per the RIM test. Therefore,

DSM expenditures on the whole are even lest cost effective to the

general rate payer because the majority of the money is spent on

DSM programs for the C & I classes of customers where the RIM

test has its lowest scores. For example, how one defines cost

effectiveness plays a part in the economic analysis. The tests

assume a cost-effective level of 1.00, which simply translates to

a return of anything

35
Contrary to the majoritys triumphalism over CF&I Steel, L.P. v.
Public Utilities Commission, 949 P.2d 577 (Colo. 1997), it proves my point as
to the formalism required before Colorado law permits rate discrimination.
The Commission can, in my view, create different rate classes based on
reasoned distinctions, including consideration of the cost of service and
value of service. Once those classes are set, however, 40-3-106(1)(a),
C.R.S., prohibits any preference of advantage or prejudice or disadvantage
within the class. As to my position that DSM creates unreasonable interclass
rate differences, I recognize that reasonable people may disagree over this.
Colorado law permits the Commissions reasoned discretion on interclass rate
differences.

56
more than $1 per $1 spent. However, in real life a $1.01 return

on a $1.00 investment would not be considered cost effective by

many people.

.g Furthermore, economic analysis has inherent

problems. All of the DSM cost benefit tests involve basic

assumptions, i.e. inflation rate, reserve margins, demand

charges, etc. each of which represents a potential for error. In

addition, the number of factors which affect the cost-

effectiveness of a particular action are potentially infinite, no

single test can take into account each and every possible factor.

Furthermore, quantifying many of the factors involved in these

particular tests is difficult at best. In fact, actual Benefit-

Cost Ratio scores for DSM programs are historically lower than

projected by economic analysis. See, Haines DSM hearing

testimony. Therefore, the actual cost effectiveness of DSM is

chronically dubious.

.h Third, much of the theoretical cost

effectiveness of DSM programs relies on the subsequent reduction

of supply-side requirements. However, the present stipulation

has no direct supply-side savings. The best that could come from

the present DSM stipulation is a possible reduction in

57
future supply-side needs.36 And even this is doubtful. DSM is

premised on giving corporations and persons grants and transfer

payments to reduce their energy load. But this assumption is

static, and fails to account for probable behavior of consumers

receiving this windfall. As a residential consumer, if you give

me money to upgrade my air conditioning, then I can take my

savings and, say, buy a computer. As a commercial customer, I

can take my DSM savings and expand my business in other energy-

using ways. The pre-Stipulation testimony in this docket from

Public Service and Staff made the point that DSM always fails to

deliver the benefits it promises.. The demand side reductions

are always more costly than anticipated or smaller than expected.

By increasing this program from $10 million failure to a possible

$75 million, the Commission meets Einsteins definition of

insanity: doing the same thing over and over and expecting

different results.

a. The DSM Stipulation is Necessary to Avoid


Interruptions in Service

.a DSM proponents could argue that the

Commission has the legal authority to authorize DSM from the duty

to ensure uninterrupted utilities service. See, Consolidated

Freightways Corp. v. PUC, 406 P.2d 83 (Colo. 1965) (Commission

36
The failure to have any corresponding offset to the IRP demand
forecast, see Docket C00-007E, undercuts both the integrity of that decision
and the necessity for this seven-fold increase in DSM. Either the Commission
does not believe its own demand forecast, or it is willing to needlessly
invest $75 million in unnecessary DSM.

58
has duty to prevent ratemaking which could result in non-

availability of the service to the public). The DSM testimony

suggests that Public Service faces challenges in meeting the

increasing demand for energy. The DSM Stipulation, it could be

argued, is designed to mitigate those challenges and thus prevent

any potential interruptions in service.

.b However, such an argument has several

problems. First, the Commission still lacks express authority to

create a preferential rates, services and facilities. Other

solutions to the potential problems facing exist for which the

Commission does have the statutory authority to implement, i.e.

accurate pricing.

.c Furthermore, the Commission has already

agreed to the supply side and demand-side calculations that were

presented as part of the current IRP. Because the DSM

Stipulation does not result in any supply side savings,

acceptance of the stipulation would be paramount to stating that

the Commission miscalculated the previous figures by more than

124 MW.37 In addition, the DSM programs proposed in the

stipulation will not be in place until the year 2002. Any

emergency authorization from the statutes justifying a

preferential rate system is lessened by the fact that the effects

37
The IRP process already has a cushion built into it. See IRP Rules
4 CCR 723-21-5.2 Modeling for Uncertainty.

59
of the potential solution are at least two years away. Finally,

the DSM stipulation represents 124 MW of energy savings over a 3

year period, whereas Public Service anticipates a demand increase

of 1500 MW in the next five year period. Even if the DSM

programs are 100% effective, the total benefit will be somewhat

insignificant given the projected demand increases.

.d Therefore, the argument that the Commission

is legally justified in authorizing the DSM stipulation based on

implication from the statute and the emergency situation facing

Public Service is legally tenuous at best. Furthermore, the

potential impact of DSM on energy supply shortfalls is

questionable. Finally, other more effective and legally

justified solutions to the problem exist, i.e. accurate pricing.

4. The Big Picture

The Real Problem

.a DSM purports to be an interim solution to

mitigate electric supply constraints the state faces in the

coming years. Legality aside, it is a terrible solution to the

supply-side problems. As recounted in the testimony, the most

severe supply-side problems are now occurring during the summer

months when needle demand peaks occur on hot days.

Unprecedented growth in the area combined with the increasing

prevalence of air conditioning cause these peaks to strain the

system to the breaking point.

60
.b DSM purports to mitigate these peaks with

transfer payments to those users who, if the program functions

properly, contribute most to these system-straining needle peaks.

But there are other, more direct, less objectionable ways to

influence the demand side.

.c As the evidence in this docket shows, part of

the problem is that consumers have the wrong price signals. The

rates are set on a flat-rate system, averaging the overall cost

of producing that energy. With regard to the peak capacity

supply shortages, the problem is that the increased cost of

carrying the supply resources necessary to meet peak demands are

not reflected in the costs at peak demand times. For example, if

energy costs $1 per unit at low demand times and $10 per unit at

peak demand times, then the rate is averaged at something like $3

per unit at all times. As a result, during peak periods

consumers are receiving $10 worth of energy for $3 and have no

incentive to reduce their consumption. Until the market signals

are in place and individuals have economic incentives to reduce

their consumption, the problems that lead to the DSM proposal

will persist.

5. The Real Solution: Accurate Cost-Based Rates

.1 The real solution to the present problem is

simple: accurate cost-based rates. To the extent feasible, the

energy rates should reflect the actual cost of producing that

61
energy. Accurate cost-based rates would send the proper pricing

signals to the individual consumers, which would allow them to

make their own decisions as to consumption. The energy that

costs $10 per unit at peak times would cost the consumer $10,

giving the consumer the incentive to reduce consumption during

peak times.

.2 Granted, true real-time cost-based rates for all

consumers are not currently possible or feasible given the costs

involved with such tracking and other administration.38 However,

a sufficient level of cost determination and subsequent rate

adjustment is possible. For example, peak times could be defined

in terms of weeks or months instead of days or hours.

Furthermore, the different classes of customers could be dealt

with in different ways, real time metering might be feasible for

the larger and more centralized commercial and industrial classes

of customers, whereas residential customers could continue to be

metered on monthly schedules. In addition, variable rates would

require adjusting across the whole to maintain the same level of

revenue to the utility company provided by the current averaged

rate system. Given the uncertainty inherent in the rate-making

process, a workable variable rate system would at least be no

38
As discussed earlier, the cost benefit of accurate pricing will
bottom out at some point resulting in an economically efficient price average.
However, the current utilities flat rate is far from this efficient average.

62
worse than the present system.39 However, the variable rates

would provide consumers with the proper pricing signals to reduce

peak time consumption and achieve an efficient level of overall

consumption.

None of these rate structures are particularly novel, either.

Marginal cost rates and time-of-day pricing have been

experimented with since the 1960s. See, e.g., New York State

Council of Retail Merchants, Inc. v. Public Service Commission,

45 N.Y. 2d 661, 384 N.E.2d 1282 (N.Y. App. 1978); In re Madison

Gas and Electric, 5 PUR 4th 28 (Wis. 1974); Charles F. Phillips,

Jr., The Regulation of Public Utilities 3d ed. 442-465 (PUR, Inc.

1993). Seasonal rates and block rates present other alternatives

for the Commission to set price signals closer to the actual

marginal cost. Phillips, supra. Surely any of these rate design

alternative is superior to the Rube Goldberg-programs that

constitute DSM. Furthermore, attempts to make rates more closely

mirror the incremental costs of energy

39
In addition, the Commission would be legally justified in changing
the rates given its properly understood broad legal authority with regard to
rate making.

63
production serves basic equityratepayers pay for what costs they

cause; instead of pay to reduce someone elses use. Finally,

marginal cost rate design does not indulge in the fatal conceits

of central planning that plague DSM. By attempting to set rates

closer to cost, the Commission then lets consumers decide to

conform their behavior to the new price signal; in contrast, with

DSM, a central authority takes from all ratepayers, gives to

deserving ratepayers, with the hope that this transfer payment

will reduce electric load. Experience teaches that this rarely

succeeds, even with a non-Paretian cost/benefit criteria.

6. Conclusion

For these reasons I am strongly opposed to the

majoritys acceptance of the DSM stipulation. First and

foremost, the Commission does not have the legal justification to

authorize DSM programs. Furthermore, DSM is a temporary solution

that does not in fact deal with the fundamental problem, that

consumers do not have economic incentives to reduce consumption.

In addition, DSM programs are not even effective even as

temporary solutions. The real solution to the problem currently

facing the Commission is to move toward arate design that better

reflects the cost of producing peaking power. Variable rates

would provide individual consumers with the economic incentives

to maintain their consumption at economically efficient levels.

Therefore, rather than authorizing the current DSM stipulation

64
the Commission should recommend to Public Service that it study

rate design alternatives that send consumers more accurate price

signals.

7. Postlude

.1 The present DSM question seems to reach deeper

than whether or not the Commission should authorize the

stipulation agreement. A more fundamental question arises: What

role should the Public Utilities Commission play in our

government and in our society?

.2 As natural monopolies public utilities do not

have competitive market pressures to prevent the exploitation of

the general public. For example, because there was only one set

of railroad tracks the railroad was free to charge different

customers different prices. Railroad companies could play

favorites or extort money from individuals or groups of

individuals. Government exists in large part to prevent the

exploitation of members of its society.40 Therefore, the task of

regulating the public utilities fell to the legislature, which in

turn found it more efficient and rational to delegate the powers

to an administrative agency. Thus, the Public Utilities

Commission was created. The regulation of utilities was the

40
Or depending on how schooled you are in public choice theory,
government exists in large part to do the exploiting rather than leave it in
the hands of private organizations.

65
simple control of prices to reflect the cost plus a reasonable

return on investment.

.3 However, various factors, i.e., a greater

understanding of the environmental impact of energy production

and technological advances that challenge the notion that public

utilities are natural monopolies, have caused the Commission to

question its proper role in our government and society. If the

Commission remains a simple substitute for market pressures, then

the technologies and social pressures which are leading to

deregulation in every aspect of the Commissions business are

slowly phasing out the Commissions reason for existence.

.4 The proponents of IRP and DSM view the Commission

as a body which does and should have a broad authority to enact

social policy through the consideration of a broad scope of

factors in conducting every day business. However, as discussed,

the Commission does not have the legal authority to be a social

policy body.41 Furthermore, the Commission should consider more

fundamentally whether such social policy decisions properly rest

with the Commission or, given our representational democracy

system of government, with the legislature.

41
The Commission has a duty to define its legal authority based on the
laws of the state of Colorado rather than on what the Commission can get away
with based on the deference given the Commission by the courts. As
constitutional officers, we have an independent responsibility to "support the
Constitution of the United States and of the State of Colorado." Colo. Const.
Art XII, 8.

66
.5 In addition to the definition of the Commissions

role, the present DSM stipulation proceedings have taken on a

ideology vs. practicality persona. On the one hand, the

stipulation may be illegal and philosophically a poor solution;

and, on the other hand, the stipulation represents an attempt at

a short-term, practical solution to potential interruptions in

service. The tension is evidenced by the schizophrenia of the

parties involved, including Public Service, the Commission staff

and the OCC, all of which appear to have taken complete opposite

stances from the stipulation either within the present or past

DSM dockets. The DSM stipulation begins to look like a political

tool to prevent real or perceived blame if in fact service is

interrupted at some point in the future. If this is the case,

the Commission and the parties charged with representing the

general ratepayers, do a great disservice to the ratepayers by

accepting the stipulation. The citizens of Colorado do not

deserve a face-saving measure with a $75 million price tag.

THE PUBLIC UTILITIES COMMISSION


OF THE STATE OF COLORADO

__________________________________
Commissioner
.1

67
I. COMMISSIONER ROBERT J. HIX
DISSENTING, IN PART:
A.

.A I agree with the Commission in all respects except for

that portion limiting the additional wind capacity to the 35

megawatts proposed by Public Service for its WindSource program.

Several witnesses discussed the value of acquiring additional

wind capacity at this time. Greater economies will be achieved

through a larger wind program. Value is added through a more

diverse, risk-mitigating portfolio that additional renewables

provide.

.B While the voluntary nature of WindSource is attractive,

it results in benefits accruing to "free riders" and the program

is artificially constrained by Public Service's slowed

acquisition of wind capacity. Parties who supported only a

voluntary wind program ignore the value of risk mitigation and

diversity in resource acquisition. Generally, electric customers

are not given the prerogative to select different types of power

supply, and this docket is not about customer choice.

.C The focus of this decision should be on what elements

of a resource plan provide the optimum package of various types

of resource inputs. This record reflects that substantially more

wind power can be added to the resource mix at minimal impact on

68
THE PUBLIC UTILITIES COMMISSION
OF THE STATE OF COLORADO

__________________________________
Commissioner

rates. Once we internalize the benefits of reduced risk and

improved environmental quality, the obvious result is substantial

reward at little or no extra cost.

.D For these reasons I would have directed Public Service

to acquire more wind power and, for ratemaking purposes, would

treat the costs associated with that power like other generation

costs.

69

You might also like