Market Efficiency in Racetrack Betting
Market Efficiency in Racetrack Betting
Market Efficiency in Racetrack Betting
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].
The University of Chicago Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The
Journal of Business.
http://www.jstor.org
Burton G. Malkiel
Yale University
Richard E. Quandt
Princeton University
Market Efficiency in
Racetrack Betting
I. Introduction Do marketinefficien-
cies in racetrackbet-
Betting at racetracksand investing in the stock ting permitprofitable
markethave several characteristicsin common. strategiesto be devised
In neither situation are future earnings known on the basis of ob-
with certainty. Both situationsare characterized served bettingpat-
terns? Logit analysis of
by a large number of participants and by the marketdata indicates
availabilityof extensive informationand profes- that profitscannot be
sional advice. Horse racing data, therefore, per- earnedin win betting,
mit interesting tests of the efficient market althoughit is possible
theory. to outperformthe aver-
age bettor substan-
Numerousauthorshave analyzedhorse racing tially. Surpris-
data and various conclusions have been con- ingly, profitsnet of
firmed: (1) There is a systematic tendency to transactionscosts on
overbet long-shots and underbet favorites place and show betting
(Rosett 1965, 1971; Snyder 1978; and Ali 1979). appearpossible, al-
thoughthere are rea-
(2) The tendency to overbet long-shots is sons to suspect that
strongest in late races (McGlothlin1956; Asch, such opportunitiesmay
Malkiel, and Quandt 1982). (3) The utility func- not be exploitableon a
tion of bettors is convex, indicating risk love substantialscale. The
(Weitzman 1965; Asch et al. 1982). Figlewsky findingsdo not suggest
irrationalbehaviorby
(1979)tested hypotheses concerningwhetherthe bettors.
betting "market" is efficient with respect to
track odds and handicappers'picks of winning
horses. By fittinga logit model with horses' win-
loss records representingthe dependentvariable
and trackodds and handicappers'picks the inde-
pendent variables,it is shown by likelihoodratio
165
B = bh.
h= 1
h B = (1 t)/(l+Oh)
- exp(pYxij)
>3 exp(I'xkj)
k= 1
Logit Run
Variable 1 2 3 4 5
I
'C 00 en00 00 - 00 tf)
\0 or0 "^ "T
Ct t aor0I
N ^ ?o0O~
o14
I I I I I I I I I I
00 - Cl t- t0 00 C 0r
go oo -or -
mo 0D O - 'IC? 00 cq ut
ct 4-> o >m
; . E~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~.
en~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~a 0
.0
0
~~~~~~~~~~~C> VI) 11W c )
N
- -0-- - 00--0
2 0~~~~~~~~~~~~~
~~~~4a) cO~n'I n ) W) C9 I
~~~~~~~~~~~~0
CB li~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
Co0 Ro0
0..~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~.
\1 e nON ir ) eq r- W) 0
t- N1 Nt \C- 0 N -4
W~~~~~~~r oo
00 OO"'t o\0X tt
t>~~~~~~C
.L,>W)e kf
4 . ? oo en C \ oo, It 'C
4.;
eq en oo en 0\ I" "t
D o o o
ooo o o o o o o
Cd CT3
t ~~ ~~~~~~% C)t-t Z C
C3
X~~~~~~~~W W) W) C>W)o
t4
-4
%0 C) 0\ m C) en eq 43 0
4- Dd \8 It *4 t- W) ON 11
m C> C
6) a:13V C
returnsare positive. Betting the horse with the highest win probability
to place yields a higherreturnthan betting it to show. The numberof
horses on which bets are made under strategy2 with y = .5 or .6 and
under strategy 3 is sufficiently small so that one cannot place great
confidence in the resulting returnfigures. But for strategy 1, for ex-
ample, involving356 bets in each subsample,the returnto place betting
rangesfrom 0.143 to 0.176. Finally, one may note that for those strate-
gies which allow a large numberof horses to be bet on (strategy 1 and
strategy2 withy = .4), the results of run 5, which employ the morning
line and marginalodds, are slightly better.
Even simpler strategies can yield positive returns. One could, for
example, predict the winner on the basis of logit runs 1, 2, or 3, em-
ploying a single explanatoryvariable.4The results are broadlycompa-
rablebut somewhatless favorable.Thus, for example, strategy1 yields
an average returnfrom place bets (over the two subsamples)of 0.081
when the morningline alone is used to predictthe winner, 0.076 when
the final odds are used, and 0.101 when the marginalodds are em-
ployed. This still compares favorably with placing win bets on the
favorites, from which the returnis - 0.173.
We were not able to improve on the results of table 3 by employing
more sophisticatedcompound strategies.The winners and runners-up
can, for example, be predictedfrom a generalizationof the logit model
that explicitly takes into account not only which horse won, but which
horses were second and third.5These predictionshave been employed
for combinationstrategiesinvolvingwin, place, and show bets simulta-
neously.6 The most successful of these combinationstrategiesyielded
average returnsof 0.133-0.140, dependingon which explanatoryvari-
ables were used in the generalizedlogit estimation.
IV. Conclusions
The results from win betting strategies show that strategies can be
developed that exceed the returnfrom simply betting the favorite to
win. The results from using place and show bets are surprisingin the
sense that we now find that net profits can be made. Several conjec-
tures may be offered to explainthis finding.It is possible, for example,
that the tendency to overbet long shots is accentuated in place and
References
Ali, Muktar M. 1979. Some evidence of the efficiency of a speculative market.
Econometrica 47:387-92.
Asch, P.; Malkiel, Burton G.; and Quandt, RichardE. 1982. Racetrackbetting and
informedbehavior.Journal of Financial Economics 10:187-94.
Figlewsky, Stephen. 1979. Subjective informationand marketefficiency in a betting
market.Journal of Political Economy 87:75-88.
Harville, D. A. 1973. Assigningprobabilitiesto outcomes of multi-entrycompetition.
Journal of the American Statistical Association 68:312-16.
Hausch, D. B.; Ziemba, W. T.; and Rubinstein,M. 1981. Efficiencyof the marketfor
racetrackbetting. Management Science 27:1435-52.
McGlothlin,W. H. 1956. Stabilityof choices among uncertainalternatives.American
Journal of Psychology 69:604-15.
Rosett, R. N. 1965. Gamblingand rationality.Journal of Political Economy 73:595-607.
Rosett, R. N. 1971. Weak experimentalverificationof the expected utility hypothesis.
Review of Economic Studies 38:481-92.
Snyder,WayneN. 1978.Horse racing:Testingthe efficiencymarketsmodel.Journal of
Finance 22:1109-18.
Weitzman,M. 1965.Utility analysisand groupbehavior:An empiricalstudy.Journal of
Political Economy 73:18-26.