Inequality and Growth-Theory and Policy Implications-Theo S. Eicher, Stephen J. Turnovsky
Inequality and Growth-Theory and Policy Implications-Theo S. Eicher, Stephen J. Turnovsky
Inequality and Growth-Theory and Policy Implications-Theo S. Eicher, Stephen J. Turnovsky
All rights reserved. No part of this book may be reproduced in any form by any
electronic or mechanical means (including photocopying, recording, or information
storage and retrieval) without permission in writing from the publisher.
This book was set in Palatino on 3B2 by Asco Typesetters, Hong Kong, and was
printed and bound in the United States of America.
Inequality and growth : theory and policy implications / Theo S. Eicher and
Stephen J. Turnovsky, editors.
p. cm. (The CESifo seminar series ; 1)
Conference papers.
Includes bibliographical references and index.
ISBN 0-262-05069-2 (hc. : alk. paper)
1. Income distributionCongresses. 2. Economic developmentCongresses.
I. Eicher, Theo S. II. Turnovsky, Stephen J. III. CESifo (Organization). IV. Series.
HC79.I5I493 2003
339.20 2dc21 2002043162
Contents
Index 319
Series Foreword
Hans-Werner Sinn
This page intentionally left blank
Preface
well suited to predict growth and inequality in the short and long
term.
Thorvaldur Gylfason and Gyl Zoega (chapter 9) sharpen the
growing literature popularized by Sachs and Warner (1995) on
natural resources and growth. The contribution of the chapter is to
demonstrate how increased dependence on natural resources tends
to go along with less economic growth and greater inequality in
the distribution of income within countries. The apparently inverse
empirical relationship between growth and inequality may hence
not imply any causal relationship between the two. Instead, natural
resource dependence may be affecting both equality and growth.
Subsidies to education can mitigate the negative effect of natural
resources and their unequal distribution. Finally, Campbell Leith,
Chol-Won Li, and Cecilia Garca-Penalosa (chapter 10) investigate
how the impact of technical change on inequality and growth is
amplied by labor market frictions. They show that when technol-
ogy generates job destruction, relative wages rise or fall depending
on the magnitude of the labor market frictions. Such dynamics are
shown to be capable of explaining U.S./European unemployment
and relative wage differentials. Most interesting is that the authors
highlight the dilemma of policymakers. While job protection may
lower inequality and increase growth, it would hurt those workers
who are now stuck longer in structural unemployment.
The two conferences on Inequality and Growth that preceded this
volume were made possible in large part by the support of Hans-
Werner Sinn and the CESifo network. We thank him for his un-
wavering support. The quality of the conferences and papers was
assured by extensive comments from discussants including Daniele
Checchi, Rafael Domenech, Walter Fisher, Carola Grun, Raji Jayara-
man, Louise Keely, Henryk Kierzkowski, Stephan Klasen, Antonio
Garcia Pascual, Cecilia Garca-Penalosa, Maria Carme Riera Prunera,
Ray Riezman, Mathias Thoenig, Gyl Zoega, and a number of
anonymous referees. CESifo, and specically Roisin Hearn and
Frank Westermann, provided excellent and efcient administrative
support throughout, and they were ably assisted by Silke U bel-
messer and Marko Kothenburger. The Castor Endowment at the
University of Washington also supported this project, a subject in
which Cecil and Jane Castor held a lifelong interest. Financial sup-
port was also provided by the European Union Center at the Uni-
versity of Washington. We are grateful to all contributors for making
Preface xiii
References
Aghion, Philippe, Eve Caroli, and Cecilia Garca-Penalosa. 1999. Inequality and Eco-
nomic Growth: The Perspective of the New Growth Theories. Journal of Economic Lit-
erature 37(4): 16151660.
Lucas, Robert E. 1988. On the Mechanics of Economic Development. Journal of Mon-
etary Economics 22(1): 342.
Sachs, Jeffrey D., and Andrew M. Warner. 1995. Natural Resource Abundance and
Economic Growth. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper no. 5398.
This page intentionally left blank
I Measuring the Impact of
Growth on Inequality
This page intentionally left blank
1 The Growth Elasticity of
Poverty Reduction:
Explaining Heterogeneity
across Countries and
Time Periods
Francois Bourguignon
1.1 Introduction
Figure 1.1
The relationship between poverty reduction and growth in a sample of growth spells
Francois Bourguignon
The Growth Elasticity of Poverty Reduction 5
Ht Ft z: 1
For the sake of simplicity, the analysis will be momentarily restricted
to that single poverty index.
The denition of the headcount poverty index implies the fol-
lowing denition of change in poverty between two points of time,
t and t 0 :
DH Ht 0 Ht Ft 0 z Ft z:
Figure 1.2
Decomposition of change in distribution and poverty into growth and distributional effects
10 Francois Bourguignon
poverty line, that is the ratio of the absolute poverty line and the
mean income, X z= yt 0 .
Shifting to elasticity concepts, the growth elasticity of poverty may
thus be dened as
~ z ~ z z
Ft Ft F~t
yt 0 yt yt
e lim : 3
t 0 !t yt 0 yt =yt
Figure 1.3
Poverty (headcount)/growth elasticity as a function of mean income and income inequality, under the assumption of constant (lognormal)
distribution
13
14 Francois Bourguignon
GDP per capita, whereas Gini coefcients are taken from the Dein-
inger and Squire (1996) database. Growth elasticities of poverty
reduction consistent with the lognormal assumption vary between 5
for a country like Indonesia to 3 for India and the Cote dIvoire,
which were poorer and/or had a higher level of inequality. The
elasticity is around 2 for Brazil, despite the fact that it is considerably
richer than the other countries. Income inequality makes the differ-
ence. Finally, the elasticity is much below 2 in the case of Senegal
and Zambia, both of which are poor and unequal.
Figure 1.3 and the underlying lognormal approximation to the
growth elasticity of poverty in (5) refers to the headcount as the
poverty index. Similar expressions and curves may be obtained
using alternative indices. For instance, the poverty gap is a measure
of poverty obtained by multiplying the headcount by the average
relative distance at which the poor are from the poverty line. The
advantage of that measure over the headcount is obviously that it
takes into account not only the proportion of people being poor but
also the intensity of poverty. Under the lognormal assumption, it
may be shown that the growth elasticity of the poverty gap is given
by the following formula:7
Plogz=yt =s s=2
eyPG ; 4
z=yt Plogz=yt =s s=2 Plogz=yt =s s=2
s plogz=yt =s s=2
esPG ;
z=yt Plogz=yt =s s=2 Plogz=yt =s s=2
2.4586 2.2104
DGini * poverty-line/mean-income 16.3898
2.8255
DGini * initial Gini coefcient 20.3600
7.4388
Y * theoretical value of growth elasticity under 0.8727 0.9261
lognormal assumption 0.0778 0.0679
DSigma * theoretical value of poverty inequality 0.6824
elasticity under lognormal assumptionb 0.0601
R2 0.2666 0.4916 0.555 0.5857 0.6651 0.6892
a Ordinary least squares estimates, standard errors in italics. The sample includes the 114 growth spells listed in the appendix. All coefcients
17
are signicantly different from zero at the 1 percent probability level except the intercept.
b Switching from the coefcient of Gini to the standard deviation of the logarithm of income is done through the formula in note 6.
18 Francois Bourguignon
are signicantly different from zero at the 1 percent probability level except the intercept.
b Switching from the coefcient of Gini to the standard deviation of the logarithm of income is done through the formula in note 6.
The Growth Elasticity of Poverty Reduction 21
This being said, the identity that links poverty reduction, mean in-
come growth, and distributional change has several implications for
policymaking and economic analysis in the eld of poverty that are
worth stressing.
On the policy side, it was shown in this chapter that this identity
permits identifying precisely the potential contribution of growth
and distributional change to poverty reduction. However, it also
introduces a point that is often overlooked in the debate of growth
vs. redistribution as poverty reduction strategiesan exception be-
ing Ravallion (1997). To the extent that growth is sustainable in the
long run whereas there is a natural limit to redistribution, it may
reasonably be argued that an effective long-run policy of poverty
reduction should rely primarily on sustained growth. According to
the basic identity analyzed in this chapter, however, income redis-
tribution plays essentially two roles in poverty reduction. A per-
manent redistribution of income reduces poverty instantaneously
through what was identied as the distribution effect. But, in
addition it also contributes to a permanent increase in the elasticity
of poverty reduction with respect to growth and therefore to an
acceleration of poverty reduction for a given rate of economic growth.
This is quite independent of the phenomenon emphasized in the
recent growth-inequality literature according to which growth
would tend to be faster in a less inegalitarian environment.11 If this
were true, there would then be a kind of double dividend asso-
ciated with redistribution policy since it would at the same time
accelerate growth and accelerate the speed at which growth spills
over onto poverty reduction.
From the point of view of economic analysis, the basic argument
in this chapter has clear implications for the understanding of pov-
erty reduction. The common practice of trying to explain the evolu-
tion of some poverty measure over time, or across various countries,
as a function of a host of variables including economic growth has
something tautological. The preceding section has shown that the
actual growth elasticity of poverty reduction in a given country
could be estimated with considerable precision, even under the log-
normal approximation. Running a regression like the standard
model above where growth appears among the regressors would
thus make sense only in the case where one does not observe the
22 Francois Bourguignon
1.5 Appendix
The countries and growth spells used in the empirical part of this
chapter appear in the following table. Spells are dened by the initial
and terminal years.
The Growth Elasticity of Poverty Reduction 23
Table 1.A.1
Countries and spells in database
Country Spell Country Spell
Algeria 8895 Honduras 9496
Bangladesh 8485 India 8386
Bangladesh 8588 India 8687
Bangladesh 8892 India 8788
Bangladesh 9296 India 8889
Brazil 8588 India 8990
Brazil 8889 India 9092
Brazil 8993 India 9294
Brazil 9395 India 9495
Brazil 9596 India 9596
Chile 8790 India 9697
Chile 9092 Indonesia 8487
Chile 9294 Indonesia 8790
China 9293 Indonesia 9093
China 9394 Indonesia 9396
China 9495 Indonesia 9699
China 9596 Jamaica 8990
China 9697 Jamaica 9396
China 9798 Jordan 9297
Colombia 8891 Kazakhstan 9396
Colombia 9596 Kenya 9294
Costa Rica 8690 Kyrgyz Republic 9397
Costa Rica 9093 Lesotho 8693
Costa Rica 9396 Madagascar 8093
Cote DIvoire 8788 Malaysia 8487
Cote DIvoire 8893 Malaysia 8789
Cote DIvoire 9395 Malaysia 8992
Dominican Rep 8996 Malaysia 9295
Ecuador 8894 Mauritania 8893
Ecuador 9495 Mauritania 9395
Egypt 9195 Mexico 8492
El Salvador 8995 Mexico 8995
El Salvador 9596 Morocco 8590
Estonia 9395 Nepal 8595
Ethiopia 8195 Niger 9295
Ghana 8789 Nigeria 8592
Ghana 8992 Nigeria 9297
Guatemala 8789 Pakistan 8790
Honduras 8990 Pakistan 9093
Honduras 9294 Pakistan 9396
24 Francois Bourguignon
Table 1.A.1
(continued)
Country Spell Country Spell
Panama 8991 Thailand 88 (2)92
Panama 9195 Thailand 9296
Panama 9596 Thailand 9698
Panama 9697 Trinidad and Tobago 8892
Paraguay 9095 Tunisia 8590
Peru 9496 Turkey 8794
Philippines 8588 Uganda 8992
Philippines 8891 Ukraine 9596
Philippines 9194 Venezuela 8187
Philippines 9497 Venezuela 8789
Romania 9294 Venezuela 8993
Russia 9396 Venezuela 9395
Russia 9698 Venezuela 9596
Senegal 9194 Yemen? 9298
Sri Lanka 8590 Zambia 9193
Sri Lanka 9095 Zambia 9396
Thailand 8188 (1)
Notes
A preliminary version of this chapter was presented at the conference World Poverty:
A Challenge for the Private Sector, organized by the Amsterdam Institute for Interna-
tional Development, Amsterdam, October 34, 2000. The present version beneted
from comments made by participants to a seminar at CESIfo (Munich, May 2001) and
by participants to LACEA 2001 in Montevideo. I am particularly indebted to Daniele
Checchi, Gyl Zoega, and an anonymous referee. I am also indebted to Martin Rav-
allion for making the data set used in this chapter available to me. Of course, I remain
solely responsible for any remaining error. Views expressed in this chapter are those
of the author and should not be attributed to the World Bank or any afliated organi-
zation.
1. See World Bank (2000, 47).
2. For a full description of these data, see Chen and Ravallion (2000).
3. See also the presentation of that methodology in the short literature survey pro-
vided by Fields (2001).
6. In the case of a lognormal distribution, both magnitudes are related by the follow-
ing relationship (see Aitchinson and Brown 1966): G 2Ps=2 1=2 1.
7. It is also known that eyPG PG H=PG, where PG is the poverty gap.
8. Instead of considering poverty measures, it would also be interesting to consider
aggregate measures of social welfare. From that point of view, the measure W
y 1 G, where y is the mean income and G is the Gini coefcient that was origi-
nally proposed by Sen, lends itself to the same simple decomposition into growth and
distribution effects as the poverty indices considered here.
9. Of course, it would have been possible to keep these observations if the original
decomposition formula (2) with the lognormal approximation, rather than (2 0 ), had
been used in the econometric analysis that follows.
10. Expression (3 0 ) relies on the standard deviation of the logarithm of income
whereas inequality is measured by the Gini coefcient in the data set. However, a one-
to-one relationship exists between these two magnitudes when the underlying distri-
bution is lognormal (see note 5). That relationship was used to derive s from the
observed value of the Gini.
11. On this see the survey by Aghion, Caroli, and Garca-Penalosa. (1999).
References
Aghion, P., E. Caroli, and C. Garca-Penalosa. 1999. Inequality and economic growth:
The perspective of new growth theories. Journal of Economic Literature 37(4): 16151660.
Aitchison, J., and J. Brown. 1966. The Log-Normal Distribution. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Chen, S., and M. Ravallion. 2000. How did the worlds poorest fare in the 1990s?
Mimeo., The World Bank.
Datt, G., and M. Ravallion. 1992. Growth and redistribution components of changes in
poverty measures: A decomposition with application to Brazil and India in the 1980s.
Journal of Development Economics 38(2): 275295.
de Janvry, A., and E. Sadoulet. 1995. Poverty alleviation, income redistribution and
growth during adjustment. In Coping with Austerity: Poverty and Inequality in Latin
America, ed. N. Lustig. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.
de Janvry, A., and E. Sadoulet. 2000. Growth, poverty, and inequality in Latin Amer-
ica: A causal analysis, 197094. Review of Income and Wealth 46(3): 267287.
Deininger, K., and L. Squire. 1996. A new data set measuring income inequality. The
World Bank Economic Review 10: 565591.
Dollar, D., and A. Kraay. 2000. Growth is good for the poor. Mimeo., The World Bank.
Fields, G. 2001. Distribution and Development: A New Look at the Developing World.
Cambridge: The MIT Press.
Foster, J., J. Greer, and E. Thorbecke. 1984. A class of decomposable poverty measures,
Econometrica 52: 761766.
26 Francois Bourguignon
Kakwani, N. 1993. Poverty and economic growth with application to Cote dIvoire.
Review of Income and Wealth 39: 121139.
Ravallion, M. 1997. Can high-inequality developing countries escape absolute pov-
erty? Economic Letters 56: 5157.
Ravallion, M., and S. Chen. 1997. What can new survey data tell us about recent
changes in distribution and poverty? The World Bank Economic Review 11: 357382.
Ravallion M., and M. Huppi. 1991. Measuring changes in poverty: A methodological
case study of Indonesia during an adjustment period. The World Bank Economic Review
5: 5782.
World Bank. 2000. Attacking Poverty, World Development Report 2000/2001. Oxford:
Oxford University Press.
2 One Third of the Worlds
Growth and Inequality
Danny Quah
2.1 Introduction
while Barro (2000), Forbes (2000), and Li and Zou (1998) reported a
positive or varying relation. To some researchers, the situation has
seemed so bad that they have simply concluded the data are not
informative for interesting issues in inequality and growth, and have
attempted to explain why this is so, within a particular model of
inequality and growth (e.g., Banerjee and Duo 2000). In this view,
the data are noisy.
This chapter takes no explicit stance on causality between in-
equality and growth, nor on the functional form relating them.
Instead, it models inequality and growth jointly as part of a vector
stochastic process, and calibrates the impact each has on a range of
welfare indicators and on the individual income distributionsrst
within China and India, and then taking the two countries together.
The chapter addresses simpler questions than those treated in the
ambitious work attempting to trace out causality across growth and
inequality.
This chapter asks, When growth occurs, how do the poor fare?
What difference have the historical dynamics of inequality and
growth made for the incomes of one third of the worlds population?
If inequality were, indeed, to fall when growth is lower, does it fall
enough to overcome the negative impact on the poor of slower eco-
nomic growth overall? Alternatively, if within-country inequality
were to rise, does that occur simultaneously with Chinese and India
per capita incomes converging, so that overall individual income
inequality across these two economies is falling?
Given the data extant, arithmetic alone sufces to retrieve useful
answers to these questions. Here, the data are loud, not noisy: For
a universe comprising China and Indiaone-third of the world
for understanding the secular dynamics of personal incomes against
a setting of cross-country inequalities, those forces of rst-order
importance are macroeconomic ones determining national patterns
of growth and convergence. Rising average incomes dominate
everything else. Within-country inequality dynamics are insigni-
cant for determining inequality across people internationally.
Several earlier papers motivate my approach here. Deininger and
Squire (1998) addressed questions closely related to those Ive just
posed. They used regression analysis and more elaborate data, in
contrast to the minimalist, arithmetic approach of this chapter. They
concluded, though, much the same as I do below: The poor benet
more from increasing aggregate growth by a range of factors than
30 Danny Quah
(as in, e.g., gure 2.1). If that is the interest, econometric analysis can
trace out f and c.
By contrast, this chapter models E_ =E and I jointly, taking them to
be elements of equal standing in a vector stochastic process Z. Let Z0
denote the vector of other variables in the system, including popu-
lation P, so that
0 1
E_ =E
def B C
fZt : t b 0g; with Z @ I A
Z0
32 Danny Quah
Figure 2.1
Inequality and growth
Figure 2.2
Income distribution dynamics
Figure 2.3
Emerging twin peaks
China and Indiaalthough only two countries out of over one hun-
dred in gure 2.3carry within them a third of the worlds popula-
tion. They thus provide substantial insight into the dynamics in
gure 2.4.
Table 2.1 records that between 1980 and 1992 Chinas per capita
income grew from US$972 to US$1,493, an annual growth rate of
One Third of the Worlds Growth and Inequality 35
Figure 2.4
Individual income distributions
Table 2.1
Aggregate income and population dynamics: China, India, and the United States
Per capita incomes (US$) Population (10 6 )
1980 1992 E_ =E 1980 1992
3.58 percent. Over this period, India grew at a lower annual rate
of 3.12 percent, increasing its per capita income from US$882 to
US$1,282. (Per capita incomes are purchasing power parity adjusted
real GDP per capita in constant dollars at 1985 prices, series rgdpch
from Summers and Heston 1991.) For comparison, table 2.1 also
contains a row for the United States, showing its 1.33 percent an-
nual growth over 19801992, taking per U.S. capita income from
US$15,295 to US$17,945. The last two columns of table 2.1 contain
population gures, again from Summers and Heston (1991). By 1992,
China had grown to over 1.1 billion people, with India approaching
0.9 billion.
It has been remarked many times elsewhere that Chinas fast-
increasing per capita income came together with rises in inequality.
Table 2.2 shows Gini coefcients for the same three countries, China,
India, and the United States, over 19801992. Inequality in China, as
36 Danny Quah
Table 2.2
Inequality in China, India, and the United States, by Gini coefcient (from Deininger
and Squire 1996)
Gini coefcient IG
1980 1992 Min. (year)
China 0.32 0.38 0.26 (1984)
India 0.32 0.32 0.30 (1990)
US 0.35 0.38 0.35 (1982)
Table 2.3
Fraction of population and number of people with incomes less than US$2 per day.
The range of estimates spans the different distributional assumptions described in
section 2.7.4.
Y 2; HCY PY ; 10 6
1980 1992
China 0.370.54 (360530) 0.140.17 (158192)
India 0.480.62 (326426) 0.120.19 (110166)
tion, and Gini coefcients, one can, with weak additional assump-
tions on the parametric form of density f, work out how the entire
distribution of individual income shifted between 1980 and 1992.
Table 2.3 shows how the situation for the very poor changed over
this time period. The fraction of the population living on less than
US$2 per day (US$730 annually) varied from 0.37 to 0.54 in China in
1980; this corresponded to between 360 million to 530 million peo-
ple.1 By 1992, the fraction of population in that income range had
fallen to 0.14 to 0.17, implying only between 158 million to 192
million people, given the population size then. In other words,
over 19801992 China reduced the population in this very poor
income range by between 210 million to 338 million people, even as
inequality and total population rose.
The situation for India is less surprising, as measured inequality
there remained constant, and only aggregate economic growth
occurred.2 But since the total Indian population also rose, it might
well have been that the poor did increase in number. Table 2.3 shows
that did not happen. Between 1980 and 1992, the number of Indians
living on less than US$2 a day fell from 326426 million to less than
half that, 110166 million. The fraction of the Indian population in
this income range fell from approximately half to perhaps one-fth,
likely less. India reduced the population living in the very poor
income range by about a quarter of a billion, a number comparable
to the change in China.
If the world comprised only China and India put together, it
would show a number of interesting features. First, the country
that grew faster on aggregate also had inequality rise morethe
upward-sloping schedule in gure 2.1 is that that is relevant. Sec-
ond, however, even despite this positive relation between growth
and inequality, overall the worlds poor beneted dramatically from
economic growth. Over the course of little more than a decade, about
half a billion peopleout of a total population across the two coun-
tries of about 1.6 to 1.9 billionexited the state of extreme poverty.
This decline in sheer numbers of the very poor divided about equally
between China and India.
Table 2.4 takes the argument further. Suppose population were
held constant at 1980 levels in China and India. The left panel in the
table shows that if inequality too were held constant at its 1980
levels, then aggregate growth alone would have removed from being
38 Danny Quah
Table 2.4
From 1980 perspective: Given aggregate growth, reduction in numbers of poor if in-
equality unchanged, and proportional inequality increase per year to maintain poverty
numbers
2.5 Extensions
Figure 2.5
Estimated absolute poverty reduction
This fact has implications for panel data analyses of inequality and
growth (Quah 2001b). Panel data econometric methods that condi-
tion out individual effectsalmost all doend up removing all the
important variation in inequality data. Moreover, since economic
growth has its principal variation in the orthogonal directionin
time rather than across countries (e.g., Easterly et al. 1993)panel
data methods shoehorn inequality and growth data into spuriously
better t with each other. In other words, econometric methods that
condition out individual effects represent here a methodologically
suspect attempt to remove statistical biases. That justication has
often been simply imported from other elds of economics, without
due attention to why applying such techniques to study inequality
and growth might be inappropriate.
From table 2.3 one concludes that China and India together
reduced the number of people living on less than US$2 a day by
between 36 million and 50 million each year. Figure 2.5 graphs this
same reduction from 1980 to 1992 in the number of people with
incomes less than US$2 per day, given the actual historical outcomes
in income inequality and economic growth. China and India alone
shifted 508 million people, more than 12 percent of the worlds pop-
ulation, about one-third of the worlds then-poor, out of poverty.
Figure 2.6 shows, for each economy, the amount of poverty re-
duction per year that would have occurred from aggregate growth
alone, had inequality and population size remained constant at their
40 Danny Quah
Figure 2.6
Growth alone
Figure 2.7
Inequality to nullify growth
2.6 Conclusions
X
N
FW; t y P1
W; t Fj; t y Pj; t ; y 2 0; y 2
j1
X
N
PW; t Pj; t :
j1
Differentiating (2) with respect to y gives the implied density for the
worldwide distribution of income as the weighted average of indi-
vidual country income distribution densities:
X
N
f W; t y fj; t y Pj; t =PW; t ; y 2 0; y: 3
j1
44 Danny Quah
Knowing the distribution FW means one can calculate directly all the
inequality indexes one wisheswhether or not particular indexes
aggregate becomes irrelevant.
Xl; t Tl jt ; Pt ; l 1; 2; . . . ; d: 4
Without loss or ambiguity, I also write Tl Ft ; Pt to denote the right
hand side of (4). Write T to denote the vector of observed func-
tionals, that is,
TFt ; Pt T1 Ft ; Pt ; T2 Ft ; Pt ; . . . ; Td Ft ; Pt 0 :
Assume, nally, that the distribution Ft is known up to a p-
dimensional vector yt A R p ,
def
Ft F j yt Fyt : 5
(In equation (5) the symbol F is used to mean a number of different
mathematical objects, but this will be without ambiguity, as the
context will always be revealing.)
Equation (5) restricts in two distinct ways. First, the functional
form Ft is assumed known. Second, time variation in the sequence of
distributions Ft is assumed mediated entirely through the nite-
dimensional parameter vector yt .
If for some yt , distribution Fyt is the true model, then
Tl Fyt ; Pt Xl; t ; l 1; 2; . . . ; d:
W d d positive denite: 6
Each different weighting matrix Wincluding, notably, the identity
matrixproduces a different estimator. Under standard regularity
conditions (as in GMM or related analogue estimation; e.g., Hansen
1982; Manski 1988), each W-associated estimator is consistent when
46 Danny Quah
1 to 4,
def
Y0:2i F; P supf y j Fy a 0:2ig; 10
yAR
Y0:2i F; P !
def
S0:2i F y dFy EF; P1 : 11
y
and let
Y0:1i
def
E0:1i F; P y dF y; i 1; . . . ; 9;
Y0:1i1
y 13
def
E1 F; P y dFy:
Y0:9
Finally, dene
Y
def y y dF y
PGIY F; P : 16
Y
and then, using (8), (9), and (17), dene a polarization index
" Y0:5 #
def y y dF y 2
PZ F; P 1 IG E Y0:5 : 18
dFy Y0:5
y
def d
FlY Fyt ; Pt Fy Y Pt
dt t
d dPt
Pt Fyt Y Fyt Y : 19
dt dt
One Third of the Worlds Growth and Inequality 49
By the same token, one might wish to take care not to view y
as deep structural parameters in any sense of the term. Instead,
a useful perspective is to treat the ys as simply convenient ways
hyperparametersto keep control on the high-dimensional cal-
culations that would be otherwise involved in tracing through
distribution dynamics. The analysis in this chapter is obviously not
one that sets out to test a multivariate regression or simultane-
ous equations model. It studies historical tendencies, notto a
large degreethe effects of articial growth paths and inequality
dynamics.
Standard econometric analysis of (6)(7) allows consistency and
limit distribution results for the hyperparameters y. Measurement
errors in the data Xt , in sample, do not logically pose any difculties.
However, whether Xt can be guaranteed to converge to underlying
population quantities, and in a manner where the limiting distribu-
tion can be characterized falls outside the domain of analysis in this
chapter.
Finally, to state the obvious, this approach is one that makes
sense when the individual distributions Fj; t are comparable. If they
are not, then the whole enterprise of trying to study worldwide in-
equality is awed from the beginning, regardless of the approach
taken.
E_ =E x > 0: 20
I wish to compare dynamically evolving income distributions
against a xed (feasible and low, but otherwise arbitrary) threshold
income level Y. One statistic I am concerned with in particular is the
rate of ow of people past Y, namely, equation (19). I am interested
in the value of (19) when inequality, as measured by the Gini coef-
cient IG say, is held constant. Alternatively, I am interested in nd-
ing how fast IG has to change to set (19) to zero.
One Third of the Worlds Growth and Inequality 51
2.7.4.1 Lognormal
The lognormal distribution is widely used in traditional studies of
personal income distributions. Its density is
1=2 1 1 2
fLy y 2py2 y exp log y y1 ; y2 > 0; y > 0:
2y2
with
1=2
Y0:2i FLy expfF1
N0; 1 0:2i y2 y1 g:
An alternative expression for the cumulative quintile share is
!
log Y0:2i y1 y2
S0:2i FLy FN0; 1 1=2
y2
1=2
FN0; 1 F1
N0; 1 0:2i y2 :
and
Y
d d
FLy Y fLy dy:
dt 0 dt
(The Pareto case that follows permits explicit calculation for all the
dynamics of interest, in particular, for all the numerical results in
section 2.4. Other distributional hypotheses will, as with the log-
normal, require at least some of the results calculated numerically as
closed-form expressions are intractable.)
When IG is held xed, y_2 is zero. Then
y_1 E_ =E x;
so that for any xed y,
One Third of the Worlds Growth and Inequality 53
d 1=2 1 1 2
fLy y 2py2 y exp log y y1
dt 2y2
y1 _
2 log y y1 y1
1=2 log y y1 _
y2 fLy y p y1 :
y2
But then,
Y
d 1=2 log y y1
FLy Y y2 p fLy y x
dt 0 y2
1=2 log Y y1
y2 EN0; 1 Z j Z a p
y2
log Y y1
FN0; 1 p x:
y2
With xed inequality at a constant IG , this expression says that the
ow of population past a given threshold level Y is proportional to
the aggregate growth rate x. The constant of proportionality, more-
over, is easily calculated from knowledge of y.
The value of I_G =IG that sets the ow dFLy Y=dt to zero can be
obtained only by numerical simulation.
with
54 Danny Quah
y^1 1 y^21 E:
In this case the dynamics in y and E; IG can be easily seen to be
related by
y_1 y_2
E_ =E y2 11 ;
y1 y2
_
2y2 y2
I_G =IG :
2y2 1 y2
y_1 E_
x
y1 E
and
d
FPy Y 1 FPy Yy2 x:
dt
2.7.5 Data
Notes
I thank the MacArthur Foundation for nancial support. I have received many helpful
suggestions from colleagues, including Abhijit Banerjee, Tim Besley, Richard Blundell,
Andrew Chesher, Frank Cowell, Bill Easterly, Theo Eicher, Raquel Fernandez, Chico
Ferreira, James Feyrer, Oded Galor, Cecilia Garca-Penalosa, Louise Keely, and Branko
Milanovic. Also useful were Clarissa Yeaps research assistance in the early stages of
this work and Claudia Biancottis Ec473 LSE seminar presentation, in the spring of
2001. All calculations and graphs were produced using LATEX and the authors econo-
metrics shell tsrf.
1. Each entry in table 2.3 is a range rather than just a single number since alternative
distributional assumptions can be used in the calculation; see section 2.7.4.
2. See again, however, the discussion at the end of section 2.2 and the more detailed
picture available from studies such as Dreze and Sen (1995).
3. The only possible exceptions are the transition economies and Russia after the col-
lapse of the Soviet Union: see, for example, Ivaschenko (chapter 6) and Shorrocks and
Kolenikov (2001). The seven instances that Li, Squire, and Zou (1998) identied with
statistically and quantitatively signicant time trends in Gini coefcients only saw
proportional growth rates of 1.02 percent (Australia), 1.04 percent (Chile), 3.18 percent
(China), 1.71 percent (France), 1.18 percent (Italy), 1.61 percent (New Zealand), and
56 Danny Quah
1.46 percent (Poland) (this authors calculations, from Table 4 in Li, Squire, and Zou
(1998)) taken linearly over a single time periodmultiple time periods would imply
yet smaller growth rates.
References
Aghion, Philippe, Eve Caroli, and Cecilia Garca-Penalosa. 1999. Inequality and eco-
nomic growth: The perspective of the new growth theories. Journal of Economic Liter-
ature 37(4): 16151660, December.
Alesina, Alberto, and Dani Rodrik. 1994. Distributive politics and economic growth.
Quarterly Journal of Economics 109(2): 465490, May.
Atkinson, Anthony B., and Andrea Brandolini. 2001. Promise and pitfalls in the use
of secondary datasets: Income inequality in OECD countries as a case study. Journal
of Economic Literature 39(3): 771799, September.
Banerjee, Abhijit V., and Esther Duo. 2000. Inequality and growth: What can the
data say? Working Paper, Economics Department, MIT, May.
Barro, Robert J. 2000. Inequality and growth in a panel of countries. Journal of Eco-
nomic Growth 5(1): 532, March.
Benabou, Roland. 1996. Inequality and growth. In Macroeconomics Annual, vol. 11,
ed. Ben Bernanke and Julio Rotemberg, 1174. Cambridge: The MIT Press.
Bertola, Giuseppe. 1999. Macroeconomics of distribution and growth. In Handbook
of Income Distribution, vol. 1, ed. Anthony B. Atkinson and Francois Bourguignon,
477540. Amsterdam: North-Holland/Elsevier Science.
Cowell, Frank. 2000. Measurement of inequality. In Handbook of Income Distribution,
vol. 1, ed. Anthony B. Atkinson and Francois Bourguignon, 87166. Amsterdam:
North-Holland/Elsevier Science.
Deininger, Klaus, and Lyn Squire. 1996. A new data set measuring income inequal-
ity. World Bank Economic Review 10(3): 565591, September.
Deininger, Klaus, and Lyn Squire. 1998. New ways of looking at old issues: Inequal-
ity and growth. Journal of Development Economics 57: 259287.
Deininger, Klaus, and Lyn Squire. 2002. Revisiting inequality: New data, new
results. Working Paper, The World Bank, Washington, DC, March.
Dollar, David, and Art Kraay. 2001. Growth is good for the poor. Working paper,
DRG, The World Bank, Washington, DC, March.
Dreze, Jean, and Amartya Sen. 1995. India: Economic Development and Social Opportu-
nity. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Easterly, William, Michael Kremer, Lant Pritchett, and Lawrence H. Summers. 1993.
Good policy or good luck? Country growth performance and temporary shocks.
Journal of Monetary Economics 32(3): 459483.
Kuznets, Simon. 1955. Economic growth and income inequality. American Economic
Review 45(1): 128, March.
Li, Hongyi, and Hengfu Zou. 1998. Income inequality is not harmful for growth:
Theory and evidence. Review of Development Economics 2(3): 318334, October.
Li, Hongyi, Lyn Squire, and Hengfu Zou. 1998. Explaining international and inter-
temporal variations in income inequality. Economic Journal 108, 118, January.
Manski, Charles F. 1988. Analog Estimation Methods in Econometrics. London: Chapman
and Hall.
Milanovic, Branko. 2002. True world income distribution, 1988 and 1993: First
calculation based on household surveys alone. Economic Journal 112(476): 5192,
January.
Perotti, Roberto. 1996. Growth, income distribution, and democracy: What the data
say. Journal of Economic Growth 1(2): 149187, June.
Persson, Torsten, and Guido Tabellini. 1994. Is inequality harmful for growth?
American Economic Review 84(3): 600621, June.
Quah, Danny. 1997. Empirics for growth and distribution: Polarization, stratication,
and convergence clubs. Journal of Economic Growth 2(1): 2759, March.
Quah, Danny. 2001a. Cross-country growth comparison: Theory to empirics. In
Advances in Macroeconomic Theory, vol. 133 of Proceedings of the Twelfth World Congress
of the International Economic Association, Buenos Aires, ed. Jacques Dreze, 332351. Lon-
don: Palgrave.
Quah, Danny. 2001b. Some simple arithmetic on how income inequality and eco-
nomic growth matter. Working paper, Economics Department, LSE, London, June.
Given as the rst Journal of Applied Econometrics Lecture at the Econometric Society
Meetings, Auckland, New Zealand, July.
Ravallion, Martin. 1997. Can high-inequality developing countries escape absolute
poverty? Economics Letters 56(1): 5157.
Ravallion, Martin, and Shaohua Chen. 1997. What can new survey data tell us
about recent changes in distribution and poverty? World Bank Economic Review 11(2):
357382, June.
58 Danny Quah
3.1 Introduction
3.2.1 Production
wt 1 aAk a 1 wkt ;
2
rt aAk a1 1 rkt ;
where wt is the wage rate per efciency unit of labor in time t, and rt
is the capital rate of return. For sake of simplicity, physical capital is
assumed to fully depreciate at the end of each period.
3.2.2 Individuals
In the rst period of their lives individuals devote their entire time
for the acquisition of human capital (measured in efciency units of
labor). The acquired level of human capital increases if their time
investment is supplemented by investment in education. However,
even in the absence of investment in education, individuals acquire
one efciency unit of laborbasic skills. The level of investment in
education of each individual in period t, et1 , is measured in ef-
ciency units of labor. The resulting number of efciency units of
labor in period t 1, ht1 , is a strictly increasing, strictly concave
function of investment in education in period t, et1 ,
ht1 het1 ; 4
Fertility Clubs and Economic Growth 67
Let t be the minimum time cost required for raising a child; addi-
tional time allocated to children positively affects their quality. That
is, t is the fraction of the individuals unit of time endowment that is
required in order to raise a child, regardless of quality. Following
Becker and Lewis (1973), Rosenzweig and Wolpin (1980), and Galor
and Weil (2000), it is assumed for the sake of simplicity that the
quantity cost per child does not vary with family size. The eco-
nomic force behind the fertility gap between rich and poor is the
lower quantity cost faced by the poor. Therefore, incorporating a
range of decreasing quantity cost would increase the marginal cost
difference faced by poor and rich, amplifying the fertility gap, and
thus strengthening the results. Increasing returns to investment in
quality would work in the opposite direction, but, up to a limit,
should not have a qualitative effect on the models results.8 As will
become apparent, fertility rates are bounded from above by b=t,
therefore it is assumed that t < b. It is further assumed that t is suf-
ciently small, so that individuals with a low level of human capital
choose the corner solution of zero investment in child education,
t < 1=g: A1
nt wt ht t wt et1 st1 ct a wt ht rt st ; 5
3.2.5 Optimization
het1 wt1
rt1 : 8
tht et1 wt
Proof Dene Get1 1 het1 =yh 0 et1 . It follows from (9) that
Get1 b thet et1 : 10
As follows from (A1), qGet1 =qet 0, qthet et1 =qet > 0, and
G0 1=g > th0 t, and as follows from the properties of (4)
G0 1=g < lim e!y thet , and h 0 et > 0. Therefore, as follows from
the intermediate value theorem, there exists a unique et ^e > 0,
given by 1=g th^e; such that G0 th^e and G0 >< thet
for all et <> ^e implying that fet 0 for all et a ^e and fet > 0
otherwise.
As follows from implicit differentiation of the rst-order condition
of the maximization problem as given by (9), noting that second-
order condition hold for a maximum, fet is single valued and
f 0 et > 0 for et > ^e. r
It follows from lemma 1, and equations (5) and (6) that the number
of children of each member of generation t, nt is given by
b=t if et a ^e;
nt net 11
bhet =thet fet if et > ^e;
where b=t b bhet =thet fet . That is, fertility rates in low edu-
cation economies (et a ^e), where there is no investment in the quality
of children, are higher than in those countries with higher education
levels who invest in childrens education.
Figure 3.1
The evolution of education
states, e and 0, and an unstable steady state ^e, which is the threshold
level of education. The lemma thus follows from continuity consid-
erations.10 r
It follows from (2), (8), (9), and lemma 1 that the dynamical system
governing the evolution of the economy is uniquely determined by
the sequence fkt ; et gyt0 , such that
et1 fet ;
14
kt1 cet ; kt aAkta thet fet =hfet ;
where k0 and e0 are given. Note that kt is the physical human capital
ratio, and that physical capital per worker is equal to het kt st > kt .
Output per worker, yt , as follows from (1), is therefore uniquely
determined by the dynamical system
yt het Akta Aht1a sta :
Figure 3.2
The dynamical system
The model generates two locally stable steady states. If the initial
level of education is above the threshold level, e0 > e T , the economy
converges monotonically to the high capital labor ratio, high educa-
tion steady state, characterized by a low fertility rate. If however
e0 < e T , the economy converges to the low capital labor ratio, low
education steady statethe poverty trapthat is characterized by a
high fertility rate.
Fertility Clubs and Economic Growth 73
left. Furthermore, since fet increases with t for e > ^e, and since it is
constant with respect to et for e a ^e, it follows from lemma 1, the
concavity of het , (9) and (15) that the kk locus, depicted in gure
3.2, shifts upward as a result of an increase in t. Hence, in the
extended model, the impact of changes in the cost of child quantity
is amplied by the diluting effect on physical capital (the change
in the kk locus). Furthermore, since the threshold level of education,
e T , declines with t, a sufcient increase in the quantity cost can fa-
cilitate a demographic transition and release the economy from the
poverty trap.
The effect of changes in the cost of education is not so straight-
forward. The analysis of public schooling on fertility and education
follows.11 Suppose the government supplies schooling free of charge
g
at a level et , which is nanced by foreign aid or taxation.12 It follows
g
from (9) that if fet < et parental investment in education would
g
be zero, or otherwise it would equal fet et . Public schooling has,
therefore, a positive effect on the offspring level of education (for
g
fet < et ), but it also reduces parental expenditure on education
if fet > 0 and therefore gives rise to a reallocation of resources
g
for increased fertility. In the long run, however, if et > e T , public
schooling will shift the economy to a path of increased education
and income and reduced fertility.
lag variables, and ve-year spans are less likely to be serially corre-
lated. The variables in this database are divided into four categories:
(1) national account variables related to expenditure and income;
(2) social and demographic indicators, including school and fertility;
(3) political indicators, indexing political instability, regime and
market distortions; and (4) geographic regions in which the country
is located. Most of the variables are in time-variant format, but
some of them, mainly the political and geographic regions, are time-
invariant.
In 1965, the average number of children per womanthe fertility
ratewas above 6 in more than half of the countries sampled, while
in only six countries they were below 2.5. Even in 2000, in some East
African countries fertility rates are still above seven. On the other
hand in many countries (such as Spain, Italy, and Korea) they are
well below 1.5. Figure 3.3 displays the distributions of fertility rates
across countries and over time, showing a sharp decrease in fertility
rates, and interesting changes in the shape of the distribution. In
1965, there were, roughly speaking, two separate groups of countries
with respect to fertility levels. The distribution peaks around seven,
capturing the mass of high-fertility countries, and it also peaks
below three children per woman capturing the mass of the low fer-
tility countries. Surprisingly, only a few countries had fertility rates
between four and six children per woman. This twin-peak structure
did not change during the next twenty-ve years, in spite of the fact
that many countries experienced a rapid demographic transition,
and thus the mass of countries in the high fertility range has
declined. These facts support the basic result of the model that there
are strong economic forces driving toward polarization in fertility
rates.
Since 1965, fertility declined in all but twelve African counties in
our 114-country sample. Interestingly, fertility in the group of the
rich countries, which was low in 1965, further declined. At the same
time, many poor countries went through a major demographic tran-
sition, signicantly reducing their fertility rates and improving their
education. In 2000, fertility rates are below 3 in more than sixty
countries, and below 1.5 in twelve, which is signicantly below the
replacement rate. On the other spectrum, only twenty-ve countries
have fertility rates above 5, and only four of them still have fertility
rates of above 7 children per woman. These observations raise inter-
76 Avner Ahituv and Omer Moav
Figure 3.3
Fertility rates across countries
Fertility Clubs and Economic Growth 77
Table 3.1
Means of fertility by country group
Low-income Middle-income High-income
economies economies economies
1965 6.51 6.26 3.69
1980 6.41 5.07 2.64
1989 5.89 4.42 2.32
2001 4.90 3.42 1.89
Number of countries 34 39 38
in each group
Note: The three groups are based on GDP per capita in 1965. Group 1: 01000; Group
2: 10012500; Group 3: 2501.
Table 3.2
Summery of selected indicators by fertility rates
Fertility rates
13 34 45 56 67 79
Notes
We wish to thank Eric Gould, Joram Mayshar, M. Carme Riera Prunera, Mathias
Thoenig, an anonymous referee and participants in CESifo conference on Growth and
Inequality: Issues and Policy Implications, Munich 2001 and Elmau 2002, for helpful
discussions.
1. See also Hazan and Berdugo (2002), who study the relationship between child
labor, fertility, and growth, and Kremer and Chen (2002), who study the effect of
income inequality on economic growth in an endogenous fertility framework. In
addition, Veloso (1999) analyzes the effect of different compositions of wealth and
human capital on education. Finally, some recent literature focuses on the long-run
phenomena of fertility and the take-off from economic stagnation to sustained eco-
nomic growth, including the work of Kremer (1993), Tamura (1996), Galor and Weil
(1996, 2000), Dahan and Tsiddon (1998), Morand (1999), Hansen and Prescott (2002),
Lagerloff (2000), Jones (2001), and Galor and Moav (2002).
84 Avner Ahituv and Omer Moav
2. See, for instance, Psacharopoulos (1994), Angrist (1995), and Acemoglu and Angrist
(2000).
3. In contrast to this chapters thesis, existing literature explaining poverty traps is
based on nonconvexities in the technology. In particular, Banerjee and Newman
(1993), Galor and Zeira (1993), Benabou (1996), Durlauf (1996a), Piketty (1997), Maoz
and Moav (1999), Ghatak and Jiang (2002), and Mookherjee and Ray (2000) show that
credit constraints combined with investment thresholds generate persistence of pov-
erty. In the model developed by Piketty (1997), the effort level, rather than capital
investment, is indivisible. Mookherjee and Ray (2000) show that while inequality per-
sists irrespective of the divisibility of investment, the multiplicity of steady states
requires indivisibilities in the return to education. An exception is presented by Moav
(2002), where increasing saving rates with income, replace the role of nonconvexities
in the technology in generating multiple steady states.
4. See Azariadis (1996) and Galor (1996) for surveys of the theoretical and empirical
literature and the summery by Durlauf (1996b).
5. Where t, formally dened in what follows, is the time cost for raising a child.
6. The Inada conditions are typically designed to simplify the exposition by avoiding
a corner solution, but they are surely not realistic assumptions.
i
7. Note that the cost of education is wt et1 , whether this is viewed as a direct cost of
hiring a teacher or an opportunity cost of teaching ones own children.
8. It is implicitly assumed that the time cost of raising a child can not be reduced by
child care employment.
9. Note that individuals optimization assures efcient investment. The marginal
return to physical capital and human capital are equal in an interior solution and the
return to physical is larger in a case of a corner solution with no investment in human
capital.
10. While the model is not designed to perform calibrations, a numerical illustration
reveals that reasonable parameters, in particular, the lifetime dollar return to each
dollar invested in education, as given by g (see Psacharopoulos 1994) can generate
multiple equilibria. For g 2, y 1, t 0:15, b 1=2 and e 1:5. earnings at the high-
income equilibrium are four times higher than earnings at the low-income equilib-
rium, and fertility rates are 1.9 children per household (of two parents) in the high-
income equilibrium and 6.6 at the low. Note that multiplicity will hold for any set of
parameters restricted by (A1) and e > ^e.
11. The analysis abstracts from the potential effect of public schooling on the quantity
cost.
12. An indirect consumption tax, for instance, will not have an impact on the quality
and quantity choice of individuals.
13. Most countries have negative fertility growth, and the minus sign means faster
decline in fertility.
14. As previously reported in the literature, for example, Barro (1991), initial GDP
has a negative effect on GDP growth, supporting the conditional convergence hypo-
thesis.
Fertility Clubs and Economic Growth 85
15. This is consistent with the ndings of Rosenzweig and Wolpin (1980) and
Hanushek (1992), who provide evidence that there exists a trade-off between quantity
and quality of children.
16. Consistent with our theoretical argument and with our empirical ndings, Altonji
and Dunn (1996) nd that parents education positively affects childrens education,
supporting the existence of persistence of low education. In addition, Behrman et al.
(1999) nd that increases in the schooling of women enhance the human capital of the
next generation, and, consistent with the underlying mechanism developed here, they
argue that a component of the signicant and positive relationship between maternal
literacy and child schooling reects the productivity effect of home teaching.
References
Acemoglu, D., and J. D. Angrist. 2000. How Large Are the External Returns to Edu-
cation? Evidence from Compulsory Schooling Laws. NBER Macroannual 15: 959.
Ahituv, A. 2001. Be Fruitful or Multiply: On the Interplay between Fertility and Eco-
nomic Development. Journal of Population Economics 14: 5171.
Altonji, J. G., and T. A. Dunn. 1996. The Effect of Family Characteristics on the Return
to Education. Review of Economics and Statistics 78: 692704.
Angrist, J. D. 1995. The Economic Returns to Schooling in the West Bank and Gaza
Strip. American Economic Review 85: 10651087.
Angrist, J. D., and V. Lavy. 2001. Does Teacher Training Affect Pupil Learning? Evi-
dence from Matched Comparisons in Jerusalem Public Schools. Journal of Labor Eco-
nomics 19: 343369.
Azariadis, C. 1996. The Economics of Poverty Traps, Part One: Complete Markets.
Journal of Economic Growth 1: 449486.
Banerjee, A., and A. Newman. 1993. Occupational Choice and the Process of Devel-
opment. Journal of Political Economy 101: 274298.
Barro, R. J. 1991. Economic Growth in a Cross Section of Countries. Quarterly Journal
of Economics 106: 407443.
Becker, G. S., and H. G. Lewis. 1973. On the Interaction between Quantity and Qual-
ity of Children. Journal of Political Economy 82: S279S288.
Becker, G. S., K. M. Murphy, and R. F. Tamura. 1990. Human Capital, Fertility, and
Economic Growth. Journal of Political Economy 98: S12S37.
Behrman, J. R., A. D. Foster, M. R. Rosenzweig, and P. Vashishtha. 1999. Womens
Schooling, Home Teaching, and Economic Growth. Journal of Political Economy 107:
682714.
Benabou, R. 1996. Equity and Efciency in Human Capital Investment: The Local
Connection. Review of Economic Studies 63: 267264.
Card, D., and A. B. Krueger. 1992. Does School Quality MatterReturns to Educa-
tion and the Characteristics of Public-Schools in the United States. Journal of Political
Economy 100: 140.
86 Avner Ahituv and Omer Moav
Galor, O., and D. Weil. 2000. Population, Technology, and Growth: From Malthusian
Stagnation to Demographic Transition and Beyond. American Economic Review 90:
806828.
Galor, O., and J. Zeira. 1993. Income Distribution and Macroeconomics. Review of
Economic Studies 60: 3552.
Ghatak, M., and N. H. Jiang. 2002. A Simple Model of Inequality, Occupational
Choice and Development. Journal of Development Economics 69: 205226.
Hansen, G., and E. Prescott. 2002. Malthus to Solow. American Economic Review 92:
12051217.
Hanushek, E. A. 1992. The Trade-Off between Child Quantity and Quality. Journal of
Political Economy 100: 84117.
Hazan, M., and B. Berdugo. 2002. Child Labor, Fertility, and Economic Growth.
Economic Journal 112: 810828.
Jones, C. I. 2001. Was the Industrial Revolution Inevitable? Economic Growth over
the Very Long Run. Advances in Macroeconomics 1, Article 1. Available online.
Kremer, M. 1993. Population Growth and Technological Change: One Million B.C. to
1990. Quarterly Journal of Economics 108: 681716.
Kremer, M., and D. Chen. 2002. Income Distribution Dynamics with Endogenous
Fertility. Journal of Economic Growth 7: 227258.
Lagerloff, N. P. 2000. From Malthus to Modern Growth: The Three Regimes Re-
visited. Mimeo., Sydney.
Lam, D., and S. Duryea. 1999. Effects of Schooling on Fertility, Labor Supply and
Investments in Children, with Evidence from Brazil. Journal of Human Resources 34:
160192.
Maoz, Y. D., and O. Moav. 1999. Intergenerational Mobility and the Process of
Development. Economic Journal 109: 677697.
Fertility Clubs and Economic Growth 87
Moav, O. 2001. Cheap Children and the Persistence of Poverty. CEPR Discussion
Paper No. 3059.
Moav, O. 2002. Income Distribution and Macroeconomics: The Persistence of In-
equality in a Convex Technology Framework. Economics Letters 75: 187192.
Morand, O. F. 1999. Endogenous Fertility, Income Distribution, and Growth. Journal
of Economic Growth 4: 331349.
Mookherjee, D., and D. Ray. 2000. Persistent Inequality. Mimeo., Boston University.
Nelson, R. R. 1956. A Theory of Low-Level Equilibrium Trap in Underdeveloped
Economies. American Economic Review 46: 894908.
Piketty, T. 1997. The Dynamics of the Wealth Distribution and Interest Rate with
Credit-Rationing. Review of Economic Studies 64: 173189.
Psacharopoulos, G. 1994. Returns to Investment in EducationA Global Update.
World Development 22: 13251343.
Psacharopoulos, G., J. Valenzuela, and M. Arends. 1996. Teacher Salaries in Latin
America: A Review. Economics of Education Review 15: 401406.
Quah, D. T. 1997. Empirics for Growth and Distribution: Stratication, Polarization,
and Convergence Clubs. Journal of Economic Growth 2: 2759.
Rosenzweig, M. R., and K. I. Wolpin. 1980. Testing the Quantity-Quality Fertility
Model: The Use of Twins as a Natural Experiment. Econometrica 48: 227240.
4.1 Introduction
where wt is the wage rate in period t and tt is the tax rate on labor
income.1 Under the public education regime taxes on incomes
nance the costs of educating the young generation. Making use of
(1) and (2), balanced government budget means
wt egt ht dmo tt wt ht o dmo;
W W
or equivalently,
egt tt ; 3
that is, the tax rate on labor is equal to the proportion of the econ-
omys effective labor used for public education.2
4.3.2 Equilibrium
subject to
c1t o yt o st o b 0; 6
c2t o 1 rt1 st o: 7
96 Jean-Marie Viaene and Itzhak Zilcha
1 rt Fk kt ; 1 egt ht ; 9
kt1 st o dmo; 10
W
c1t a1
; 11
c2t a2 1 rt1
b if et o 0: 13
The last equation allocates the unit of nonworking time between
leisure and the time spent on education by the parents. The latter,
et o, increases with the parents human capital htu and the wage,
net of taxes, at the future date. Equation (12) establishes a negative
relationship between types of education, that is, public education
substitutes for parental tutoring as tt1 increases. Hence, for each
individual there exists a particular value of the tax rate such that
et o 0. This is obtained when the marginal utility of leisure is
larger than the net future wage received from a marginal increase in
the human capital of the younger generation as a result of parental
Human Capital Formation 97
It is clear from (18) that the growth factor of effective labor is the
sum of two terms, one representing the contribution of parental
tutoring, the other the contribution of public education. While the
latter is inuenced by the tax rate the former depends upon the dis-
tribution of human capital at each date.
kt1 1 ya2
1 rt : 19
kt ya1 a2
Making use of (17) and of the expression for the rental rate:
y
kt1 Aa2 1 y 1y 1 kt
1 tt gt ; 20
ht1 a1 a2 ht
qt1
g:
qt
Table 4.1
Baseline and parameters of the utility function
(1)
a1 a2 1
a3 2 (2) (3) (4) (5)
a4 1 a1 1:1 a2 1:1 a3 2:2 a4 1:1
Consider two similar economies that differ only in the initial distri-
butions of human capital: One economy has higher levels of human
capital but the same inequality of human capital distribution. Can
we compare the equilibrium intragenerational income distributions
102 Jean-Marie Viaene and Itzhak Zilcha
Table 4.2
Baseline and public education
(1) (2)
t 0:2 t 0:22
Relative factor returns 0.471 0.493
1 rt =wt 0.471 0.495
Gini coefcient gt 0.155 0.145
0.025 0.020
Growth rate (%) 28 29.7
(aggr. output) 28 30.1
Parental education et
Poorest agent 0.550 0.543
0.596 0.590
Richest agent 0.622 0.616
0.605 0.598
104 Jean-Marie Viaene and Itzhak Zilcha
Table 4.3
Baseline and other specication externalities
Externalities (1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
u 1 0.9 1 1.1 1
h 1 1 0.9 1 1.1
Relative factor returns 0.471 0.366 0.445 0.816 0.513
1 rt =wt 0.471 0.345 0.430 3.29 0.581
Gini coefcient gt 0.155 0.095 0.182 0.288 0.129
0.025 0.003 0.050 0.327 0.008
Growth rate (%) 28 7.1 23.0 86.9 35.9
(aggr. output) 28 2.9 20.0 large 48.1
Parental education et
Poorest agent 0.550 0.550 0.570 0.548 0.518
0.596 0.578 0.621 0.633 0.527
Richest agent 0.622 0.598 0.636 0.649 0.597
0.605 0.580 0.632 0.661 0.533
Table 4.4
Baseline and other specication efciency
Efciency (1) (2) (3) (4)
b1 1.6 1.76 1.6 1.76
b2 1.6 1.6 1.76 1.76
Relative factor returns 0.471 0.526 0.482 0.537
1 rt =wt 0.471 0.528 0.483 0.540
Gini coefcient gt 0.155 0.166 0.145 0.155
0.025 0.031 0.020 0.025
Growth rate (%) 28 38.2 30.0 40.2
(aggr. output) 28 38.7 30.1 40.8
Parental education et
Poorest agent 0.550 0.556 0.543 0.550
0.596 0.601 0.590 0.596
Richest agent 0.622 0.627 0.616 0.622
0.605 0.612 0.598 0.605
a3 a4 a1 a2 b1 ht on
tt o : 25
a1 a2 a3 a4 a1 a2 a3 a4 b2 hth
Each agent chooses the optimal tt o such that the cost of cur-
rent spending on education (in terms of foregone current and future
consumption) is equal to the reward of a marginal increase in the
human capital of their children. It is clear that the heterogeneity in
108 Jean-Marie Viaene and Itzhak Zilcha
Table 4.5
Externalities and median voter
Externalities (1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
u 1 0.9 1 1.1 1
h 1 1 0.9 1 1.1
Tax rate tt 0.222 0.299 0.109 0.101 0.347
0.203 0.323 0.031 0.019 0.460
Relative factor returns 0.496 0.447 0.384 0.684 0.751
1 rt =wt 0.476 0.440 0.315 2.31 1.67
Gini coefcient gt 0.143 0.079 0.213 0.338 0.096
0.021 0.001 0.127 0.586 0.001
Growth rate (%) 30.1 12.4 9.3 80.6 52.8
(aggr. output) 28.6 8.5 10.3 large large
Parental education et
Poorest agent 0.539 0.496 0.602 0.585 0.422
0.595 0.511 0.657 0.641 0.189
Richest agent 0.616 0.556 0.651 0.657 0.519
0.603 0.511 0.662 0.666 0.191
Table 4.6
Efciency and median voter
Efciency (1) (2) (3) (4)
b1 1.6 1.76 1.6 1.76
b2 1.6 1.6 1.76 1.76
Tax rate (tt 0.222 0.188 0.254 0.222
0.203 0.166 0.238 0.203
Relative factor returns 0.496 0.516 0.545 0.565
1 rt =wt 0.476 0.490 0.532 0.546
Gini coefcient gt 0.143 0.166 0.124 0.143
0.021 0.037 0.011 0.021
Growth rate (%) 30.1 37.8 35.0 42.6
(aggr. output) 28.6 35.4 34.7 41.4
Parental education et
Poorest agent 0.539 0.560 0.517 0.539
0.595 0.611 0.577 0.595
Richest agent 0.616 0.630 0.600 0.616
0.603 0.622 0.583 0.603
4.7 Appendix
where Ct and Ct are positive constants. Since h0 and h0 are equally
distributed, the same holds for h0v o and h0 o v , since v a 1.
Moreover, since h0 < h0 we obtain that h1 o is more equal than
h1 o (see Lemma 2 in Karni and Zilcha 1994). It is easy to verify
from (18) that h1 o are lower than h1 o for all o. In particular, we
obtain that h1 o v is more equal than h1 o v (see Shaked and
Human Capital Formation 113
Notes
We are grateful to the participants of the CESifo conferences on Growth and Inequal-
ity: Issues and Policy Implications for contributing remarks. We also wish to express
our thanks to an anonymous referee and to T. Eicher, H. Kierzkowski, H. de Kruijk,
R. Riezman, H.-W. Sinn, O. Swank, and S. Turnovsky for numerous suggestions.
Research assistance by D. Ottens is gratefully acknowledged.
4. Externalities that yield increasing returns to scale to parents human capital, that is
u > 1, have been observed in China (Knight and Shi 1996) and are therefore not a mere
theoretical curiosum.
References
Fernandez, R., and R. Rogerson. 1998. Public education and income distribution:
A quantitative dynamic evaluation of education-nance reform. American Economic
Review 88(4): 813833.
Fischer, R. D., and P. J. Serra. 1996. Income convergence within and between countries.
International Economic Review 37(3): 531551.
Forbes, K. J. 2000. A reassessment of the relationship between inequality and growth.
American Economic Review 90(4): 865887.
Galor, O., and O. Moav. 2000. Ability biased technological transition, wage inequality
and growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 115: 469497.
Galor, O., and J. Zeira. 1993. Income distribution and macroeconomics. Review of Eco-
nomic Studies 60: 3552.
Glaeser, E. L. 1994. Why does schooling generate economic growth? Economics Letters
44(3): 333337.
Human Capital Formation 117
Glomm, G., and B. Ravikumar. 1992. Public versus private investment in human
capital: Endogenous growth and income inequality. Journal of Political Economy 100:
818834.
Jovanovic, B., and Y. Nyarko. 1995. The transfer of human capital. Journal of Economic
Dynamics and Control 19: 10331064.
Karni, E., and I. Zilcha. 1994. Technological progress and income inequality: A model
with human capital and bequests. In The Changing Distribution of Income in an Open
U.S. Economy, ed. J. H. Bergstrand et al., 279297. Amsterdam: North-Holland.
Knight, J., and L. Shi. 1996. Educational attainment and the rural-urban divide in
China. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 58(1): 83117.
Lindahl, M. 2001. Home versus school learning: A new approach to estimating the
effects of class size on achievement. Discussion Paper No. 261. IZA (Bonn).
Loury, G. 1981. Intergenerational transfers and the distribution of earnings. Econo-
metrica 49(4): 843867.
Lucas, R. 1988. On the mechanics of economic development. Journal of Monetary Eco-
nomics 22: 342.
OECD. 1997. Education at a Glance: OECD Indicators. Paris: OECD.
Persson, T., and G. Tabellini. 1994. Is inequality harmful for growth? American Eco-
nomic Review 84(3): 600621.
Shaked, M., and J. G. Shanthikumar. 1994. Stochastic Orders and Their Applications.
Boston: Academic Press.
Tamura, R. 1991. Income convergence in an endogenous growth model. Journal of
Political Economy 99: 522540.
van Marrewijk, C. 1999. Capital accumulation, learning and endogenous growth.
Oxford Economic Papers 51: 453475.
Viaene, J.-M., and I. Zilcha. 2002a. Capital markets integration, growth and income
distribution. European Economic Review 46(2): 301327.
Viaene, J.-M., and I. Zilcha. 2002b. Public education under capital mobility. Journal of
Economic Dynamics and Control 26: 20052036.
This page intentionally left blank
III European Transition and
Inequality
This page intentionally left blank
5 Social Transfers and
Inequality during the
Polish Transition
5.1. Introduction
Beginning in the late 1980s and early 1990s, all the countries of the
former Soviet Union and Eastern Europe have, to a greater or lesser
extent, undertaken a process of transition away from central plan-
ning toward more market-oriented economic systems. However,
different countries have chosen very different approaches to the
process of transition. The outcomes, in terms of macroeconomic and
social indicators, have been quite diverse as well. In general, how-
ever, most countries of the former Eastern bloc have experienced
poor growth performance and large increases in income inequality
during the transition process. The most obvious success story in the
process of transition to date has been Poland, which has outstripped
other transition economies in terms of growth performance, while at
the same time experiencing only modest increases in inequality.
Hence, a detailed analysis of the Polish experience, with a view
toward asking what the country did right, is of considerable interest.
There has been a lively debate on the efcacy of alternative
market-oriented reform strategies, both in terms of the sequencing
and magnitude of reforms (see, e.g., Aghion and Blanchard 1994;
Dewatripont and Roland 1996). Poland pursued a strategy of rapid
and decisive reform that has often been referred to as shock ther-
apy. This process began in August 1989January 1990, a period that
has become known as the big bang. Price controls on food were
lifted in August 1989 and those on most other products were lifted in
January 1990. Numerous other macroeconomic and microeconomic
reforms, including restraints on credit for state-owned enterprises,
the hardening of their budget constraints, and the opening up of
122 Michael P. Keane and Eswar S. Prasad
1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000
Real GDP 4.2 2.1 4.0 0.3 11.4 7.0 2.6 3.8 5.2 7.0 6.1 6.9 4.8 4.1 5.0
Consumer price index 16.5 26.4 60.2 251.1 585.8 70.3 43.0 35.3 32.2 27.8 19.9 14.9 11.8 7.3 9.9
(annual average)
Employment (end-year) 0.3 0.0 1.0 0.8 6.2 3.9 3.1 1.7 1.1 0.3 3.5 1.3 1.4 1.5 6.7
Unemployment rate (%) 0.1 6.1 11.8 14.3 16.4 16.0 14.9 13.2 8.6 10.5 13.0 15.1
(end-year)
Levels of real GDP in 1999 (1989 100) for selected transition economies
Poland 122 Czech Republic 95
Slovenia 109 Albania 95
Slovak Republic 100 Uzbekistan 94
Hungary 99 Belarus 80
ing. The basic idea of our approach is to assume that income consists
of a permanent or predictable component (determined by education,
age, and other observable characteristics of households and their
members) plus a mean zero idiosyncratic component. We rst re-
gress household income on a large set of controls; these regressions
were run separately for each quarter from 19851992 and for each
month from 19931997. We then assume that the variance of the
idiosyncratic component would not have jumped abruptly between
the fourth quarter of 1992 and the rst month of 1993, since, to our
knowledge, no dramatic policy changes or exogenous shocks oc-
curred at that point in time. Rather, we assume that the variance of
the idiosyncratic component varies smoothly over time (measured
in months) according to a polynomial time trend. We estimate this
polynomial trend, along with a dummy for the post-1992 period that
captures the discrete jump in variance that occurred with the change
to monthly income reporting.
The second-stage estimation, where the standard deviations of
the income residuals from the rst-stage regressions are used as the
dependent variable, is done separately for households with differ-
ent primary income. The results, shown in table 5.2, indicate that
the adjustment factor ranges from 0.369 for farmers to 0.044 for
Table 5.2
Regressions using income residuals
Workers/
Workers Farmers farmers Pensioners
Time 0.001 0.006 0.006 0.000
(0.002) (0.006) (0.006) (0.001)
Time 2 /10 3 0.000 0.188 0.171 0.002
(0.000) (0.092) (0.092) (0.023)
Time 3 /10 6 0.001 0.919 0.859 0.009
(0.010) (0.365) (0.364) (0.095)
Mean real 0.207 0.126 0.116 0.367
income (0.014) (0.013) (0.021) (0.027)
Dummy for 0.165 0.369 0.201 0.044
9397 (0.028) (0.102) (0.098) (0.026)
Adjusted R 2 0.88 0.65 0.51 0.85
Number of 92 92 92 92
observations
Note: The dependent variable is the log standard deviation of the residuals from
equation (1). Standard errors are reported in parentheses.
128 Michael P. Keane and Eswar S. Prasad
Note: The components of income and consumption are shown as (mean) shares of total income and consumption, respectively. Dashes indicate
data are not available.
Social Transfers and Inequality during the Polish Transition
131
132 Michael P. Keane and Eswar S. Prasad
Figure 5.1
Households sorted by income net of transfers
Social Transfers and Inequality during the Polish Transition 137
Figure 5.2
(a) Percentiles of pretransfer distribution: 10, 25; (b) Percentiles of pretransfer distri-
bution: 50, 75, 90
5.3.4 Summary
Figure 5.3
Gini coefcients
142 Michael P. Keane and Eswar S. Prasad
Figure 5.4
Transfers as share of GDP
144 Michael P. Keane and Eswar S. Prasad
5.6 Conclusions
of inequality for Poland remain only modestly above those for the
Scandinavian countries.
Our results further indicate that inequality in labor earnings did
increase substantially during the Polish transition. However, a strik-
ing aspect of government policies during the early years of transition
was a sharp increase in social transfers, from about 10 percent of
GDP to roughly 20 percent. This is the highest level of transfers (as a
share of GDP) of any transition country. We have argued that this
increase in transfers substantially mitigated the increase in overall
income inequality that might otherwise have resulted from increased
earnings inequality.
From these patterns we draw one clear policy conclusion: The
Polish experience makes clear that a substantial increase in income
inequality is not a necessary concomitant of successful transition.
Clearly, it is possible to use high levels of social transfers to maintain
income equality, without hindering the transition process or choking
off economic growth.
A more speculative hypothesis that is not inconsistent with our
ndings is that the generous social transfer policy pursued by
Poland may have actually promoted the transition process and pro-
moted growth. One mechanism through which social transfers
could promote successful transition is by cushioning (or buying
off) groups that would have been most adversely affected by
reforms.
For instance, older workers had the most to lose from the privati-
zation or closure of state-owned rms and would have been most
adversely affected by enterprise restructuring. But, early in the
transition process, Poland substantially increased the availability
and generosity of pensions.22 This induced large numbers of older
workers to take early retirement. This may have facilitated transition
both by removing potential opposition to reforms by a powerful
interest group and by helping to reduce employment at enterprises
to more efcient levels and promoting other aspects of enterprise
restructuring.23
More generally, we found that transfers in Poland have to a great
extent been targeted at the middle class rather than just the poor. A
number of authors have argued, on political economy grounds, that
the development of a solid, property-owning middle class is essen-
tial to the consolidation of capitalism (Kornai 2000). For further
148 Michael P. Keane and Eswar S. Prasad
Notes
We thank the staff at the Polish Central Statistical Ofce, especially Wiesaw agod-
zinski and Jan Kordos, for assistance with the data. We also thank Krzystof Przyby-
lowski and Barbara Kaminska for excellent translations of the survey instruments and
Branko Milanovic for generously sharing his cross-country data with us. We received
helpful comments on earlier drafts from Theo Eicher, Omer Moav, Stephan Klasen, an
anonymous referee, and the participants of the 2001 and 2002 CESIfo Growth and In-
equality conferences. Financial support was provided by the National Council for
Eurasian and East European Research. The views expressed in this chapter do not
necessarily represent those of the IMF.
1. These indicators measure the progress made by transition countries in many areas
of market-oriented reforms including enterprise privatization and reform; price and
trade liberalization; and establishment of the rule of law, property rights, and well-
functioning nancial markets.
2. The reasons for this transition recession, experienced by all transition economies,
are controversial. Some authors stress the contraction of credit to state enterprises (see
Calvo and Coricelli 1992), while others stress the aggregate demand contraction, due
in part to the opening to import competition and the sharp contraction in exports to
other former communist bloc countries (see Berg and Blanchard 1994).
3. Although the survey sample is designed to be representative of the underlying
population, nonresponse rates tend to differ across demographic groups. This neces-
sitates the use of sampling weights, although these weights had little effect on any of
our main results.
4. Higher-order polynomial terms were insignicant in these regressions, which t the
time path of the idiosyncratic component of variance quite well.
5. One other important change that was made in the 1993 survey was an attempt
to obtain a more representative sample of the self-employed. This groups size is
believed to have increased markedly since the transition began, resulting in its under-
representation in the HBS data during the period 19901992. However, as shown in
Keane and Prasad (2002a), underrepresentation of the self-employed is likely to have
led to only a marginal understatement of the extent of inequality in the early years of
the transition.
6. It is possible to make some (but not all) of the necessary adjustments to income
using information in the aggregate data on categories of income.
8. At the time we began our study, the Polish CSO had never before released the HBS
microdata. A long negotiation process by the rst author during 19921993 led to its
release. Subsequently, the microdata for the rst half of 1993 was released to the
World Bank and this data is used in World Bank (1995) and Milanovic (1998). More
recently, the data for 19931996 have been obtained by researchers at the World Bank.
As noted above, a subsample of the HBS is also now available in the through the
Luxembourg Income Survey (LIS) for 1987, 1990 and 1992. Thus, no prior researchers
have had access to the microdata for the entirety of the extended period that we
examine.
9. The sample size falls in 1992 since half of the total sample in that year was used to
test the new monthly survey. These monthly data from 1992 were considered unreli-
able and not made available to us.
10. For details on the estimation of the food share based equivalence scales, and for a
comparison with other commonly used equivalence scales, see Keane and Prasad
(2001a). We are aware of the potential problems associated with the use of food share
based equivalence scales. However, we were concerned about estimating a complete
demand system under conditions when rationing of certain commodities was proba-
bly an issue in some years of our sample, but where we do not observe the rationing
regimes.
11. Besides our own FS scale, we also used the OECD scale, the McClements scale
(which is commonly used in Britain), and the simple per capita scale. Appendix Table
B1 in Keane and Prasad (2001a) shows values of different equivalence scales for a
representative set of household types.
12. We recomputed many of the results in this chapter using different equivalence
scales. Although the levels of inequality were slightly affected by the choice of equiv-
alence scale, patterns of the evolution of inequality over time were robust to this
choice.
13. In all cases, we examine the distribution of individual income (or consumption),
assigning to each individual the per equivalent income for the household in which the
person resides.
14. Since transfers tend to be stable over time, the adjustment factors (used to adjust
for the change in survey frequency in 19931996) for income net of transfers were
nearly identical to those we computed for income including transfers.
15. In Keane and Prasad (2001a, 2002a), we show that similar results hold if one
examines alternative inequality measures such as quantile ratios, quantile shares, or
kernel density estimates of the income distribution.
16. A similar result is reported by Garner and Terrell (1998), who nd that pensions
substantially reduced inequality during the early transition years in the Czech and
Slovak republics.
17. In Keane and Prasad (2002a), we report that changes in within-group inequality
were very different across different groups. Within-group inequality actually fell
Social Transfers and Inequality during the Polish Transition 151
among farmer and mixed worker-farmer households during the transition, which, in
addition to the roles of pensions and other social transfers, also helps to account for
the rather small increase in overall income inequality. The Gini for household income
for individuals in worker-headed households rose from 0.189 in 1988 to 0.248 in 1997.
This increase of 0.059 is almost three times as great as the 0.020 increase in the Gini
for the overall income distribution, and is consistent with the increase in labor income
inequality noted earlier.
18. The typical retirement age in Poland is 65 for men and 62 for women. Among
households with heads in the 4555 age range and in lower age ranges, there was a
small drop from 1989 to 1992 in the share of income from labor income, but this was
mostly offset by an increase in other social benets rather than pensions. Among
households with heads aged 65 and older, pensions constitute 8590 percent of total
income, with labor income accounting for barely 2 percent.
19. The level of transfers is expressed as a percent of GDP and is the average, for each
country, from the rst year of its transition through 1997. The Gini coefcients are for
per capita income and the change is the difference between the value of the coefcient
four to ve years into the transition and the value of this coefcient before transition.
For data and sources, see Keane and Prasad (2002a).
20. Note that higher transfers do not necessarily imply more redistribution. An
extreme example is provided by Commander and Lee (1998), who note that transfers
in Russia have actually become regressive in the transition.
21. In Keane and Prasad (2002a), we provide a more detailed regression analysis of
the relationship between inequality changes and growth in the transition economies.
We nd a negative relationship even after controlling for initial conditions (including
the pretransition level of inequality) and measures of the extent of market-oriented
reforms. Grun and Klasen (2001) report similar ndings.
22. The Polish situation is considerably different from that in numerous other transi-
tion economies, where the real value of pensions and other transfers fell precipitously
during transition (both in absolute terms and relative to average wages).
23. Fidrmuc (2000) presents an interesting empirical analysis of voting patterns in
transition countries. He notes that various politically powerful groupsincluding
unions and retireeswere more likely to vote for left-wing parties. Notwithstanding
their political leanings, these were in fact the regimes that had enough political capital
to institute signicant reforms. The Polish experience can be seen as one where suc-
cessive (relatively short-lived) governments during early transition used generous
transfers to acquire such political capital and appease groups that had the most to
lose, in the short run, from market-oriented reforms.
References
Aghion, Philippe, and Olivier Blanchard. 1994. On the Speed of Transition in Central
Europe. NBER Macroeconomics Annual 9: 283320.
Aghion, Philippe, and Simon Commander. 1999. On the Dynamics of Inequality in
the Transition. Economics of Transition 7(2): 275298.
Aghion, Philippe, and Patrick Bolton. 1997. A Trickle-Down Theory of Growth and
Development with Debt Overhang. Review of Economic Studies 64(2): 151162.
152 Michael P. Keane and Eswar S. Prasad
Aghion, Philippe, Eve Caroli, and Cecilia Garca-Penalosa. 1999. Inequality and Eco-
nomic Growth: The Perspective of the New Growth Theories. Journal of Economic
Perspectives 37(4): 16151660.
Alesina, Alberto, and Dani Rodrik. 1994. Distributive Politics and Economic
Growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 109(2): 465490.
Atkinson, Anthony B., Lee Rainwater, and Timothy M. Smeeding. 1995. Income Dis-
tribution in OECD Countries: Evidence from the Luxembourg Income Study. OECD
Social Policy Studies No. 18. Paris: OECD.
Banerjee, Abhijit, and Andrew F. Newman. 1993. Occupational Choice and the Pro-
cess of Development. Journal of Political Economy 101(2): 274298.
Benabou, Roland. 1996. Inequality and Growth. NBER Macroeconomics Annual 11:
1174.
Berg, Andrew, and Olivier Blanchard. 1994. Stabilization and Transition: Poland
19901991. In The Transition in Eastern Europe, Vol. 1: Country Studies, ed. Olivier
Blanchard, Kenneth Froot, and Jeffrey Sachs. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Calvo, Guillermo A., and Fabrizio Coricelli. 1992. Stabilizing a Previously Centrally
Planned Economy: Poland 1990. Economic Policy 14: 176226.
Commander, Simon, and Une Lee. 1998. How Does Public Policy Affect the Income
Distribution? Evidence from Russia, 19921996. Manuscript, EBRD, London.
de Crombugghe, Alain. 1997. Wage and Pension Pressure on the Polish Budget.
World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 1793.
Gomuka, Stanisaw. 1998. The Polish Model of Transformation and Growth. Eco-
nomics of Transition 6(1): 163171.
Social Transfers and Inequality during the Polish Transition 153
Grun, Carola, and Stephan Klasen. 2001. Growth, Income Distribution and Well-
Being in Transition Countries. Economics of Transition 9(2): 359394.
Havrylyshyn, Oleh, and John Odling-Smee. 2000. Political Economy of Stalled
Reforms. Finance and Development 37(3): 710.
International Monetary Fund (IMF). 1994. Poland: The Path to a Market Economy.
Occasional Paper No. 113.
Keane, Michael P., and Eswar S. Prasad. 2001a. Consumption and Income Inequality
during the Transition to a Market Economy: Poland, 19851992. IMF Staff Papers 47:
121154.
Keane, Michael P., and Eswar S. Prasad. 2001b. Poland: Inequality, Transfers and
Growth in Transition. Finance and Development 38(1): 5053.
Keane, Michael P., and Eswar S. Prasad. 2002a. Inequality, Transfers and Growth:
New Evidence from the Economic Transition in Poland. Review of Economics and Sta-
tistics 84(2): 324341.
Keane, Michael P., and Eswar S. Prasad. 2002b. Changes in the Structure of Earnings
during the Polish Transition. IMF Working Paper No. 02/135.
Kornai, Janos. 2000. Making the Transition to Private Ownership. Finance and
Development 37(3): 1213.
Kuznets, Simon. 1955. Economic Growth and Income Inequality. American Economic
Review 45(1): 128.
Milanovic, Branko. 1998. Income, Inequality and Poverty during the Transition from
Planned to Market Economy. World Bank Regional and Sectoral Studies, Washing-
ton, DC.
Milanovic, Branko. 1999. Explaining the Increase in Inequality during Transition.
Economics of Transition 7(2): 299341.
OECD. 1997, 1998. OECD Economic Surveys: Poland. Paris: OECD.
Perotti, Roberto. 1996. Growth, Income Distribution and Democracy: What the Data
Say. Journal of Economic Growth 1: 149187.
Persson, Torsten, and Guido Tabellini. 1994. Is Inequality Harmful for Growth?
American Economic Review 84(3): 600621.
Pinto, Brian, Marek Belka, and Stefan Krajewski. 1993. Transforming State Enter-
prises in Poland: Evidence on Adjustment by Manufacturing Firms. Brookings Papers
on Economic Activity, 213270.
Roland, Gerard. 1993. The Political Economy of Restructuring and Privatization in
Eastern Europe. European Economic Review 37(23): 533540.
Svejnar, Jan. 1996. Enterprises and Workers in the Transition: Econometric Evidence.
American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 86(2): 123127.
World Bank. 1995. Understanding Poverty in Poland. Country Study, World Bank,
Washington, DC.
World Bank. 19972000. World Development Indicators. World Bank, Washington,
DC.
This page intentionally left blank
6 Growth and Inequality:
Evidence from Transitional
Economies in the 1990s
Oleksiy Ivaschenko
6.1 Introduction
countries of EE and the FSU and embracing the period from 1989 to
1998. The fact that the combined population of these countries
exceeds 400 million people makes the understanding of the factors
driving the changes in income distribution go far beyond a purely
research interest. Although it is often argued that policymakers
should be more concerned about absolute poverty than income
inequality, there are several reasons why one may (or should) care
about the latter as well. At a given rate of economic growth, more
unequal distribution of income would be associated with a lower
rate of poverty reduction, assuming, of course, that the poor partici-
pate fully in sharing the gains from growth. Moreover, as suggested
in many studies (e.g., Alesina and Rodrik 1994; Birdsall, Ross, and
Sabot 1995; Deininger and Squire 1998; Persson and Tabellini 1994;
Sylwester 2000; Easterly 2001), an unequal income distribution might
itself be detrimental to long-run economic growth for a variety of
reasons.2 The most common arguments for this are that an unequal
distribution of income creates pressure for redistributional policies,
and hence distorts incentives for working and investing; that it leads
to abuse of power by the elite and to sociopolitical instability and,
thus, harms the investment environment; and nally that, in the
presence of imperfect capital markets, it reduces opportunities for
accumulating human capital (such as education and health) and
physical assets. From a social welfare point of view, it has also been
argued that both utilitarian and nonutilitarian views of welfare sug-
gest that income inequality reduces aggregate well-being.3 These
considerations leave no doubt that inequality indeed matters, and
in this chapter I investigate which factors underlie the trends in
inequality observed in transitional economies.
There is a growing amount of research which attempts to explain
the rise in income inequality during the transition. Many existing
studies try to gure out the possible factors behind the changes in
the distribution of income using either theoretical models of transi-
tion (Aghion and Commander 1999; Ferreira 1999; Milanovic 1999)
or a Gini decomposition analysis (by income component or recipient)
applied to a single country or a set of countries (Garner and Terrell
1998; Milanovic 1999; Yemtsov 2001). Yet a third approach employs
cross-country regressions to examine why income inequality is dif-
ferent across countries at a given point in time (World Bank 2000).
This chapter represents the rst attempt to identify factors under-
lying the changes in income inequality over time within countries
Growth and Inequality 157
Figure 6.1
The dynamics of income inequality and GDP growth in transitional economies,
19891998
Source: Authors calculations using a constructed panel of inequality estimates and the
Real GDP index from the Trans/MONEE2000 database, UNICEF, Florence.
serves as a basis for the choice of variables used later in the empirical
analysis. Most of the factors that I consider are those commonly
found in the literature on the determinants of cross-country inequal-
ity, while others are specic to the transitional region circumstances
that I expect to be inuential in explaining the pattern of income
inequality.
The dynamics of income inequality and GDP growth in transitional economies of EE and the FSU
Avg. annual change Avg. annual change in
Real GDP index in the real GDP index the Gini index
Population (1989 100) (percentage points) (percentage points)
Region/ (mid-1997, at the bottom decline growth decline growth
country millions) of decline (year) in 1998 period period period period
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8
I. FSU
a. Baltic states
Estonia 1.5 60.76 (94) 75.70 7.85 3.74 3.31 0.65
Latvia 2.5 51.04 (95) 59.30 8.16 2.75 1.00 1.20
Lithuania 3.7 64.83 (94) 79.53 7.03 3.67 2.51 0.26
b. Western CIS
Belarus 10.2 62.69 (95) 77.75 6.22 5.02 0.31 0.44
Moldova 4.0 32.00 8.11 1.95
Russia 147.0 55.89 4.90 2.58
Ukraine 50.4 36.61 7.04 0.69
c. Caucasus
Armenia 3.8 31.63 (93) 41.68 15.29 2.08 8.42 0.40
Azerbaijan 7.8 41.86 (95) 49.40 9.69 2.51 2.05 0.33
Georgia 5.4 24.60 (94) 31.70 8.64 2.57
d. Central Asia
Kazakhstan 15.3 61.20 5.49 0.84
Kyrgyz Rep. 4.6 50.39 (95) 60.30 5.09 1.97
Tajikistan 6.0 39.19 (96) 41.90 6.44 1.69
Turkmenistan 4.6 41.99 (97) 43.75 6.25 1.04
Uzbekistan 23.6 83.36 (95) 89.50 3.18 0.48
Oleksiy Ivaschenko
II. Central EE
Czech Rep. 10.3 84.58 (92) 94.90 5.14 2.53 0.33 1.46
Hungary 10.2 81.89 (93) 95.20 4.53 2.66 0.32 0.52
Poland 38.7 82.21 (91) 117.15 5.22 5.47 0.34 1.33
Slovak Rep. 5.4 74.97 (93) 99.60 6.26 4.09 0.41 0.74
III. South EE
Bulgaria 8.3 63.69 (97) 65.90 4.54 1.27
Romania 22.6 74.99 (92) 82.08 8.34 3.30 0.63 1.37
Growth and Inequality
IV. FY
Croatia 4.7 59.54 (93) 77.70 10.11 3.65 0.35 1.36
Macedonia 2.0 67.99 (95) 71.50 5.34 0.79 0.60 0.41
Slovenia 2.0 82.04 (92) 103.90 5.99 3.66 0.37 0.40
Note: Dashes indicate data are not available.
Note: Dashes in columns means that by the end of 1998 a country under consideration continued to decline. South EE also includes Albania;
the former Yugoslavia (FY) also includes Yugoslavia, FR, and Bosnia-Herzegovina. These countries are not included in the table due to the lack
of data.
Sources: Authors calculations using a constructed panel of inequality estimates and the real GDP index and population data from the Trans-
MONEE2000 database, UNICEF, Florence.
161
162 Oleksiy Ivaschenko
the regressions in the natural log form. The natural log of (1 INFL/
100) is used for INFL variable in the estimations to deal with nega-
tive and very high values of INFL. The natural log of (1 UNEMP)
is used for UNEMP variable in the estimations since the unemploy-
ment rate equals zero for many countries at the start of the transi-
tion. A squared value of GDPPC (with GDPPC expressed in the
natural log form) is included into the regression to account for the
potential quadratic relationship between income inequality and per
capita GDP.
In view of the large body of literature exploring the effect of
income distribution on economic growth, one may be quick to point
out the possible problem with the given model specication arising
from the potential existence of a reverse causality between inequality
and growth. I argue that the transition economies of EE and the
FSU represent a unique case when the possibility of causality from
income distribution to economic growth can be ruled out, at least
for the period under investigation, since the reasons for the eco-
nomic collapse and subsequent recovery in the region had clearly
nothing to do with the distribution of income. This is conrmed by
the Granger causality tests (Granger 1969). I have tested whether
income inequality Granger-causes economic growth using from one
to ve lags, which provides 87 to 22 observations, respectively. In
none of the cases did the test statistic indicate that I could reject the
null hypothesis that the Gini coefcient does not Granger-cause per
capita GDP.22
I estimate equation (1) using the assembled panel for twenty-four
transitional countries covering a period from 1989 to 1998. The use of
panel data produces several well-known advantages. The most
important is that it allows one to control for unobservable time-
invariant country-specic effects that result in a missing-variable
bias, an often encountered problem when cross-section data are
used. This problem is recognized in Bourguignon and Morrison
(1998), Bruno, Ravallion, and Squire (1995), Deininger and Squire
(1998), Forbes (2000), Ravallion (1995), and other studies.
To control for unobservable country-specic characteristics I in-
troduce country-specic intercepts in the xed-effects model setting.
The addition of xed effects to the model also helps alleviate poten-
tial heteroscedasticity problems stemming from possible differences
across countries (Greene 1997).
Growth and Inequality 169
Third, it has been argued (Barro 1997, 37; Temple 1999) that the
xed-effects technique eliminates the cross-sectional information
and, hence, lowers precision of the estimates. This problem is, of
course, especially acute if most of the variation in the data is due to
cross-country differences. While in nontransition countries most
(approximately 90%) of the variation in inequality is due to variation
across countries (Deininger and Squire 1996; Li, Squire, and Zou
1998; Quah 2001), in transition countries a substantial source of
the variation in inequality over the last decade is attributable to the
profound changes in inequality over time (see table 6.A2). Hence, the
use of the xed-effects estimation for transitional countries seems to
be appropriate. In addition, if one bears in mind that inequality
comparisons across countries are likely to be much less reliable than
inequality comparisons for a single country over time, despite all
efforts to assemble the inequality estimates that are as consistent as
possible both across space and time, the reliance on mostly variation
over time in inequality is even desirable.
Given all considerations outlined here, I prefer to use the xed-
effects model since its advantages seem to outweigh its weaknesses
given the data and research purposes. Nevertheless, to check the
robustness of the results to the estimation technique the random-
effects model is also estimated. The empirical results are described
later in the chapter. The panel that I estimate is unbalanced as a
number of time-series observations differ across countries. However,
assuming that observations are missing randomly, consistency of the
xed-effects estimator is not affected. The xed-effects model is esti-
mated with OLS, which, given the assumed properties of residuals,
is the best linear unbiased estimator (Hsiao 1986).
I rst estimate a full version of equation (1) with both the log of
per capita GDP (GDPPC) and its squared value (GDPPC_S) included
among the explanatory variables. This allows capturing a potential
threshold effect in the relationship between income inequality and
per capita GDP.
It is worth noting that up to now most of the attempts to test for a
U-shaped relationship between income inequality and economic
development have used cross-sectional regressions. This approach
may be conceptually incorrect when studying the intertemporal rela-
Growth and Inequality 171
Table 6.2
Fixed-effects estimates from the regression of the Gini coefcient on selected explana-
tory variables: All countries
Reduced Reduced
Full model Full model model 1 model 2
Explanatory (quadratic (linear (quadratic (quadratic
variable relationship) relationship) relationship) relationship)
1 2 3 4 5
Intercept
GDPPC 4.190*** 0.157** 3.650*** 4.912***
(1.084) (0.063) (1.131) (1.208)
GDPPC_S 0.239*** 0.203*** 0.272***
(0.064) (0.067) (0.072)
INFL 0.033*** 0.034*** 0.024*
(0.013) (0.013) (0.013)
UNEMP 0.001 0.023 0.035* 0.086***
(0.021) (0.021) (0.020) (0.019)
CONSG 0.014 0.023 0.061 0.090*
(0.047) (0.050) (0.048) (0.052)
INDVA 0.288*** 0.350*** 0.375***
(0.072) (0.074) (0.073)
PRIVS 0.105*** 0.091***
(0.027) (0.028)
Number of 24 24 24 24
countries
Number of 129 129 129 129
observations
R 2 adj. 0.65 0.61 0.61 0.52
F-value 32.66 31.97 33.33 12.14
Estimated 6405 8015 8337
threshold level
(PPP-adjusted
GDP per capita,
1992 USD)
Note: All variables are in the natural log form. Standard errors are presented in
parentheses. The model is estimated in deviations from the group means. The Yule-
Walker (iterated) method was used to correct for serial correlation and hetero-
skedasticity.
* indicates signicance at 10 percent level; ** indicates signicance at 5 percent level;
*** indicates signicance at 1 percent level (two-tailed tests).
Growth and Inequality 173
United States (Meier 1973; Metcalf 1969; Thurow 1970). So, given
that economic decline in many transition countries reached an un-
precedented scale, the adverse changes in the distribution of income
are not surprising.
Ination is found to increase income inequality, although the esti-
mated coefcient in one of the specications turns out to be only
marginally signicant.30 The magnitude of the effect, however, does
not appear to be large. A 10 percent increase in ination would raise
inequality at the mean by at most 0.08 Gini points (see table 6.2). I
have also tested (using the LSDV specication) for a threshold effect
of ination as one would expect that it is only the ination above
a particular level that affects income distribution. Indeed, when I
include among the explanatory variables in equation (1) dummies
for ination levels instead of INFL, a clear threshold effect is appar-
ent. I nd (see column 2, table 6.3) that hyperination (annual CPI
exceeds 500 percent) is associated with a 9.5 percent higher income
inequality compared to the situation of the relative macroeconomic
stability (annual ination below 20 percent).
Unemployment rate does not seem to have an impact on inequal-
ity in the base model (see column 2, table 6.2). It is very likely, how-
ever, that the parameter estimate on unemployment is contaminated
due to a high correlation of the unemployment rate with other indi-
cators of structural changes, namely de-industrialization and priva-
tization (see table 6.A3). Indeed, when I eliminate PRIVS from the
estimation, the coefcient on UNEMP becomes positive and margin-
ally signicant (see column 4, table 6.2). Finally, when INDVA and
INFL are also omitted from the regression, the parameter estimate on
UNEMP becomes statistically signicant at a 1 percent level (see
column 5, table 6.2). The magnitude of the coefcient suggests that a
1 percentage point increase in the unemployment rate at the mean
would raise the Gini coefcient at the mean by 0.33 points.
The lack of robustness of the effect of unemployment on income
inequality may also be due to the following factors. First, a likely
inequality-increasing effect of growing unemployment can be coun-
terbalanced by an increasing ow of unemployment benets. Sec-
ond, it is also possible that the increase in between-groups inequality
stemming from larger unemployment could be offset by a more
equal distribution of income among transfer recipients (Milanovic
1999). Third, it has been argued that in developing countries the
unemployment statistics can in fact reect the extent of the informal
174 Oleksiy Ivaschenko
Table 6.3
Estimates from the regression of the Gini coefcient on selected explanatory variables:
All Countries
Model with Model with
ination Model Model war dummy
Explanatory dummy with CLI with IPF (pooled
variable (LSDV) (LSDV) (LSDV) regression)
1 2 3 4 5
Intercept 4.370***
(0.365)
GDPPC 3.834*** 2.993** 4.005***
(1.225) (1.217) (1.230)
GDPPC_S 0.216*** 0.162** 0.225***
(0.073) (0.073) (0.073)
Ination > 500 0.091** 0.106*** 0.089** 0.163***
dummya (0.038) (0.037) (0.038) (0.036)
UNEMP 0.007 0.014 0.003 0.002
(0.025) (0.025) (0.025) (0.022)
CONSG 0.035 0.044 0.045 0.049
(0.054) (0.051) (0.054) (0.046)
INDVA 0.242*** 0.199** 0.205** 0.360***
(0.081) (0.079) (0.086) (0.074)
PRIVS 0.098*** 0.020 0.097*** 0.117***
(0.032) (0.039) (0.032) (0.028)
CLI 0.034***
(0.011)
IPF 0.016
(0.013)
War dummy 0.125**
(0.050)
Number of 24 24 24 24
countries
Number of 129 129 129 129
observations
R 2 adj. 0.999 0.999 0.999 0.61
F-value 4290.35 4573.36 4194.15 15.73
Estimated 7255 10432 7293
threshold level
(PPP-adjusted
GDP per capita,
1992 USD)
Note: All variables are in the natural log form. Standard errors are presented in
parentheses. Yule-Walker (iterated) method was used to correct for serial correlation
and heteroskedasticity.
a excluded category is ination < 20 percent annual. The coefcients on other catego-
ries (2150, 51100, 101500) are not reported since they are not signicant.
* indicates signicance at 10 percent level; ** indicates signicance at 5 percent level;
*** indicates signicance at 1 percent level (two-tailed tests).
Growth and Inequality 175
Table 6.4
Fixed-effects estimates from the regression of the Gini coefcient on selected explana-
tory variables: Robustness to the denition of the dependent variable and the choice of
the data series
Table 6.5
Random-effects estimates from the regression of the Gini coefcient on selected
explanatory variables: All countries
Reduced Reduced
Full model Full model model 1 model 2
Explanatory (quadratic (linear (quadratic (quadratic
variable relationship) relationship) relationship) relationship)
1 2 3 4 5
Intercept 19.749*** 6.638*** 17.926*** 20.524***
(4.288) (0.464) (4.218) (4.682)
GDPPC 3.427*** 0.234*** 2.811*** 3.673***
(1.030) (0.046) (1.011) (1.115)
GDPPC_S 0.190*** 0.151*** 0.197***
(0.061) (0.060) (0.066)
INFL 0.027** 0.025* 0.021
(0.013) (0.014) (0.014)
UNEMP 0.003 0.017 0.027* 0.073***
(0.020) (0.020) (0.016) (0.016)
CONSG 0.036 0.057 0.080* 0.094*
(0.047) (0.048) (0.046) (0.052)
INDVA 0.312*** 0.352*** 0.389***
(0.073) (0.075) (0.071)
PRIVS 0.080*** 0.068**
(0.027) (0.028)
Number of 24 24 24 24
countries
Number of 129 129 129 129
observations
R 2 adj. 0.64 0.62 0.63 0.53
Estimated 8374 13422 11260
threshold level
(PPP-adjusted
GDP per capita,
1992 USD)
Note: All variables are in the natural log form. Standard errors are presented in
parentheses.
* indicates signicance at 10 percent level; ** indicates signicance at 5 percent level;
*** indicates signicance at 1 percent level (two-tailed tests).
Growth and Inequality 181
Table 6.6
Fixed-effects estimates from the regression of the Gini coefcient on selected explana-
tory variables: EE versus the FSU
Full model
FSU Full model Full model Full model
Explanatory (quadratic EE (quadratic FSU (linear EE (linear
variable relationship) relationship) relationship) relationship)
1 2 3 4 5
Intercept
GDPPC 2.766** 3.424 0.314*** 0.252***
(1.373) (2.679) (0.095) (0.089)
GDPPC_S 0.146* 0.212
(0.082) (0.154)
INFL 0.039** 0.031 0.039** 0.026
(0.019) (0.020) (0.019) (0.020)
UNEMP 0.014 0.047* 0.028 0.031
(0.042) (0.024) (0.042) (0.021)
CONSG 0.006 0.076 0.021 0.046
(0.072) (0.061) (0.073) (0.055)
INDVA 0.301** 0.233** 0.339** 0.203**
(0.127) (0.094) (0.129) (0.091)
PRIVS 0.060 0.100*** 0.044 0.118***
(0.051) (0.038) (0.041) (0.036)
Number of 15 9 15 9
countries
Number of 65 64 65 64
observations
R 2 adj. 0.72 0.67 0.70 0.65
F-value 20.83 20.11 22.88 21.99
Estimated
threshold level
(PPP-adjusted
GDP per capita,
1992 USD)
Note: All variables are in the natural log form. Standard errors are presented in
parentheses. The model is estimated in deviations from the group means. The Yule-
Walker (iterated) method was used to correct for serial correlation and hetero-
skedasticity.
* indicates signicance at 10 percent level; ** indicates signicance at 5 percent level;
*** indicates signicance at 1 percent level (two-tailed tests).
Growth and Inequality 183
Table 6.7
Estimates from the regression of the Gini coefcient on selected explanatory variables:
EE versus the FSU
Model Model
with war with war
Model Model dummy dummy
with CLI with CLI (pooled (pooled
Explanatory (LSDV) (LSDV) regression) regression)
variable FSU EE FSU EE
1 2 3 4 5
Intercept 4.440*** 4.510***
(0.488) (0.626)
GDPPC 0.386*** 0.243***
(0.105) (0.096)
Ination > 500 0.122** 0.006 0.208*** 0.026
dummya (0.059) (0.051) (0.047) (0.059)
UNEMP 0.050 0.001 0.005 0.047
(0.041) (0.025) (0.036) (0.031)
CONSG 0.082 0.046 0.024 0.209***
(0.084) (0.055) (0.078) (0.058)
INDVA 0.222* 0.201* 0.376*** 0.286**
(0.133) (0.103) (0.102) (0.136)
PRIVS 0.132*** 0.068*
(0.050) (0.040)
CLI 0.039*** 0.041***
(0.019) (0.008)
IPF
War dummy 0.112* 0.193***
(0.067) (0.061)
Number of 15 9 15 9
countries
Number of 65 64 65 64
observations
R 2 adj. 0.999 0.999 0.69 0.64
F-value 2705.14 8450.25 15.71 10.57
Estimated
threshold level
(PPP-adjusted
GDP per capita,
1992 USD)
Note: All variables are in the natural log form. Standard errors are presented in
parentheses. Yule-Walker (iterated) method was used to correct for serial correlation
and heteroskedasticity.
a excluded category is ination < 20 percent annual. The coefcients on other catego-
ries (2150, 51100, 101500) are not reported since they are not signicant.
* indicates signicance at 10 percent level; ** indicates signicance at 5 percent level;
*** indicates signicance at 1 percent level (two-tailed tests).
Growth and Inequality 185
6.8 Conclusions
The main goal of this chapter is to identify the factors that caused
dramatic changes in income inequality in the transitional countries
of EE and the FSU throughout the 1990s. The empirical analysis is
performed using a unique panel of inequality estimates that cover
twenty-four transitional countries over the period 19891998. The
econometric approach employs panel data estimation methods.
I nd support for a normal U-shaped relationship between income
inequality and per capita GDP for the transitional region as a whole.
It suggests that for a country below (above) some threshold level
of development economic growth is associated with falling (rising)
income inequality. Specically, the relationship between income in-
equality and economic growth is shown to be negative for coun-
tries of EE, but positive for those of the FSU. The results suggest that
economic recovery-promoting policies may certainly have an equal-
izing effect on income distribution in some transition countries.
However, at least in the short run, there can be a trade-off between
economic growth and income inequality in other countries.
Although undoubtedly important, the relationship between in-
come inequality and economic growth does not represent the main
focus of this study. I have searched for specic economic factors and
noneconomic forces that determine the changes in income distribu-
tion during the transition.
The empirical results indicate that economic liberalization and
structural adjustments are associated with rising income inequality.
More specically, I nd that a 10 percent increase in the CLI at the
mean is associated with a 0.27 and 0.34 percentage point increase in
the Gini coefcient at the region-specic means in the FSU and EE
countries, respectively. De-industrialization has a strong impact on
income distribution in both regions. A 10 percent decline in the share
186 Oleksiy Ivaschenko
Table 6.A1
Description of the Inequality Data Used in the Empirical Analysis
No. Gini Gini Max. Area/ Sample/
Region/ of index index value Welfare population reference Source
country Start End obs. (start) (end) (year) measure coverage unit (year)
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 12
I. FSU
a. Baltic states
Estonia 1989 1998 9 23.00 36.97 36.97 (98) DI, GI (90) All/All HH/HH pc WIID, BM (89)
Latvia 1989 1998 5 22.50 32.10 32.60 (97) DI, GI (89) All/All HH/HH pc WIID, BM (89)
Lithuania 1989 1999 6 22.50 34.00 35.04 (94) DI, GI (89) All/All HH/HH pc WIID, BM (89),
WB (99)
b. Western CIS
Belarus 1989 1999 5 22.80 26.00 26.00 (99) DI, GI (89) All/All HH/HH pc WIID, BM (89),
WB (99)
Moldova 1993 1997 2 36.50 42.00 42.00 (97) DI, GI (93) All/All HH/HH pc BM (93), WB (97)
Russia 1989 1996 5 23.80 37.83 37.83 (96) GI All/All HH/HH pc WIID, BM (89)
Ukraine 1989 1999 6 25.80 32.00 32.00 (99) DI, GI (97) All/All HH/HH pc WIID, WB (99)
c. Caucasus
Armenia 1990 1998 6 26.90 59.00 62.14 (95) DI, GI (90) All/All HH/HH pc WIID, WB (98)
Azerbaijan 1995 1999 2 44.00 43.00 44.00 (95) CS All/All HH/HH pc WB
Georgia 1989 1997 4 31.30 51.86 58.71 (96) DI, GI (88, 90) All/All HH/HH pc WIID
Oleksiy Ivaschenko
d. Central Asia
Kazakhstan 1990 1996 4 29.70 35.00 35.00 (96) DI, GI (90, 93) All/All HH/HH pc WIID, WB (96)
Kyrgyz Republic 1990 1997 3 30.80 47.00 55.30 (93) DI, GI (90) All/All HH/HH pc WIID, BM (93),
WB (97)
Tajikistan 1989 1990 2 31.80 33.40 33.40 (90) GI All/All HH/HH pc WIID
Turkmenistan 1989 1993 3 31.60 35.80 35.80 (93) DI, GI (89, 90) All/All HH/HH pc WIID
Uzbekistan 1990 1994 3 31.50 33.00 33.30 (93) DI, GI (90, 94) All/All HH/HH pc WIID
II. Central EE
Czech Republic 1989 1997 9 19.36 27.64 28.14 (96) DI All/All HH/HH pc WIID
Growth and Inequality
Hungary 1989 1997 7 21.41 24.58 24.58 (97) DI All/All HH/HH pc WIID
Poland 1989 1998 9 25.05 32.00 34.20 (97) DI All/All HH/HH pc WIID, WB (98)
Slovak Rep. 1989 1997 9 18.06 23.36 24.83 (96) DI All/All HH/HH pc WIID
III. South EE
Bulgaria 1989 1997 8 24.47 34.59 34.78 (96) DI, GI (89, 91) All/All HH/HH pc, WIID
HH (89, 98)
Romania 1989 1997 9 23.24 30.27 31.18 (95) DI All/All HH/HH pc WIID
IV. FY
Croatia 1989 1998 4 25.10 33.30 33.30 (98) DI All/All HH/HH pc WIID
Macedonia 1990 1997 5 34.90 36.65 36.94 (96) DI All/All HH/HH pc WIID
Slovenia 1991 1998 4 22.71 25.00 25.05 (93) DI All/All HH/HH pc WIID, WB (98)
189
Sources: UNU/WIDER-UNDP World Income Inequality Database, Version 1.0, September 12, 2000, provides further reference on the source
190
and estimation methodology for each data point drawn from this database. The data by Branko Milanovic are from appendix 4, The Original
Income Distribution Statistics, in his book Income, Inequality and Poverty during the Transition from Planned to Market Economy (1998). The data
by the World Bank are taken from appendix D, Poverty and Inequality Tables, in the book Making Transition Work for Everyone: Poverty and
Inequality in Europe and Central Asia (World Bank 2000).
Note: Disposable income (DI) is equal to gross income (GI) minus payroll and direct personal income taxes (PIT). Gross income consists of earn-
ings from labor, cash social transfers, self-employment income, other income (gifts, income from property) and in-kind consumption (e.g.,
agricultural products grown on a households plot of land). It is argued (Milanovic 1998) that the difference between gross and disposable
incomes is negligible for transition countries (especially for the pretransition period) as gross income already excludes payroll taxes withdrawn
at the source, and PIT is minimal (less than one percent of gross income). That allows one to use the Gini coefcients based on gross incomes as
the benchmarks for the levels of income inequality observed before the transition (mostly for the FSU countries, for which the pretransition
disposable income Gini indexes are not available). It is very important to have these pretransition observations in the sample since the evidence
suggests that most of the variation in income inequality over time has taken place over the initial period of transition and economic collapse.
As the rst transition period surveys were often conducted a few years into the transition process, by taking the estimates of inequality derived
solely from these surveys one would signicantly underestimate the changes in inequality over time (which is what I want to explain).
The Gini coefcients for Romania and Macedonia are based on disposable monetary income, which does not include in-kind consumption.
These Gini coefcients are likely to overestimate the levels of inequality, but not the changes in inequality. Note that two data points (Azerbai-
jan, 1995, 1999) are Gini coefcients based on consumption (CS). These observations are used due to the lack of alternatives. They are not found
to inuence the overall results. The Gini index for 1988 is used in the absence of 1989 data.
The data coming from the Family Budget Surveys (FBS) (mostly 1989 data in our sample) are not completely representative and may
underestimate inequality as FBS excluded pensioner-headed households and households headed by the unemployed. However, the estimates
of inequality obtained from transition-year surveys can also be downward-biased due to decreased response rates among the rich, inadequate
coverage of informal sector incomes, etc. (for a detailed discussion of these and other data issues see Milanovic 1998). It is not clear, though,
how all these biases would, on the net, affect the changes in inequality. In any case, there is not much that one can do about these sorts of
problems except trying to use observations that are as fully consistent as possible (Atkinson and Brandolini 2001). That was a guiding prin-
ciple in the compilation of the data.
Oleksiy Ivaschenko
Growth and Inequality 191
Table 6.A2
Descriptive Statistics and Variance Decomposition
Std. Dev.
Variable Mean Min Max Overall Between Within
Notes
1. In many countries of the FSU the outputs declined to 3040 percent of their pre-
transition levels.
2. A number of recent studies (e.g., Forbes 2000) suggest, however, that in the short
run the relationship between inequality and growth could be positive.
3. Grun and Klasen (2001) applied a set of inequality-adjusted indicators of well-being
to measure aggregate welfare in transition countries. They found that an adjustment
for inequality signicantly inuences the ranking of transition countries in terms of
their absolute levels of well-being and the achievements in well-being over time.
4. In our sample, the mean annual ination is 248 percent, and the maximum is 9,750
percent (Turkmenistan 1993).
5. The regressivity of the ination tax and imperfect indexation have been found,
using micro-level data, to increase income inequality in Brazil during the years of high
ination (Ferreira and Litcheld 1998).
6. The ofcial unemployment statistics are likely to signicantly understate the real
level of unemployment. Indeed, unofcial estimates indicate signicantly higher levels
of unemployment. Moreover, many people are registered as employed even when
they are not receiving payment for their labor.
7. Government consumption, however, can affect the distribution of income not only
on the expenditure side, but also through the tax collection.
13. About half of the WIID database is formed by K. Deininger and L. Squires 1996
database. However, for the transitional region most of the data in the database come
from the UNICEF/IRC TransMonee2000 Database, Florence.
14. In the original WIID database most of the countries are represented with multiple
time series of inequality estimates that often are not compatible.
15. As there are only ve observations for 1999, in the estimation they are used as
1998 values.
16. This is true, however, only if these differences are systematic. I am thankful to a
referee for pointing this out to me.
17. As a check of how good this proxy is, I estimate the model with the industrial
employment variable as well. The results (discussed in what follows) indicate that
industry value added is a very good proxy indeed.
18. The data are updated up to 1998.
19. The assumption is that the effect of civil conict (if any) on income inequality is
likely to persist for a certain period.
20. In the case of Russia, I refer to the military conict in Chechnya.
23. H0 is that there is no correlation. The test statistic is distributed as Xk2 , where k
denotes the dimension of the slope vector b (Baltagi 1995, 68).
24. The random effects estimator combines the within and between estimators, thus
giving some weight to the cross-country variation.
25. F-test of the null hypothesis that country-specic effects are not signicant yields
an F-value of 6.14, which is higher than a critical value of 2.07. This means that I can
reject the hypothesis that there are no country-specic effects of omitted variables. The
same test was conducted for time effects. In this case the F9;88 statistic was 2.10, indi-
cating that it is not possible to reject the hypothesis of no time-specic effects. Hence,
the use of the one-way model is appropriate.
26. Specifying the original formulation of equation (1) as yit a i b 0 Xit eit , the for-
mulation in terms of deviations from the country means becomes:
yit yi b 0 Xit Xi eit ei ; where yi Syit =t; Xi SXit =t; ei Seit =t:
27. I note here that the test of multicollinearity for the linear model indicates that the
highest condition index equals 4.17, which is below a cutoff point of 10 suggested in
the literature. Hence, I do not have a problem of severe collinearity in the estimation of
the model.
28. To detect outliers and inuential cases, I have conducted inuence diagnostics
such as the studentized residuals, the hat matrix, the COVRATIO statistic, DFFITS,
and DFBETAS (Belsley, Kuh, and Welsch 1980; Bollen and Jackman 1985). I then
deleted those observations that were detected inuential by at least three tests. These
observations turned out to be Moldova (1990), Russia (1998), Tajikistan (1998), and
Uzbekistan (1989). However, when the model is estimated with these outliers included
the results are very similar to those reported in table 6.2.
Growth and Inequality 195
29. I have also estimated the model with GDPPC and GDPPC_S being the only
explanatory variables. The parameter estimates (not shown here) on both terms are
statistically signicant at 1 percent and 5 percent levels respectively (negative for
GDPPC and positive for GDPPC_S). The F-test statistics for their joint signicance is
45.71 (signicant at a 1% level). Adjusted R 2 for the model is equal to 0.46.
30. The recent study by the World Bank (2000) has found that ination volatility is also
associated with distributional costs in the transitional region.
31. Unemployment data can also be a poor indicator of labor market conditions since
in many transition countries adjustments in the labor market manifested themselves in
underemployment and nonpayment of wages rather than in the shedding of labor.
32. I note that when the model is estimated using the available observations on the
industrial sector employment as a share of total employment (100 observations, 23
countries), instead of those on INDVA, the parameter estimate is nearly identical to
the one on INDVA reported in table 6.2. These estimation results are not reported here
for brevity.
33. This nding is in contrast to that reported in the World Bank (2000), where they
use the same reform index as I do, but a smaller sample of countries (20) and a differ-
ent estimation technique (a pooled regression rather than xed effects).
34. Note that the higher value of the IPF means fewer political rights and civil
liberties.
35. The xed effects model cannot be estimated in this setting. Thus I perform a
pooled regression. A pooled regression refers to an OLS regression with a single
overall intercept.
36. The civil war dummy remains signicant at a 5 percent level even when GDPPC
and GDPPC_S enter the regression. The estimated effect, however, is slightly lower in
this case than the one reported.
37. Note that the estimation of the model in deviations from the country means
requires that the Gini coefcients are as comparable as possible within countries over
time but not necessarily across countries. For this reason, the use of consumption-
based Gini coefcients for Azerbaijan (see table 6.A1) does not cause a problem since
like is compared with like. The same applies to the disposable monetary income Gini
coefcients for Romania and Macedonia.
38. Unfortunately, I cannot test the robustness of our ndings to the use of alternative
measures of inequality, as only the Gini coefcients are available.
39. One may not conclude here on the quality of different data series, though, as the
changes in the parameter estimates could be driven by exclusion of the observations
for particular countries and/or time periods.
40. The comparison category is Gini coefcient based on the household per capita
disposable income.
41. These results are not shown here but are available from the author upon request.
42. I do not have sufcient longitudinal data on the levels of corruption in transitional
countries to run the xed effects regression. However, a simple regression of the
average Gini coefcient during the transition period on the corruption perception
index for sixteen transition countries of EE and the FSU indicates that higher corrup-
tion is associated with larger income inequality (the parameter estimate is signicant
196 Oleksiy Ivaschenko
at a 7% level). The regression results are not shown here but are available from the
author upon request.
43. This is reected in the composition of our sample, where the majority of observa-
tions for the FSU and EE countries cover the periods of economic decline and eco-
nomic recovery, respectively.
44. The results are not reported here but are available from the author upon request.
I have also estimated several alternative specications with IPF, but the parameter
estimate on IPF is found to be insignicant.
References
Aghion, P., and S. Commander. 1999. On the Dynamics of Inequality in the Transi-
tion. Economics of Transition 7(2): 275298.
Ahluwalia, M. S. 1976. Income Distribution and Development: Some Stylized Facts.
American Economic Review 66: 125135.
Alesina, A., and D. Rodrik. 1994. Distributive Politics and Economic Growth. Quar-
terly Journal of Economics 109(2): 465490.
Atkinson, A., and A. Brandolini. 2001. Promise and Pitfalls in the Use of Secondary
Data Sets: Income Inequality in OECD Countries as a Case Study. Journal of Economic
Literature 39(2): 771799.
Atkinson, A., and J. Micklewright. 1992. Economic Transformation in Eastern Europe and
the Distribution of Income. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Baltagi, B. H. 1995. Econometric Analysis of Panel Data. West Sussex, UK: John Wiley
and Sons Ltd.
Barro, R. J. 1997. Determinants of Economic Growth: A Cross-Country Empirical Study.
Cambridge: The MIT Press.
Belsley, D., E. Kuh, and R. E. Welsch. 1980. Regression Diagnostics: Identifying Inuential
Data and Sources of Collinearity. New York: Wiley.
Birdsall, N., D. Ross, and R. Sabot. 1995. Inequality and Growth Reconsidered: Les-
sons from East Asia. The World Bank Economics Review 9(3): 477508.
Bollen, K. A., and R. W. Jackman. 1985. Regression Diagnostics: An Expository
Treatment of Outliers and Inuential Cases. Sociological Methods and Research 13:
510542.
Bourguignon, F., and C. Morrison. 1998. Inequality and Development: The Role of
Dualism. Journal of Development Economics 57: 233257.
Boyd, R. L. 1988. Government Involvement in the Economy and the Distribution of
Income: A Cross-National Study. Population Research and Policy Review 7: 223238.
Bruno, M., M. Ravallion, and L. Squire. 1995. Equity and Growth in Developing
Countries: Old and New Perspectives on the Policy Issues. Paper prepared for the
IMF Conference on Income Distribution and Sustainable Growth, Washington, DC.
Growth and Inequality 197
Deininger, K., and L. Squire. 1996. A New Data Set Measuring Income Inequality.
World Bank Economic Review 10(3): 565591.
Deininger, K., and L. Squire. 1998. New Ways of Looking at Old Issues: Inequality
and Growth. Journal of Development Economics 57: 259287.
De Melo, M., C. Denizer, and A. Gelb. 1996. From Plan to Market: Patterns of Tran-
sition. The World Bank Policy Research Paper No. 1564. Washington, DC.
Easterly, W. 2001. The Middle Class Consensus and Economic Development. The
World Bank Development Research Group Working Paper No. 2346. Washington, DC.
European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD). Various years. Transition
Report.
Ferreira, F. H. G. 1999. Economic Transition and the Distributions of Income and
Wealth. Economics of Transition 7(2): 377410.
Ferreira, F. H. G., and J. Litcheld. 1998. The Roles of Structural Factors and Macro-
economic Instability in Explaining Brazilian Inequality in the 1980s. LSE Discussion
Paper No. DARP 41.
Forbes, K. J. 2000. A Reassessment of the Relationship between Inequality and
Growth. American Economic Review 90(4): 869887.
Freedom House. Index of Political Freedom. Available online at hwww.freedomhouse.
orgi.
Garner, T. I., and K. Terrell. 1998. A Gini Decomposition Analysis of Inequality in the
Czech and Slovak Republics during the Transition. Economics of Transition 6(1): 2346.
Gradstein, M., B. Milanovic, and Y. Ying. 2001. Democracy and Income Inequality:
An Empirical Analysis. The World Bank Development Research Group Working
Paper No. 2561. Washington, DC.
Levy, F., and R. J. Murnane. 1992. U.S. Earnings Levels and Earnings Inequality: A
Review of Recent Trends and Proposed Explanations. Journal of Economic Literature
30: 13331381.
Li, H., L. Squire, and H. Zou. 1998. Explaining International and Intertemporal Vari-
ations in Income Inequality. Economic Journal 108: 118.
Meier, T. 1973. The Distributional Impact of the 1970 Recession. Review of Economics
and Statistics 55: 214224.
Metcalf, C. 1969. The Size Distribution of Personal Income during the Business
Cycle. American Economic Review 59: 657668.
Rodrik, D. 1999. Democracies Pay Higher Wages. Quarterly Journal of Economics 114:
707738.
Gunther Rehme
7.1 Introduction
All agents act price-takingly and have logarithmic utility. (In the
rest of the chapter, time subscripts are dropped for convenience.)
The low-skilled do not invest and consume their entire wage and
transfer income. Thus, their intertemporal utility is given by
y 1n
cl 1 rt K
e dt where cl wl fr : 7:4
0 1 n Ll
In contrast, the high-skilled own all the assets that are collateralized
one-to-one by capital. A representative high-skilled agent takes the
paths of r, wh , wl , Q as given and solves
y 1n
ch 1 rt
max e dt 7:5a
ch 0 1n
c_h 1 Qr r
g1 ; 7:6
ch n
The return on capital is constant over time and wages grow with the
capital stock. Note that wl t does not directly depend on x. It only
does so indirectly through kt and so gx when t 0 0. See, for exam-
ple, Johnson (1984).
As wh wl 1 bx a1 , high-skilled labor receives a premium over
what their low-skilled counterpart gets, regardless of whether high-
skilled labor is taken as scarce or not. This reects that the high-
skilled may always (perfectly) substitute for low-skilled labor so that
both types of labor receive the same wage wl for routine tasks and
that performing high-skilled tasks is remunerated by the additional
amount wl bx a1 .
The wage premium depends on the percentage of high-skilled
labor in the population, grows over time at the rate g, and is
decreasing in x for a given capital stock.10 On the other hand the
(relative) wage premium wh =wl increases when production is getting
more (high-)skill biased (higher b).11
From the production function gy gk so that for given x per capita
output and the capital-labor ratio grow at the same rate. With con-
stant N and x total output also grows at the same rate as the aggre-
gate capital stock. From (7.6) the consumption of the representative
high-skilled agent grows at g.
Each high-skilled worker owns kh0 K0 =Lh units of the initial
capital stock. Equation (7.5b) implies k_h wh 1 Qrkh ch so that
gkh wh ch =kh 1 Qr where 1 Qr is constant. In steady
state, gkh gk is constant by denition. But wi =k, i h; l is constant as
well, because
wh aAkt 1 bx a1 wl
aA1 bx a1 and aA;
kt kt kt
1 cx 1= f1 aA1 bx a r
g ; 7:7
n
which is rst increasing and then decreasing, that is, concave in x.12
208 Gunther Rehme
g wlt 1 x a1 x
sl 1 g ; 7:8a
mt 1 bx a
wlt 1 x frkt a1 x f1 a1 bx a
sln 1 ; 7:8b
mtn 1 bx a 1 1 acx 1=
where use has been made of t cx 1= . The corresponding Lorenz
curve (LC), which relates cumulative population shares to cu-
mulative income shares, is presented in gure 7.1. The LC has
a kink at the point A at which 1 x percent of the population
receive sl percent of total income. The Gini coefcient is then calcu-
lated as
1 xsl 1 sl x
G12 xsl 1 sl x;
2 2
(Re-)Distribution of Personal Incomes 209
Figure 7.1
Ordinary Lorenz curve
Table 7.1
Numerical simulation
x Gg Gn P g t
0.10 0.386 0.342 0.044 0.0195 0.027
0.15 0.392 0.345 0.047 0.0201 0.054
0.20 0.390 0.339 0.051 0.0202 0.089
0.25 0.382 0.327 0.056 0.0200 0.131
0.30 0.370 0.310 0.059 0.0194 0.179
Note: Parameter values: a 0:7, b 1:13, c 1:43, 0:58, f 0:13, n 3:55, r 0:01.
7.3.2 Findings
coefcient for net income goes up from 31.46 in 1974 to 37.24 in 1997.
On the other hand, redistribution (RE) goes up from 3.59 in 1974 to
4.57 in 1997. Thus, policy in the United States has corrected slightly
increasingly for some of the increase in pre-tax inequality. A similar
picture holds for the United Kingdom so that higher inequality in
pre-tax incomes often seems to be associated with more redistribu-
tion within countries over time.
Sweden has low pre-tax inequality that fell over the period (1967:
32.05; 1995: 26.2). It reduced redistribution from 6 in 1967 to 4.2 in
1995. Thus, Sweden and the United States have very different pre-tax
income inequality, but redistribute approximately the same. On
period averages the United States redistributes more (RE: 4.4) than,
for example, Germany (RE: 3.7), France (RE: 2.49) or Canada (RE:
3.4). All the latter countries have lower pre-tax inequality than the
United States.
Clearly, growth of GDP per capita should be controlled for by
many factors. This is done here by means of simple growth regres-
sions and by focusing on parsimonious models. Following a common
procedure, a benchmark model with often used robust regressors
is used to add education and distributional variables to see what
the latter contribute to the explanation of long-run growth across
countries.
The benchmark model used here for i countries is gi a
b 1 LY70i b 2 LAFERTi b3 CVLIBi i , where LY70 denotes the (nat-
ural) logarithm of GDP per capita in 1970, LAFERT represents the
logarithm of the average fertility rate for the period 19601984,
CVLIB is Gastils index of civil liberties (from 1 to 7; 1 most
freedom) for the period 19721989, and i is a disturbance term.
According to the estimated coefcients, CVLIB does not really add to
the explanation of growth and is dropped in the subsequent anal-
ysis, because it is not the main variable of interest.18
In table 7.2 model (1) is the reduced benchmark model. In all
models the estimated coefcient on LY70 is always negative and that
on fertility (LAFERT) is negative in ten out of the sixteen models.
The estimates then suggest the following.
The association between the human capital as well as the dis-
tributional variables and growth is not very strong. Most of the
coefcients on these variables are statistically insignicant. However,
even small effects may have important and economically signicant
consequences in the long run.19
214 Gunther Rehme
Table 7.2
Growth regressions
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7)
Const. 23.225 23.375 16.656 16.374 23.008 24.755 22.129
(6.344) (5.209) (5.959) (6.198) (5.708) (6.867) (8.886)
[0.004] [0.001] [0.023] [0.030] [0.004] [0.006] [0.038]
LY70 2.262 2.587 1.825 1.844 2.563 2.449 2.121
(0.638) (0.541) (0.641) (0.649) (0.580) (0.707) (0.985)
[0.005] [0.001] [0.021] [0.022] [0.002] [0.007] [0.064]
LAFERT 0.534 0.407 2.413 2.253 0.434 0.656 0.025
(0.905) (0.840) (1.340) (1.306) (0.894) (0.945) (1.681)
[0.568] [0.639] [0.109] [0.123] [0.640] [0.506] [0.988]
SECP 0.029 0.036 0.036 0.030
(0.012) (0.011) (0.012) (0.013)
[0.039] [0.014] [0.015] [0.049]
TERP 0.019 0.018
(0.027) (0.028)
[0.501] [0.535]
GEDU
Note: The dependent variable is the average growth rate of real GDP per capita over
the period 19701990. The estimation method is OLS. Standard errors are shown in
parentheses and t-probabilities are reported in square brackets.
Table 7.2
(continued)
(8) (9) (10) (11) (12) (13) (14) (15) (16)
22.954 25.886 22.403 21.092 22.102 22.972 20.497 20.911 23.334
(9.439) (7.857) (6.585) (8.665) (9.062) (7.091) (8.241) (8.469) (6.931)
[0.041] [0.011] [0.008] [0.041] [0.041] [0.012] [0.034] [0.036] [0.008]
2.236 2.554 2.235 2.059 2.196 2.287 0.183 1.990 2.270
(1.032) (0.797) (0.653) (0.978) (1.015) (0.702) (1.609) (0.910) (0.687)
[0.062] [0.013] [0.008] [0.069] [0.063] [0.012] [0.912] [0.057] [0.009]
0.266 0.712 0.424 0.061 0.352 0.425 0.183 0.009 0.538
(1.644) (1.006) (0.938) (1.740) (1.703) (0.987) (1.609) (1.528) (0.956)
[0.875] [0.499] [0.662] [0.973] [0.842] [0.678] [0.912] [0.996] [0.587]
0.017 0.024
(0.029) (0.031)
[0.569] [0.470]
0.086 0.071 0.082 0.106
(0.116) (0.135) (0.146) (0.133)
[0.477] [0.611] [0.590] [0.449]
0.017 0.031
(0.065) (0.057)
[0.810] [0.596]
0.016 0.003 0.022
(0.053) (0.063) (0.051)
[0.773] [0.960] [0.672]
0.050 0.051 0.007
(0.139) (0.137) (0.123)
[0.724] [0.719] [0.954]
0.664 0.666 0.663 0.665 0.663 0.668 0.654 0.650 0.642
13 13 13 13 13 13 13 13 13
Determinants of inequality
Dependent (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)
variable LIS.G LIS.G LIS.G LIS.N LIS.N LIS.N RE RE RE
Const. 87.562 79.199 43.246 104.390 92.394 59.485 14.814 11.109 13.734
(36.683) (35.545) (42.709) (41.330) (37.240) (45.991) (17.153) (16.805) (22.422)
[0.038] [0.053] [0.341] [0.030] [0.035] [0.232] [0.408] [0.525] [0.557]
LY70 10.903 10.627 7.789 12.268 11.872 9.275 1.158 1.035 1.243
(3.687) (3.527) (3.939) (4.154) (3.695) (4.241) (1.724) (1.668) (2.068)
[0.014] [0.015] [0.083] [0.014] [0.011] [0.060] [0.517] [0.550] [0.565]
LAFERT 23.036 21.910 18.214 23.728 22.114 18.730 0.525 0.026 0.296
(5.236) (5.066) (5.519) (5.899) (5.307) (5.943) (2.448) (2.395) (2.897)
[0.001] [0.002] [0.011] [0.002] [0.002] [0.014] [0.835] [0.992] [0.921]
CVLIB 3.163 2.896 0.231
(2.289) (2.465) (1.202)
[0.204] [0.274] [0.852]
GEDU 0.876 1.438 1.256 1.771 0.388 0.347
(0.626) (0.722) (0.655) (0.777) (0.296) (0.379)
[0.195] [0.081] [0.088] [0.052] [0.222] [0.387]
R2 0.660 0.720 0.774 0.620 0.730 0.770 0.051 0.204 0.207
Obs. 13 13 13 13 13 13 13 13 13
Note: Estimation by OLS. Standard errors in parentheses and t-probabilities in square brackets.
Gunther Rehme
(Re-)Distribution of Personal Incomes 219
In terms of the model this suggests that c and may not be inde-
pendent of one another. Furthermore, one may argue that they are
also related to b. For instance, Walde (2000) shows that the structure
of education systems (elitist vs. egalitarian) may inuence the skill
intensity in production. In that sense the estimates here would sup-
port such an argument.
Notes
I am grateful for helpful comments made by Theo Eicher, Danny Quah, Cecilia Garca-
Penalosa, and the participants at the conference Growth and Inequality: Issues and
Policy Implications at CESifo, Munich, and Schloss Elmau, Bavaria, in 2001/2, and the
220 Gunther Rehme
9. Here the assumption is that regardless of the source of new ideas or blueprints
production is undertaken so that all agents are affected relatively equally from
knowledge spillovers. The results would not change if the externality depended on the
entire capital stock instead.
10. On this see, for instance, Bound and Johnson (1992), Katz and Murphy (1992), or
Autor, Krueger, and Katz (1998).
11. The idea that skill-biased technological change within rms with its corresponding
demand for high-skilled labor and the (education systems) supply of high-skilled
people are in a run determining wage inequality over time can, e.g., be found in
Tinbergen (1975).
12. This follows because dg=dx 1=nD1 D2 , where D1 c=x 1=1 1 a
A1 bx a and D2 1 cx 1= f1 aAabx a1 . For x ! 0 we have dg=dx y.
When x ! 1 we have dg=dx 1=c1 aA1 b 1 cf1 aAab < 0. Fur-
thermore, dD1 =dx > 0 and dD2 =dx < 0 imply d 2 g=dx 2 < 0. These properties capture that
expanding education may lead to lower growth under some especially congestive cir-
cumstances. See, for example, Temple (1999, 140).
13. In an economy with income growth such as the one modelled here this property of
the Gini coefcients often follows by construction. See Fields (1987) or Amiel and
Cowell (1999).
14. Recall that the result is conditional on (observable) x. Given that policy may react
to a change in fundamentals there is nothing to preclude the possibility that a change
in them produces different effects in total. Notice also that the result applies only when
income inequality is measured by the Gini coefcient. For instance, a higher may
increase income inequality (given t) when measuring it by the concept of Generalized
Lorenz Curve Dominance. See Shorrocks (1983). Thus, the results depend on which
measurement concept one uses.
15. See OECD (1998), Table A1.2A.
16. For a critical assessment of other frequently employed data sources measuring
human capital see de la Fuente and Domenech (2000).
17. As a sensitivity check, I have also used data from the World Income Inequality
Database (WIID) in Helsinki and found that the papers results are robust for samples
with more countries when using slightly less rigorous consistency requirements. These
results are available on request.
18. The estimate for b 3 was 0.082 with a standard error of 0.378 and a t-probability of
0.832.
19. Bearing in mind that due to the consistency requirement the sample size is small
and although given statistical insignicance the focus of this chapter is on the point
estimates and their economic signicance, but not on inferential statistics. On the dis-
tinction between statistical and economic signicance see, for example, McCloskey
(1985) or McCloskey and Ziliak (1996).
222 Gunther Rehme
20. Suppose one mixes Gini coefcients for net and gross incomes to get an unadjusted
inequality index I, which is then used in growth regressions.
g
The model really run: giu a bGi cGin i ;
g
The model run: giu a 0 bi0 IGi ; Gin i0 ;
where giu is the residual of the regression of gi on a vector of control variables. For
simplicity assume that the control variables are not correlated or even orthogonal to
the distributional variables. Commonly giu is called the unexplained part of the growth
rate. The latter is attempted to be explained by I in the models above. In general,
g
Gi Gin RiA for country i. This is true by the denition of RiA as a measure of redis-
g
tribution. Not every observation in Gi may necessarily have a corresponding match-
ing value of Gi in the data set. However, values of Gin are included by many NCV
n
proponents in order to boost the number of observations. Now what is basically done
g g g ~ A where G~ g and R
is to create Ii Gi Gin . But this means Ii Gi G~i R i i
~ A may be
i
g
unknown if there is no matching value for Gi available in the data set. This implies
that their estimate for b 0 , call it ^b 0 , would contain information of the distribution of
gross incomes, but also information on redistribution. Thus, the model they run is
g g
giu a bGi cG~i cR
~ A i which puts a restriction on the effect that R
i
~ A exerts.
i
g
Relaxing it and noting that G~i and R ~ A are unknown, when there are no matching
i
g
values in Gi , the regression is really run on values of known Gini coefcients for gross
incomes, some unknown Gini values for gross income, and some unknown values for
redistribution. But consequently their true model is
g g
g u a bG cG~ dR
i i i
~ A i ;
i
where d c. But this suggests the following argument: The estimates for b and c
have often been found to be negative in earlier contributions. Furthermore, there is an
empirical literature that shows that the estimate for d is likely to be positive. Thus, one
has an upward bias for the estimate of b 0 . This bias may be so strong that one may
even get a positive estimate for b 0 b c d, that is, b^0 b 0 is compatible with b^ < 0,
c^ < 0 and d^ > 0.
References
Atkinson, A. B., and A. Brandolini. 2001. Promise and pitfalls in the use of second-
ary data-sets: Income inequality in OECD countries as a case study. Journal of Eco-
nomic Literature 39: 771799.
Autor, D., A. Krueger, and L. Katz. 1998. Computing inequality: Have computers
changed the labour market. Quarterly Journal of Economics 63: 11691213.
Banerjee, A. V., and E. Duo. 2000. Inequality and growth: What can the data say?
Working Paper 7793, NBER.
Barro, R. J. 1997. Determinants of Economic Growth: A Cross-Country Empirical Study.
Cambridge: The MIT Press.
Barro, R. J., and J.-W. Lee. 1994. Sources of economic growth. Carnegie Rochester Con-
ference Series on Public Policy 40: 146.
Benabou, R. 1996. Inequality and growth. In NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1996, ed. B.
S. Bernanke and J. J. Rotemberg, 1173. Cambridge: The MIT Press.
Bertola, G. 2000. Macroeconomics of distribution and growth. In Handbook of Income
Distribution, vol. 1, ed. A. B. Atkinson and F. Bourguignon, 477540. Amsterdam:
Elsevier.
Bound, J., and G. Johnson. 1992. Changes in the structure of wages in the 1980s: An
evaluation of alternative explanations. American Economic Review 82: 371392.
Caselli, F. 1999. Technological revolutions. American Economic Review 89: 78102.
Caselli, F., G. Esquivel, and F. Lefort. 1996. Reopening the convergence debate: A new
look at cross-country growth empirics. Journal of Economic Growth 1: 363389.
Chiu, W. H. 1998. Income inequality, human capital accumulation and economic per-
formance. Economic Journal 108: 4459.
Cowell, F. A. 1995. Measuring Inequality, 2d ed. Hemel Hempstead, UK: Prentice Hall/
Harvester Wheatsheaf.
de la Fuente, A., and R. Domenech. 2000. Human capital in growth regressions: How
much difference does data quality make? Working Paper 262, OECD.
Deininger, K., and L. Squire. 1996. A new data set measuring income inequality. World
Bank Economic Review 10: 565591.
Deininger, K., and L. Squire. 1998. New ways of looking at old issues: Inequality and
growth. Journal of Development Economics 57: 259287.
Easterly, W., and S. Rebelo. 1993. Fiscal policy and economic growth. An empirical
investigation. Journal of Monetary Economics 32: 417458.
Fernandez, R., and R. Rogerson. 1998. Public education and income distribution: A
dynamic quantative evaluation of education-nance reform. American Economic Review
88: 813833.
Fields, G. S. 1987. Measuring inequality change in an economy with income growth.
Journal of Development Economics 91: 611625.
224 Gunther Rehme
Katz, L. F., and K. M. Murphy. 1992. Changes in relative wages, 19631987: Supply
and demand factors. Quarterly Journal of Economics 107: 3578.
Kuznets, S. 1955. Economic growth and income inequality. American Economic Review
45: 128.
Lambert, P. J. 1993. The Distribution and Redistribution of Income: A Mathematical Analy-
sis, 2d ed. Manchester, UK: Manchester University Press.
Li, H., and H.-F. Zou. 1998. Income inequality is not harmful for growth: Theory and
evidence. Review of Development Economics 2: 318334.
McCloskey, D. N. 1985. The loss function has been mislaid: The rhetoric of signicance
tests. American Economic Review 75: 201205.
McCloskey, D. N., and S. T. Ziliak. 1996. The standard error of regressions. Journal of
Economic Literature 34: 97114.
OECD. 1998. Education at a Glance 1998. Paris: OECD.
OECD. 2000. Education at a Glance 2000. Paris: OECD.
Perotti, R. 1993. Political equilibrium, income distribution, and growth. Review of Eco-
nomic Studies 60: 755776.
Perotti, R. 1996. Growth, income distribution, and democracy: What the data say.
Journal of Economic Growth 1: 149187.
Persson, T., and G. Tabellini. 1994. Is inequality harmful for growth? American Eco-
nomic Review 84: 600621.
Rehme, G. 1999. Education, economic growth and personal income inequality across
countries. Working Paper ECO 99/42, European University Institute, Florence, Italy.
Romer, P. M. 1986. Increasing returns and long-run growth. Journal of Political Economy
94: 10021037.
Saint-Paul, G., and T. Verdier. 1996. Inequality, redistribution and growth: A chal-
lenge to the conventional political economy approach. European Economic Review 40:
719728.
Sala-i-Martin, X. 1996. A positive theory of social security. Journal of Economic Growth
1: 277304.
(Re-)Distribution of Personal Incomes 225
Theo S. Eicher,
Stephen J. Turnovsky, and
Maria Carme Riera Prunera
8.1 Introduction
Ji aJ 1 y eN 1 cHi eH 1 fKi eK K fK H fH : 1b
Each individual is endowed with a unit of labor, y of which is allo-
cated to the production of new output and 1 y to the production
of new human capital. In addition, he allocates a fraction c of his
230 Theo S. Eicher, Stephen J. Turnovsky, and Maria Carme Riera Prunera
G gY gNYi ; GS gYi ; 3
and substituting (3) into (1a) we can rewrite the production function
as
Yi aF y bN =1cG cHi bH =1cG fKi bK =1cG K cK =1cG H cH =1cG ; 1a 0
where aF 1 aF g cG 1=1cG .
Allowing for depreciation of both human and physical capital
(dK ; dH ), the rate at which the individual accumulates the two types
of capital is described by
K_ i 1 ty Yi Ci Ti dK nKi ; 4a
H_ i Ji dH nHi : 4b
According to (4a), income is taxed at the rate ty , and in addition we
allow for lump-sum taxation, Ti .
Agents maximize their intertemporal utility function
y
1
Ci 1g ert dt r > 0; g > 0; 5
1g 0
The Impact of Tax Policy on Inequality and Growth 231
Yi Ji
ni bN 1 ty mi eN ; 6b
y 1y
Yi Ji
ni bH 1 ty mi eH ; 6c
c 1c
Yi Ji
ni bK 1 ty mi eK ; 6d
f 1f
Yi m Ji n_
bK 1 ty dK n i e K r ; 6e
Ki ni Ki n
ni Yi Ji m_
bH 1 ty dH n eH r ; 6f
mi Ki Hi m
Y aF y sN f sK c sH K sK H sH N sN ; 7a
J aJ 1 y eN 1 f eK 1 c eH K hK H hH N hN ; 7b
where6
bN bK bH
sN 1 ; sK 1 ; sH 1 ;
1 cG 1 cG 1 cG
bK cK bH cH bH bK
sK 1 ; sH 1 ; sN 1 1 ;
1 cG 1 cG 1 cG
hH 1 e H f H ; hK 1 eK fK ; hN 1 1 e H e K :
Next, we introduce the government and consider the aggregate
accumulation equations. We assume that the government nances its
expenditure in accordance with a balanced budget, which, aggre-
gated over N individuals, can be expressed as
ty NYi NTi gNYi ;
Summing (4a) and (4b) over the individuals in the economy, and
applying the government budget constraint (8), the aggregate rates
of capital accumulation can be expressed as
K_ 1 gY C dK K; 9a
H_ J dH H; 9b
^ n 1 hH sH sN sK 1 sH hH hN hK 1n :
Y 10c
1 hH 1 sK sH hK
It is evident from (10a) and (10b) that the magnitudes of the relative
sectoral growth rates depend upon the assumed production elastic-
ities in conjunction with the population growth rate. Equation (10c)
implies that countries converge to identical output per capita growth
rates if either their production technologies are identical, or their
production functions exhibit constant returns to scale. If production
technologies differ across countries, growth rates exhibit conditional
convergence. The fact that (10c) implies that the per capita growth
rate of output in general depends upon the population growth rate,
n, is a double-edged sword. The evidence on the correlation between
population growth and output growth is ambiguous (see, e.g., Barro
and Sala-i-Martin 1995). On the other hand, the growth rate has the
great advantage that it is no longer a function of the absolute size of
the population, N, as in previous R&D-based models, an implication
that is soundly rejected by the data.
Finally, the possibly differential equilibrium growth rates of phys-
ical capital and knowledge are reected in the growth rates of their
respective shadow values, n; m. Using the optimality conditions (6),
these can be shown to grow in accordance with
n^ m^ bH bK n; 10d
where since agents are identical we drop the subscript i.
234 Theo S. Eicher, Stephen J. Turnovsky, and Maria Carme Riera Prunera
y aF y sN f sK c sH k sK h sH ; 11a
j aJ 1 y eN 1 f eK 1 c eH k hK h hH : 11b
aJ eN 1 y eN 1 1 f eK 1 c eH k hK h hH ; 12a
1 ty aF qbH y sN f sK c sH 1 k sK h sH
aJ eH 1 y eN 1 f eK 1 c eH 1 k hK h hH ; 12b
1 ty aF qbK y sN f sK 1 c sH k sK h sH
aJ eK 1 y eN 1 f eK1 1 c eH k hK h hH : 12c
~j eH y~ bK
dH b H n 1 ty dK b K n; 15c
h~ 1 c~ ~k f~
y~ bK
1 ty dK bK n r 1 g1 bK n; 15d
~k f~
together with the two production functions (11a, 11b), and the sec-
toral allocation conditions (13).
These nine equations determine the steady-state equilibrium in the
following sequential manner. First, equation (15b) yields the gross
equilibrium growth rate of knowledge, ~j=~h ~J =H ~ , in terms of the
returns to scale, bH , and the rates of population growth and depre-
ciation. Next, given ~j=~ h, equations (15c) and (15d) determine the
sectoral allocation of human capital, c~, such that the rate of return
on investing in human capital, given by the left hand side of (15c),
equals the rate of return on consumption, given by the right-hand
side of (15d). Having determined the allocation of human capital, c~,
dividing (12a) and (12b), respectively, by (12c) yields the corre-
sponding sectoral allocation of labor, y~, and physical capital, f~.
Having determined f~, (15c) and (15d) determine the output-capital
ratio such that the rate of return on physical capital equals the
(common) rate of return on consumption and human capital.
Then having obtained the output-capital ratio, (15a) determines the
consumption-capital ratio consistent with the growth rate of capital
necessary to equip the growing labor force and replace deprecia-
tion. Given y~, c~, f~, y~=~k, and ~j=~
h, the scale-adjusted production func-
tions determines the stocks of physical capital, ~k, and human capital,
~
h, and thus y~. Finally, having derived y~, c~, f~, ~h, ~k, any of the three
sectoral allocation conditions determine the long-run equilibrium
relative shadow value of the two assets, q~.
A more formal characterization of the transitional dynamics is
provided in the appendix. The dynamics underlying our analysis are
based on the linearization of the fourth-order system (14). In order
for the dynamics to describe a unique stable adjustment path, we
require that the number of unstable roots equal the number of jump
variables (2). Unfortunately, the system is too complex to yield in-
tuitive formal stability conditions that ensure well-behaved saddle-
point behavior. Nevertheless, we assume that this condition is
met, as indeed it is in all of our numerical simulations. For the pur-
poses of this chapter, the analysis of changes in tax regimes on
The Impact of Tax Policy on Inequality and Growth 237
q~
h=qty hK
< 0: 16b
~
h 1 t y 1 sK 1 hH sH hK
238 Theo S. Eicher, Stephen J. Turnovsky, and Maria Carme Riera Prunera
Thus a decline in the tax rate will increase the long-run scale-
adjusted stocks of both physical and human capital. Assuming that
hK < 1 hH , so that human capital is relatively more important than
physical capital in the production of new human capital, then the tax
cut will have a relatively larger positive impact on physical capital.
This assumption, which is conventional throughout the two-sector
endogenous growth models, is equivalent here to hN > fK fH , thus
imposing an upper bound on the externalities in the human capital
sector.
Much of the focus of our simulations shall be on income inequal-
ity, which we measure by the skill premium
rH qY=cH bH y N
wR 1 1 1 1 > 1; 17
w qY=yN bN c H
Table 8.1
Benchmark parameters
Production function aF 1, bN 0:41, bK 0:31, bH 0:28
cG 0:1, cK 0, cH 0
Education sector aJ 1, eN 0:30, eK 0:20, eH 0:50
fK 0, fH 0
Preferences r 0:04, g 2:5
Depreciation/Population dK 0:05, dH 0:05, n 0:015
Fiscal policy g 0:1, ty 0:15152
240 Theo S. Eicher, Stephen J. Turnovsky, and Maria Carme Riera Prunera
Figure 8.1
Effective U.S. income taxes
Source: OECD (1984, 1997).
Figure 8.2
U.S. skill premium (college/high school)
Source: U.S. Census Bureau (2000). Mean earnings of workers 18 by educational
attainment.
Table 8.2a
Initial benchmark equilibrium values
d
Y=N d
H=N y~ j~ c~ g
Y=K g
C=Y
0 0 0.845 0.861 0.691 0.344 0.711
Table 8.2b
New steady-state equilibrium
d
Y=N d
H=N y~ j~ c~ g
Y=K g
C=Y
0 0 0.845 0.861 0.691 0.332 0.702
percent and about 31 percent of the skills are used in the human
capital sector. The implied equilibrium output-capital ratio is 0.34,
and the consumption-output ratio is 0.71. All of these simulated
equilibrium values coincide with those found in standard OECD
data. Although less information exists on the sectoral allocation of
assets, we feel the implied fractions are reasonable.
We can now analyze the dynamics predicted by the model fol-
lowing an accumulated reduction in the tax rate to 11.031 percent by
considering the new steady-state equilibrium as reported in table
8.2b. As discussed, the only long-run responses to the tax cut are
reductions in the ratios of output to capital and consumption to
output. The sectoral allocations of raw labor, physical capital, and
human capital remain unchanged. As mentioned earlier, this invari-
ance of the growth rate to tax policy is indeed a feature of the U.S.
long-run growth rate.
More interesting, however, is the determination of the extent to
which variations in the skill premium, as generated by the model,
correlate with U.S. data in the short run as described in gure 8.2.
During 19801985 the skill premium initially fell, then rose, and
subsequently fell for one period, before continuing to rise during the
next two periods. Figure 8.3A shows that the this nonscale model not
only replicates the steady-state variables well, but also that the sim-
ulations also mimic the short-run transition of the skill premium in
response to the Reagan tax cuts simulations quite successfully as
well. As panel (i) of gure 8.3A shows, on impact the skill premium
declines, it then increases for uniformly for approximately four
years, after which it begins to decline. The explanation for that can
be seen by considering panels (ii) and (iii).
244 Theo S. Eicher, Stephen J. Turnovsky, and Maria Carme Riera Prunera
Figure 8.3
Dynamic adjustments
The Impact of Tax Policy on Inequality and Growth 245
8.5 Conclusion
The purpose of the chapter has been to examine the relevance of the
most recent strand of growth models in predicting steady states and
transitions in response to policy experiments. We derive qualitative
results and simulate the model to examine specically how the
model predicts the transition of the skill premium to changes in the
income tax. The policy experiment that we have in mind is the his-
toric Reagan tax cuts of the early 1980s.
We show that the model simulates the steady states, convergence
speeds, and the actual nonlinear adjustment pattern of the skill pre-
The Impact of Tax Policy on Inequality and Growth 247
ht ~
h B1 n21 e m1 t B2 n22 e m2 t ; A:1b
where B1 ; B2 are constants and the vector
d~
h n22 d~k n21 d~k dh
~
B1 ; B2 : A:2
n22 n21 n22 n21
dh B1 n21 m1 e m1 t B2 n22 m2 e m2 t
A:3
dk B1 m1 e m1 t B2 m2 e m2 t
248 Theo S. Eicher, Stephen J. Turnovsky, and Maria Carme Riera Prunera
and is time varying. Note that since 0 > m1 > m2 , as t ! y this con-
verges to the new steady state along the direction dh=dkt!y n21 ,
for all shocks. The initial direction of motion is obtained by setting
t 0 in (12) and depends upon the source of the shock.
It is convenient to express the dynamics of the state variables in
phase-space form:
0 1
! m1 n22 m2 n21 m2 m1 !
B C
k_ B n22 n21 n22 n21 C k ~k
B C : A:4
h_ @ m2 m1 n21 n22 m2 n22 m1 n21 A h ~h
n22 n21 n22 n21
By construction, the trace of the matrix in (A.4) m1 m2 < 0 and the
determinant m1 m2 > 0, so that (A.4) describes a stable node. The
dynamics expressed in (A.1) and (A.4) are in terms of the scale
adjusted quantities, from which the growth rates of per capita capital
and knowledge can be derived.11
Equations (A.1a) and (A.1b) highlight the fact that with the tran-
sition path in k and h being governed by two stable eigenvalues, the
speeds of adjustment for physical capital and human capital are nei-
ther constant nor equal over time. In addition, with output being
determined by the two types of capital, the transition of output is
also not constant over time, but a simple composite of the transition
characteristics of h and k as determined in (A.4).
Notes
We thank Uwe Walz, Danny Quah, Walter Fisher, and participants at the Munich
Inequality and Growth Conferences in May 2001 and January 2002 for helpful com-
ments on earlier drafts.
1. Cross-country evidence on the effect of growth on inequality and on that of in-
equality on growth is inconclusive (see Anand and Kanbur 1993; Deininger and Squire
1998; and Forbes 2000), while historical and recent time series shows a diversity of
experiences (Williamson 1991, 1999; Gottschalk and Smeeding 1997). For a review see,
Aghion, Caroli, and Garca-Penalosa (1999).
2. See Kuznets (1955).
3. See Galor and Zeira (1993).
4. See Bertola (1993), Alesina and Rodrik (1994), Persson and Tabellini (1994), and
Alesina and Perotti (1995).
5. See Eicher (1996), Garca-Penalosa (1994), and Galor and Tsiddon (1996).
The Impact of Tax Policy on Inequality and Growth 249
6. The elasticity sN reects the assumption that the government good is rival but
excludable. If it were a pure public good sN 1 sK sH =1 cG .
7. Under constant returns to scale, these scale-adjusted quantities are just regular per
capita quantities.
8. See Lucas (1988), Jones (1995), Ortigueira and Santos (1997), and Ogaki and Rein-
hart (1998).
9. ty taxes on income, prot, and capital gains divided by the sum of (1) unin-
corporated surplus of private unincorporated enterprises, (2) households property
and entrepreneurial income, and (3) wages and salaries of dependent employment.
Our tax data are OECD Revenue Statistics and OECD National Accounts.
10. In the more distant future (around 50 years) the decline in the skill premium is
reversed and it convergesalbeit slowlyto its long-run steady state, which lies
below its original starting point. However, this is not relevant for the impact of the
policy shock we are considering.
11. Note that the representation of the transitional dynamics in k h space takes full
account of the feedbacks arising from the jump variables, q and c; these are incorpo-
rated in the two eigenvalues.
References
Ogaki, M., and C. Reinhart. 1998. Measuring Intertemporal Substitution: The Role of
Durable Goods. Journal of Political Economy 106: 10781098.
Ortigueira, S., and M. S. Santos. 1997. On the Speed of Convergence in Endogenous
Growth Models. American Economic Review 87: 383399.
Perroni, C. 1995. Assessing the Dynamic Efciency Gains of Tax Reform when
Human Capital is Endogenous. International Economic Review 36(4): 907925.
Persson, T., and G. Tabellini. 1994. Is Inequality Harmful for Growth? Theory and
Evidence. American Economic Review 84: 600624.
Romer, P. 1990. Endogenous Technical Change. Journal of Political Economy 98:
S71S103.
Stokey, N. L., and S. Rebelo. 1995. Growth Effects of Flat-Rate Taxes. Journal of
Political Economy 103(3): 519550.
U.S. Census Bureau. 2000. Available online at hhttp://www.census.gov/population/
socdemo/education/tableA-3.txti. 1/25/2001.
9.1 Introduction
For a long time, many economists were of the view that economic
efciency and social equality were essentially incompatible, almost
like oil and water. The perceived but poorly documented trade-off
between efciency and equality was commonly regarded as one of
the main tenets of modern welfare economics. One of the key
ideas behind this perception was that increased inequality could
increase private as well as social returns to investing in education
and exerting effort in the hope of attaining a higher standard of
life. Redistributive policies were supposed to thwart these tenden-
cies and blunt incentives by penalizing the well-off through taxation
and by rewarding the poor. Economic efciencyboth static and
dynamicwas bound to suffer in the process, or so the argument
went.
More often than not in recent empirical work, measures of income
inequality have turned out to have a negative effect on economic
growth across countries. Thus Alesina and Rodrik (1994), Persson
and Tabellini (1994), and Perotti (1996) report that inequality hurts
growth. Barro (2000) assesses the relationship between economic
growth and inequality in a panel of countries over the period from
1965 to 1995 and ndsby studying the interaction of the Gini index
and the initial level of income in a growth regressionthat increased
inequality tends to retard growth in poor countries and boost
growth in richer countries.1 However, Barro nds no support for a
relationship between inequality and growth in his sample as a
whole. Forbes (2000) nds that the relationship between inequality
and growth becomes positive in a pooled regression when country
effects are included. She claims that country-specic, time-invariant,
256 Thorvaldur Gylfason and Gyl Zoega
would seem likely to foster social cohesion and peace and thus to
strengthen incentives rather than weaken them, whereas in places
like Denmark and Sweden, where the Gini index is 25 and incomes
and wealth are thus already quite equitably distributed by world
standards, further equalization might well have the opposite effect.
Excessive inequality may be socially divisive and hence inefcient: It
may motivate the poor to engage in illegal activities and riots, or at
least to divert resources from productive uses, both the resources of
the poor and those of the state. Social conict over the distribution of
income, land, or other assets can take place through labor unrest, for
instance, or rent seeking that can hinder investment and growth
(Benhabib and Rustichini 1996).2 Alesina and Perotti (1996) report
empirical evidence of an inverse relationship between inequality and
growth through sociopolitical instability.3
Third, national saving may be affected by inequality if the rich
have a higher propensity to save than the poor (Kaldor 1956). In this
case inequality may be good for growth in that the greater the level
of inequality, the higher is the saving rate and hence also investment
and economic growth. Against this Todaro (1997) suggests that the
rich may invest in an unproductive mannercount their yachts and
expensive cars. Barro (2000) nds no empirical evidence of a link
between inequality and investment.
Fourth, increased inequality may hurt education rather than help-
ing it as suggested by the political-economy literature referred to at
the beginning of this brief discussion. If so, increased inequality may
hinder economic growth through education. Galor and Zeira (1993)
and Aghion (1998) argue that this outcome is likely in the presence
of imperfect capital markets. If each member of society has a xed
number of investment opportunities, imperfect access to credit, and
a different endowment of inherited wealth, the rich would end up
using many of their investment opportunities while the poor could
only use a few. Therefore, the marginal return from the last in-
vestment opportunity of the rich would be much lower than the
marginal return of the last investment opportunity of the poor.
Redistribution of wealth from the rich to the poor would increase
output because the poor would then invest in more productive proj-
ects at the margin. This argument can also be applied to investment
in human capital if we assume diminishing returns to education. In
this case, taking away the last few quarters of the university educa-
tion of the elite and adding time to the more elementary education
258 Thorvaldur Gylfason and Gyl Zoega
of the poor would raise output and perhaps also long-run growth,
other things being the same. Income redistribution would reverse the
decline in investment in human capital resulting from the credit-
market failure.4
The distribution of income and wealth may also affect the amount
of public and private investment in education. When a large part of
the population is poor, it may be more likely that the majority of
voters will support expenditures on public education aimed at the
poor, as argued by Saint-Paul and Verdier (1993, 1996) and corrobo-
rated empirically by Easterly and Rebelo (1993), but the effect could
also, in principle, go the other way. If so, the more deprived and
detached from the mainstream population is the poorer segment, the
less likely the poor are to participate in or affect the outcome of
elections. As a result the general level of education may suffer
the more so, the more capital-constrained is the poorer segment of
the population. A virtuous circle may arise when redistribution of
income leads to an increase or improvement in human capital, which
then induces voters to prefer higher expenditures on education,
which again pulls more workers out of poverty, and so on. At an
empirical level, we would expect increased equality to enhance eco-
nomic growth through its effect on education, and vice versa. That is,
more and better general education may be expected to reduce public
tolerance against extreme inequality and thus to reduce inequality
through the political process, thereby stimulating economic growth.
These processes can be mutually reinforcing; that is, if increased
social equality encourages education and economic growth, this does
not mean that more and better education cannot similarly, and
simultaneously, enhance equality and growth.
The previous models all have the same basic structure: Inequality
affects some unknown intermediate variable X which, in turn, makes
a difference for economic growth. In this chapter we take a different
approach: we view both economic growth and inequality of incomes
as well as of educational attainment and of land as endogenous var-
iables and argue that the inverse relationship between inequality and
growth does not imply causality one way or the other. We propose
an explanation which, in contrast to the ones surveyed in the litera-
ture reviewed briey earlier, involves a variable that is exogenous to
most economic models. This variable is the abundance of, or rather
dependence on, natural resources, which we measure by the amount
of natural capital per person and the share of natural capital in
Inequality and Economic Growth 259
eg1b g1 b N
f N for N 0; 1; 2; . . . ; 1
N!
where the mean arrival ratethat is, the expected number of dis-
coveries by a given worker or, equivalently, the probability that a
discovery will be made by the worker within a unit of timeis
EN g1 b. The expected number of discoveries for the repre-
sentative individual is thus a linear function of the fraction of time
spent searching. The larger the share of time spent in nature, the
more bundles will be discovered. The parameter g measures search
effectiveness.
There are L individuals (identical by assumption) spending part of
their time searching. The aggregate income from the natural resource
is then
Y n NLR: 2
The expected value and the variance of N given by the Poisson dis-
tribution are both equal to g1 b. Since all individuals are identi-
cal, it follows that the variance across the population in the number
of discoveries of the natural resource bundles per unit of time is also
equal to g1 b. We now have the following result: The variance of
the distribution of income emanating from the natural resource is an
increasing function of the time devoted by each worker to the natu-
ral resourcebased sectorprimary sector, for short. Dene income
per capita by lower-case letters. We then have
E y n g1 bR; vary n g1 bR 3
The expected per capita income or rent from the natural resource as
well as the variance of this per capita income across the population
of workers is an increasing function of the abundance of the resource
R and also an increasing function of the time spent procuring it
1 b.
Inequality and Economic Growth 263
Here q denotes the quality of capital and takes a value between zero
and one,5 Ki and Li denote the capital and labor used by rm i and K
is the aggregate capital stock in the manufacturing sector. As in
Romer (1986) the aggregate capital stock is a proxy for the accumu-
lated knowledge that has been generated in the past through invest-
ment at all rms. This is what sets manufacturing apart from the
primary sector; it uses capital and the installation of new units of
capital generates a ow of ideas that raises productivity in a labor-
augmenting fashion. In contrast, the primary sector does not offer
similar opportunities for learning and innovation.
We assume a perfectly competitive market for labor and capital.
Assuming symmetric equilibrium, so that K kL, gives the follow-
ing rst-order conditions for maximum prot, and also for equilib-
rium in the two factor markets:
dYi
1 akq a bL 1a bw 5
dLi
dYi
aq a bL 1a r d; 6
dKi
where w is the real wage, r is the real interest rate and d is the rate at
which installed capital loses its usefulness over time, as a result of
economic obsolescence as well as physical wear and tear (Scott
1989).6
The representative worker/consumer has to make two decisions
each moment of his innite life. He has to decide how much to con-
sume and save and how much time to spend working in the manu-
facturing sector rather than trying his luck in the primary sector. We
assume that he cannot do both at the same time. Hence a decision to
spend more time in the primary sector causes him to spend less time
in paid employment making manufactures. Moreover, we assume
that time spent in the primary sector is costly: A direct cost h is in-
curred for each moment spent. Finally, there is a tax on wages tw and
also a tax on income from the natural resources tn .
264 Thorvaldur Gylfason and Gyl Zoega
By assumption, the worker does not gain any utility (or suffer dis-
utility) in the primary sector, nor from being employed. The worker
has assets a, which he accumulates if his earnings exceed expendi-
tures (henceforth, we omit time subscripts). His earnings come from
three sources: There is interest income on assets ra, which is tax-free,
there is wage income from employment bw, taxed at tw , and there is
the value of the primary goods he picks or produces 1 bR, taxed
at tn . The worker then incurs the direct cost h and consumes c per
unit of time. A necessary condition for optimal consumption is
1
c ; 8
l
w1 tw gR1 tn h: 9
The left-hand side of equation (9) shows the marginal benet from
working longer in manufacturing net of taxes, while the right-hand
side shows the marginal benet from fruit picking, also net of taxes.
While each worker takes wages w as given, wages do nevertheless
respond to market forces. Combining equations (5) and (9) gives the
following equation:
1 akq a L 1a b a 1 tw gR1 tn h: 10
Solving for b gives
1=a
1 akq a L 1a 1 tw
b : 11
gR1 tn h
Inequality and Economic Growth 265
c_
r r: 12
c
Equations (6) and (12) give the optimal rate of growth of consump-
tion and output:
g aq a bL 1a d r: 13
Growth is an increasing function of b, the share of time spent pro-
ducing manufactures rather than primary goods.
There are two market failures in the model. The rst is the stan-
dard one that rms, when investing, neglect the gains from learning
and knowledge spillovers to other rms. In contrast, a social planner
uses the average product of capitalnot the private marginal prod-
uctto measure the cost of capital. Second, workers compare the
current benet from spending time in the two sectors but ignore
the growth effect of industrial employment: by spending more time
in the manufacturing industry they, collectively, would raise the
marginal product of capital, the interest rate and economic growth.
This makes their wages grow more rapidly. By withdrawing labor
from the primary sector, workers would invest in a higher future
wage. However, each worker has only a very small effect on growth
imparting an external benet to others.
We can now summarize the relationship between natural
resources and growth.
0
A rise in the natural resource rent R attracts more people to the
primary sector in the hope of securing a piece of the action. These
people leave the manufacturing sector, thereby lowering the private
marginal product of capital, the rate of interest and the rate of
growth of consumption and output. This is the Dutch disease work-
ing through the labor market (Paldam 1997).
Inequality and Economic Growth 267
0
When abundant natural resources reduce the incentive to provide
good education (Gylfason 2001), this reduces labor productivity and
wages, hence reinforcing the incentive to stay in the natural resource
sector. An abundant natural resourcea high value of Rattracts
workers and this effect is reinforced by bad education which drives
people away from industrial employment.
0
If natural resources reduce the quality of societys institutions, this
could manifest itself in a reduction in the private cost of rent seeking
h. Moreover, less developed capital markets are likely to generate a
lower quality capital stock q, which depreciates at a higher rate d
(Gylfason and Zoega 2001a, 2001b).
We can now combine these insights with the earlier result showing
that the variance of income or rent emanating from the natural re-
source sector is
vary n g1 bR: 14
Figure 9.1
The Gini index and the 20-20 ratio
Figure 9.2
Income inequality and gender inequality
Figure 9.3
Income inequality and initial income: The Kuznets curve
Figure 9.4
Gender inequality and initial income
The third measure of inequality that we will use is the Gini index
for the distribution of land. This measure is taken from Deininger
and Olinto (2000), and covers fty of the eighty-seven countries in
our sample. Figure 9.5 shows that, almost without exception, land is
less equally distributed than income in our sample. Spearmans rank
correlation between the two measures is 0.57.
In this section, we allow the data to speak for themselves in the form
of a series of bivariate cross-sectional correlations. We rst take a
look at the correlations between our three measures of inequality
and economic growth, all of which are unambiguously negative in
our data: Greater inequality in the distribution of income and land as
well as in access to education tends to go together with lower rates
of growth. We then move on to show that two of the three measures
of inequality increase from country to country in tandem with the
share of natural capital in national wealth. This opens up the possi-
bility that it is the variation in natural capital in the sample that
272 Thorvaldur Gylfason and Gyl Zoega
Figure 9.5
Distribution of income and land
Figure 9.6
Income inequality and economic growth
Figure 9.7
Gender inequality and economic growth
since 1965 has been about 1.25 percent per year. We see no signs of
the positive cross-sectional relationship between inequality and
growth in rich countries reported by Barro (2000), nor do we see any
evidence of the nonlinearity in the panel relationship documented by
Banerjee and Duo (2000a,b).
Figures 9.7 and 9.8 tell a similar story. Here we see the cross-
country pattern of per capita growth as measured in Figure 9.6
and gender inequality of education (gure 9.7) and land inequality
(gure 9.8). The pattern is not as clear as in gure 9.6, but it is still
statistically signicant (Spearmans rank correlation is 0.32 and
0.37, respectively). The number of countries is seventy-ve and
fty in the two gures. All countries for which the requisite data
are available are included in all the gures in the paper, without
exception.
Figure 9.8
Land inequality and economic growth
Figure 9.9
Income inequality and natural capital
276 Thorvaldur Gylfason and Gyl Zoega
and natural capital (though not social capital; see World Bank 1997).
The natural capital variable is intended to come closer to a direct
measurement of the intensity of natural resources across countries
than the various proxies that have been used in earlier studies,
mainly the share of primary (i.e., nonmanufacturing) exports in total
exports or in gross domestic product (GDP) and the share of the
primary sector in employment or the labor force. The latter proxies
may be prone to bias due to product and labor market distortions.
Figure 9.9 shows that the share of natural capital in national
wealth is positively correlated with income inequality as measured
by the Gini index. Spearmans rank correlation is 0.41. Notice the
cluster of ve countries (Niger, Guinea-Bissau, Madagascar, Mali,
and Zambia, in descending order) in the northeast corner of the
gure with a natural capital share above 35 and Gini above 45. Even
if this cluster is removed from the sample, the pattern remains sta-
tistically signicant. Notice, further, the two countries (Sierra Leone
and the Central African Republic) with a natural capital share of
around 30 and Gini above 60. If this pair of observations is omitted,
the pattern remains signicant. If, however, both clusters (i.e., all
seven countries) are removed from the sample, the remaining pat-
tern becomes insignicant in a statistical sense. In this sense, this
group of seven African countries in the northeast corner of the gure
explains the inverse correlation. Even so, we are inclined to keep
these African countries in our sample. We nd it instructive that no
country with a natural capital share above 25 has a Gini coefcient
below 45.
Figure 9.10 shows that the natural capital share is also positively
correlated with gender inequality as measured by the male minus
female secondary-school enrollment rate. Spearmans rank correla-
tion is 0.32. The pattern observed is statistically signicant with or
without the seven African countries mentioned above. Moreover,
there is a positive albeit insignicant correlation between land
inequality and natural capital in our sample (not shown); Spear-
mans rank correlation is 0.19.
From gures 9.9 and 9.10 combined with gure 9.11, which shows
that the natural capital share varies inversely with per capita eco-
nomic growth from 1965 to 1998 across the same group of countries,
we conclude that these ndings may help explain the inverse cross-
sectional relationship between inequality and growth shown in
gures 9.6 and 9.7. In gure 9.11, the rank correlation between nat-
Inequality and Economic Growth 277
Figure 9.10
Gender inequality and natural capital
Figure 9.11
Natural capital and economic growth
278 Thorvaldur Gylfason and Gyl Zoega
Figure 9.12
Natural capital and expenditure on education
Figure 9.13
Expenditure on education and income inequality
Figure 9.14
Years of schooling and income inequality
Figure 9.15
School enrollment and income inequality
The rst equation shows how economic growth depends on (a) the
logarithm of initial per capita income (i.e., in 1965), dened as
income in 1998 divided by an appropriate growth factor, (b) the
share of natural capital in national wealth (which comprises physi-
cal, human and natural capital), (c) the share of gross domestic
investment in GDP in 19651998, (d) the log of the secondary-school
enrollment rate (the log in order to capture diminishing returns to
education), (e) the Gini index, and (f) gender inequality of education
as measured by the difference between male and female secondary-
school enrollment rates in 19801997. This equation can be inter-
preted either as a description of endogenous long-run growth or of
medium-term growth in the neoclassical model where economic
growth is exogenous in the long run. Initial income is intended to
capture conditional convergence. Natural capital is another exoge-
nous determinant of growth. Investment and education are intended
to capture the contribution of physical and human capital accumu-
lation to growth. The inequality measures reect the hypothesized
effects of income and gender inequality on growth.
The second equation shows the relationship between the invest-
ment rate and the natural capital share (as spelled out in Gylfason
and Zoega 2001b; the underlying explanation is that increased
dependence on natural resources reduces the share of physical capi-
tal in GDP and thereby weakens the incentive to save and invest by
our extension of the Golden Rule).
The third equation shows how the enrolment rate depends on
initial income (because wealthy countries can afford to spend more
on education) as well as on natural capital (as in Gylfason 2001;
Gylfason and Zoega 2001b; the idea behind this formulation is that
the natural-resource-intensive sector may nd it protable to use
workers with fewer skills than the manufacturing sector).
The fourth equation shows the relationship among the Gini index,
initial income (i.e., the Kuznets curve), and the natural capital share
that we documented in section 9.4. The fth and last equation
shows the relationship between gender inequality and the natural
capital share. To recapitulate, our hypothesis from section 9.2 is that
because natural resource ownership tends to be less equally dis-
tributed than other assets, countries that depend heavily on their
Inequality and Economic Growth 283
All the coefcient estimates shown in table 9.1 are economically and
statistically signicant, with one exception. The coefcient on initial
income in the growth equation indicates a conditional convergence
speed of 1.3 percent per year. The direct effect of the natural capital
share on growth is 0.05 and the indirect effects through investment
and education are 0:20 0:11 0:022 and 0:03 1:08 0:032.
The additional indirect effect of the natural capital share on growth
via the Gini index is 0:30 0:04 0:012. The total effect of natu-
ral capital on growth is, therefore, about 0.12 (for given initial
income). Hence, the income distribution channel accounts for about
one-tenth of the total effect of natural capital intensity on growth.
Of additional interest here are the effects of education and
inequality on growth. The rst equation in the table shows the direct
effect of education on growth to be 1.08/E 0.025, evaluated at the
mean value of the secondary-school enrollment rate, E 0.43; this
means that an increase in the enrollment rate by ten percentage
Table 9.1
284
Regression results
Initial Natural
Initial income capital Investment Enrollment Gender
Dependent variable income squared share rate rate (log) Gini index inequality R2 Countries
Economic growth 1.26 0.05 0.11 1.08 0.04 0.01 0.68 74
(6.05) (5.19) (3.82) (3.88) (2.84) (0.76)
Investment rate 0.20 0.15 87
(3.98)
Enrollment rate 0.54 0.03 0.70 87
(11.31) (6.29)
Gini index 48.88 3.20 0.30 0.31 74
(3.54) (3.69) (2.84)
Gender inequality 0.25 0.09 87
(2.98)
Note: Estimation method: SUR. t-ratios are shown within parentheses. Constant terms are not reported to conserve space.
Thorvaldur Gylfason and Gyl Zoega
Inequality and Economic Growth 285
coefcient of the Gini index in the rst equation in table 9.1. When
we replace the Gini index of income inequality in the above experi-
ment with our measure of gender inequality or of land inequality,
we obtain the same results: The greater the natural capital share, the
greater is the adverse effect of increased inequality on growth.
Third, we replaced our gender inequality measure (the arithmetic
difference between male and female secondary-school enrollment
rates) by the absolute difference between male and female enrolment
rates. The new measure means that a change from a situation where
more boys than girls go to school to one where more girls than boys
go to school leaves gender inequality unchanged if the numbers are
the same. When we reestimate our system using this new measure,
increased gender inequality reduces economic growth directly: The
coefcient on gender inequality in the rst equation in table 9.1 is
now 0.05 with t 2.09. In this case, however, the effect of the nat-
ural capital share on gender inequality becomes small and statisti-
cally insignicant (the coefcient is 0.08 with t 1.47). In other
respects, the regression results (not shown) are very similar to those
reported in table 9.1.
Our fourth and last experiment involves Africa and Latin America.
When we add a dummy variable for Africa to each equation in our
model, in case Africa might be different from other regions, as some
studies have shown, the dummy coefcient has the expected sign
everywhere, but it is statistically signicant only in the equations for
education and the Gini index. The annual rate of per capita growth
in Africa is thus 0.75 of a percentage point smaller than elsewhere
according to our results (not shown), but the difference is not signif-
icant (t 1.73). The investment rate is almost 2 percentage points
lower in Africa than elsewhere, but again the difference is insigni-
cant (t 1.38). The secondary-school enrollment rate is 15 percent-
age points lower in Africa than elsewhere (evaluated at the sample
mean), and this difference is signicant (t 3.23). Gender inequality
in education is also signicantly greater in Africa than elsewhere, by
almost ve percentage points (t 2.15). There is, on the other hand,
no signicant difference between the Gini index in Africa and the
rest of our sample. All the estimates shown in table 9.1 remain
essentially intact in the presence of the African dummy. When
we add a dummy variable for Latin America (with or without Cen-
tral America) rather than for Africa, the dummy has no effect on
growth, investment, or education, but it does matter for distribution;
288 Thorvaldur Gylfason and Gyl Zoega
9.6 Conclusion
Notes
which may overstate its productivity; or (c) as a consequence of aging: the larger the
share of old capital in the capital stock currently in operation, namely, the higher the
average age of capital in use, the lower is its overall quality (Gylfason and Zoega
2001a). For our purposes, the three interpretations are analytically equivalent. How-
ever, we assume that the quality of capital has remained constant in the past, which
means that all units of capital are of the same quality. In other words, we are not
interested here in the implications of having different vintages of capital.
6. The parameters q and d can both be modeled as endogenous choice parameters (as
in Gylfason and Zoega 2001a), but here we treat them as exogenous magnitudes for
simplicity, even if we acknowledge that depreciation may depend on quality, through
obsolescence.
7. All countries for which the requisite data are available are included in all the
gures in the chapter, without exception.
References
Aghion, Philippe, with Eve Caroli and Cecilia Garca-Penalosa. 1998. Inequality and
Economic Growth. Part I in Growth, Inequality and Globalization: Theory, History and
Policy, Philippe Aghion and Jeffrey G. Williamson. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press.
Aghion, Philippe, Eve Caroli, and Cecilia Garca-Penalosa. 1999. Inequality and Eco-
nomic Growth: The Perspective of the New Growth Theories. Journal of Economic Lit-
erature 37: 16151660, December.
Alesina, Alberto, and Roberto Perotti. 1996. Income Distribution, Political Instability,
and Investment. European Economic Review 40: 12031228, June.
Alesina, Alberto, and Dani Rodrik. 1994. Distributive Politics and Economic
Growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 109: 165190, May.
Banerjee, Abhijit V., and Esther Duo. 2000a. Inequality and Growth: What Can the
Data Say? Working Paper No. 0009, Department of Economics, MIT.
Banerjee, Abhijit V., and Esther Duo. 2000b. A Reassessment of the Relationship
Between Inequality and Growth. Unpublished manuscript, Department of Econom-
ics, MIT.
Barro, Robert J. 2000. Inequality and Growth in a Panel of Countries. Journal of Eco-
nomic Growth 5: 532, March.
Benabou, Roland. 1996. Inequality and Growth. NBER Macroeconomics Annual.
Benhabib, Jess, and Aldo Rustichini. 1996. Social Conict and Growth. Journal of
Economic Growth 1: 124142, March.
Bourguignon, Francois, and C. Morrison. 1990. Income Distribution, Development
and Foreign Trade. European Economic Review 34: 11131132, September.
Bruno, Michael. 1984. Raw Materials, Prots, and the Productivity Slowdown.
Quarterly Journal of Economics 99: 128, February.
Deininger, Klaus, and Pedro Olinto. 2000. Asset Distribution, Inequality, and
Growth. Working Paper No. 2375, World Bank, Development Research Group.
Inequality and Economic Growth 291
Deininger, Klaus, and Lyn Squire. 1996. A New Data Set Measuring Income Inequal-
ity. World Bank Economic Review 10: 565591, September.
Easterly, William, and Sergio Rebelo. 1993. Fiscal Policy and Growth: An Empirical
Investigation. Journal of Monetary Economics 32: 417458, December.
Forbes, Kristin J. 2000. A Reassessment of the Relationship Between Inequality and
Growth. American Economic Review 90: 869887, September.
Galor, Oded, and Omer Moav. 1999. From Physical to Human Capital: Inequality in
the Process of Development. CEPR Discussion Paper No. 2307, December.
Galor, Oded, and Joseph Zeira. 1993. Income Distribution and Macroeconomics.
Review of Economic Studies 60: 3552, January.
Garca-Penalosa, Cecilia. 1995. The Paradox of Education or the Good Side of
Inequality. Oxford Economic Papers 47(2): 265285.
Gylfason, Thorvaldur. 2001. Natural Resources, Education, and Economic Develop-
ment. European Economic Review 45: 847859, May.
Gylfason, Thorvaldur, and Gyl Zoega. 2001b. Natural Resources and Economic
Growth: The Role of Investment. CEPR Discussion Paper No. 2743, March.
Gylfason, Thorvaldur, Tryggvi Thor Herbertsson, and Gyl Zoega. 2001. Ownership
and Growth. World Bank Economic Review 15: 431449, October.
Kaldor, Nicholas. 1956. Alternative Theories of Distribution. Review of Economic
Studies 23: 83100.
Lahiri, Kajal, and Peter Schmidt. 1978. On the Estimation of Triangular Structural
Systems. Econometrica 46: 12171221.
Paldam, Martin. 1997. Dutch Disease and Rent Seeking: The Greenland Model.
European Journal of Political Economy 13: 591614, August.
Perotti, Robert. 1996. Growth, Income Distribution, and Democracy: What the Data
Say. Journal of Economic Growth 5: 149187, June.
Persson, Torsten, and Guido Tabellini. 1994. Is Inequality Harmful for Growth?
American Economic Review 84: 600621, June.
Pritchett, Lant. 2000. The Tyranny of Concepts: CUDIE (Cumulated, Depreciated,
Investment Effort) Is Not Capital. Journal of Economic Growth 5: 361384, December.
Romer, Paul M. 1986. Increasing Returns and Long-Run Growth. Journal of Political
Economy 94: 10021037, October.
Sachs, Jeffrey D., and Andrew M. Warner. 1995. Natural Resource Abundance and
Economic Growth. NBER Working Paper 5398, Cambridge. Revised 1997, 1999.
Saint-Paul, Gilles, and Thierry Verdier. 1993. Education, Democracy and Growth.
Journal of Development Economics 42: 399407.
Saint-Paul, Gilles, and Thierry Verdier. 1996. Inequality, Redistribution and Growth:
A Challenge to the Conventional Political Economy Approach. European Economic
Review 40: 719728.
292 Thorvaldur Gylfason and Gyl Zoega
Scott, Maurice Fitzgerald. 1989. A New View of Economic Growth. Oxford, UK: Claren-
don Press.
Sen, Amartya. 1999. Development as Freedom. Oxford: University Press.
Todaro, Michael P. 1997. Economic Development. London: Longman.
Campbell Leith,
Chol-Won Li, and
Cecilia Garca-Penalosa
10.1 Introduction
rms about whether or not employees are shirking forces the former
to pay wages above the market clearing level, which in turn leads
to unemployment. The combination of high wages and the risk of
remaining unemployed if found shirking and red, induces optimal
effort on the part of workers. We introduce technological progress
into this framework. We stress that an important feature of new
technologies is that they not only create new jobs, they also destroy
old ones. When an innovation arrives, some workers retain their jobs
but others are reallocated between jobs or made redundant.3 This
process affects the effort incentives of workers, and hence the effec-
tive labor supply. That is, changes in the rate of technical change
alter the trade-off between pay and unemployment that rms face,
and will affect equilibrium wages and employment.
In our model, the net impact of technical change on wages is
ambiguous. Faster technical change increases the discounted wage
ow but, since it also raises turnover, it reduces the probability
of remaining with the current employer. Hence it may increase
or decrease the present value of being employed, depending on
parameter values. We consider two types of workers, skilled and
unskilled, and assume that it is easier to monitor the effort levels of
the unskilled, and that it is easier for a skilled worker that has lost
her job to immediately nd a new one, as her transferable skills
make her more adaptable to the new technology than an unskilled
worker. These differences imply that the incentives of the two types
of workers will not be affected in the same way by a change in the
rate of technical progress, and that consequently the relative (effec-
tive) supply of workers will shift.
A number of results emerge. First, if technical change is biased, in
the sense that it increases the demand for skilled workers relative to
that for the unskilled, then the incentive mechanism may strengthen
or partially offset the impact of demand on relative wages. A more
surprising nding is that if technical change is skill-neutral, in the
sense that it leaves the relative demand for labor unchanged, an
increase or fall in the rate of technical change will still change the
relative wage. Third, we show that a reduction in the rate of tech-
nical change can generate an increase in the skill premium, which is
consistent with the productivity slowdown experienced during the
1970s and 1980s.
The model also generates patterns of unemployment that t the
data. As we see in detail in section 10.2, previous work cannot
explain the increase in both the skilled and unskilled unemployment
Wage Inequality and Technical Change 295
As was rst pointed out by Nickell and Bell (1995, 1996), unem-
ployment rates were much higher in the 1980s than in the 1970s for
both skilled and unskilled workers. This increase in unemployment
took place in both the North American and the European economies.
Neither the demand-based explanations nor the hypothesis of an
increase in the supply of unskilled labor are capable of accounting
for the simultaneous shift in relative wages and the increase in
unemployment for both types of workers. An exception is the search
model developed by Acemoglu (1999). Yet, in his setup, the mecha-
nism that triggers the changes is an acceleration of the rate of skill-
biased technical change. By using a supply-side approach based on
an efciency-wage model we are capable of providing a framework
in which productivity, relative wages, and unemployment can move
in a way consistent with the evidence.
10.3.1.1 Workers
Time is continuous and denoted by t. There are H skilled and L
unskilled workers, and Ei t and Ui t, i H; L denote the number of
workers employed and unemployed, respectively. This means
H EH t UH t and L EL t UL t. All workers have identical
preferences, are risk-neutral, and their intertemporal utility function
is time-additive.7 This implies that the real rate of interest is given
by the rate of time preference, r, which is common to all consumers.
We assume that agents consume all their labor income, wi t, as they
receive it. They also decide whether or not to exert effort when
employed. The instantaneous utility function when employed is
wi t eTi t, where eTi t is the disutility of effort and e can take
values of either 0 or 1. Ti t is an index of the level of technology
which is specic to each type of labor since, as we will see later,
skilled and unskilled workers operate different technologies.
We assume that technological progress is the only way in which
workers are separated from rms in equilibrium. There is a proba-
bility hi that, following a technological innovation which destroys
her job, a worker immediately nds a job elsewhere. This assump-
tion captures the observation of Davis and Haltiwanger (1992) that
job-to-job reallocation represents a substantial fraction of worker
298 Campbell Leith, Chol-Won Li, and Cecilia Garca-Penalosa
turnover. In what follows we assume hH > hL , that is, that the rate of
job-to-job reallocation is larger for skilled than for unskilled workers,
reecting the fact that the former have more transferable skills mak-
ing adoption of new technologies easier.
The return to a worker from being employed and not shirking,
denoted by ViN t, is dened by the following asset equation,
where ViU t is the value of being unemployed. The interest rate, r,
times asset value ViN t must equal the ow benets
10.3.1.2 Production
We assume that we are in a small open economy, where the prices of
the N varieties of good are exogenously determined in world mar-
kets. A particular variety is produced by one type of labor only. Let
Wage Inequality and Technical Change 299
QL j AxLa j AxLa ; 5a
QH j AxHa j AxHa ; 5b
aAPi
oi ; 6a
ni x i 1a
aAPi
; 6b
Ei1a
where Ei ni x i is total employment of type i workers.
n_ L n_ H
gL and gH : 7
nL nH
EHt wLt =PLt 1=1a nH0 gH gL t
e ; 8
ELt wHt nL0
where ni0 is the initial number of type i varieties. When the rates of
growth of the two types of varieties are the same, the two labor
demand functions shift proportionally, leaving the relative demand
for skills unchanged. This is what we term skill-neutral technical
change. A faster (slower) rate of growth of skill-produced varieties
implies that the relative demand for skills increases (decreases) over
time, namely, results in skill-biased (deskilling) technical change.
The number of jobs lost in a given variety in a unit time interval, x_ i ,
is proportional to the number of jobs that existed with a coefcient
determined by the rate of increase in real wages and by the rate of
technological progress. If all workers who are separated from rms
could not nd jobs elsewhere, x_ i would be equivalent to the num-
ber of individuals becoming unemployed in a given variety. How-
ever, recall that we have assumed that a fraction hi of workers who
are separated from rms are immediately recruited by a new rm.
Therefore, the number of workers joining the unemployment pool
from a given variety is 1 hi x_ i , and the probability of a given
worker becoming unemployed is bi 1 hi x_ i =x i . We then have
1 o_ i
bi 1 hi gi
1 a oi
!
E_ i
1 hi gi : 10
Ei
Wage Inequality and Technical Change 301
hi E_ i 1 hi gi Ei
ai : 11
Ui
Figure 10.1
Equilibrium in the labour market
a higher gi reduces the effective discount rate and hence the no-
shirking wage. Second, the job destruction and job creation effects
are also combined in a single term capturing the probabilities of
entering and exiting unemployment, as ai bi 1 hi gi =1 Ei =i.
Through these probabilities faster technical change increases job
turnover, implying that workers have less incentive to avoid shirk-
ing and rms need to increase the wage. Either of these two net
effects may dominate.
The equilibrium wage and employment level are given by the inter-
section of the demand function with the steady state NSC, which are,
respectively,
aAPi
oi ; DD
Ei1a
e e 1 hi
oi z e r 1 a gi : NSC
si si 1 Ei =i
Figure 10.2
The impact of a productivity slowdown
8
> 0 for Ei > E^i
doi < h a
0 for Ei E^i ; where E^i i i < i: 16
dgi : 1a
< 0 for Ei < E^i
Now suppose that the number of the two types of varieties increase
at the same rate, gH gL g, and that there is a reduction in the rate
of technical change. What would be the impact on the relative wage?
Wage Inequality and Technical Change 307
where
Table 10.1
Inequality and the productivity slowdown
hL 0:75 and hL 0:8 and hL 0:75 and
sL 0:2 sL 0:2 sL 0:1
oH oL oH =oL oL oH =oL oL oH =oL
g 0:05 2.67 1.70 1.57 1.68 1.49 1.79 1.40
g 0:03 2.73 1.67 1.63 1.66 1.54 1.74 1.47
g 0:01 2.88 1.64 1.75 1.64 1.72 1.68 1.68
Figure 10.3
The unskilled labor market
Wage Inequality and Technical Change 311
Table 10.2 reports the results. The rst row replicates the situation
in 1970, with a skill premium of 1.49 and low rates of unemployment
of 1.7 and 5.27 for skilled and unskilled workers, respectively.12 The
second row considers the effect on wages and employment of a fall
in the price of the unskilled-produced good from PL 0:660 to
PL0 0:568. (i.e., by 16%). The next row adds to that a fall in g. For
the unskilled, a low reallocation rate implies that the productivity
slowdown partly offsets the increase in unskilled unemployment,
while it reinforces the increase in the skill premium. For the skilled, a
lower g results in a higher wage and unemployment rate. A demand
shift due to increased import penetration together with a fall in the
rate of (skill-neutral) technical progress can thus account for the
simultaneous increase in the skill premium and the unemployment
rates for both educated and noneducated workers.
In this section we argue that labor market policies can indeed help
explain differences in inequality between Europe and the United
Table 10.2
Simulating unemployment and wages in the United States
oH 1-EH oL 1-EL oH =oL
Table 10.3
Changes in unemployment benets and job-to-job reallocation
Labor market Technical change
parameters and prices oH 1-EH oL 1-EL oH =oL
z 0:05 g 0:03, PL 0:660 1.839 2.2 1.240 7.3 1.49
hL 0:7435 g 0:01, PL 0:568 1.870 6.2 1.121 18.1 1.67
z 0:12 g 0:03, PL 0:660 1.849 3.42 1.260 10.9 1.47
hL 0:7435 g 0:01, PL 0:568 1.930 13.3 1.180 28.5 1.63
z 0:12 g 0:03, PL 0:660 1.849 3.42 1.233 5.9 1.50
hL 0:90 g 0:01, PL 0:568 1.930 13.3 1.175 27.1 1.63
Notes
12. We use observations for the average unemployment rates over the period 1971
1974 from Nickell and Bell (1995).
13. A higher rate of job-to-job reallocation in Europe than in the United States is con-
sistent with the evidence in Boeri (1999).
References
Card, D., and T. Lemieux. 2001. Can Falling Supply Explain the Rising Return to
College for Younger Men? A Cohort-Based Analysis. Quarterly Journal of Economics
116: 705746.
Caselli, Francesco. 1999. Technological Revolutions. American Economic Review 89:
78102.
Davis, S. J., and J. Haltiwanger. 1992. Gross Job Creation, Gross Job Destruction and
Employment Reallocation. Quarterly Journal of Economics 107: 819863.
Eicher, T. S. 1996. Interactions between endogenous human capital and technological
change. Review of Economic Studiess 63: 127144.
Eicher, T. S. 1999. Training, Adeverse Selection and Appropriate Technology. Journal
of Economic Dynamics and Control 23: 272246.
Eicher, T. S., and P. G. Kalaitzidakis. 1997. The Human Capital Dymension to Foreign
Direct Investment: Training, Adverse Selection, and Firm Location. In Trade, Dynam-
ics, and Growth, ed. B. Jensen and K. Y. Wong, 337364. Ann Arbor: Michigan Univer-
sity Press.
Feenstra, R. C., and G. H. Hanson. 1999. The Impact of Outsourcing and High-
technology Capital on Wages: Estimates for the United States, 19791990. Quarterly
Journal of Economics 114(3): 907940.
Galor, Oded, and Daniel Tsiddon. 1997. Technological Progress, Mobility, and Eco-
nomic Growth. American Economic Review 87: 363382.
Wage Inequality and Technical Change 317
Nickell, Stephen, and Brian Bell. 1996. Changes in the Distribution of Wages and
Unemployment in OECD Countries. The American Economic Review 86(2): 302309.
OECD. 1993. Employment Outlook. Paris, July.
Yemen, 24t
Yemtsov, R., 156
Ying, Y., 164, 176