What Is Microfinance and What Does It Promise

Download as docx, pdf, or txt
Download as docx, pdf, or txt
You are on page 1of 16

https://www.cairn.

info/revue-finance-et-bien-commun-2007-2-page-
64.htm
Microfinance institutions are currently experiencing very high
repayment rates of between 95-99%. Coupled with growing loan
sizes by clients, these institutions are even making profits. No
wonder there seems to be a good reason for the world to celebrate
the microfinance revolution. It is not necessarily wrong to reduce
poverty and make some money on the side. The question however
arises as to whether that is indeed what is happening with
microfinance.

What is microfinance and what does it


promise

2
R. P. Christen (1997) defines microfinance as the means of providing
a variety of financial services to the poor, based on market-driven
and commercial approaches. These services may include savings,
insurance, money transfers and credit. However the microfinance
movement to date has generally favoured microcredit, which is the
provision of small loans to households who are perceived to be too
poor to qualify for loans from formal financial institutions. This essay
mainly discusses microfinance to these very poor clients who cannot
even borrow as individuals, but must borrow through a joint liability
group.
3
Poor households are caught up in a vicious cycle of poverty, where
labour, their best resource, is locked up due to different constraints
including a lack of liquidity. The households productivity as such is
limited to a level whereby the available household income is
insufficient to sustain good standards of living. For example a poor
household may have family members who are willing to work in the
family garden to grow sufficient food crops. However if they cannot
afford improved crop varieties and farm inputs then it will not be
possible for the family to grow enough food. The households labour
is therefore said to be locked up due to a liquidity constraint among
other constrains.
4
Many governments and donor communities believe that the liquidity
constraint is the most important constraint impeding poor
households and that if it is addressed it will be possible for
households to escape poverty. Economists argue that to break the
vicious cycle of poverty, there needs to be an outside force that will
break the vicious chain by injecting some liquidity, thereby
unlocking the household labour. Microfinance promises not only to
break the vicious chain of poverty but also to initiate a whole new
cycle of virtuous spirals of self-enforcing economic empowerment
that leads to increased household well-being.

Misleading assumptions

5
Such is the model that has promoted the microfinance institution
and given it the polite and respectable image it currently enjoys.
With all due respect, it is worth raising some questions regarding the
underlying assumptions of such a popular model.
6
In the first place, proponents of the model assume that many poor
people can become micro-entrepreneurs. Entrepreneurship skills and
managerial capability are assumed as given, thus the ability for
microfinance to create employment even if self-employment.
Secondly, even if the first assumption were correct, the model
continues to assume that there is going to be a vibrant market for
goods and services and that it will be possible for all micro-
entrepreneurs to gain access to markets for their products;
otherwise how else can incomes be improved from entrepreneurship
if there were no markets? Thirdly, the supporters of this model also
assume that as long as the poor can repay at market rates, or
slightly above market rates, it is a good indication that they are
doing well financially. Ironically, one of the major reasons why it was
felt so justified to bring more formal financial services to the poor
was because it was assumed that the local money lenders were
exploiting the poor by charging extortionate interest rates. Yet the
poor were paying even then!
7
The point is that microfinance should be understood as a resource
reallocation policy tool and, just like any other such policy, it is
important to keep close watch of the underlying assumptions, for if
they are not valid, the policy objectives may not be realized.
8
The main objective of this essay is not to challenge, prove or
disapprove anything, but rather to bring to light the realities of what
the poor people have to cope with in order to repay their loans
promptly. The goal is to bring the social and financial costs
associated with microfinance instalments to the awareness of the
policy maker.

Keeping loan repayments high

9
Over 120 million people currently benefit from the services of over
10.000 microfinance institutions paying interest rates of between 15
and 35%. In November 2006 the official Microfinance Information
Exchange, Inc. released some thought-provoking statistics from the
leading microfinance institutions. The most profitable microfinance
institution in 2006 was in Africa, with an average of 30.90% return
on assets, followed by another in Asia with an average of 30.2%
return on assets. On average the top 100 most profitable
microfinance institutions worldwide have an average of 10.44%
return on assets. The second largest microfinance institution after
Grameen (in terms of client outreach) is ASA, with over 4 million
clients. ASA has a 14.53% return on assets and it is among the top
15 global microfinance institutions in terms of profitability.
The top 5 Microfinance institutions in terms of outreach are all in
Asia where high population density is the norm, coupled with a high
level of poverty and lack of alternative finance. These unfortunate
social characteristics are the ones that make Asia a prime market for
microfinance. D. Roodman and U. Qureshi (2006) argue that the real
genius in microfinance is not because they firmly believe that the
poor can pay, but rather it is because they have been able to come
up with clever solutions to the problems of building volume, keeping
loan repayment rates high, retaining customers, and minimizing
scope for fraud, and being able to deliver cost-effective microfinance
to thousands and millions of poor clients.
Figure 1 - Loan repayment by the poor

10
Microfinance institutions have innovatively shifted two classic
banking obligations to the borrowers. Firstly, it is the poor who
decide the credit worthiness of borrowers through peer selection into
the borrowing groups. Secondly, it is still the poor who impose debt
collection from peers while being governed by innovative contracts
that are too costly to breach.

Four principles for repayment

11
The popular explanation of how the poor repay their loans is based
on four principles. The first is the principle of dynamic incentive to
loan repayment. This means that the lending institution will offer the
prospect of a larger loan once an individual borrower has been able
to repay the current loan.
12
This alone is supposed to be an incentive to the clients to finish
repaying their current loan and qualify for a larger one. Proponents
of joint responsibility borrowing argue that dynamic incentives make
microfinance for the poor operate in a similar fashion to the credit
card in developed countries, whereby clients repay because they
want to access more credit in the future. Other writers have argued
that the same dynamic incentive is a great incentive for providing
bridging loans to poorer households in order to clear their earlier
debts. Poor microfinance clients are therefore likely to get locked up
in a vicious debt cycle, contracting more debts to repay
microfinance debts in order to get more funds and hopefully offset
the debts so far incurred. The clients keep borrowing to repay, until
the ultimate face to face with excess debt. Excess debt can deplete
household capital assets and other basic livelihood assets, thereby
leaving the household exposed and vulnerable.
13
The second is the principle of joint responsibility borrowing. This
means that a group of borrowers rather than the individual is
responsible for repaying microfinance loans. If the individual
borrower defaults, the whole group is held responsible. The third is
the principle of peer monitoring and peer pressure. The individuals
within a group monitor and bring pressure to bear on each other to
ensure that all loans are repaid on time. In case the individual is not
able to repay due to having made wrong investment decisions or for
some other reason, then all the members of the group have a moral
obligation to help in the repayment. Finally, joint liability borrowing
is purported to thrive due to the principle of forced savings.
Individual borrowers are forced to save a fixed regulated amount of
money every month.
14
Neither the group nor the individual can access the forced savings at
will, but they can be used as security for future loans and can only
be paid back if the individual borrower is dropping out of the project
and has been cleared by all members of the group. The forced
saving is not only a partial security for loans borrowed by an
individual, but can also be seized by the microfinance institution if
any other member(s) of the group defaults on their loan repayment.

A success story

15
The best-known story in microfinance is that of Muhammad Yunus,
the founder of the Grameen Bank who has inspired many other
microfinance institutions worldwide. The Grameen Bank started in
the aftermath of the countrys war of independence. At this time
Bangladesh was plagued by desperate poverty aggravated by very
high birth rates. The economy was still very rural, coupled with a
government that was perceived to be weak and corrupt. In order to
deal with the poverty situation, there was a strong preference for
non-bureaucratic grass roots and other collective approaches. This
prompted the formation of self help groups for equally
disadvantaged groups in order to pool resources for the mutual
benefit of the group members. It was in this environment that
Muhammad Yunus, an Economics professor at the University of
Chittagong, began an experimental research project, providing
credit to the rural poor of Bangladesh. He began by lending people a
little money out of his own pocket and soon realised that it was
enough for villagers to run simple business activities like rice
husking and bamboo weaving. He later found that borrowers were
not only benefiting greatly by accessing the loans but they were also
repaying reliably even though they could offer no collateral. Later,
with the support of the Central Bank of Bangladesh and donor
support, that humble experiment developed into the worlds most
famous microfinance institution, the Grameen Bank, and institutions
that replicate its pioneering methodology worldwide. The Grameen
Bank today boasts a Nobel Prize, 1.700 branches, 16, 000
employees, and 6 million customers of which 96% are women.

not always that good

16
However, the microfinance story does not always have such a good
track record. A study carried out by the International Food Policy
Research Institute (IFRI) that focused on the Malawi Rural Finance
Corporation came up with rather unconventional results (Diagne,
2000). The results were in sharp contrast to conventional wisdom
and assumptions regarding the informal advantage of the joint
liability and its implications of incentives for peer selection, peer
monitoring and peer pressure with respect to loan repayment. The
findings did not support the widely held assumption that joint
liability is responsible for the high repayment rates of the successful
group lending programs. In particular the study found that no
effective peer monitoring was taking place in the credit groups
because of the associated social costs.
17
Another important finding of the same study is that peer pressure
took place less frequently than implied by the joint liability, and
when it did in most cases it failed to induce defaulters to repay their
loans. M. Schrieder (2003) argues that joint liability borrowing may
lead to domino effects, in which borrowers who would have repaid,
choose to default because they would lose access to future loans in
any case, due to the default of others. In reality joint liability may
not cut the cost of lending but rather shift it from lenders to
borrowers.
18
A study by J. Kiiru and J. Mburu (2007) found that joint responsibility
borrowing in Kenya today does not necessarily mean zero collateral
loans. Peers no longer agree to guarantee each others loans based
on sociological ties and trust alone; rather they demand a tangible
guarantee that the loans shall be repaid. Unlike in Asia where
shame, honour and reputation are important incentives to loan
repayments by poor clients in the groups, those are of no great
importance in Kenia, while it is possible for a client to get a loan and
move to another village or city, without being much concerned
about such social stigmas.
On the contrary D. Roodman and U. Qureshi (2006) write: even MFIs
(in Asia) that do not employ either joint liability or regular group
meetings for transaction purposes tap into this sensitivity to
reputation for delinquency control: XacBank in Mongolia posts
names of clients and their instalment repayment reports on the
walls of its branches. Peer pressure, [] is pressure arising from
public transactions in communities where individuals worry about
reputations. And the discovery is not really new to micro credit;
money lenders too have used public honor to motivate repayments.
When interviewed, a woman street vendor who was a client of a
group of moneylenders called the Bombays in the Philippines
noted that the Bombays always picked the busiest hour of the day to
collect so that there would always be witnesses to her
embarrassment.

Trust is not enough

19
Faced with the fact that trust does not provide systematic solutions,
joint liability borrowing groups have invented drastic measures to
deal with un-cooperating peers. In the study by J. Kiiru and J. Mburu
(2007), the joint liability groups studied had included two
preconditions for prospective new members that had to be met
before being admitted as members of the group.
20
The first precondition is that a prospective member will have to
formally sign a contract with her peers, guaranteeing her future
loans with collaterals; the assets used for this kind of transaction are
basic livelihood assets such as livestock, household furniture and
cutlery; also accepted are capital assets such as sewing machines,
and electronic equipment and the suchlike.
21
Secondly, the prospective member must also provide an acceptable
guarantor for her loans. The guarantors acceptability is based on his
or her ability to repay. This person is obliged to sign documents
accepting responsibility for defaulted loans by the borrower.
22
The same study revealed the existence amongst all solidarity groups
of a rigorous administrative structure to ensure that every loan is
repaid on time. For example, in order to minimize the risk of non-
repayment by some poorer borrowers, solidarity groups advise their
weaker members to start submitting their loan instalments to the
groups treasurer on a weekly basis. There is need for research to
help understand the extent to which forced savings and weekly loan
repayments lead to undercapitalization of small enterprises and to
what extent this undercapitalization compromises returns and
therefore incomes.
23
Microfinance lending institutions impose financial penalties on
groups that delay the remittance of a loan instalment. These
penalties are borne equally by all group members. This gives an
incentive for group members to exclude very poor households or
colleagues who have a bad debt repayment record, in order to
minimize the risk of penalties in case of default. The financial
penalties also have the effect of making peers extremely aggressive
when dealing with a colleague who is not in a position to meet her
immediate financial obligations. In many cases such instances lead
to strained relations in social networks. Again there is a need to
understand the extent to which strained social relations lead to a
depletion of the social capital in poor communities.
Group meetings are held on a weekly basis, and are usually
attended by a loan officer to ensure that all due instalments are
collected. In some cases the loan officer will not agree to end a
meeting until all the instalments have been repaid. It frequently
means the groups officials (chairperson, treasurer and secretary)
are obliged to use the groups pooled fund.

From harassment to loss of property

24
These funds are raised through group registration fees, and regular
contributions to a pool. Usually this money is not banked, but held
by the treasurer of the group. In the event of there not being enough
money in the pool, the officials may resort to borrowing from friends;
and if this is still not adequate, they may even choose to borrow
from the local money lenders to avoid the consequences imposed by
the microfinance institution, and to keep their records clean with the
institution. Once the group has cleaned its records with the
microfinance institution, they may take possession of the assets of
the defaulted borrower until every cent of the debt has been repaid.
25
Currently the only way to avoid repaying a loan and get away with it
(at the risk of the forced savings only) is if all members of the group
decide to do the same. However microfinance institutions already
have taken measures to minimize these kinds of eventualities. They
do not grant loans simultaneously to every member of the group,
but rather do so on a rota basis. In this way, at any given time, there
are those members who have already begun repaying and have
almost finished their repayments. This group will rationally exert
pressure on the others to repay. In this case it is almost impossible
for the entire group to default, and leads to the likelihood of all loans
being repaid. D. Roodman and U. Qureshi (2006) observe that
through an interaction of human ingenuity and evolutionary
dynamics, microfinance leaders have found a set of techniques in
their product design and management, that solve the fundamental
problems of microfinance of cost control, building volume, keeping
repayment high, and preventing internal fraud, while operating in a
poor country.
26
In the study by J. Kiiru and J. Mburu (2007) revealed that at least
60% of microfinance clients had experienced some form of
harassment by fellow group members in an attempt to convince
them to repay loans on which they would otherwise have defaulted,
given their current financial capability. 4% had had some of their
property confiscated by group members to settle loans on their
behalf, while another 17% had actually sold some of their pre-
existing assets in order to meet their repayment obligations, and a
further 2% had to borrow from friends and relatives to meet their
repayment obligations. Domestic animals, furniture, and electronic
goods and sometimes clothing were some of the major assets sold
or confiscated from the poor to repay the loans.
There is a greater than ever need to set up a regulatory framework
for microfinance that would protect existing property of the
borrowers. As expected, such a regulatory policy is likely to change
the operations of microfinance institutions in an attempt to reduce
the risk to their clients. However this should not be viewed
negatively, as microfinance is a policy tool for resource reallocation.
And like any other such policy, subsequent adjustments are
inevitable, to ensure that the policy intervention tool continues to be
relevant to the objectives for which it was devised.

A call for regulatory policy

27
Just as personal bankruptcy should not be a reason for banning
access to credit cards or mortgages in richer countries, it is also not
rational to denigrate the whole idea of loaning to the poor. It is
nevertheless important to realize that in the quest to alleviate
poverty, it is possible to capitalize on the benefits of microfinance,
while minimizing vulnerability to crisis, by improving debt
management capacities of the poor and by setting up clear
regulations in the microfinance sector. There is therefore a need to
create policies that increase the demand for goods and services in
rural areas; otherwise the benefits of entrepreneurship to peoples
livelihood cannot be achieved.
28
It is not necessarily wrong for the poor to borrow to meet basic food
needs. However savings rather than microfinance would offer a
better alternative. This is because it is unsustainable to depend on
excess debt for consumption purposes. This calls for innovative yet
cheaper technologies to meet the very basic needs of food, health
and education. All this should be neatly wrapped together with
responsible governance, in terms of resource mobilization and
reallocation. This should be developed to ensure that households
would need credit for reasons other than for meeting basic
consumption needs, but rather to use for income-generating
activities that bring about real increases in income. This would
provide an efficient way of lending money to the poor, since only
those who can make best use of it in terms of entrepreneurship will
require access to credit.
Finally there is currently a receptive attitude within the national and
international community to microfinance instruments and, by and
large the microfinance institutions still have a polite and
respectable image among many donors and governments. It is also
true that there is no major apparent crisis or emergency in the
microfinance institutions. But there are signs of cracks in the overall
impact that microfinance has had among poor borrowers. These
borrowers continue to operate under such tight debt schedules that
it is a real struggle for them to build business volume and therefore
growth for the enterprises, let alone escape poverty. This calls for
regulatory policy, and it is important to note that policies
implemented in tranquil times can help prevent major problems in
the future.

Annexe

[Synthse en franais]

29
Les conomistes affirment que, pour briser le cercle vicieux de la
pauvret, il faut une force extrieure qui injecte de largent, afin de
librer la force de travail de lconomie familiale.
30
La microfinance promet non seulement de casser le cercle vicieux
de la pauvret, mais aussi dinitialiser un nouveau cercle vertueux
sappuyant sur un potentiel conomique gnrateur de bien-tre.
31
Limportant est de comprendre la microfinance comme un outil
pratique de redistribution des ressources et, de mme quavec
nimporte quelle politique similaire, il est important davoir lesprit
les prsupposs sous-jacents, parce que si ceux-ci ne sont pas
fonds, les objectifs poursuivis peuvent savrer irralistes.
32
Ici, lobjectif principal nest pas de poser des problmes, de prouver
ou dsapprouver quoi que ce soit, mais plutt de mettre en vidence
les pressions auxquelles doivent faire face les pauvres pour
rembourser leurs emprunts rapidement.
33
Les institutions de microfinance ont innov en reportant deux
obligations bancaires traditionnelles sur les emprunteurs.
Premirement, cest les pauvres qui dcident de la solvabilit des
emprunteurs, entre pairs. Deuximement, cest encore les pauvres
qui se chargent du recouvrement de la dette dautres membres du
groupe, dans le cadre de contrats novateurs quil serait trop coteux
de dnoncer.
34
Lhistoire la plus connue en microfinance est celle de M. Yunus, le
fondateur de la Grameen Bank qui a inspir de nombreuses
institutions de microfinance travers le monde.
35
La Grameen Bank a aujourdhui son actif un Prix Nobel, 1700
succursales, 16000 employs et 6 millions de clients dont 96% sont
des femmes.
36
Cependant, lhistoire de la microfinance ne se passe pas toujours
aussi bien.
37
M. Schrieder (2003) constate quune coresponsabilit des
emprunteurs peut mener un effet domino, dans lequel des
emprunteurs qui auraient pu payer dcident de ne pas le faire,
sachant quils nauraient de toute faon pas accs de futurs
emprunts cause de linsolvabilit dautres dbiteurs.
38
Contrairement lAsie o la honte, lhonneur et la rputation sont
des motivations importantes pour que les clients pauvres dans un
groupe remboursent leurs emprunts, cela importe peu au Kenya,
alors quil est possible pour un client demprunter de largent et de
partir pour un autre village ou une autre ville, sans tre trop
stigmatis socialement.
39
Confronts linsuffisance de la confiance dans les recherches de
solutions, les groupes demprunteurs solidairement responsables ont
imagin des mesures drastiques pour traiter ceux de leurs membres
qui ne cooprent pas.
40
Les institutions de prt de microfinance infligent des pnalits
financires aux groupes qui ont du retard sur le remboursement
dun acompte. Ces pnalits retombent de manire gale sur tous
les membres du groupe. Cela donne une motivation aux membres
du groupe dexclure les mnages ou les collgues trs pauvres qui
prsentent de mauvaises perspectives de remboursement, de
manire minimiser les consquences en cas de non-
rembousement.
41
Selon ltude de J. Kiiru et J. Mburu (2006), au moins 60% des clients
de microfinance ont connu certaines formes de harclement par des
membres de leur groupe, mis sous pression pour leur faire
rembourser des emprunts quils nauraient pas pu assumer en
regard de leur situation financire relle.
42
Les animaux domestiques, les meubles, les objets lectroniques et
parfois les vtements ont t parmi les principaux objets vendus ou
confisqus aux pauvres pour rembourser des emprunts.
43
Il est donc ncessaire de mettre en place des politiques pour
augmenter la demande de biens et de services dans les
campagnes ; autrement, la qualit de la vie ne pourra pas tre
amliore par lentrepreneuriat.

References

Christen, R. P., 1997. Banking services for the poor: Managing


for financial success, Washington DC, ACCION International.
Diagne, A., 2000. Design and sustainability Issues of Rural
credit and Savings Programs: Findings From Malawi, Washington DC,
IFRI Policy Brief No12.
Kiiru, J. and Mburu, J., 2007. User Costs of Joint Liability
Borrowing and their Effect on Livelihood Assets for Rural Poor
Households, International Journal for Gender Women and Social
Justice, July-December.
Roodman, D. and Qureshi, U., 2006. Microfinance as Business,
Working paper No101, Washington DC, Centre for Global
Development.
Schreiner, M., 2003. A Cost-Effectiveness Analysis of the
Grameen Bank of Bangladesh, Development policy Review, Vol.21,
No3.

Plan de l'article
1. What is microfinance and what does it promise

2. Misleading assumptions

3. Keeping loan repayments high

4. Four principles for repayment

5. A success story

6. not always that good

7. Trust is not enough

8. From harassment to loss of property

9. A call for regulatory policy

Pour citer cet article


Mueni Maina Kiiru Joy, Microfinance: Getting Money To the Poor or
Making Money Out Of the Poor? , Finance & Bien Commun, 2/2007
(N 27), p. 64-73.

URL : http://www.cairn.info/revue-finance-et-bien-commun-2007-2-
page-64.htm
DOI : 10.3917/fbc.027.0064

You might also like