Fatal Side Effects: Medicine Patents Under The Microscope
Fatal Side Effects: Medicine Patents Under The Microscope
Fatal Side Effects: Medicine Patents Under The Microscope
Acknowledgements iii
Oxfam GB's Health Programme iv
Summary 1
Introduction 1
The health crisis 2
How much will the new patent rules increase prices? 2
Is TRIPS 'flexible' enough, and are the public-health safeguards adequate? 3
Will patenting in developing countries stimulate research into the diseases of poverty? 5
Is TRIPS good for development and poverty reduction? 6
The IP that TRIPS does not protect 6
Corporate social responsibility 7
Oxfam's principal recommendations 7
1. Background 9
Introduction 9
What is a patent, and what do World Trade Organisation (WTO) patent rules do? 9
Why are patents a health issue? 10
The development damage of excessive IP protection 12
Trade rules are loaded against the poor 13
3. The impact of WTO patent rules on access, prices, and local industry 16
The new generation of medicines 17
Effective patent duration under TRIPS 17
Price differences 18
TNC views on the relation between prices and patents 19
The effect of patent systems on industry as a whole 20
i
Contents
9. Patent politics 38
Who makes the rules? 38
Who polices the rules? 38
Which governments want to change the rules 39
and which do not? 40
Public opinion 41
Who is responsible in London, Brussels, Geneva, and Washington, and in the boardrooms? 41
Bibliography 50
Endnotes 54
ii
Acknowledgements
This report was produced by the Policy Department of Oxfam (Great Britain) as part of the Cut
the Cost of Medicines Campaign. The principal authors were Michael Bailey, Ruth Mayne, and
Dr Mohga Smith.
Oxfam has simultaneously issued two other publications as part of this Campaign: a shorter
report entitled Patent Injustice: How World Trade Rules Threaten the Health of the Poor; and
'Dare to Lead', an analysis of the responsibilities towards the developing world of
GlaxoSmithKline, the UK-based pharmaceuticals company. All three publications and further
information on the Campaign are available from Oxfams website
(www.oxfam.org.uk/cutthecost) or from Anni Long ([email protected]), tel no: +44 (0)1865
312127, fax no: +44 (0)1865 312245.
iii
Oxfam GBs health programme
Oxfam GBs health programme addresses five broad themes: access to basic health services
(including the issue of financing), access to essential medicines, access to water and
sanitation, responding to HIV/AIDS, and health programmes in schools. This work focuses on
reducing inequities, including those based on gender, and improving the appropriateness and
quality of services. The programme spreads across more than 25 countries. Local projects
support some of the most marginalised and impoverished groups. Others address the health
needs of communities affected by conflict or natural disasters. Drawing on this experience and
on research findings, Oxfam seeks to work with others to change policies, practices, ideas, and
beliefs that affect poor peoples health.
In India, Oxfams HIV/AIDS programme aims to increase treatment, care, and support for those
infected and affected, as well as raising public awareness about the disease, while in Southern
Africa we are piloting programmes to integrate responses to HIV/AIDS into development work.
In Bangladesh, Sri Lanka, Ethiopia, Somaliland, South Sudan, and Liberia, Oxfam supports the
rehabilitation of community health centres and the development of basic services, including
medicine supply. In the Caucasus, the programme involves training health workers, improving
access to essential drugs, and the development of community health insurance schemes. The
Network for Consumer Protection, an Oxfam partner in Pakistan, promotes peoples access to,
and the rational use of, essential drugs. In Afghanistan, Oxfam has ensured that basic health
services have been made available to remote communities in the highlands.
Oxfam GB is widely known for its public health work in emergencies. The rapid supply of clean
water to populations displaced from their own homes is vital, and Oxfam GB has particular
expertise in this area. In recent years, major programmes have been established in the Great
Lakes Region of Central Africa, in the Balkans, in Angola, and in the State of Orissa in India.
iv
Fatal Side Effects:
Medicine Patents under the Microscope
Summary
Introduction
Every week, 200,000 people die of infectious diseases, the great majority of them women, men,
and children living in poverty in the developing world. Global patent rules agreed at the World
Trade Organisation (WTO) in 1994 are deepening this public-health crisis by increasing the
cost of medicines. In this report, Oxfam argues that governments must amend the rules now to
ensure that impoverished people have access to the medicines they so desperately need, at
prices they can afford. This demand is at the centre of a public campaign launched by Oxfam in
February 2001.
The WTO rules, laid down in the Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property
Rights (TRIPS), were introduced after sustained lobbying by transnational corporations (TNCs).
The Agreement obliges the member countries to grant at least 20-year patent protection in all
fields of technology, including medicines. This enables already powerful Northern
pharmaceutical TNCs to consolidate their market domination on a global scale. Longer patent
periods will delay the appearance of the low-cost generic equivalents that traditionally supply
developing-country needs only the expensive, patented version of a new medicine will be
available. At a time when millions of people are already unable to afford essential medicines,
and when public health is threatened by a combination of new diseases and drug-resistant
variants of old killers, WTO rules will further reduce access to modern medicines for poor
people, and lead to unnecessary death and suffering. The controversy surrounding the price of
patented HIV/AIDS drugs in Southern Africa has already drawn public attention to this issue.
This report is structured as follows. Section 1 explains briefly how the WTO patent rules work
and how they will affect the price of medicines in developing countries. It also sets out Oxfams
concerns about the wider negative effects of the rules, and the way in which management of
the international trading system puts corporate interests before poverty reduction. Section 2
describes the health crisis in developing countries. Section 3 examines the likely effect of WTO
patent rules on the price of medicines and on local pharmaceutical industries. Section 4 looks in
more detail at WTO rules and their implementation in developing countries, giving Oxfams
assessment of the flexibility that supposedly enables governments to ensure access to
affordable medicines, and examining the problem of TRIPS plus systems. The issue of
whether high levels of patent protection will stimulate pharmaceutical research and
development (R&D) relevant to developing countries is considered in Section 5. The
relationship between TRIPS and the problem of bio-piracy in the pharmaceutical field is
addressed in Section 6. Section 7 deals with the need for governments to fill the gaps in
pharmaceutical research and increase health-sector support, while Section 8 looks at what
companies could do to make drugs more affordable. Section 9 considers the politics of patent
rules who makes the decisions, and where governments stand on the issues. The final part,
Section 10, presents the full range of Oxfams policy recommendations. These focus on TRIPS
reform and on the need for rich countries and TNCs to stop harassing developing countries on
patent issues; they also cover the necessity for public funding for research into new medicines,
and the role that industry could play in making medicines affordable.
1
The health crisis
Medicine prices will rise in the context of a growing health crisis. Although there have been
improvements in health indicators in many developing countries, 11 million people, the great
majority of them poor, die every year from infectious diseases. AIDS claims three million of
these lives, tuberculosis two million, and malaria one million. This human tragedy is
compounded by the economic consequences of ill health, which destroys opportunities for
poverty reduction. Africas gross domestic product (GDP), for example, would be one-third
higher if malaria had been eliminated 35 years ago. Drug-resistant strains of many common
diseases such as pneumonia are spreading fast, making existing medicines redundant and
posing a threat to public health in the industrialised world as well. In addition, developing
countries face a rising incidence of First World illnesses such as heart conditions, cancer, and
diabetes. The HIV/AIDS epidemic now infecting 25 million people in sub-Saharan Africa
demonstrates the huge risk posed by previously unknown diseases. All the new or improved
drugs developed to face these challenges will be under patent for at least 20 years and, unless
something is done, will be too expensive for people living in poverty.
The causes of public-health crises are complex. One in five of the worlds population does not
have access to health services. Poor nutrition, inadequate water supply and sanitation, and the
low quality of education are major contributory factors to ill health. Underlying these failures is
the lack of equitable economic growth, itself a product of both national and international factors
and the lukewarm commitment to poverty-reduction policies by many governments. Where
governments have done their best, they have been seriously constrained by public-expenditure
cuts caused by debt obligations and the structural adjustment packages prescribed by
international creditors over the last two decades. Developing-country governments could do
more to make medicines accessible to the poor. Many continue to spend far less on public
health than on other priorities, such as military budgets. The impact of inadequate overall
spending is compounded by inequitable patterns of spending. All too often, tertiary-level
services used mainly by better-off groups absorb a disproportionately large part of the health
budget, while primary health care is chronically under-funded.
2
figure is likely to be an underestimate - for some products, prices could be ten or twenty times
higher. But of course many sick people will simply do without, making TRIPS a prescription for
a public-health disaster.
Until recently, many developing countries either exempted drugs from patenting or allowed only
limited patenting. Some created national industries capable of producing inexpensive
equivalents of new patented products appearing elsewhere. Under TRIPS, every member of
the WTO must introduce a comprehensive IP protection system, with a minimum 20-year term
for all patents, including medicines, or face costly disputes that could lead to trade sanctions. In
effect, patents on life-saving drugs are treated the same way as patents on ice-cream
machines. Seventy developing countries had to be TRIPS-compliant by January 2000; the
least-developed countries (LDCs) have been given an extension until 2006.
Under the even stronger national patent protection demanded of developing countries by the
pharmaceutical TNCs and some industrialised countries, monopolies for medicines are being
extended still further. These TRIPS plus rules are based on the most restrictive interpretation
of TRIPS, weaken the public-interest safeguards it allows, or contain even longer protection for
patent holders. Countries such as South Africa, Brazil, the Dominican Republic, and Thailand
have been threatened with trade sanctions by the United States if they do not bring laws
governing pharmaceuticals into line with what the TNCs want. In the case of the Dominican
Republic, sanctions would have destroyed the jobs of thousands of women working in the
textile industry and damaged the countrys economic growth.
The rules affect all drugs with patents filed after 1995, some of which are already on the market
and some still under development. These include any new or improved medicines for treating
TB, malaria, and HIV/AIDS, and for drug-resistant pneumonia, meningitis, and gonorrhoea.
Advances in biomedical science hold out hope for novel medicines able to treat existing or new
infectious diseases, as well as traditionally First World diseases. Oxfam fears that all these
new drugs will be surrounded by patents and priced out of reach of developing-country health
services and individual families. Where there is widespread drug resistance, the established,
cheap treatments are becoming ineffective, but people will not be able to afford the substitutes,
or will suffer even greater economic hardship in their effort to pay. Women will be deterred
more than men from buying medicines for themselves because of financial austerity or lack of
control over family resources. Higher prices exacerbate the problem of people not completing
courses of treatment or taking the right doses, which contributes to the spread of drug-
resistance.
Some industrialised countries claim that the patenting issue is not crucial for public health in
developing countries since only five per cent of the current WHO (World Health Organisation)
Model List of Essential Drugs is under patent. However, one criterion for inclusion in the list,
which helps developing countries decide which medicines they must prioritise in the face of
severe resource constraints, is price. This rules out a number of vital but expensive products,
such as anti-HIV/AIDS drugs. With the spread of drug resistance and with new or improved
drugs appearing, the number of essential, patented products will grow. And as one developing-
country trade official put it to Oxfam, When peoples lives are at stake, five per cent is five per
cent too many. Some Third World governments argue that drugs on the WHO list or
comparable national lists should be exempted from patenting in developing countries.
3
about the negative development impact of TRIPS, including the threat to public health, some
industrialised-country governments now accept a more liberal application of the Agreement, and
indeed extol its flexibility as a virtue. Oxfam welcomes this shift, but argues that the value of
this flexibility should not be overstated, and that the Agreement remains seriously flawed. The
problems stem, firstly, from the demands of the Agreement itself, and secondly, from the
political reality in which it is being implemented.
With regard to the terms, the simple fact is that TRIPS gives countries no choice about
important aspects of their national IP law and about the huge extension of patent protection for
all products and processes, including medicines. Moreover, the safeguards to protect public
health are hedged with conditions that make them difficult to operate, especially for the poorer
countries:
1. TRIPS allows countries to adopt measures necessary to protect public health but then
qualifies the principle by requiring that measures be consistent with the Agreement. Oxfam
believes that TRIPS should be amended to include a stronger statement on the primacy of
public-health needs, similar to the general exception clauses found in other WTO
agreements.
3. TRIPS also allows a country to pass laws which enable it to import a patented product from
wherever it is sold cheapest, whatever the wishes of the patent holder. This parallel
importing is an effective restraint on the most abusive pricing, especially if there is a
country with effective price controls from where medicines can be obtained. However, with
the extension of 20-year patenting worldwide and the resulting lack of generic competition,
the tendency will be for patent holders to set higher prices everywhere, and there may be
less parallel differential. TNCs and the US government have been pressing vigorously for
national laws to prohibit parallel importing, which Oxfam believes should be resisted. If
TRIPS were consistent with the WTOs ostensible trade liberalisation philosophy, it would
outlaw such prohibitions.
The problems with the terms of the Agreement are compounded by the political realities. The
United States is using political pressure and the threat of trade sanctions to force countries to
enact laws which are based on a highly restrictive interpretation of TRIPS, which dilute or
exclude key public-health safeguards, or which strengthen patent protection beyond the
minimum standards set by TRIPS. Until recently, the European Union was also overtly
pressing for strict interpretations of the Agreement. Many developing countries do not have the
political strength or technical expertise to resist these pressures. Nor do they have the ability to
make good use of any safeguards once legislation is in place, either for fear of expensive
litigation with companies, or because they cannot afford being taken to the WTO court by
powerful countries. These realities underline the pressing need for the WHO to provide
independent data and technical assistance to poor countries, but they also call into question the
nature of TRIPS itself.
At the moment, powerful countries and the pharmaceutical TNCs are using the flexibility of
TRIPS to their advantage, imposing their interpretations of the grey areas of the Agreement on
developing countries. The formal arbiters of ambiguity are the WTO Dispute Settlement panels;
but, regrettably, their decisions may give more weight to economic concerns and to the
commercial standards prevailing in the industrialised countries, and less weight to development
4
goals or to the public interest. WTO member-states could collectively issue definitive
interpretations of TRIPS that protect the common good over the interests of big business, but
this will require sustained pressure from public opinion.
One aspect of the deepening global health divide between rich and poor is the tragic failure of
the pharmaceutical industry to meet the need for medicines in the developing world. Only ten
per cent of health research targets the illnesses that make up 90 per cent of the global disease
burden. A miserly 0.2 per cent of research effort is directed to diarrhoea, pneumonia, and TB,
which cause 18 per cent of all illness. Instead, TNCs are geared to manufacturing medicines of
commercial interest, which means producing for the consumers in the industrialised world who
make up 85 per cent of their market. Because poor women do not have the money to become a
market, for example, there is little investment in the development of vaginal microbicides effective
against sexually transmitted diseases, including HIV.
Advocates of a high level of patent protection in developing countries argue that it will stimulate
research into the diseases from which poor people suffer. For diseases common to rich and
poor countries, the argument is bogus. Since most developing-country markets will remain
relatively small for the foreseeable future, the extra revenue for companies will make no
perceptible difference to R&D investment decisions. The lucrative markets will be the better-off
households in economies like Argentina, Brazil, India, and China the prizes sought by TNCs
through the worldwide extension of IP protection. But the pattern of illness among the middle
classes in the developing world is similar to that in the industrialised world, so their demand
does not stimulate research into the diseases common among low-income families. For these
diseases, the purchasing power of 1.2 billion people living on US$1 a day simply does not
constitute a commercial incentive to R&D investment a reality admitted by companies
themselves. Spending on drugs by health ministries is also not large enough to act as a
significant stimulus. 61 countries have public drug expenditure of less than US$10 per capita.
Drug TNCs justify patent protection by the large sums needed for R&D; yet what matters is not
that R&D is costly, but whether there is an adequate return on the investment. In the case of
the pharmaceutical industry, returns are among the highest of any sector. While patents in
Northern markets do generate huge resources for companies, only a relatively small part is
allocated to therapeutically valuable research. Company figures for R&D spending are
frequently exaggerated indeed, marketing costs are often double expenditure on R&D.
Moreover, a great deal of research goes into non-essential drugs, or into prolonging the life of
money-spinning patented products by changing a dosage or formulation. Much socially useful
research is funded by governments, charities, and, through fiscal incentives, by the taxpayer.
5
Given the fact that the market fails hundreds of millions of people living in poverty, there is an
overwhelming case for major investments by governments in R&D, as well as in health-care
delivery systems, and in subsidising access to treatment for those who cannot pay. Oxfam
believes that increased public funding is the most effective and efficient way of generating the
appropriate research. This effort should harness the strengths and capacity of industry, North
and South. In order to maximise the benefits to people in poverty, governments should exercise
due control over financial returns to the private sector. Oxfam proposes the creation of an
international fund for research into medicines and vaccines, supported by governments
worldwide, in proportion to their means. Operating under the auspices of the WHO, this
mechanism could help to fill the gaps in funding and overcome the fragmentation of current
research efforts and public-private partnerships.
Not only does TRIPS lack a credible development rationale, but many developing countries had
little idea what the Agreement would commit them to in reality, and little choice about signing,
since it was an integral part of the Final Act of the Uruguay Round. Oxfam therefore believes
that there should be a far-reaching review of the public-health and development impact of
TRIPS, reopening discussion on the appropriate length and scope of IP protection for poor
countries. The TRIPS review due in 2001 offers an excellent starting point.
TRIPS established different deadlines for country compliance. This provision was based on the
practical recognition that it takes time to set up IP-protection systems, but does not contradict
the one size fits all approach of the Agreement, with which Oxfam disagrees. There is a strong
case for linking transition periods to changes in development indicators rather than to arbitrary
dates. A developing country could introduce higher levels of patent protection earlier for product
areas where it has achieved international competitiveness, for example software in India. A delay
in implementation would also help the many countries currently facing the huge administrative
and financial burden of instituting complex IP systems.
6
needed for the invention, and about the identity of the legitimate owners or originators of that
knowledge. Secondly, the Agreement requires countries to allow patenting of micro-organisms
and microbiological processes. This, combined with loose interpretation of inventiveness in
national Patent Offices, accelerates patenting of genetic resources and stimulates appropriation
of developing-country biological assets by Northern companies. If a two per cent royalty were
levied on genetic resources, the North would owe the South more than US$5bn in royalties for
medicinal plants alone. Many developing countries want TRIPS amended to require patent
applicants to disclose the origin of the resources or knowledge they are using, to obtain the prior
informed consent of the original knowledge-holders, and to share the benefits with them. A tight
definition of inventiveness and novelty in national law would exclude applications where the
subject matter is not a real invention, or where the knowledge is already in the public domain.
Although an equitable pricing system makes drugs more affordable in developing countries, it
should be seen as a complement to the strategy of maintaining a low level of patent protection
on medicines in poor countries and letting generic competition reduce prices. Equitable pricing
does pose a significant administrative challenge, which does not arise with the market-based
approach. Moreover, with TRIPS untouched, many generic manufacturers will be out of
business, and developing countries will become increasingly dependent for drug supply on a
handful of Northern transnational corporations. In contrast, with the kind of patent regime for
medicines many developing countries had before TRIPS, there is scope to develop national
industry and greater pharmaceutical self-sufficiency, with corresponding benefits for livelihoods
and health security. For these reasons, while calling for fairer TNC pricing, Oxfam also
stresses the need for reform of WTO rules. Since the UK is the worlds second-largest exporter
of pharmaceuticals, and Europe as a whole supplies 75 per cent of the branded drugs imported
by developing countries, European companies and governments have a major responsibility to
act urgently on both these fronts.
An international fund totalling US$5bn should be established under the auspices of the
WHO to fund research into new medicines and vaccines for infectious diseases plaguing
poor countries. Resulting patents should be held as public goods, and prices controlled in
order to ensure full benefit to people living in poverty. Funding should also be increased for
primary health services and drug purchases in LDCs.
7
Rich countries, above all the USA, should stop using global trade rules and the threat of
trade sanctions to force developing countries to introduce the excessively strong national
patent laws sought by the pharmaceutical TNCs.
TNCs should reduce the price of key medicines in developing countries to improve access
by poor people and reduce pressures on over-stretched health-service budgets. Prices
should be determined within the framework of a standardised, transparent system of equitable
pricing which would offer drastically reduced prices to the poorest countries. Companies should
also accept the introduction of strong public-health safeguards into patent laws.
8
Fatal Side Effects:
Medicine Patents under the Microscope
1. Background
Belkis Perez, 31, lives in a shack in Puerto Plata in the Dominican Republic. Belkis and her
second child, Jennifer, who is now seven years old, were diagnosed HIV-positive three years
ago, when she was pregnant with her third daughter, Yania. She did not receive the
medication that would have prevented transmission of the virus, and Yania was also born with
AIDS. Since then a large slice of the family budget goes each month on buying medicines,
because the girls often suffer from amoebic dysentery, colds, or influenza. When Oxfam talked
to Belkis in November 2000, she complained of stomach pains, but had not consulted a
doctor, concerned about the price of the medicines she might be prescribed. Unable to afford
costly anti-retroviral drugs that would combat AIDS, she said, I cant really see a future, not for
me, not for my children. But we will keep on struggling. A monthly course can cost up to
US$1,200 12 times the minimum salary. We just cannot budget for anti-retrovirals, says Dr.
Raul Benoit, head of the governments essential medicines programme. 1
The United States, the Dominican Republics main export market, has threatened trade
sanctions against the country if it does not ban the production or import of cheap generic
drugs that compete with US-patented products, including those needed to treat HIV/AIDS.
Introduction
Through its international relief and development programmes, Oxfam is acutely conscious of
the health crises now afflicting a number of countries, most notably in Africa. In the sub-
Saharan region, decades of community effort to build better lives are being swept away by the
HIV/AIDS epidemic. In 25 countries, Oxfam is supporting health workers who are facing
increasing challenges to public health with ever-diminishing budgets. Several years ago we
were prompted by the worries of our local partners and public-health groups about the effects of
patenting on the prices of priority medicines (a concern also voiced by developing-country
governments) to research the subject in more depth and to take up the policy issues.
We are also increasingly aware of how world trade rules and global economic management, of
which the patent regime is now part, are affecting the lives of people living in poverty, and so
we have stepped up our research and advocacy in that field. The present paper aims to support
our campaign for improved access to essential medicines, and our campaign for a fair
international trading system.
9
Until now, there has been no global minimum level of patent protection, giving governments
considerable flexibility to decide upon the coverage and legal framework for patents, in
accordance with their national interests. The WTO IP rules, now coming into force in many
developing countries, introduce new global standards for all member states. Prior to this, many
developing countries excluded products such as medicines or plants from patentability, or had
short patent periods in order to keep prices down and encourage local industry. Up to 50
countries, including Brazil and Argentina, 2 did not grant patents for pharmaceuticals. Some,
such as India and Egypt, granted only process patents, thereby allowing local firms to produce
products, patented elsewhere, by alternative processes. Some governments, while granting
patents, routinely issued compulsory licences on public-health grounds, authorising third
parties to manufacture a patented product without the consent of the patent holder.
Use of these measures will be seriously curtailed by WTO rules. Ironically, these policy options
were precisely what enabled many industrialised countries to establish their pharmaceutical
industry. Many European countries, including Switzerland, home of many innovative
pharmaceutical companies, resisted providing pharmaceutical product patents until their
industries had reached a certain degree of development. France introduced product patents in
1960, Germany in 1968, Japan in 1976, Switzerland in 1977, and Italy and Sweden in 1978. 3
Yet in 1994, 123 nations, rich and poor, agreed mandatory, multilateral rules for IP protection.
The Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS) was formally
an appendix to the Final Act of the Uruguay Round of trade negotiations, which simultaneously
gave birth to the WTO. The Agreement was described as a set of minimum standards, but in
practice it constituted the most significant extension of patenting rights in the twentieth century.
The pharmaceutical industry had achieved its greatest-ever lobby victory.
TRIPS obliges countries to treat patents on life-saving drugs as essentially the same as patents
on ice-cream machines, despite the fact that essential drugs are more akin to public goods, and
access to them is a human right. The Agreement goes some way towards recognising this by
allowing safeguards to protect public health, including the right of States to override a patent
10
and authorise third-party production of a medicine. But these safeguards are difficult for
developing countries to use in practice, and are often not incorporated into the national
legislation now being introduced. Some industrialised countries, notably the United States, are
using political pressure and the threat of trade sanctions to force countries to enact laws which
are based on a highly restrictive interpretation of TRIPS, which exclude key public-health
safeguards and which extend IP protection beyond the minimum required by TRIPS. This drive
for TRIPS plus legislation reflects the continued influence of the pharmaceutical transnational
corporations (TNCs) over Northern and developing-country policies, in pursuit of their
commercial interests.
New national patent legislation will take effect at different moments, although all WTO member-
states, even the poorest in the world, must be compliant with the whole of TRIPS by 2006. If
they are not, rich countries can take them to the WTO court, which can authorise trade
sanctions if non-compliance continues. Even before new laws take full effect, developing-
country governments must grant market exclusivity for up to five years for medicines for which
a patent application has been filed after 1995. This exclusivity has the same effect as a patent.
There are concerns that companies in developing countries are already abandoning the
practice of developing generic versions of new patented medicines coming on to the market,
and are under intense pressure to stop producing some of the generics that they already supply
at low prices, such as treatments for HIV/AIDS and related conditions.
1. India, Mexico, China, Argentina, and Korea have quite sophisticated manufacturers who are capable
of innovation in complex manufacturing processes. In India, within three to five years of a new
patented drugs first appearance in a Northern market, the local industry has had an equivalent on
sale in the Indian market, and available for worldwide export to other developing countries where the
patent is not valid.
2. Eight countries, including Brazil, Cuba, and Egypt, can produce both therapeutic ingredients and
finished products, and export to regional markets. They also have some innovative capacity in
production processes. Some keep reliance on proprietary brands to a minimum generics supply 93
per cent of the market in Egypt, for example. 7
3. Eighty-seven countries, including the Dominican Republic, Pakistan, and South Africa, produce some
finished products from imported compounds, mainly for the domestic market.
4. Fifty-nine countries have no pharmaceutical industry at all. They have very small domestic markets
and are totally reliant on imports. Most African countries are in this situation.
In the first three categories, manufacturers include the big international companies as well as local
companies operating under licence or producing generics. Overall, foreign-owned firms probably account
for more than half of production in developing countries, though in India, for example, their share is only
20 per cent. Virtually all countries import medicines produced by the big international companies,
although the degree of dependence on these products varies enormously. In the majority of countries,
imports are principally supplied by the big companies, but most also buy some medicines from generic
producers, North and South. Developing countries accounted for 7.2 per cent of world exports in 1988,
with India leading the field with 1 per cent.
11
The development damage of excessive IP protection
Just as knowledge is becoming the undisputed centrepiece of global prosperity (and lack of it,
the core of human impoverishment), the global regime on intellectual property rights requires a
new look. The United States prevailed upon the world to toughen patent codes and cut down on
intellectual piracy. But now transnational corporations and rich-country institutions are patenting
everything from the human genome to rainforest bio-diversity. The poor will be ripped off unless
some sense and equity are introduced into this runaway process.
Jeffrey Sachs (1999)
Everyone has the right to share in scientific advancement and its benefit.
Article 15, Universal Declaration of Human Rights
Patent laws are one of the ways to encourage innovation, and thus offer benefits to society.
However, the rules must strike an appropriate balance between the commercial interests of the
innovator and the public good. In multilateral agreements, a balance must also be struck
between the commercial interests of the advanced industrial nations and the development
needs of poorer countries. Oxfam and many public-interest organisations believe that the
TRIPS Agreement and the associated national legislation in the pipeline in developing countries
are extremely unbalanced on both counts.
Excessive IP protection will have a negative impact on economic development, raising the cost
of the technological expertise and products to which poorer countries need access if they are to
compete and grow. For example, there are widespread concerns about the threat to rural
livelihoods posed by the extension of patenting in agriculture, which will increase the price of
seeds and other inputs. Industrialisation usually relies on reproducing the technologies of the
more advanced economies, and patenting only becomes of interest to a country when it has
developed a capacity to innovate. 8 Indeed, the United States itself copied British technology
extensively in the nineteenth century. It is sometimes claimed that strong patent protection in
developing countries will stimulate foreign investment, because companies will be less afraid of
their intellectual assets leaking into the local economy, but this is a relatively small potential
benefit. In this light, the story of how TRIPS came to have a place at the WTO is one of
remarkable achievement. It is remarkable because one country, the US, was able to persuade
more than 100 other countries that they, as net importers of technological and cultural
information, should pay more for the importation of that information. 9
High levels of patent protection will reinforce the growing market domination of the global
corporations, who hold 90 per cent of patents. The marginalisation of small and medium
enterprises in developing countries will have a negative impact on poverty reduction and equity.
Some people in government and business in the industrialised world are now saying that todays
high level of IP protection amounts to restrictive practice and is stifling competition everywhere.
This fear is reinforced by the vertiginous rise in the number of patents, and the extension of
patenting into controversial areas such as business methods and gene research. In 1999, IBM
alone took out 2,756 US patents. Critics also cite the problem of inadequate scrutiny of patent
applications and loose definition of the criteria for patentability, especially in the USA.
TNC mobility and power also make it difficult for governments in impoverished countries to
regulate them in pursuit of national development strategies, to control their anti-competitive
practices, or to override patents on public-health grounds. The frenzy of fusion among
pharmaceutical TNCs heightens anxiety over excessive corporate power. The December 2000
merger of UK-based Glaxo Wellcome with SmithKline Beecham created a conglomerate
(GlaxoSmithKline - GSK) that leads the field in anti-infective, respiratory, and vaccine products,
and whose combined revenue in 1999 was US$27.2bn. 10 This is equivalent to 315 times
Ugandas public-health budget and 27 times that of Bangladesh, a country with 125 million
people. 11 Pfizer, which recently acquired Warner-Lambert, was expected to earn approximately
US$31bn in 2000, including US$24bn in prescription pharmaceutical sales, 12 making its income
larger than the GDP of 115 developing countries.
12
A number of developing-country governments, notably those of African nations, are deeply
unhappy about TRIPS. Oxfam believes there should be a far-reaching review of the public
health and development impact of the whole Agreement, reopening discussion on the
appropriate length and scope of IP protection for poor countries, and giving countries greater
freedom to decide their own patenting regimes.
The lid opens: When TRIPS was signed in 1994, few people in the industrialised countries,
apart from an inner circle of trade officials and business lawyers, knew what the small print
would mean for the real world. The mere mention of IP rules would bring glazed looks to the
eyes of most politicians, and the broader public was barely aware that such rules existed.
That began to change in 1997, when the US government, with support from the European
Union, provoked a storm of controversy by attempting to coerce South Africa to change its
policy on patents, which drug companies claimed violated TRIPS. In 1998 the then vice-
president of the European Commission, Sir Leon Brittan, wrote to vice-president MBeki of
South Africa saying that the 1997 Medicines Act would appear to be at variance with South
Africas obligations under the WTO Agreement on TRIPS and its implementation would
negatively affect the interests of the European pharmaceutical industry. 13
Pretorias offence was to introduce a law enabling it to avoid paying the exorbitant prices that
international pharmaceutical companies were asking for their patented HIV/AIDS drugs by
importing copies made by other developing countries and sold at one-tenth of the cost.
South Africa had decided that reducing the incalculable suffering of four million victims of the
disease was more important than passing the patent laws that the industrialised countries
were demanding at the behest of their corporations. Fortunately, a rising tide of public
opinion obliged the US administration to back away from trade sanctions, though its officials
continue to raise concerns with Pretoria. The companies, however, have stepped up their
offensive. The South African pharmaceutical manufacturers association, which represents
the international companies, is taking the government to court in a bid to stop the importation
of cut-price drugs. 14 The case will be heard in March 2001. Some observers believe that
South Africa was not breaching the TRIPS Agreement, which highlights the fact that
safeguards in the rules are not enough to ensure that, in practice, countries can confidently
place public health before corporate interests.
13
2. The health crisis in developing countries
The burden of disease
The extension of patenting on medicines is happening in the context of a growing health crisis.
Although there have been improvements in health indicators in many developing countries,
eleven million people, nearly half of them children, die each year from infectious diseases. 15
Pneumonia is the number-one killer, taking three and a half million lives. AIDS claims a further
three million, and TB two million. Another million more succumb to malaria most in Africa, and
75 per cent of them children. 16 Although the 48 least-developed countries (LDCs) face the
greatest challenges, countries with higher per capita gross domestic product (GDP) but with
marked social inequalities, such as Peru and Brazil, also face high levels of meningitis, malaria,
dengue, cholera, tuberculosis (TB), and respiratory infections.
This human tragedy is compounded by the economic consequences of ill health, which will
claim even more lives as the prospects for poverty reduction ebb away. It has been estimated
that sub-Saharan Africas GDP would be up to US$100bn greater if malaria had been
eliminated 35 years ago. 17 At the household level, an illness can affect the livelihoods and
earnings capacity of the whole family. Oxfam research in Vietnam found poor farmers selling
buffaloes to meet health costs. In Kampala, Uganda, three-quarters of poor urban households
surveyed by Oxfam reduced spending on meals in order to buy medicines a single episode of
sickness cost one-third of their monthly income.
Drug-resistant diseases, once they take hold, spread fast and pose a huge threat to public
health. Malaria is re-emerging where previously under control, often in strains against which
established treatments are helpless. Over the next 20 years, one billion people will be newly
infected with TB, and 35 million will die, many of them from the resistant strains spreading
throughout the developing world. 18 The WHO describes the development of drug-resistant
gonorrhoea as one of the major health-care disasters of the twentieth century. 19 As with all
sexually transmitted diseases, women are particularly vulnerable to the infection, and less likely
to seek treatment. Untreated gonorrhoea greatly increases the risk of HIV/AIDS infection,
infertility, and miscarriages. This highlights the need for more attention to the diseases that
affect women, countering the gender bias present in most health systems. In Zambia,
resistance levels to front-line treatment for cholera and malaria exceed 60 per cent, and simple
antibiotics are now ineffective in 40 per cent of respiratory infections. 20 Drug resistance is a big
problem in Bangladesh. In coming years, it will be more dangerous than HIV, says Dr Samir
Saha, head of microbiology in Dhakas childrens hospital. We have recently lost four patients
to multi-drug-resistant disease. Eventually there will be new drugs, but they will be even more
expensive than the antibiotics we use now, adds chief paediatrician Dr Zaman Khan. 21
High drug prices, together with the lack of health services, contribute indirectly to the creation of
drug resistance. Because of the expense, sick people take less than a full course of medicine,
or stop treatment before completing a course. They feel better, but the strains not killed off
develop resistance. Along comes a new treatment, which is inappropriately used, resistance
builds up, and there is need for yet another new drug. The development of microbial resistance
is worse in developing countries, but resistant strains are spreading and causing concern to
health authorities in rich countries too. Scandinavia, for example, is worried about multi-drug-
resistant TB spreading from Russia.
Developing countries also face a rising incidence of traditionally First World diseases such as
cardiovascular conditions, cancer, and diabetes. To complete this grim picture, the HIV/AIDS
epidemic has demonstrated the risk posed by newly virulent diseases, of which Ebola and West
Nile Fever are other recent examples. It has been estimated that HIV now infects 25 million
people in sub-Saharan Africa. 22 In Zimbabwe, perhaps one in every four adults has the virus,
and in Botswana the figure could be more than one in three. In both countries, life expectancy
has fallen by about seven years. 23
14
The effects of the HIV/AIDS epidemic in Southern Africa are felt throughout Oxfam's
programmes. Across the region, staff turn up for meetings and activities with communities
only to find them postponed as key people fail to appear, owing to their own illness, to the
demands of caring for others, or to attendance at funerals. Ethan Mhlanga, Oxfams co-
ordinator in Zimbabwe, recalls a village near Masvingo where all but a few people were
prevented from attending a project meeting because there were six funerals that day. When
there is a funeral in a community, all adults are expected to attend. Imagine, if you have to
go to funerals daily, you don't have time for the project. In one Zimbabwean partner NGO,
most of the key people are not coming to work regularly because of their poor health. If
those people are lost, it will virtually destroy an organisation that has been working to reduce
poverty.
The causes of the public-health crises are complex. One in five of the worlds population does
not have access to health services. Poor nutrition, lack of water and sanitation, and the low
quality of education are major contributory factors to ill health. Underlying these failures is the
lack of equitable economic growth, itself a product of both national and international factors,
and a half-hearted commitment from many governments to poverty-reduction policies. Where
governments have done their best, they have been seriously constrained by public-expenditure
cuts caused by debt obligations, and the structural adjustment packages imposed by
international creditors over the last 20 years.
Although tackling disease depends critically on appropriate social and economic policies, as
well as on interventions in the health field, one piece of the jigsaw is access to effective,
affordable medicines and vaccines. As noted by Dr. Brundtland, Director General of the WHO,
access represents a very important measure of the quality of health services. It is one of the
key indicators of equity and social justice. 24 Access is particularly sensitive to price, because
most poor people in developing countries pay for medicines out of their own pockets, and State
health services spend a significant share of their budgets on pharmaceuticals. And price is
related to the presence of monopoly, or market exclusivity, in pharmaceutical markets, now
greatly extended by the TRIPS Agreement a point regrettably missed out in Northern
government discussions. Nevertheless, the G-8 has strongly reaffirmed its support for the UN
targets to reduce the number of HIV/AIDS-infected young people by 25 per cent and to halve
the deaths and illness caused by TB and malaria by 2010, although it remains to be seen
whether effective action will follow.
In developing countries, most prescription medicines are bought over the counter by individuals
(often without a prescription). State health services and private insurance schemes cover at
best 50 per cent of purchases, and at worst only 10 per cent. 25 In South Asia, the figure is
around 20 per cent. In Oxfams experience very poor people do buy medicines, especially if the
15
illness is life-threatening, though often with great sacrifice by the family. Medicines find their
way into remote rural areas via traders or people who have been visiting the towns. If people do
not have the cash for medicines, they will sell animals or other assets, even land. Household
research by Oxfam in Manila, in the Philippines, found poor families borrowing from relations or,
if desperate, from moneylenders. Of course, at times people will simply go without medicines.
This is particularly true for women, partly because they have less income than men, tend to
have less control over household spending, and may be less able to sell assets or borrow.
Developing countries spend a much higher proportion of their national health budgets on
pharmaceuticals than industrialised countries over one-fifth in the case of Mali, Vietnam, and
Colombia. And these budgets are sometimes tiny. Oxfam research found that the allocation for
drug purchases in the Delanta area of Ethiopia is nine US cents per person per year. 26 Even in
countries with much greater resources, the burden of drug procurement is substantial and could
become intolerable. For example, if Brazil provided patented treatments to HIV/AIDS sufferers,
the cost would consume the entire national drugs budget. Fortunately, despite US pressure,
Brazil continues to manufacture equivalents at one-fifth of the cost of the US products and is
making them widely available. This has reduced mortality rates by 50 per cent since 1996. 27
Price increases shall be a regular feature, and not an accident, with the introduction of and/or
strengthening of patent protection in developing countries. One outstanding example is the
case of pharmaceuticals. There is an uncontested and solid set of studies, undertaken in
developed and developing countries, and in institutions such as the World Bank and
International Monetary Fund, that consistently indicate that developing countries are going to
suffer from substantial price increases and other costs.
Prof. Carlos Correa
(academic and TRIPS negotiator for Argentina during the Uruguay Round) 28
16
The new generation of medicines
TRIPS requires all member states to give longer market exclusivity to all drugs with patents
filed after 1995, some of which are already on the market and some of which are being tested.
These include new or improved medicines for treating TB, malaria, and HIV/AIDS, and for drug-
resistant pneumonia, meningitis, and gonorrhoea. Scientific advances hold out hope for novel
medicines able to treat existing or new infectious diseases, as well as cancer, heart disease,
and diabetes, which are increasingly prevalent in developing countries. Oxfam fears that all
these new drugs will be ringed by patents and priced out of reach of developing-country health
services and individual families. The European Commission, in a frank moment, accepted that
the problem had already arrived: Several key products to prevent, diagnose and treat
HIV/AIDS, malaria and tuberculosis, largely produced in industrialised countries, under patent,
are still too expensive for the poor. 30
Where there is widespread drug resistance, the old treatments are becoming ineffective, but
people will not be able to afford the substitutes, or will suffer even greater economic hardship in
their effort to pay. A WHO study showed that a staggering 70 per cent of patients with chest
infections were resistant to first-line antimicrobials and needed newer antibiotics. 31 Dr
Brundtland has stated, With the onset of resistancenewer treatments are proving too costly
to the vast majority of those living in poor developing nations. 32
Major advances in bio-medical science, including genomics, hold out hope for a new generation
of medicines to prevent or treat the newly virulent diseases appearing worldwide, and to deal
more effectively with some old, intractable illnesses. Mass screening of molecules for potential
therapeutic value can be carried out relatively cheaply, for example. Sequencing of the TB
bacillus genome occurred two years ago, and genetic sequencing of the parasite that causes
malaria is currently underway, allowing new lines of research. Improvements can also be
expected in treating cancer and diabetes. However, unless national governments are exercising
rigorous control, all these new medicines will be priced out of reach of the worlds poor.
It has been argued that the patenting issue is not crucial for developing countries, since only
five per cent of the WHO Model List of Essential Drugs is currently under patent. The 308-
strong list includes basic medicines that address common diseases safely, effectively, and
inexpensively. Health ministries use it as the basis for their national-priority drug lists, on which
scarce resources are concentrated. Yet since the WHO model list takes price into account, a
number of vital medicines are excluded, such as anti-HIV/AIDS drugs. The list is periodically
revised, and with the spread of drug resistance and the appearance of new or improved
medicines, the number of essential but patented products will steadily grow. Developing-
country governments have spoken out against even five per cent being subject to patenting
because of their importance in treating disease, and have called for TRIPS to allow automatic
patent exemption for drugs on the WHO list or on comparable national lists.
The evidence suggests that WTO rules could extend the market exclusivity for new or improved
patented drugs sold in developing countries by as much as ten or even fifteen years. During
that period, prices will be far higher than they would otherwise have been. Although there are
methodological problems when quantifying the price effect of new patenting laws and of TRIPS
specifically, it is possible to make some rough estimates for each country. Further research in
this area should be a high priority for concerned governments and for the WHO, which has a
mandate from its 1999 Assembly to monitor the impact of TRIPS on public health.
17
In the past, after a novel, patented medicine has appeared in an industrialised country, it has
taken an Indian drug company about four years to develop an equivalent generic product. 33 It
then takes a year or two for this equivalent to establish a foothold in domestic and foreign
markets and obtain the economies of scale that reduce costs. This meant that the TNC
originator has had an effective monopoly for perhaps five to six years in countries with low levels
of IP protection, such as India. Under TRIPS, the worldwide patent term is a minimum of 20
years, but since the TNC originator spends the first five to ten years after filing on research, trials,
and obtaining regulatory approval for its new product, the effective monopoly in the market
becomes 10 to 15 years. Product-development times have been falling over the last decade or
more, thanks to technological advance and faster regulatory processes, so the average period of
effective monopoly is now probably closer to 15 years. This double bonus for pharmaceutical
patent-holders underlines how the extension of patent periods in TRIPS has little to do with social
benefit and everything to do with corporate gain.
Under the even stronger patent rules demanded of developing countries by the pharmaceutical
TNCs and some industrialised countries, above all the USA, monopolies will be extended still
further. These rules, commonly referred to as TRIPS plus, are based on the most restrictive
interpretation of TRIPS, contain extra protection for patent-holders, and weaken the safeguards
contained in TRIPS (see Section 4 for further details).
Price differences
The difference in price between patented and non-patented medicines is substantial in all
countries. One indicator of the price effect of market monopoly is the difference between the
price of patented drugs in markets with strong patent laws (i.e. no competition), and the price of
generic equivalents produced in competitive markets where there is no patenting. As Table 1
illustrates, there is a stark contrast between the prices of patented products in ten industrialised
countries and the price of the non-patented equivalent in India. For example, Roches
ceftriaxone, an anti-infective for respiratory tract infections, meningitis, and gonorrhoea, sells for
between US$1,525 and US$3,380 in rich countries, while its Indian generic equivalent sells for
US$277. According to UNAIDS, a combination of two AIDS drugs, AZT and 3TC, made by UK-
based GlaxoSmithKline (GSK), that sells for about US$18 a day in the USA, and US$7 a day in
Uganda, is marketed by generic manufacturers in Brazil for US$1.50. 34
Table 1:
Retail prices for medicines under patent in ten OECD countries, and for their generic
equivalent in India. (Prices of 100 units in US$, surveyed in 1999) 35
18
Some of the price differences in these examples might be attributable to higher production
costs in OECD countries, for example, or to currency exchange-rates. However, price
comparisons between developing countries with different patent regimes show similar results.
One study shows that prices in Pakistan, which grants product patents for pharmaceuticals, are
3 to 14 times higher than in India, which will not grant them until 2005. 36 The most widely used
anti-infective generic drug in India is ciprofloxacin, which is manufactured by nearly fifty
companies. The drug is effective in the treatment of resistant shigella. Shigellosis causes most
of the estimated 370,000 deaths from dysentery that occur worldwide each year in children
under the age of five. 37 Its patented equivalent is eight times more expensive in Pakistan than
in India. Although Pakistan is relatively richer than India, the difference in income is too small to
explain the price differentials. The conclusion must be that when India moves to strong
patenting, prices will rise significantly.
This opinion is shared by Nihchal Israni, president of the Indian Drug Manufacturers
Association, who says prices in Pakistan, the Philippines and Indonesia, which now recognise
product patents, are three to five times Indian prices. 38 A simulation study of the Indian
pharmaceutical market shows that the price increase following the introduction of product
patents could be 250 per cent. 39 In relation to the developing world as a whole, the author
concludes that TRIPS requires the availability of product and process patents for
pharmaceuticals virtually from 1995, dramatically changing patent laws in developing countries
that earlier allowed such exclusions. This change will, almost certainly, lead to higher prices up
to about 200300% for patented medicines, including for some important diseases such as
HIV/AIDS, in countries where such patents are valid. 40 Reports from China suggest that drug
prices in Beijing and Shanghai have risen three or four-fold since the introduction of higher
levels of patent protection in 1993.
Another indicator of the impact of patenting is a comparison between the price of a patented
product in a country where it enjoys a effective monopoly, and the price where it faces
competition, as graphically illustrated by Pfizers fluconazole sold in Thailand. The price of this
treatment for fatal meningitis, contracted by one-sixth of Thai HIV patients, plummeted from
US$14 to US$3 after local generic versions appeared at US$1. 41
Evidence from the UK also points to a substantial price gap between patented and generic
products: the average cost to the National Health Service of a generic prescription is 3.78, and
that of a branded prescription is 13.04. A US Congressional Budget Office study of
prescription charges showed that those for patented products cost three times as much on
average as those for generics. In Canada, between 1969 and 1993, compulsory licensing kept
prices low and helped the development of the Canadian generic-drugs industry. In 1993, the
practice of compulsory licensing was eliminated as part of the North American Free Trade
Agreement, thus reducing the supply of cheaper generics. 42 The Drug Manufacturers
Association, representing generic companies, estimated that the cumulative cost of this change
to patients and taxpayers would be CAN$1.7bn by 2000, rising to CAN$4bn by 2010. 43
19
TNCs also argue that there are significant differences in quality between their products and
those produced by generic manufacturers in developing countries, so like is not being
compared with like. There is a problem of lower production standards and lack of regulation,
and governments need to address the issue, but the quality difference is commonly
exaggerated. Top-quality generic producers, such as Cipla Ltd. in India, meet the standards
necessary to supply the UK and US markets, yet still sell at greatly reduced prices.
i Ceftriaxone sodium, on which Hoffman-La-Roche holds nearly 100 Swiss patents, can be
used in the treatment of acute respiratory-tract infections that led to 3.45 million deaths in
1998. According to Bala and Sagoo, 44 this antibiotic costs 30 per cent more in Latin
America than in developed countries. Despite desperate need and crippling constraints on
Africas health budgets, GSKs lamivudine, used in the treatment of HIV/AIDS, is 20 per
cent more expensive in Africa than in the ten industrialised countries surveyed.
i A 1998 survey of 13 drugs found that prices in Tanzania were 50 per cent higher than in
Canada. An unskilled worker had to work 8 days to buy these medicines in Canada, and
215 days in Tanzania. 45
In an effort to defuse criticism of the price effect of patents, TNCs sometimes point out that
branded medicines that are off-patent are also more expensive than generics. This is true, but
the price of the branded product usually falls sharply after patent expiry, even if a differential
remains. Branded off-patent drugs marketed by the original patent holders can often command
a better price than their rivals because of the market domination and brand loyalty that the
company consolidates during its effective monopoly period and reinforces with expensive
promotion. TRIPS contributes to this domination by prolonging the effective monopoly period.
Another blow to the generic competition, and the final step towards the commercial
commodification of medicines, could be allowing TNCs to advertise prescription drugs direct to
consumers. This is still prohibited in the UK and much of Europe, but the companies are
lobbying energetically to change the rules. In the developing world, where many people buy
prescription drugs over the counter or from a local trader, the public will be extremely
vulnerable to direct marketing.
The fact that pharmaceutical TNCs can sell their products at huge premiums in some
developing countries, even though cheaper generic equivalents are theoretically available on
the international market, shows that the global marketplace is far from perfect. There is certainly
not a free flow of information and products. Indeed, many smaller countries pay excessive
amounts for drugs because they do not know what is available where, and they do not have a
centralised purchasing scheme. This lack of information and organisation, combined with little
experience of IP protection, is one reason for doubting that low-income countries will be able to
resist international pressure for excessively strong patent protection, or that they will be able to
exploit the public-health safeguards in TRIPS. Section 4 looks in more detail at these safeguards.
20
pharmaceutical manufacturers came to offer some of the lowest prices in the world,
successfully exporting to 130 countries. Local companies fear that TRIPS will now allow
Northern TNCs to consolidate gradually their monopoly position. Much of the Indian industry,
which employs nearly half a million people, may fail financially, although some of the biggest
firms will survive by allying with the TNCs.
Developing countries that seek to stimulate their national drug industry, as part of their public-
health and industrial development strategy, will find their hands tied. TRIPS Article 27.1 (see
appendix) implies that countries cannot make local manufacture a condition for granting a
patent, although some interpret this article differently. Brazil is currently facing a formal dispute
at the WTO, brought by the United States, because its 1996 Industrial Property law allows the
state to require so-called local working of the patent in certain circumstances. 46
In summary, Oxfams conclusion is that excessive IP protection granted by WTO rules will
make medicines much less affordable to poor people and poor countries, and is therefore
prejudicial to public health. A London School of Economics (LSE) research project on generic-
drug policies, commissioned by the WHO, reached the same conclusion, stating that the
impact of TRIPS on the developing world is significantly negative. In defence of TRIPS,
industrialised countries now claim that developing countries enjoy ample room to design
appropriate national policies, that the Agreement contains adequate safeguards for public
health, and that strong IP protection will stimulate needed research and development (R&D)
arguments that are addressed in the following sections.
Under pressure from developing countries and public interest groups, many rich-country
governments now argue that the TRIPS Agreement is merely a set of minimum standards, and
that its flexibility grants developing countries the leeway to strike an appropriate balance
between the inventors interests, the public interest in innovation, and the public good. This
includes the ability to override a patent when necessary, and to set prices. Moreover, they
claim, there are longer timeframes for developing-country compliance. Oxfam believes this
flexibility is largely illusory, for four reasons:
21
Few developing countries have the specialised legal expertise and experience to interpret
the rules to their own advantage with confidence or to risk costly legal or commercial
battles. This is a fight between David and Goliath. Some of the multinational companies we
are facing are bigger than the Dominican Republic itself, says a representative of the local
generic industry, referring to the US threat to block the countrys exports because of its new
patent legislation. 47
This is the harsh reality of the emerging global IP system, of which TRIPS is the centrepiece,
however it looks from Brussels, Geneva or London.
GSK has warned Cipla Ltd, a rival Indian company exporting vital HIV/AIDS medicines to
Ghana, that further infringement of GSKs patent rights there would be challenged. This
might have pleased some of GSKs shareholders, but it could prove damaging to the
440,000 Ghanaians currently infected with the disease. GSK is selling Combivir
(lamivudine/zidovudine) at US$4.20 per daily dose, 20% more than Ciplas equivalent,
Duovir. There are experts who question whether GSKs claims would be upheld in court. The
patents, which elsewhere run until 2016, do not appear to be valid in Ghana. Yet the warning
has worked, and Ciplas drugs are not likely to be imported in these circumstances. 48 Oxfam
fears that many corporate challenges and threats to local companies and developing
countries go unreported.
GSK has recently offered Combivir to Ghana at US$2 per day as part of the UNAIDS-
sponsored Accelerating Access Initiative for African nations. This matches the price Cipla is
now reported to be offering to Africa. If the Cipla equivalent had not been available, as
competitor or benchmark, what would the price of the patented product be?
GSKs worldwide operating profit on this one drug in 1999 was an estimated US$245m. The
average health spending of member states in the African Regional Industrial Property
Organisation (ARIPO), to which Ghana belongs, is just US$156m.
22
Compulsory licensing
The compulsory licensing provision is important, but most developing countries, even if they
include it in national legislation, cannot derive advantage from it, because it is hedged in with a
number of conditions:
The main problem is that a country needs to have a reasonably advanced pharmaceutical
industry in order to reproduce new medicines, especially if this requires sophisticated
reverse engineering, and must be able to achieve economies of scale to bring the price
down to affordable levels. The great majority of developing countries fail on both counts.
The solution might be to issue a compulsory licence and obtain the medicine from a generic
manufacturer in another country who has the technical capacity. Some experts, such as
Prof. Carlos Correa, argue that TRIPS allows this. The pharmaceutical TNCs argue that it
does not. Whatever, a manufacturer is unlikely to make the required investment or offer a
competitive price unless a compulsory licence has also been issued in the exporting country
or a number of other countries, thereby creating a viable market. This could conceivably
happen for a few medicines but is a hugely more complex and uncertain answer to the
affordability problem than the simple alternative of allowing generic producers into the
market before the minimum 20-year period now mandated by TRIPS.
A compulsory licence has to be revoked once the circumstances that led to its granting
have ceased to exist. The threat that a TNC could drop its local price and cause a licence to
be cancelled could well deter any third party from making the investments necessary to get
a generic equivalent on to the market in the first place.
Compensation must be paid to the patent holder. The basis for this calculation is not fully
specified, and a WTO dispute panel may not opt for a definition that is fair and in the public
interest. In Canada, licensing rules fixed the payment to the patent holder at four per cent of
the domestic sale price, far below what the big pharmaceutical companies wanted, but
these rules were abolished under pressure from the USA.
Double standards? In 1999, under pressure from a public increasingly angry about
medicine prices, the US Congress passed the Prescription Drugs Act, which amends
legislation on compulsory licensing. The Act allows the Secretary of Health to issue licences
where the patent holder has not taken, or is not expected to take within a reasonable time,
effective steps to achieve practical application of the subject invention in a field of use; or to
alleviate health or safety needs which are not adequately satisfied by the patent holder or if
the patented material is priced higher than may be reasonably expected based on criteria
developed by the Secretary of Commerce. 49 However, the US Patent and Trademark office
states that the government regards compulsory licensing as undesirable and unnecessary
anywhere in the world, except where there is a violation of competition law or a declared
national emergency. 50
23
Parallel importing
Parallel importing, i.e. importing from wherever a patented product is sold cheapest, works well
if there are low prices around the world of which to take advantage, and it curbs the highest
pricing by patent-holding TNCs. In 1999, Britains health service made considerable savings by
importing drugs worth 750m from other European countries (though the EU does not allow
parallel importing from outside the region). The potential benefits are illustrated by price
variations for GSKs amoxil: this antibiotic cost US$60 in Germany, US$40 in Indonesia, US$29
in the Philippines and New Zealand, US$16 in Italy, and US$8 in Pakistan. 51 However, with 20-
year patenting worldwide and the lack of generic competition, the danger is that TNCs will set
high world prices, and that parallel importing will offer little benefit.
If one country retains tight price controls, other countries can in theory buy their drugs there. In
practice, the TNCs may restrict supply to the country that operates price controls, so that it can
only meet its domestic needs and has no surplus for export. In Europe, it has proved difficult
under competition law to stop companies doing this. Alternatively, a TNC may operate a dual-
price system in the country with price controls, with a higher selling price for goods destined for
export. The European Commission has prevented GSK employing this practice in Spain,
although the company has taken the case to the European Court.
Across the world, TNCs have been pressing vigorously for national laws to prohibit parallel
imports, as these reduce their capacity to charge the maximum that each individual market can
bear. If TRIPS were consistent with the WTOs ostensible philosophy of removing barriers to
trade, it would outlaw such prohibitions. Oxfam believes that it is vital for developing
countries to retain the right to parallel importing in their national legislation, and for
competition law to prevent TNCs from withholding supply. But if a company agrees to sell
a medicine at a very reduced price in a particular developing country so-called tiered pricing'
it is reasonable that governments should prevent that medicine from finding its way back into
industrialised-country markets. The controls can be negotiated as and when necessary it
does not require a country to outlaw all parallel importing, as the TNCs demand. In the
standardised, global system of equitable pricing proposed by Oxfam, there could be
internationally agreed measures to prevent re-selling in rich markets (see Section 8).
If production under compulsory licence or production of any generic drug is sub-standard, the
best solution is to improve regulation and quality assurance. If these aspects of health policy
are weak, governments should be provided with appropriate technical assistance.
24
How will the grey areas be defined?
Powerful countries and companies are currently exploiting the grey areas of TRIPS to their
advantage, forcing developing countries into accepting their interpretation of the rules. Over
time, the arbiters of ambiguity in TRIPS will be WTO Dispute Settlement panels, usually
composed of trade experts. Since these give more weight to economic concerns and to the
commercial standards prevailing in the industrialised countries, and less weight to development
goals or to the public interest, Oxfam argues for substantial reform to the Dispute
Settlement mechanism to make it a fairer and more balanced process. When disputes
have a non-trade dimension, such as public health, panels should make greater use of
relevant expertise and amicus curiae briefs, possibly establishing joint panels with the WHO or
other appropriate international organisations. Technical assistance to low-income countries for
dealing with disputes should be increased. There should be an appeal mechanism involving an
independent judicial body, though where a case involves a conflict between different
international agreements, it could be dealt with by the International Court of Justice.
Member states, through the WTO General Council or a Ministerial Conference, could
collectively issue definitive interpretations of TRIPS that favour the common good over the
interests of big business, but this will require sustained pressure from public opinion.
Fortunately, increasing numbers of health professionals, non-governmental organisations, and
trade unions are criticising the social and economic damage caused by the Agreement. They
are adding their voices to those of economic liberals in government and the business
community who criticise its damaging effect on competition and efficiency, and even question
its inclusion in the WTO framework. If these coalitions develop in both North and South, there
could be enough leverage to secure not only public health and development-friendly
interpretations of TRIPS but also a commitment by governments to reassess the whole
Agreement, and to stop the implementation of TRIPS plus systems.
25
2. Legal prohibition of the development of an equivalent medicine by a competitor before the
original patent expires. This ban on so-called early working obliges a competitor to wait
until patent expiry before testing and registering a product, thus adding three or four years
to the de facto market monopoly enjoyed by the originator. A recent WTO dispute panel, in
a ruling against the European Commission, clarified that TRIPS allows early working,
although manufacture and stockpiling is prohibited. This reduces the post-patent delay in
the appearance of a generic to some six months. However, national laws can still ban all
early working. US pharmaceutical TNCs press for this in developing countries, even though
US law allows it.
3. Loose definitions of patent criteria, such as inventiveness and novelty, allow companies to
take out a second patent on a product, either by modifying the dosage or an ingredient, or
by inventing a second use. This common industry practice is known as evergreening.
Nearly half of the new drugs approved for use in the USA in the 1990s did not offer
important clinical improvements. Claritin, Schering-Ploughs medication for allergies, which
earned US$2.7bn in 1999, was evergreened by purification, extending its US patent from
2004 to 2014. Schering-Ploughs first patent on the active ingredient was acquired as far
back as 1981. 53 Legally, competitors can copy the older product when its patent expires,
but heavy branding makes it harder to enter the market.
4. In many industrialised countries, including Australia and the USA, governments have been
persuaded of the need to allow extensions to patent duration if it takes an exceptionally long
time to bring a product to the market. These are called Supplementary Protection
Certificates in the EU.
The problem of over-extended patent periods is not new. A review of the evidence in the USA
suggests that the average effective patent life of many new drugs has increased by at least
50% between the early 80s and today. This is mainly due to more efficient management of
R&D and shorter FDA approval times. However, the study also concluded that for companies
able to take advantage of the full array of changes in intellectual property protection, effective
patent life of some drugs may have doubled. 54 Pharmaceutical industry profits also rose
sharply in the same period. One study showed that the 199599 rate of profit in relation to
revenue had risen to four times the Fortune 500 average. 55
The US drugs industry lists countries whose patent laws it considers inadequate. The
offenders find themselves on a watch list maintained by the US government, which can
later lead to unilateral trade sanctions. This Special 301 provision of the countrys trade law
was introduced in 1988 at the request of big business to force countries to introduce strong
protection of IP. It has been used against more than 30 countries. India, Egypt, Brazil, and
Argentina, all of which have strong generic-drug industries, have been among the prime
targets. Apart from its uncertain legality in terms of WTO principles, the use of Special 301
has raised disturbing questions about corporate influence over US trade policy and WTO
rules. The threat of trade sanctions, rehearsed by the USA, is pivotal in the implementation
of the WTO regime.
Given the way in which TRIPS plus further extends corporate privilege at the expense
of the public good, Oxfam believes that rich countries, above all the USA, should stop
using global trade rules and the threat of trade sanctions to force developing countries
to introduce the excessively strong national patent laws. There should be no pressure on
countries to introduce TRIPS plus systems. G-8 countries and the EU should issue a clear
statement to the effect that they will not take action against countries that use compulsory
licensing and parallel importing to respond to public-health needs. The United States should
renounce the use of unilateral trade sanctions for alleged violation of the property rights of US-
based pharmaceutical corporations.
26
Are transition periods the answer?
TRIPS established different deadlines for country compliance. This provision was based on
practical recognition that it takes time to set up IP-protection systems, but does not contradict
the one size fits all approach of the Agreement, with which Oxfam disagrees. Seventy
developing countries were allowed until 1 January 2000 to comply, i.e. an extra five years from
the date when the Agreement came into force. Developing countries that have to introduce
product patents in areas of technology not already protected are granted until 2005. This
includes patent protection for pharmaceuticals and agricultural chemical products. The LDCs
were granted until 2006, and can apply for an extension on a case-by-case basis.
Nevertheless, companies can file patent applications from 1995 onwards. When a countrys
new legislation takes effect, and if the patent is formally approved, the patent protection period
dates from the moment of filing. Patent applications during the transitional period are held in a
mailbox, whereby the applicant obtains exclusive marketing rights for up to five years until the
patent is either refused or granted.
By 2005/2006, few, if any, developing countries are likely to have reached a stage of
development where they can benefit from strong IP protection. Even if patenting does have pro-
innovation effects in some sectors, prolonged across-the-board patent duration is a blunt
instrument with which to achieve it. Nor is there any necessity for patent periods to be the same
globally, given that the socially optimal trade-offs will differ among nations. There is therefore
a strong case for linking transition periods to changes in development indicators rather
than to arbitrary dates, or better still, converting TRIPS to a plurilateral agreement, to
which countries adhere when it suits them. This proposal is consistent with the important
principle, recognised in all WTO agreements, that countries with a lower level of economic
development should not have the same obligations as the advanced industrial nations.
Indicators for adherence to TRIPS might include levels of technological development, capacity
for innovation, and ability to compete internationally. These could be applied on a sector-by-
sector basis. For example, India may have reached a point where it benefits from a high level of
IP protection in the software field, but this does not mean that it gains by introducing the same
level of protection for every other product or process. Deferral of the introduction of TRIPS rules
would also spare countries the huge administrative burden of instituting First World IP systems
(legislation, patent offices, specialised judiciary, enforcement mechanisms, etc.) and the
enormous financial cost, which amounts to tens of millions of dollars. 56
The benefits of price controls are evident in Europe, where governments have kept
responsibility for health services and regulate the type and price of medicines offered within
national systems. France and Spain have been relatively successful at keeping prices down,
and Britain now takes advantage of parallel imports from them. Pharmaceutical companies are
lobbying against these controls and advocate the US system where the market supposedly
decides price. In fact, the combination of business-friendly patent laws and market
concentration in the United States has led to some of the highest medicine prices in the world,
an issue that featured prominently in the 2000 presidential elections.
27
Developing-country health ministries also find it hard to set prices or negotiate good deals on
bulk purchases because they lack information about production costs, and because they are
dealing with powerful, well-organised companies whose revenue will probably be larger than
their national income. Attempts to calculate a TNCs costs can be thwarted by the company
setting an artificially high price for active ingredients exported to its local subsidiary part of a
widespread practice known as transfer pricing. Countries may also face pressure from
individual Northern governments or multilateral donors not to regulate prices, as happened
under Pakistans Structural Adjustment Programme. 57 In Oxfams view, Northern governments
should not prevent developing countries from using policy instruments commonly employed in
rich countries on public-health grounds. Developing countries will be greatly helped in
negotiations with companies if TRIPS allows them the fallback option of issuing
compulsory licences. They will also benefit from increased technical assistance and
comprehensive market data, which the WHO should be funded to provide.
Novartis makes a drug to treat separation anxiety in dogs. No major company is doing new
research into sleeping sickness.
Donald McNeil, New York Times, 21 May 2000
Advocates of high levels of patent protection for pharmaceuticals in developing countries argue
that it will stimulate R&D in the field of tropical and infectious diseases. Oxfam believes that
commercial incentives will still be inadequate, and argues instead for massive targeted
government investment in R&D. This may involve partnership with companies, but governments
should remain firmly in charge and should exercise due control over returns to the private
sector, so that the benefits to poor people are maximised. This proposal is discussed further in
Section 6. First, we look at why the extension of patent protection will not generate more
research into the diseases of poverty, and why patenting in general contributes less to medical
innovation than is commonly believed, and sometimes even obstructs it. Our conclusion is that:
Research priorities are determined by markets. The purchasing power of people in poverty
and of under-funded health services is not a sufficient incentive for research into the
diseases of the poor, even with high levels of IP protection worldwide.
Much of the revenue from patents in the North goes into marketing, into research on
medicines that are not genuinely innovative or important from a public health perspective,
and into shareholders pockets.
State funding contributes significantly to drug research and development, though some of it
constitutes a subsidy to industry rather than a clear, public health-orientated investment.
High levels of IP protection can distort research priorities and discourage investigation.
28
What is not researched by pharmaceutical TNCs
Enhancing life worldwide: Our strategic focus on innovation and unwavering commitment to
excellence have produced pharmaceuticals that are meeting todays health care needs, while
our pipeline promises to yield many of tomorrows therapies.
Pfizer Inc.
The pharmaceutical TNCs claim to enhance life worldwide, but the facts suggest otherwise:
Only 10 per cent of research targets the diseases that cause 90 per cent of the global
disease burden.
TB, diarrhoea, and pneumonia, which account for 18 per cent of illness, receive only 0.2 per
cent of R&D. 58 There has been only one new treatment for TB in the last 30 years.
Only 13 of the 1,223 new drugs marketed between 1975 and 1997 were specifically
developed to treat tropical diseases (and only four of these were direct results of industry
R&D). 59
Some diseases, such as sleeping sickness and leishmaniasis, are not researched
commercially at all.
Industry is geared to producing medicines of commercial interest, which means producing for
people in the industrialised world, who account for 85 per cent of its market. It fails dramatically
to meet the needs of women and men in the developing world, further deepening the health
divide between rich and poor. For example, progress towards development of vaginal
microbicides that will be effective against sexually transmitted diseases, including HIV, has
been fragmentary, mainly because industry lacks confidence that such a market exists. 60 In
other words, poor women do not have any money, so their health-care needs are not being
met.
In 2002, Africa will account for only 1.3 per cent of global pharmaceutical sales, and South-
East Asia, including China, for a further 5 per cent. 61 Even allowing for sales growth due to
rising incomes, most developing-country markets will remain relatively small for the foreseeable
future. For diseases common to rich and poor countries, the claim that the extension of
patenting will make a perceptible difference to R&D is without foundation. The lucrative markets
will be the more affluent classes in the larger economies such as India, Brazil, Mexico, Korea,
and China which are the principal prizes sought by TNCs through the extension of IP
protection. However, the pattern of illness among the better-off in the developing world is
similar to that in the industrialised world, so their demand does not stimulate research into the
diseases most common among low-income families.
The purchasing power of the 1.2 billion people living on one dollar a day does not constitute a
sufficient commercial incentive to research the diseases from which they are suffering, even if
there is strong patent protection a reality admitted by companies themselves. Spending on
drugs by health ministries is also not large enough to act as a significant market stimulus. LDC
health services typically spend no more than a few dollars per head per year on medicines. 61
countries have public drug expenditure of less than US$10 per capita. 62
29
single product. 63 Since then, mergers between large firms have reinforced this pattern. One of
the main consequences of recent mega-mergers in the industry has been a focusing of R&D on
a narrower range of commercially-attractive products. These products may not even be
treatments for serious illness indeed, vast sums are spent researching baldness and obesity,
for example. When Glaxo bought Wellcome in 1995, the aim of R&D was simple: to bring three
financially important products to market each year from 2000. 64
Blockbusting: the name of the game. Of the ten best-selling drugs in August 2000, three
were anti-depressants, two were for lowering cholesterol, and two were for gastric ulcers.
The remainder were for arthritis, hypertension/angina, and allergies/asthma. 65 Losec, one of
the ulcer treatments, yields US$6bn a year for AstraZeneca, 66 while the aggregated sales of
the three anti-depressants (Prozac, Zoloft, Seroxat/Paxil) reached US$6.1bn 67 not far
short of what the whole of Africa spends on medicines in a year. Losec is guarded by 14
different patents: as a company spokesman put it, this makes it very difficult for generic
companies. It is like a minefield, you go a little to the left and then boom! You bump into
another one.
Since companies are desperate to extend the market-monopoly period of their winning
products, they spend further R&D funds on modifying a dosage or an ingredient, and then apply
for a new patent. Companies also invest heavily in developing me-too drugs, which are
therapeutically similar to successful patented products, but sufficiently different not to violate
the patent. For example, Eli Lilly is trying to produce an impotency drug to compete with Pfizers
lucrative Viagra (sildenafil). This could reduce prices, but Lillys R&D is therapeutically
unproductive.
Public-interest groups have drawn particular attention to the numerous patents on breast and
ovarian cancer genes held by Myriad Genetics, and how this might discourage research or
increase the cost of treatment. 69 In 1999, according to a newspaper report, Myriad Genetics
claimed royalties from the UKs National Health Service for developing their own test kits for
breast cancer susceptibility genes, BRCA1 and BRCA2. Myriad had patented these gene
sequences even though their research had relied upon work by the Institute of Cancer
Research in London. If forced to pay a licence fee to Myriad, Shirley Hodgson of Guys Hospital
said in theory, it could completely cripple a lot of labs. 70
Even some big companies who normally lobby for strong patent laws are concerned about
constraints on research imposed by patents held by the bio-tech industry. 71 The situation is
worst in the USA, where the law permits companies to register a gene patent and then do
nothing with it for the whole twenty-year term, either waiting for a windfall or merely blocking the
competition. 72 Dr James Watson, whose work on DNA with Francis Crick laid the foundations
for the Human Genome Project and the modern bio-tech industry, described the patenting of
human genes as sheer lunacy. 73
30
But it can be different. The SNIP Consortium, a publicprivate partnership between the
Wellcome Trust and some industries to investigate human genetic variations, will disseminate
all findings as public goods. The companies funding the research have accepted that, by
sharing, they can all learn more and benefit. The Internet, at the heart of the new economy,
also demonstrates how socialising knowledge can sometimes be the best path to innovation: it
developed though the interactive effort of people explicitly committed to keeping their work in
the public domain.
A great deal of research into drugs is funded by governments, charities, and tax breaks. In
most countries, R&D is tax-deductible, so if the marginal rate of corporation tax is 35%, for
example, the real cost to a company of US$100 of R&D is US$65. Many countries also
offer additional tax credits. Moreover, the pool of scientific information in the public domain,
much of it paid for by public bodies, provides important inputs to commercial
pharmaceutical research. Nevertheless, the resulting financial benefits accrue primarily to
the patent holder. 76
Claims about the R&D costs of new drugs are frequently exaggerated by a factor of ten,
according to some critics. Company calculations often include market-research costs and
the opportunity cost of capital, apart from glossing over the tax benefits. 77 Studies often
relate total R&D spending to the number of new molecular entities launched (i.e. drugs with
a new active ingredient), ignoring the much larger number of approvals for new formulations
and combinations, and thereby further inflating the figure for cost per new drug. Moreover,
many industry experts expect new technologies, notably genomics, to cut substantially the
R&D failure rate. Lehman Brothers, for example, postulate a fall of more than 25 per cent in
cost per new drug between 1996 and 2005. 78 Spending is rarely externally verified; in the
United States, industry has gone as far as the Supreme Court five times in order to prevent
official bodies from examining the figures.
Much more money goes into marketing than goes into R&D. In 1999, GW spent 35 per cent
of revenue on sales, general, and administrative costs, more than double R&D expenditure.
Drug-industry advertising in the USA alone costs more than Africa spends on medicines. 79
Marketing expenditure in the developing world is also substantial up to 30 per cent of
sales and these costs are passed on to the patient.
Technology transfer
Advocates of the TRIPS Agreement argue that TNCs, including pharmaceutical companies, are
reluctant to manufacture products in developing countries where patent protection is weak. It is
claimed that, since local manufacture makes it easier for competitors to obtain a TNCs know-
31
how, a TNC will prefer to export finished products. Strong IP protection therefore increases
licensing and direct investment by TNCs, and this in turn will stimulate R&D. There is some
evidence that pharmaceutical TNCs are encouraged to invest because of the reduced damage
caused by know-how leakage, but it is unlikely to be the most important factor in their decision.
The LSE report commissioned by the WHO says: despite claims that TRIPS will encourage the
transfer of technology for drug development, the reality has been a lack of technology transfer,
with the multinational companies maintaining control in industrialised countries.their response
has primarily involved opening local distribution centres whose activities are restricted to the
final stages of production finishing and distribution.
It is true that some of the biggest Indian companies are likely to undertake R&D in partnership
agreements with the Northern TNCs. However, this may be aimed principally at reducing the
R&D costs for the TNCs, such as the cost of running clinical trials, and is unlikely to involve
significant investment in researching the diseases that affect poor people. The patenting
system also restricts knowledge diffusion to a select few, rather than sharing it with industry as a
whole, and will increase the bargaining power of patent holders, allowing them to negotiate higher
licence charges and royalty fees, or impose more onerous conditions for technology transfer.
In summary, with a high level of patent protection in developing countries, the revenue from
medicines developed principally for Northern markets, but important in the South, will rise. But
there is no reason to believe that a significant share of the revenue from the sales in developing
countries will go into R&D related to the diseases of poverty. Oxfam therefore believes that
the most effective and efficient way of stimulating this research is through greatly
expanded government action. This should harness the strengths and capacity of
industry, North and South, with due control over financial returns to industry so that the
benefits to people living in poverty are maximised. This proposal is discussed further in
Section 7.
Paradoxically for an agreement designed to protect property rights, TRIPS is silent about the
appropriation of traditional knowledge about medicinal plants from developing countries, an IP
theft motivated by the desire of Northern companies to find commercially valuable
pharmaceuticals. First, TRIPS omits any requirements on patent applicants to state where the
knowledge needed for their invention was obtained, and who the legitimate owners or
originators of that knowledge might be. Secondly, the controversial Article 27.3(b) of the
Agreement (see appendix), currently under review, obliges all countries to allow patenting of
micro-organisms and microbiological processes, i.e. everything related to the genetic
manipulation and transfer of genes and cells. This, combined with a loose interpretation of
inventiveness by national Patent Offices, accelerates patenting of genetic resources, invariably
by powerful Northern companies, and stimulates appropriation of the biological assets of the
South. The Africa Group of nations has strong ethical and developmental objections to the
patenting of life forms and deeply resents seeing its members biological resources snatched
away, to be later sold back to them at high prices.
32
Developing countries hold an estimated 90 per cent of the worlds biological resources. Bio-
prospectors take samples of plant material and document traditional medicinal uses developed
by local communities over centuries. This knowledge is then exploited by TNCs to develop
highly profitable drugs. More than half of the worlds most frequently prescribed medicines are
derived from plants or are synthetic copies of plant chemicals. It is estimated that if a 2 per cent
royalty were levied on genetic resources that had been developed by local innovators in the
South, the North would owe more than US$5bn in royalties for medicinal plants alone.
In 1999, for example, a US patent was granted to a US-based pharmaceutical company for a
diabetes remedy based on egg plant, bitter gourd, and jamun, despite the fact that the
treatment had been used in India for years and was well documented in texts on medicinal
plants. The Indian Minister for Agriculture described the patent as an onslaught on the
traditional knowledge and practices prevalent in the developing countries and called on the
WTO to institute rules protecting local knowledge and products from poaching by foreign
companies. 80
In accordance with the commercial interests of its corporate sponsors, TRIPS is silent on bio-
piracy. Many developing countries, including the Africa Group and India, along with
development agencies like Oxfam, want to see TRIPS amended to make it consistent
with the Convention on Bio-Diversity and the FAOs International Undertaking on Plant
Genetic Resources. Patents applicants would then be required to disclose the origin of
the resources or knowledge that they are using, to obtain the prior informed consent of
the original knowledge holders, and to share the benefits with them. A tight definition of
the criteria of inventiveness and novelty in national laws would also help to rule out
applications in which the subject matter is not a proper invention, or where the knowledge is
already in the public domain.
33
7. The need for government action on health needs
Since the market tragically fails the health needs of hundreds of millions of people living in
poverty, there is an overwhelming case for major investments by governments in R&D, as well
as in health-delivery systems and in subsidised access to treatment for those that cannot pay.
International assistance in all these areas declined over the 1990s, although the 1999 World
Health Assembly recognised the urgency to act, and the World Bank, the G-8, and the
European Commission have all announced their intentions to step up their efforts, particularly in
regard to reducing TB, malaria, and HIV/AIDS.
There are now numerous initiatives on the table, many of which are partnerships involving
governments, the private sector, and corporate philanthropy. Some focus on prevention, such
as the Global Alliance for Vaccines and Immunisation (GAVI) and the European Malaria
Vaccine Initiative, which has two products entering clinical trials. Others concentrate on the
development of cures, or on delivery systems, or on subsidising drug purchasing. Some
initiatives are potentially valuable, others are little more than thinly disguised subsidies to
industry. An example of the latter was the US Export-Import Bank offer to make loans available
to sub-Saharan Africa for the purchase of US-made, patented medicines for treating HIV/AIDS.
Health ministers in the region said that the offer did not address the structural pricing problem
and would aggravate an already grave situation of indebtedness.
Overall, Oxfam sees the initiatives by Northern governments as positive, but still small in
relation to need, and requiring much greater co-ordination. Governments and companies
proudly announce new programmes that have some benefits in developing countries, but this
can give an over-optimistic impression of the level of real success. The scale of human
suffering caused by infectious disease demands a more wholehearted response.
Based on an industry figure of around US$300m for the average cost of new drug development
(excluding the opportunity cost of capital invested), such a fund could finance at least fifteen
breakthrough products. If the figure of US$50100m quoted by some independent analysts is
correct, the number of new products could be many times greater. The Fund, operating under
the auspices of the WHO, would be a key means both for filling the gaps in current research
effort, and for co-ordinating the presently fragmented efforts of individual countries and
programmes. Evidently, it would not seek to replace networks that are working well, such as the
International TB Alliance. The Fund could raise and disburse US$500m a year over ten years.
All countries, rich and poor, could contribute annually according to their means, making it a
genuine global initiative. The burden on the tax-paying citizen would be very small, especially
since some of the funds could come from a tax on the profits of the big drug companies (a 0.5
per cent tax would raise US$170m), or from the US$100 levy on patent applications proposed
by UNDP, which would generate a further US$350m.
34
Who should do the research?
Much research can be conducted by networked public institutions, as was the case with the
agricultural research that lead to the Green Revolution, and with the Human Genome Project.
Publicprivate partnerships can also be part of the strategy, as the pharmaceutical industry has
expertise in drug development and the necessary productive capacity, particularly for vaccines.
However, incentives to industry must be designed to get real solutions, and generate a
reasonable, capped return to the companies. If firms derive excessive financial advantage from
publicly funded research, this will reduce the benefits to those in poverty. As noted above,
although there has long been public subsidy of research by pharmaceutical companies, there is
currently little transparency over their actual spending, and therefore no assurance of value for
money.
One partnership that seems to be working well is GSKs development of an improved anti-
malarial called LapDap (chlorproguanil/dapsone) with funding from the WHO and the UKs
Department for International Development (DFID). The investment is not large, because the
active ingredients have been extensively tested. The product will not be patented, thus ensuring
generic competition and affordable prices (US$0.50 per treatment). This is one of several
medicines under development by SmithKline Beechams Tropical Diseases Unit, now inherited
by GSK and currently guaranteed at least a year of post-merger operation. SBs policy was to
require only an acceptable (as opposed to maximum) profit from the Unit.
It is essential not to concentrate all public investment in industrialised countries, and to ensure
that research centres and pharmaceutical firms in developing countries are able to play an
active part in responding to the diseases of poverty. The domestic drug industry in several
countries has a capacity to innovate that should be encouraged rather than stifled.
The impact of the TRIPS Agreement makes it doubly important that, where public funds
are invested, arrangements with industry over patents and prices are rigorous and
subject to public scrutiny. One solution is for patents to be held as public goods, perhaps by
the WHO, or for research results to be placed in the public domain. Another option is to require
drug companies to offer their products developed with taxpayers money at a reasonable price,
as proposed by the US Congress in June 2000. The design and implementation of public
private partnerships should involve experts who are independent of the often cosy relationship
between Northern governments and industry, as well as representatives of the developing
countries.
Complementary policies
Even if commercially developed drugs were available at lower cost through more equitable
pricing arrangements, and new drugs funded by public resources were marketed without patent
protection, the poorest countries might still not be able to afford them. Oxfam and other
groups concerned about public health believe that there needs to be a complementary
international fund established which could subsidise purchases and reduce costs by
bulk buying. The fund would offer long-term support on needs-based criteria and would
remove the arbitrariness and uncertainty of bilateral drug donations by companies.
Aid funds are also essential to support delivery systems in the poorest countries as part
of their broader national health services. The decline in international assistance for the
health sector in developing countries should be reversed, and support given to the
poorer countries as grants rather than loans.
35
8. The need for company action
We try never to forget that medicine is for the people. It is not for the profits.
George W. Merck, Merck & Co.
The focus in this paper is on patent rules and how they might be changed in order to benefit the
health of women and men in poverty. Yet pharmaceutical TNCs play a key part in determining
the availability and affordability of medicines. First, they exercise great influence over the patent
rules, nationally and globally. Secondly, they develop and manufacture most of the worlds
medicines, deciding what is produced (and what not), and how much it will sell for. Oxfam
recognises the value of corporate philanthropy, but argues that effective social
responsibility and enhancing life worldwide must go beyond isolated acts of charity,
and address the systemic issues of affordability. If companies do this, they will not only
ensure benefits to women and men living in poverty but they will also improve their standing in
the eyes of investors and the wider community. Companies which own well-known consumer
brands will particularly benefit from an enhanced public image. GSKs soft drinks, Ribena and
Lucozade, are household names in the UK, for example. Conversely, if companies disregard the
fate of millions of poor people, they could face public criticism and the consequent loss of sales
and investor confidence, as well as greater likelihood of regulatory action by governments.
Corporate philanthropy
Corporate philanthropy supports health projects throughout the developing world and offers
drug donations or special price reductions. Donations for disease control programmes under
the auspices of the WHO can play a very positive role when the disease is liable to eradication,
as in the case of lymphatic filariasis (donations by GSK and Merck) and river blindness
(donation by Merck, to be continued until the disease is eliminated). Giving drugs is
inappropriate, however, when it distorts local priorities, when not accompanied by support for
related health-care infrastructure, or when it is only for short periods.
Oxfam and other public-health groups would also like to see more company research
into infectious diseases, in co-ordination with publicly funded researchers. In order to
avoid an individual company suffering a competitive disadvantage because of low
returns, the major firms should all agree to allocate a set percentage of their research
budgets for this purpose.
While expanded and well-designed corporate philanthropy is highly desirable, it will have little
impact in relation to the broader problem and it does not offer the drug security which
countries need. This is illustrated by GSKs help with treating drug-resistant malaria in East
Africa, using its patented product, Malarone (atovaquone/proguanil). Malarone is a combination
drug to deal with the widespread chloroquine-resistant strains. It is a three-day treatment, thus
facilitating patient compliance with dosages, and costs US$42. The drug, patented until 2012,
has commercial value in the industrialised world as a new, effective prophylactic and treatment.
GSK promised one million free treatment courses a year for East Africa, as part of a well-
designed programme. The question is: what price will be charged to the countries dealing with
the rest of the 300 million cases, many of whom are resistant to existing medicines? And what will
happen when the one million free doses have been used up in East Africa? GSK has suggested
that governments should take out loans to pay the full price, but most of the countries with a high
incidence of the disease are already drowning in debt. Had the drug been the subject of a public
private partnership similar to the case of LapDap, in which public-health needs were the overriding
concern and IP protection a secondary consideration, it could be much more widely available.
36
profits than reform of WTO intellectual property rules. The TNCs see tiered pricing as a limited,
preferential system in which individual firms bilaterally negotiate different prices in different
countries. This might bring some benefits, especially where there is sufficient public pressure
on companies, but the scale is limited and the balance of negotiating power remains strongly in
favour of industry. Instead, Oxfam argues for a WHO-sponsored, worldwide classification
of markets, according to transparent and internationally agreed criteria of need, together
with guidelines for pricing agreed by all large companies. The criteria could include a
countrys mortality/morbidity rates and ranking on the Human Development Index, as well as its
capacity to pay. In some cases, it would make sense to group countries by region, especially
where there is a significant measure of economic integration and co-operation, as in Central
America or Southern Africa. Though a global scheme is an ambitious project, it could start with
selected regions, or selected vital medicines, such as those used to treat HIV/AIDS and related
illnesses, and then evolve to cover other key drugs. The present arrangements whereby prices
for some vaccines are lower in developing countries are a good working precedent for such a
scheme. GSK, for example, has been selling its patented hepatitis B vaccine to UNICEF at 10
per cent of list price. 82
In a comprehensive equitable pricing system, all firms respect the same guidelines, so no
company will suffer a competitive disadvantage. Tax concessions currently available for drug
donations could be reallocated to support the system, provided it is transparent, effective, and
genuinely equitable. Governments will need to respond to industry concerns about leakage of
products back into Northern markets by including measures for preventing re-import and
smuggling. These could include different packaging for the reduced-price products and
prohibition of their sale in rich countries.
Within this global framework, Oxfam believes that all companies should set prices for
priority drugs in the 48 LDCs as low as possible, using marginal unit cost as a guideline
(i.e. the cost of producing an extra unit, which is commonly well under 10 per cent of
sale price). This could dramatically bring down prices for the worlds poorest people and
demonstrate that companies are serious about their social duty. Since the LDCs probably
account for less than 0.25 per cent of the global pharmaceuticals market, companies would
hardly notice the revenue loss.
Although an equitable pricing system makes drugs cheaper in poor countries, it should be seen
as a complement to the policy of maintaining a low level of patent protection on medicines in
developing countries and letting generic competition reduce prices. Equitable pricing does pose
a significant administrative challenge, which simply does not arise with the market-based
approach. Moreover, with TRIPS unreformed, many generic manufacturers will be out of
business, and developing countries will become increasingly reliant for drug supply on a
handful of Northern transnational corporations. In contrast, with the kind of patent regime for
medicines many developing countries had before TRIPS, there is scope to develop national
industry and greater pharmaceutical self-sufficiency, with corresponding benefits for livelihoods
and health security. For these reasons, while calling for fairer TNC pricing, Oxfam also
stresses the need for reform of WTO rules.
Policy influencing
Any efforts to extend transition periods or renegotiate the substantive provisions of TRIPS
should be vigorously opposed.
Transatlantic Business Dialogue 83
37
seek laws that only favour profits. Companies should accept government measures based
on public-health needs, such as reasonable price controls, compulsory licensing/parallel
imports, use of bulk purchasing, etc. and should support national and multilateral
legislation that embodies the legitimate social purpose of IP protection.
If companies want to persuade public-policy makers that R&D into the diseases of poverty will
flow from patent protection in developing countries, they must be able to identify which
diseases they will be targeting, in which markets, complete with data concerning costs and
potential sales. Without such details, the benefits to developing countries remain hypothetical,
while the benefits to companies are only too apparent.
9. Patent politics
Who makes the rules?
The WTO is an inter-governmental organisation dedicated to the promotion and liberalisation of
trade, yet it harbours an agreement that erects barriers to trade, undermines competition, and
protects private rights rather than those of States. 84 The explanation of this paradox lies in the
enormous power over the establishment of trade rules that is wielded by the TNCs in their
pursuit of commercial gain.
The US drug companies and other big businesses played a particularly significant part in the
198694 Uruguay Round negotiations as a result of the influence they exerted behind-the-
scenes on their government. The recommendations of industrys Advisory Committee for Trade
Negotiations (ACTN) and Intellectual Property Committee (IPC) were fundamental to the
development of the US strategy for IP. The ACTN and IPC, in which Pfizer Inc. had the leading
role, convinced the government that the theft of US technology and profit could be halted only
by creating international rules, enforced by the threat of trade sanctions. The US TNCs skilfully
enrolled their European and Japanese counterparts to put pressure on the other rich-country
governments, and the deal was done. In the words of Edmund Pratt of Pfizer: Our combined
strength enabled us to establish a global private sectorgovernment network which laid the
groundwork for what became TRIPS. 85
Many developing-country governments were unaware of the implications of TRIPS. To talk
about TRIPS some years ago was totally unknown, it was something from another planet to
most of us, said Ho-Chy Vega, director of the Dominican Republics Pharmaceutical Trade
Association, in an interview with Oxfam. 86 Even now, many of the poorer countries are oblivious
to the commitments they made in 1994. Even when developing-country trade officials knew
what was going on, there was little scrutiny of the issue by parliaments, health professionals,
and the general public. Dr Awudu Tinorgah, former director of Ghanas medical services and
board member of an Oxfam partner organisation, stated recently that the Ministry of Health has
no knowledge of TRIPS and what it will mean for access to medicines. Mr Osafo-Acquaah of
Phyto-Riker Pharmaceuticals, a local company interviewed by Oxfam in November 2000, says
that the TRIPS Agreement has never been discussed by Ghanas drugs industry. 87
38
Unfortunately, both trade agreements and the means for enforcing them are biased against
poorer countries. According to WTO officials, the mechanism had been invoked 23 times on
TRIPS-related issues by December 2000, but never by a developing country. Brazil and
Argentina are currently being challenged by the USA over whether their patent legislation is
TRIPS-compliant. Contesting a case at the WTO is extremely demanding for low-income
countries. Consequently the threat of a dispute by a rich country is often enough to make them
back down, even without the greater menace of losing valuable exports. In the absence of
definitive interpretations of TRIPS agreed by member states, the panels determine the rules.
India has recently complained that judgements have been biased in favour of patent holders,
rather than users of knowledge.
With the collapse of the Seattle talks, the proposals for reform have been passed to the WTO
General Council Special Sessions on implementation concerns of developing countries. The
Like-Minded Group re-submitted a call for the exemption of essential drugs from patenting to
the October 2000 General Council, but there has been no substantive discussion to date. In a
recent paper to the TRIPS Council, the Africa Group of nations expressed concern about how
TRIPS could lead to escalating medicine prices and divert research increasingly to developing
products for the affluent rather than for the majority. Developing countries are also asking for a
review of the deadlines for TRIPS compliance.
Grave concern about the health impact of TRIPS has also been expressed through the UN
system. Despite dogged resistance from some industrialised countries, led by the United
States, the World Health Assembly in May 1999 charged the WHO with providing countries with
technical support on patenting issues and for monitoring the effect of international trade
agreements on access to drugs. A key issue in the 2000 Special Session of the UN General
Assembly on Social Development was the right of people to essential medicines at affordable
prices, and how this right is being undermined by TRIPS. The Group of 77, representing
most of the developing world, proposed that essential and life-saving medicines be
excluded from patentability, and that the TRIPS Agreement should not take precedence
over the human right to health care.
UNDP has taken a lead in highlighting concerns about the risk that TRIPS will raise the price of
technology transfer, and can block developing countries from dynamic knowledge sectors such
as computer software and generic drugs. It also argues that new patent laws pay scant
attention to the knowledge of indigenous people, which results in a silent theft of centuries of
knowledge from developing to developed countries. 88 More recently, the UN Sub-Commission
on the Promotion and Protection of Human Rights declared that since the implementation of
the TRIPS Agreement does not adequately reflect the fundamental nature and indivisibility of all
human rights including the right of everyone to enjoy the benefits of scientific progress and its
applications, the right to health, the right to food, and the right to self-determination, there are
apparent conflicts between the intellectual property rights regime embodied in the TRIPS
Agreement, on the one hand, and international human rights law, on the other. 89 It also
requested that the WTO take full account of existing State obligations under international
human-rights instruments during the review of the TRIPS Agreement.
39
and which do not?
At the WTO, the USA and EU member states, including the UK, continue to defend TRIPS and
have resisted developing-country calls to reform it. The USA, the main beneficiary of the
Agreement, is particularly vehement in its refusal to countenance change. Technology is
extremely important to its economy, which receives more than half of the worlds royalties and
licensing fees. 90 US policy is also a testimonial to the remarkable influence exercised by big
business over government, not least because it pays many bills. In 199799, the
pharmaceutical industry spent US$236m on lobbying Congress and the executive. 91 The
health-care industry, in which the pharmaceutical sector is the largest player, was expected to
spend US$90m in an attempt to influence the results of the 2000 US elections. 92
Until recently, the industrialised-country defence of TRIPS has closely mirrored the arguments
from TNCs. They argue that the price of medicines is not the primary cause of poor peoples
lack of access to medicines. Consequently, seeking to amend TRIPS is a red herring, which will
also have the undesirable effect of reducing R&D. More recently, there has been some
movement in official positions as a result of public disquiet. The European Commission, for
example, has now said that it will not press countries to implement TRIPS plus legislation. This
commitment will need monitoring carefully, since, to date, getting countries to sign up to all the
international conventions on IP has been part of the brief given to EC officials who negotiate
regional trade agreements. The US government and European Commission have had to stop
overtly bullying South Africa over its Medicines Act (though corporate legal actions continue in
the South Africa courts). In May 2000, responding to public pressure, President Clinton issued
an executive order stating that the US would not take action against African countries which
resorted to parallel importing and compulsory licensing when facing medical emergencies,
provided the measures were consistent with the terms of the TRIPS Agreement. Unfortunately,
press reports in January 2001 suggested that President Bush might reverse the order.
While the EU is now expressing more openness to discuss developing-country concerns in the
TRIPS Council, it has made it clear that it would consider reforms only in exchange for
concessions in the next round of trade talks. In essence, this means treating vital development
concerns affecting the health of millions of people as a bargaining chip to be traded at the
negotiating table with the developing world. The European Commission has also recently
launched an important and welcome new initiative, in which the UK government is closely
involved, aimed at accelerating action to reduce major infectious diseases in the context of
poverty reduction. The EC analysis notes that IP rules have a bearing on access to medicines
but stops short of recommendations for change, preferring to place its faith in use of the TRIPS
safeguards. The EC also stresses tiered pricing and technology transfer through voluntary
licensing agreements as ways of improving access and affordability. The United States
government has been very reluctant to admit the importance of more affordable drugs in the
fight against communicable diseases, though it was finally persuaded to accept a clause
affirming that point in a joint statement issued with the EU at the December 2000 G8 meeting
on health in Okinawa.
The UK White Paper on Globalisation published in December 2000 argues that the [TRIPS]
agreement allows WTO members sufficient flexibility to implement domestic IPR regimes which
take adequate account of their national circumstances. The Paper also states that TRIPS does
not affect access to and cost of pharmaceuticals, seeds, and technology for poor people,
because countries can resort to parallel importing and compulsory licensing. At the same time,
developing-country concerns are acknowledged, and the government declares itself open to
constructive suggestions on how to improve the agreement in TRIPS reviews and to more
substantive negotiations in the context of a new Trade Round. As a contribution to this
discussion, the government will establish a Commission to consider how IP rules need to
develop in the future to take greater account of the interests of developing countries and poor
people. Oxfam welcomes this tacit recognition that there is a problem and hopes that the
Commission will produce strong recommendations for effective policy reform that can be led by
the UK and its European partners.
40
Public opinion
There is widespread questioning of the way in which international trade rules are working. IP
protection, though one of the more obscure and complex components of the system, is coming
under scrutiny from various quarters. Public-interest groups everywhere are raising concerns
about the effects on biotechnology, development, health, agriculture, and equity. Among
economic liberals in business, government, academia, and the media, there are growing
worries about the effect of high levels of IP protection on competition and efficiency; some
believe that TRIPS should never have been part of the WTO system.
Organisations such as Mdecins Sans Frontires (MSF), Health Action International (HAI), the
UK-based Voluntary Service Overseas (VSO), and the Washington-based Consumer Project
on Technology (CPT) are campaigning internationally for pro-public-health interpretations of
TRIPS and for other measures to improve access to medicines, as are civic organisations and
consumer groups in developing countries, such as the Treatment Action Campaign in South
Africa and Oxfams local partner, the Network for Consumer Protection in Pakistan. Medicine
prices are now also a source of intense controversy in the United States, where the elderly, the
majority of whom are women, are outraged by what they have to pay. Developing-country
governments, combined with public opinion in both North and South, can create the political
momentum to change the rules. So who has to be persuaded?
In the EU, policy on multilateral IP rules is decided by member states, but the European
Commission is active in trying to harmonise positions, and has been delegated authority to
represent the members in WTO negotiations on the subject. IP policies fall under the
mandate of the Directorate General for Trade (DG Trade), led by Commissioner Pascal
Lamy. The EC is currently seeking to extend its power to negotiate on behalf of the member
states on a number of trade-related subjects such as IP and investment a fast-track
procedure that threatens to reduce public and parliamentary debate of the issues.
The US Trade Representative (USTR), a cabinet member, is responsible for trade policy
and speaks for the government in trade negotiations and at the WTO. President Bushs new
appointee is Robert Zoellick. The Office of the USTR has very close relations with industry.
The current head of PhRMA is an ex-Trade Representative.
At the WTO in Geneva, the TRIPS Agreement has its own standing Council, composed of
delegates from member states, although some of the issues are dealt with in the General
Council. There is a mandated review of the TRIPS Agreement scheduled for 2001. Article
71.1 states that the member states shall undertake reviews in the light of relevant new
developments which might warrant modification or amendment of this. Changes in TRIPS
would require consensus among the members in the General Council, or agreement at a
Ministerial Conference.
41
on products on the model list, on a wide range of HIV-related drugs, and on starting
materials for over 100 selected essential drugs. The WHO also has disease-specific
programmes such as Roll Back Malaria and Stop TB. Pharmaceutical R&D for communicable
diseases falls within the remit of the Programme for Research and Training in Tropical
Diseases. In mid-2000 the WHO became an official observer on the TRIPS Council.
The World Intellectual Property Organisation (WIPO), also based in Geneva, is the inter-
governmental administrator of 18 international conventions on IP. TRIPS is in effect the
enforcement mechanism for these conventions, not their replacement. 93 WIPO, which has a
membership of 140 nations, seeks to harmonise and streamline patenting procedures.
In industry, the giants are US-based Pfizer and UK-based GSK. The majority of the latters
shareholders are British, including many pension funds. The Association of British
Pharmaceutical Industries (ABPI) represents more than 100 companies in the UK. Between
them, they supply more than 90 per cent of the medicines prescribed through the National
Health Service. Its US counterpart is PhRMA, which has the worlds top ten pharmaceutical
companies among its 45 members. The International Federation of Pharmaceutical
Manufacturers Associations (IFPMA) represents the industry worldwide, and is the main
channel of communication between industry and international organisations that are
concerned with health and trade-related issues. The generic manufacturers have their own
trade associations: the European Generic Medicines Association (EGA) and the
International Generic Pharmaceutical Alliance (IGPA).
At the WTO
Some aspects of the TRIPS Agreement should be given immediate attention. In the meantime,
work should start on a major overhaul that goes beyond the scope of the regular review
process. Since the problems concern vital matters of public welfare, reforms should not be tied
to the horse-trading associated with normal trade talks. The mandated review under TRIPS
Article 71.1 creates the ideal opportunity to place the common good and sustainable
development at the heart of the Agreement and to strike a better balance between IP rights and
the rights of States to defend the public interest, notably the publics health. It also enables
member states to ensure that TRIPS is consistent with other international agreements such as
the Convention on Bio-Diversity (CBD) and human-rights instruments. From the public-health
perspective, Oxfam calls for the following actions at the WTO:
WTO Member States should reform the patent rules so that poor countries retain the
right to make or import low-cost generic equivalents of the key medicines that they
vitally need. Existing public-health safeguards need to be strengthened so that
countries can limit the length and scope of patent protection on medicines, without
42
facing the threat of trade sanctions. In the short term, the TRIPS Council should review
ambiguous provisions in the Agreement, issuing definitive interpretations that favour public-
health goals and assuring governments the leeway to protect public health in national laws.
The weak general public-health safeguard in Article 8 should be replaced by the unqualified
statement that nothing in the Agreement shall prevent the adoption of measures to protect
public health. The conditions for compulsory licensing must be eased, including any
restriction on production of medicines for export to countries where a compulsory licence
has been issued. The right to engage in parallel importing and early working of a patent
should be clearly reaffirmed, along with the lack of obligation to introduce EU-style rules on
data exclusivity.
WTO members should agree longer transition periods for introducing new IP laws,
based on development milestones rather than arbitrary dates. In practice, this means
that LDCs would not be required to implement any part of TRIPS for the foreseeable future,
and implies a moratorium on WTO trade disputes with any developing country on the
grounds of non-compliance with current deadlines.
The Dispute Settlement mechanism should be reformed to allow public health and
human rights considerations, as well as international development objectives, to be
taken into account when deciding outcomes. This could include:
establishing joint panels with the WHO or other appropriate international organisations
when disputes have a significant non-trade dimension;
establishing a more independent, judicial process for dealing with appeals and referring
disputes involving a conflict between different international agreements to the
International Court of Justice;
Rich countries, above all the USA, should stop using global trade rules and the threat
of trade sanctions to force developing countries to introduce the excessively strong
national patent laws sought by the pharmaceutical TNCs. There should be no pressure
on countries to introduce TRIPS plus systems based on the most restrictive interpretation
of TRIPS, or in which the protection of IP goes beyond TRIPS standards. The negotiation of
bilateral or regional trade agreements should not be used for this purpose. G-8 countries
and the EU should issue a clear statement that they will not take action against countries
that use compulsory licensing and parallel importing to respond to public-health needs. The
United States should repeal the Special 301 trade provision and renounce the use of
unilateral trade sanctions for alleged violation of the property rights of pharmaceutical
corporations.
43
TRIPS should be amended to prevent the piracy of traditional knowledge and genetic
resources from poor countries, in line with developing-country proposals and the
Convention on Bio-Diversity. As a first step, the TRIPS obligation to grant patents for
microbiological organisms should be lifted. It should require patent applicants to disclose the
origin of the resources or knowledge used, to demonstrate the prior informed consent of the
original knowledge holders, and to have made arrangements to share the benefits with them.
Initiating research into the social and economic impact of TRIPS and into the costs and
benefits of various patent regimes, assessed from a development perspective.
The creation of a US$5bn international fund under the auspices of the WHO to fund
research into new medicines and vaccines to treat the infectious diseases plaguing
poor countries. Capital should be provided by governments worldwide, in proportion to
their means, giving all countries a stake. The fund could help to overcome the fragmentation
of current research efforts. Allocation of resources would follow clearly defined public-health
priorities, include the development of cheaper and more easily used medicines and
vaccines for TB, malaria, and HIV/AIDS, and investment in the treatment of grossly
neglected tropical diseases. One objective should be to promote locally based R&D in
developing countries, including research into traditional medicines. Much research could be
carried out in the public and non-profit sectors, although industry would have an important
role. In partnerships with industry, the arrangements over patents and prices should be
rigorous and transparent, in order to maximise benefits for the poor. One solution is for
research results to be placed in the public domain, or for patents to be held by the WHO.
The design and implementation of publicprivate partnerships should involve independent
experts and full participation by developing countries.
44
At the WHO
WHO Member States should actively support and fund an expanded WHO role and work
programme, including the following:
a closer relationship with the WTO and a formal function in trade dispute settlement where
public-health issues are involved;
researching and monitoring the impact of TRIPS to help to ensure that trade policies
support public health;
helping countries to design patent and other trade-related legislation consistent with public-
health needs; this includes a health-orientated definition of patentability and simplified
procedures for issuing compulsory licences;
developing global standards for equitable pricing of patented drugs; this could be linked to a
database on medicine patents in developing countries established by WIPO;
assisting countries/regions with broader policies for improved medicine provision, including
greater use of essential drugs lists, expanded drug financing options and resources, bulk
purchasing and price controls, tighter control of counterfeiting and sub-standard medicines,
and measures to improve the efficiency of distribution and dispensing;
Extending the full benefits of modern medicines to the entire worlds population will ultimately
benefit both people and business. The pharmaceutical industry should therefore:
support national and multilateral legislation that embodies the legitimate social purpose of
IP protection; this may include exempting priority medicines from patenting on public-health
grounds;
establish a standardised and transparent system of equitable pricing; this should include
reducing prices in LDCs for priority medicines, using marginal unit cost as a guideline;
agree investment targets and priorities for increased research into the neglected diseases
of poverty.
The present patent law has played a major role in ensuring that the drug prices in India are
among the lowest in the world and has facilitated the introduction of new drugs in the
country. However, all that may change after 2005, when the patent law is likely to be
drastically modified. Unless the government provides for compulsory licensing, fights the
issue of exclusive marketing rights, allows non-commercial manufacture of patented
products and insists on indigenous manufacture of patented products within a stipulated
timeframe, the new law will end up encouraging monopolies and ultimately lead to
domination of the industry by MNCs. This would affect both the availability and the
affordability of essential drugs and the Indian consumer may have to pay a heavy price for
his health and well being.
Chairman of Cipla, one of Indias most successful pharmaceutical firms
45
Annexe:
Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of
Intellectual Property Rights
Selected articles of the Agreement:
Article 6
Exhaustion
For the purposes of dispute settlement under this Agreement, subject to the provisions of Articles 3
and 4 nothing in this Agreement shall be used to address the issue of the exhaustion of intellectual
property rights.
Article 7
Objectives
The protection and enforcement of intellectual property rights should contribute to the promotion
of technological innovation and to the transfer and dissemination of technology, to the mutual
advantage of producers and users of technological knowledge and in a manner conducive to
social and economic welfare, and to a balance of rights and obligations.
Article 8
Principles
1. Members may, in formulating or amending their laws and regulations, adopt measures
necessary to protect public health and nutrition, and to promote the public interest in sectors
of vital importance to their socio-economic and technological development, provided that
such measures are consistent with the provisions of this Agreement.
2. Appropriate measures, provided that they are consistent with the provisions of this Agreement,
may be needed to prevent the abuse of intellectual property rights by right holders or the resort
to practices which unreasonably restrain trade or adversely affect the international transfer of
technology.
Article 27
Patentable Subject Matter
1. Subject to the provisions of paragraphs 2 and 3, patents shall be available for any inventions,
whether products or processes, in all fields of technology, provided that they are new, involve
an inventive step and are capable of industrial application. 1 Subject to paragraph 4 of
Article 65, paragraph 8 of Article 70 and paragraph 3 of this Article, patents shall be available
and patent rights enjoyable without discrimination as to the place of invention, the field of
technology and whether products are imported or locally produced.
2. Members may exclude from patentability inventions, the prevention within their territory of the
commercial exploitation of which is necessary to protect ordre public or morality, including to
protect human, animal or plant life or health or to avoid serious prejudice to the environment,
provided that such exclusion is not made merely because the exploitation is prohibited by their
law.
1
For the purposes of this Article, the terms "inventive step" and "capable of industrial application" may be deemed by a Member to
be synonymous with the terms "non-obvious" and "useful" respectively.
46
3. Members may also exclude from patentability:
(a) diagnostic, therapeutic and surgical methods for the treatment of humans or animals;
(b) plants and animals other than micro-organisms, and essentially biological processes for
the production of plants or animals other than non-biological and microbiological
processes. However, Members shall provide for the protection of plant varieties either by
patents or by an effective sui generis system or by any combination thereof. The
provisions of this subparagraph shall be reviewed four years after the date of entry into
force of the WTO Agreement.
Article 28
Rights Conferred
1. A patent shall confer on its owner the following exclusive rights:
(a) where the subject matter of a patent is a product, to prevent third parties not having the
owners consent from the acts of: making, using, offering for sale, selling, or importing 2
for these purposes that product;
(b) where the subject matter of a patent is a process, to prevent third parties not having the
owners consent from the act of using the process, and from the acts of: using, offering
for sale, selling, or importing for these purposes at least the product obtained directly by
that process.
2. Patent owners shall also have the right to assign, or transfer by succession, the patent and to
conclude licensing contracts.
Article 29
Conditions on Patent Applicants
1. Members shall require that an applicant for a patent shall disclose the invention in a manner
sufficiently clear and complete for the invention to be carried out by a person skilled in the art
and may require the applicant to indicate the best mode for carrying out the invention known
to the inventor at the filing date or, where priority is claimed, at the priority date of the
application.
2. Members may require an applicant for a patent to provide information concerning the
applicants corresponding foreign applications and grants.
Article 30
Exceptions to Rights Conferred
Members may provide limited exceptions to the exclusive rights conferred by a patent, provided
that such exceptions do not unreasonably conflict with a normal exploitation of the patent and do
not unreasonably prejudice the legitimate interests of the patent owner, taking account of the
legitimate interests of third parties.
2
This right, like all other rights conferred under this Agreement in respect of the use, sale, importation or other distribution of
goods, is subject to the provisions of Article 6.
47
Article 31
Other Use Without Authorization of the Right Holder
Where the law of a Member allows for other use 3 of the subject matter of a patent without the
authorization of the right holder, including use by the government or third parties authorized by
the government, the following provisions shall be respected:
(a) authorization of such use shall be considered on its individual merits;
(b) such use may only be permitted if, prior to such use, the proposed user has made efforts
to obtain authorization from the right holder on reasonable commercial terms and
conditions and that such efforts have not been successful within a reasonable period of
time. This requirement may be waived by a Member in the case of a national emergency
or other circumstances of extreme urgency or in cases of public non-commercial use. In
situations of national emergency or other circumstances of extreme urgency, the right
holder shall, nevertheless, be notified as soon as reasonably practicable. In the case of
public non-commercial use, where the government or contractor, without making a patent
search, knows or has demonstrable grounds to know that a valid patent is or will be used
by or for the government, the right holder shall be informed promptly;
(c) the scope and duration of such use shall be limited to the purpose for which it was
authorized, and in the case of semi-conductor technology shall only be for public non-
commercial use or to remedy a practice determined after judicial or administrative process
to be anti-competitive;
(e) such use shall be non-assignable, except with that part of the enterprise or goodwill which
enjoys such use;
(f) any such use shall be authorized predominantly for the supply of the domestic market of
the Member authorizing such use;
(g) authorization for such use shall be liable, subject to adequate protection of the legitimate
interests of the persons so authorized, to be terminated if and when the circumstances
which led to it cease to exist and are unlikely to recur. The competent authority shall have
the authority to review, upon motivated request, the continued existence of these
circumstances;
(h) the right holder shall be paid adequate remuneration in the circumstances of each case,
taking into account the economic value of the authorization;
(i) the legal validity of any decision relating to the authorization of such use shall be subject
to judicial review or other independent review by a distinct higher authority in that
Member;
(j) any decision relating to the remuneration provided in respect of such use shall be subject
to judicial review or other independent review by a distinct higher authority in that
Member;
(k) Members are not obliged to apply the conditions set forth in subparagraphs (b) and (f)
where such use is permitted to remedy a practice determined after judicial or
administrative process to be anti-competitive. The need to correct anti-competitive
practices may be taken into account in determining the amount of remuneration in such
cases. Competent authorities shall have the authority to refuse termination of
authorization if and when the conditions which led to such authorization are likely to recur;
3
"Other use" refers to use other than that allowed under Article 30.
48
(l) where such use is authorized to permit the exploitation of a patent ("the second patent")
which cannot be exploited without infringing another patent ("the first patent"), the
following additional conditions shall apply:
(i) the invention claimed in the second patent shall involve an important technical
advance of considerable economic significance in relation to the invention claimed in
the first patent;
(ii) the owner of the first patent shall be entitled to a cross-licence on reasonable terms to
use the invention claimed in the second patent; and
(iii) the use authorized in respect of the first patent shall be non-assignable except with
the assignment of the second patent.
Article 32
Revocation/Forfeiture
An opportunity for judicial review of any decision to revoke or forfeit a patent shall be available.
Article 33
Term of Protection
The term of protection available shall not end before the expiration of a period of twenty years
counted from the filing date. 4
Article 34
Process Patents: Burden of Proof
1. For the purposes of civil proceedings in respect of the infringement of the rights of the owner
referred to in paragraph 1(b) of Article 28, if the subject matter of a patent is a process for
obtaining a product, the judicial authorities shall have the authority to order the defendant to
prove that the process to obtain an identical product is different from the patented process.
Therefore, Members shall provide, in at least one of the following circumstances, that any
identical product when produced without the consent of the patent owner shall, in the absence
of proof to the contrary, be deemed to have been obtained by the patented process:
(b) if there is a substantial likelihood that the identical product was made by the process and the
owner of the patent has been unable through reasonable efforts to determine the process
actually used.
2. Any Member shall be free to provide that the burden of proof indicated in paragraph 1 shall be
on the alleged infringer only if the condition referred to in subparagraph (a) is fulfilled or only if
the condition referred to in subparagraph (b) is fulfilled.
3. In the adduction of proof to the contrary, the legitimate interests of defendants in protecting
their manufacturing and business secrets shall be taken into account.
Source: http://www.wto.org/english/docs_e/legal_e/final_e.htm#TRIPs
4
It is understood that those Members which do not have a system of original grant may provide that the term of protection shall be
computed from the filing date in the system of original grant.
49
Bibliography
Abouellenein, Dr. Ahmed Ali (1996) 'Trade-related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights and
the Pharmaceutical Industry in Egypt', Cairo: Federation of Egyptian Industry.
Bala, K. and K. Sagoo (2000) 'Patents and prices', HAI News 112, April/May 2000.
Balance, R., J. Pogany and H. Forsteiner (1991) The Worlds Pharmaceutical Industries: An
International Perspective on Innovation, Competition and Policy, UNIDO.
Bermudez, J., R. Epsztejn, M.A. Oliveira, and L. Hasenclever (2000) The WTO TRIPS
Agreement and Patent Protection in Brazil, Rio de Janeiro: WHO/PAHO Collaborating Centre
for Pharmaceutical Policies, National School of Public Health, Oswaldo Cruz Foundation.
Birmingham, K. and H. Wunsch (1999) 'Grants will determine European malaria vaccine
future' Nature Medicine, Vol 5, No.9, p.969, September 1999.
Boseley, S. (1999) 'US attempts to stop developing countries producing cheap AIDS drugs
have become a political time bomb', The Guardian, 11 August 1999.
British Medical Journal (1996) 'US gene discovery leads to patent war', BMJ 312:1378, 1
June 1996.
Connor, S. (2000) 'Nobel scientist happy to "play God" with DNA', The Independent, 17 May
2000.
Correa, C. (2000b) Integrating Public Health Concerns into Patent Legislation in Developing
Countries, Geneva: South Centre.
Correa, C. and the South Centre (1999) Intellectual Property Rights and the Use of
Compulsory Licenses: Options for Developing Countries,
www.southcentre.org/publications/complicence
Drahos, P. (1995) 'Global property rights in information: the story of TRIPS at the GATT',
Prometheus, Vol 13, No 1, June 1995.
Duckett, M. (1999) 'Compulsory Licensing and Parallel Importing: What do they mean?'
Background paper, International Council of AIDS Service Organisations,
www.icaso.org/compulsory-english.html
European Generic Medicines Association (EGA) (2000) 'TRIPS Article 39.3 Does Not
Require Data Exclusivity Provisions: a critical issue for access to medicines', EGA Position
Paper, www.egagenerics.com, July 2000.
50
Finger, J.M. and P. Schuler (1999) 'Implementation of Uruguay Round Commitments: the
Development Challenge', undated paper presented at Wilton Park conference, July 1999.
Garnier, J-P. (2000) 'Access to medicines: a role for industry', Eurohealth, No.4, Autumn 2000.
Gerster, R. 'How WTO/TRIPS Threaten the Indian Pharmaceutical Industry', mimeo, undated
([email protected]).
Ghangurde, A. (2000) 'Pfizer to pump US$4 million into Navi Mumbai plant', Financial Express,
26 April 2000.
Harper, M. (2000) 'Lilly, Other Drugmakers Rely on Patents', Forbes.com, 16 August 2000.
Harris, G. (2000) 'Drug firms, stymied in the lab, become marketing machines', Wall St.
Journal, 6 July 2000.
't Hoen, E. (2000) 'Europe is beginning to address the crisis of global access to medicines',
Eurohealth, No.4, Autumn 2000.
Keayla, B.K. (1996) New Patent Regime: implications for domestic industry, research and
development and consumers, New Delhi: Centre for Study of GATT Issues.
Loewenson, R. (2000) 'Essential drugs in Southern Africa need protection from public health
safeguards under TRIPS', Bridges, Geneva: ICTSD, September 2000.
Mayer, Christopher S. (1998) 'The Brazilian pharmaceutical industry goes walking from
Ipanema to prosperity: will the new intellectual property law spur domestic investment?',
Temple International and Comparative Law Journal, Autumn 1998.
McNeil, D. (2000) 'Drug companies and the Third World: a case study in neglect', New York
Times, 21 May 2000.
Morgan, O. (2000) 'Glaxo mergers acid test', The Guardian, 23 January 2000.
MSF (2000) 'Globalization and Medications: a New Constraint for Developing Countries',
briefing paper: Paris, 26 January 2000.
Myhr, K. (2000) 'Pharmaceutical Pricing: Law of the Jungle', paper presented at Access to
Essential Medicines seminar: Nairobi, 15-16 June 2000.
51
NIHCM (1999) 'Factors Affecting the Growth of Prescription Drug Expenditures', Washington
DC, July 1999.
NIHCM (2000) 'Prescription Drugs and Intellectual Property Protection', NIHCM Foundation
Issue Brief, Washington DC, August 2000.
Oxfam (forthcoming) 'Access to Basic Health and Education Services in Ethiopia', Oxford:
Oxfam.
Oxfam/The Network for Rational Use of Medication (forthcoming) 'TRIPS and Access to
Medicines in Pakistan', briefing paper.
Palast, G. (2000) 'Keep taking our tablets (no one elses)', The Observer, 23 July 2000.
Pilling, D. and R. Wolffe (2000) 'Drug abuses', Financial Times, 20 April 2000.
Pollack, A. (2000) 'US hopes to stem rush towards patenting of genes', New York Times, 28
June 2000.
Prove, P. and M. Kothari (2000) 'Human rights bodies gear up on TRIPS', Bridges, July-
August 2000.
Public Citizen (2000) 'Addicting Congress: drug companies' campaign cash and lobbying
expenses', Public Citizen Congress Watch Report, Washington.
Roberts, I., A. Li Wang Po, and I. Chalmers (1998) 'Intellectual property, drug licensing,
freedom of information and public health', The Lancet; Vol 352, pp 726-9.
Sachs, J. (2000) 'Helping the world's poorest', The Economist, 14 August 2000.
Schoofs, M. (2000) 'Glaxo attempts to block access to generic AIDS drugs in Ghana', Wall
Street Journal, 1 December 2000.
Schweiger, T. (2000) 'The directive that just wont lie still', GRAIN newsletter Seedling,
September 2000. Available at www.grain.org
Shankar, S. and D. Pilling (2000) 'India seeks a cure for tough patent laws', Financial Times,
24 May 2000.
Simpson, A., N. Hildyard, and S. Sexton (1997) 'No patent on life', The Corner House
Briefing 1, www.cornerhouse.icaap.org/briefings/1.html
Skinner, A. (2000) 'Continuity of supply of drugs is critical'. BMJ, 320:874, 25 March 2000.
Sridhar, V. (1999) 'Big business at work', Frontline, Vol.16, Issue 26, December 1999.
Stilwell, M. 'The Article 71.7 Review of the TRIPS Agreement', forthcoming, as part of the
South Centre trade series.
52
The Economist (2000) 'The knowledge monopolies', 8 April 2000.
Ticehurst, S. (2000) 'Bio-piracy in Mexico: a case study from Chiapas', Oxfam GB research
paper, unpublished.
Trouiller, P. and P. Olliaro (1999) 'Drug development output: what proportion for tropical
diseases?' The Lancet, Volume 354, 10 July 1999.
US Senate (1991) 'The Drug Manufacturing Industry: A Prescription for Profits', Staff Report of
the Special Committee on Ageing, Washington DC: US Government Printing Office.
VSO (2000) 'Drug Deals: Medicines, Development and HIV/AIDS', London: VSO.
Watal, J. (2000a) 'Access to Essential Medicines in Developing Countries: Does the WTO
TRIPS agreement hinder it?', Centre for International Development, Harvard University.
Watal, J. (2000b) 'Pharmaceutical prices and welfare losses: Policy options for India under the
WTO TRIPS Agreement', World Economy, Volume No 23, pages 733-52.
Weissman, R. (1996) 'A long strange Trips: the pharmaceutical industry drive to harmonize
global intellectual property rules and the remaining WTO-legal alternatives available to Third
World countries', Journal of International Economic Law, University of Pennsylvania, Winter
1996 (17 U.Pa.J.Intl Econ.L.1069).
WHO (2000b) 'Economic costs of malaria are many times higher than previously estimated',
Press Release, www.who.int/inf-pr-2000/en/pr2000-28.html.
53
Endnotes
1
Interview with Oxfam, Santo Domingo, November 2000.
2
Weissman (1996).
3
Consumers International (1999).
4
Medecins Sans Frontieres (2000).
5
Bermudez et al (2000).
6
Balance (1991).
7
Abouellenein (1996).
8
Mayer (1998).
9
Drahos (1995).
10
http://208.243.118.38/gw_index.html.
11
Calculated from figures in UNDP (2000) and WHO (2000c).
12
www.pfizer.com/pfizerinc/investing/annual/1999/pf99ar01.html
13
t Hoen (2000).
14
Reuters, 15 January 2001, www.q.co.za/news/2001/01/010115-drug.htm
15
WHO (2000a).
16
WHO (1999a).
17
WHO (2000b).
18
EC (2000).
19
WHO (1999a).
20
Oxfam interview with Dr. Francis Chisaka Kasolo, Consultant Epidemiologist, Lusaka, November 2000.
21
Oxfam interviews, Dhaka, December 2000.
22
UNAIDS (2000a).
23
UNDP (2000).
24
Speech made in Brazil in 2000, quoted in Myhr (2000).
25
WHO (2000c).
26
Oxfam (forthcoming).
27
UNAIDS (2000a).
28
Correa (2000a)
29
The Economist, 30 September 2000.
30
European Commission (2000).
31
WHO (2000a).
32
WHO (2000a).
33
Keayla (1996).
34
UNAIDS, quoted in Wall St Journal, 13 July 2000.
35
Bala and Sagoo (2000).
36
Lanjouw (1999).
37
WHO (1994).
38
Shankar and Pilling (2000).
39
Watal (2000b).
40
Watal (2000a).
41
www.haiweb.org/campaign/cl/corpfocus.html
42
Correa (2000b).
43
www.healthnet.org/programs/e-drug-hma/e-drug.200008/msg00054.html. See also Correa (1999).
44
Bala and Sagoo (2000).
45
Bala, Lanza and Kaur, Retail Drug Prices: the law of the jungle, HAI News, 1998, quoted in Myhr
(2000).
46
http://www.cptech.org/ip/health/c/brazil/
47
Ho-Chy Vega, Director of the Pharmaceutical Trade Association of the Dominican Republic,
interviewed by Oxfam in Santo Domingo, November 2000.
48
Schoofs (2000).
49
http://thomas.loc.gov/cgi-bin/query/z?c106:H.R.2927
50
Paper presented by Lois Boland of the US Patent and Trademark Office at an NGO meeting on
compulsory licensing in Geneva, March 1999. www.haiweb.org/campaign/cl/boland.html
51
Research by the Consumer Project on Technology, quoted by Margaret Duckett (1999).
52
European Generic Medicines Association (2000).
53
NICHM (2000).
54
ibid.
54
55
Quoted in NIHCM (2000).
56
Finger and Schuler (1999).
57
Oxfam (forthcoming).
58
UNDP (1999).
59
Trouiller and Olliaro (1999).
60
European Commission (2000).
61
www.ims-global.com/insight/report/global/report.htm
62
WHO (2000e).
63
UNIDO (1991).
64
Morgan (2000).
65
www.ims-global.com/insight/world_in_brief/0008/products.htm
66
Shankar and Pilling (2000).
67
Harper (2000).
68
Cook-Deegan (2000).
69
Schweiger (2000). See also British Medical Journal (1996).
70
The Guardian, 17 January 2000.
71
Pollack (2000).
72
Weissman (1996).
73
Quoted by S. Connor (2000).
74
These figures, calculated by Oxfam using company website data, do not include Mercks non-
pharmaceuticals business.
75
1999 Company Reports.
76
Story (2000).
77
New England Journal of Medicine (2000) and US Senate (1991).
78
Lehman Brothers (1997).
79
NIHCM (2000).
80
India may contest US patent on diabetic remedy ENS, 27 August 1999, quoted in Bridges Weekly
Trade News Digest Vol.3, Number 42, 25 October 1999.
81
Ticehurst (2000).
82
Garnier (2000).
83
http://tabd.com/about.html
84
Stilwell (forthcoming).
85
Sridhar (1999).
86
Interview with Oxfam, Santo Domingo, November 2000.
87
Interviews with Oxfam, Accra, November 2000.
88
UNDP (1999).
89
E/CN.4/SUB.2/RES/2000/7.
90
Figure for 1995. UNDP (1999).
91
Public Citizen (2000).
92
Story (2000).
93
WHO (1999b).
55