Soviet Growth
Soviet Growth
American Textbooks
David M. Levy
Center for Study of Public Choice
George Mason University
Fairfax VA 22030
Sandra J. Peart
Jepson School of Leadership Studies
University of Richmond
Richmond VA 23173
December 3, 2009
Earlier versions were presented at the 2006 History of Economics Society, the 2006 Public Choice Society,
NYU and the 2008 Summer Institute for the Preservation of the History of Economics at which we
benefitted from the discussion. We thank Richard Ware for the Nutter-Rostow correspondence, Alex
Tabarrok for suggestions and encouragement and the Earhart Foundation for financial support. Adam C.
Smith and Margaret Albert provided valuable research assistance. We are responsible for the errors and
omissions.
Abstract
JEL A20, P17, P27
We examine the treatment of Soviet growth in successive editions of American economics textbooks
published between 1960 and 1980. What we find repeatedly is over-confidence in the potential for Soviet
growth and an asymmetric response to past forecast errors. More than this, the textbooks report faster Soviet
income growth combined with a constant ratio of SovietUS income. Textbooks that abstracted from these
institutional details (thin) offered a wider range of application than those which focused on one society
(thick). A simple way to distinguish these two traditions is whether the book used a productivity possibility
frontier [PPF] for cross-societal comparisons. Thick accounts did not while thin ones did. It was in the
institutional dimension that the account by Tarshis differed from that of Samuelson.
22 October 1963
Dear Warren,
Many thanks for your kind invitation of September 24th. This autumn is
too tied up for me to take the trip to Charlottesville. Could we fix it for the
spring? Your name and your work are very much on my mind these days.
Our loyalty to the notion that key Soviet sectors were subject to
deceleration, a loyalty we both pursue against the views of the intellectual
establishment appears increasingly to be vindicated. Should you come this
way I should very much like to chat with you.
Walt Rostow.
The collapse of the Soviet Union came as a surprise to many western economists in part because its
economy had long been portrayed in textbooks as a viable alternative to democratic capitalism. Textbooks
had shown that the Soviet economy was growing faster than the US and Soviet citizens would soon enjoy a
higher standard of living than Americans. Of course the Soviet economy was not growing faster than the US
economy.
In what follows, we examine the treatment of Soviet growth in successive editions of American
economics textbooks published between 1960 and 1980. What we find repeatedly is over-confidence in the
potential for Soviet growth and an asymmetric response to past forecast errors. More than this, the
textbooks report faster Soviet income growth combined with a constant ratio of SovietUS income. This
trust in the future and skepticism about the past was the basis of a standard Soviet-era joke: Under
Communism, the Poles are fond of saying, only the future is certain; the past is always changing (Nutter
1969). This fact, that accounts of Soviet growth emerged and changed over time in successive editions of
American economics textbooks, has passed almost unnoticed. More than this, at some key junctures textbook
authors disagreed about how to characterize the Soviet economy and, indeed, whether US-style economic
A number of textbook reviews late in the 1940s and early in the 1950s complicate the account below.
These reviews surely altered the textbook landscape in the early 1960s. Textbooks that persisted in the early
1960s survived earlier attacks from libertarian writers, Rose Wilder Lane (1947), V. Orval Watts (1950)
and William F. Buckley (1951). One great textbook (Paul Samuelsons) passed through the attendant
political controversy, while another (Lorie Tarshis) succumbed. Why one survived and the other did not has
been a puzzle; their authors ideology is by all accounts very similar (Elzinga (1992), Colander and Landreth
1
So there are two puzzles for what follows. Why were important textbooks of the 1960s and 1970s so
over-confident about Soviet economic growth that evidence of model failure was repeatedly blamed on events
outside the models control? Second, how did the earlier libertarian attack on particular textbooks affect the
discussion of Soviet growth by changing the mix of surviving textbooks? The counter-factual question is this:
absent a libertarian censoring would a Tarshis-influenced textbook universe offer the same analysis as what we
observe and describe below? On this question, our conjecture is that competition among differing viewpoints
was prematurely suppressed by the attacks. As a result, too few viewpoints persisted in the textbook
landscape, where by too few we mean too few to penetrate the non-transparent institutional arrangements
A critical aspect for the Soviet-American comparison is whether the textbook offers a model by
which the economist can compare one society with another. Textbooks written in what might be described as
a thick, empirical institutionalist tradition focused on a particular society and as such they offered no basis for
comparison in the analysis. By contrast, textbooks that abstracted from these institutional details offered a
wider range of application using a thinner model. A simple way to distinguish these two traditions is to check
whether the book used a productivity possibility frontier [PPF] for cross-societal comparisons. Thick
The difference between thick and thin models in the textbooks was replicated in the specialist
controversy over Soviet-American growth. Nutter (1958, 1962) insisted that growth comparisons preserve
institutional information by asking whether the Soviet Union was catching up with America. His many critics
It was in the institutional dimension that the account by Tarshis differed from that of Samuelson.
Like Samuelson, Tarshis wrote in a reformist tradition. He was, however, immersed in the details of the
American economy. Consequently, he offered little by way of cross country comparisons. Samuelsons text, on
2
the contrary, pioneered the use of the PPF as the means by which to compare different economies. His model,
which collapsed societies into a two-dimension production possibility set, bought elegance by abstraction. Of
course, if an omitted variable was important in only one of the societies in the comparison, th.e models
We turn next to the textbooks after Sputniks October 1957 launch. The texts discussed in most
detail below were selected for attention in Kenneth Elzingas study of market leaders (Elzinga 1992). 1 The
first two constitute the most successful multi-edition post-World War II texts, Campbell McConnells
Economics: Principles, Problems and Policies first published in 1960 and Samuelsons Economics: An
Introductory Analysis first published in 1948. The other successful text noted by Elzinga is George Bachs
Economics. Elzinga also offers a careful discussion of Tarshis 1947 Elements of Economics. We use
Tarshis little-known 1967 Modern Economics to address the counter-factual question of how a
Tarshis-dominated textbook market might have considered Soviet growth. Three others are selected to
illustrate related issues. Robert Heilbroners influential book speaks to the question of ideology and
institutional thickness. Rendiz Fels first edition seems unique in recognizing the consequence of the two
McConnell
1
Documentation of the treatment of Soviet growth and the use of the PPF in all principles textbooks catalogued in the Library of
Ccngress under HB 171.5 between 1948 and 1970 is available on request.
3
very complex economy (1960, p. 718), he offered a snapshot view of the US and the Soviet economies. He
did so using a pie graph which appeared with only minor variations in McConnells chapter on the Soviet
McConnells second edition (1963), now entitled Economics: Principles, Problems and Policies,
added a discussion of the growth record of Soviet Russian controlled economy (1963, vi). The 50% ratio
reappears in McConnell for most of the editions that follow. In the 1990 version McConnell and his
co-author presented the same Soviet-US output ratio of 50%. Twenty-seven years have passed in which the
textbook. It always appears in the last chapter. From 1975 onwards, US investment is said to be about half
that of the Soviet Union as a share of GNP and yet the ratio of Soviet to US GNP never changes. The table
below presents the contents of the McConnell pie chart over all editions of the textbook.
4
The US v USSR in McConnell
Edition Figure US Investment USSR Investment GNP Ratio
(% of GNP) (% of GNP) US to USSR
In McConnells pie chart, consumption and investment always sum to 100% of GNP; there is no
room for inefficiency.2 Consequently, investment in the two countries is equally effective and, without some
disturbing cause from outside the economic system, higher investment in one country manifests itself in
higher growth. But there is no catching up. Thats what the chart seems to be saying.
McConnells explanations also refer to higher Soviet investment and growth without catching up. In
1963 he writes that Soviet GNP is roughly one-half that of the United States. (1963, p. 754) and the rate
of economic growth is two or three times as great as that of the United States. In 1975 we read: Although
the Soviet GNP is only one-half as large as that of the United States, the Soviet GNP has grown more rapidly
than ours (1975, p. 905). In 1984, Although the Soviet GNP is only one-half as large as that of the
2
Our reproduction above is from the 1963 edition. McConnell cited the same sources for the pie charts in 1960 and 1963.
However the ratio of reported Soviet to US output changed from 40% to 50% in the three year period.
5
United States, the Soviet GNP has grown more rapidly than ours (1984, p. 837). In 1987 the text notes
that Although the Soviet GNP is only about 60 percent as large . (1987, p. 911). It comes as a relief of
sorts that the sentence is removed from the 1990 edition, leaving only a statement about the high historical
McConnell also discusses Soviet and US growth rates separate from the issue of catching up. Starting
with 1963, McConnell states that the annual rate of growth in the Soviet Union is two or three times as great
as that now achieved in the United States (1963, p. 750). In 1966, he writes in italics that the Soviet GNP
had been expanding at about 6 to 7 per cent per year as compared to 3 to3 per cent per year for the United
States (1966, p. 766). From 1966 until 1990, McConnell cites the lack of cyclical unemployment in the
Soviet Union, something which makes the US less efficient, as an additional explanation for the Soviet
In the 1966 edition McConnell adds a discussion of Sources of Soviet Growth (1966, pp. 767-68)
in conjunction with Possible Retarding Factors (1966, pp.768-70) and Possible Accelerating Factors
(1966, pp. 770-72). In the retarding group he includes the possibility of an increase in consumption (p.
768), the changing nature of investment from the aging of the capital stock, a reduced ability to profit from
western technology, labor shortages, a variety of problems in agriculture and planning problems. Each of these
is matched by possible accelerating factors, e.g., Against the tendency of Soviet planning to become less
efficient in the face of an increasingly complex economy must be set the likelihood of significant
breakthroughs in the techniques and mechanics of central planning (p. 771). The 1969, 1972 and 1975
editions contain the same discussion of sources of growth and retarding and accelerating factors (1969, pp.
The editions of 1978, 1981 and 1984, however, retain the retarding factors but omit the possible
accelerating factors in the growth section (1978, pp. 935-38, 1981, pp. 887-89, 1984, pp. 831-33).
6
McConnell adds a discussion of the recent growth slowdown to the 10th and 11th editions (1987, pp.
All editions contain estimates of Soviet and American growth. In 1969, McConnell writes in italics
that the Soviet GNP had been expanding at about 6 to 7 per cent per year as compared to 3 to 4 per cent per
year for the United States. (The previous edition, as noted above, had the US growing between 3 and 3.5 per
cent.) In 1972 this becomes: But Soviet growth performance slackened to about 5 percent per year in the
1960s, and projections for the 1970s suggest possible further deterioration to 4 to 4 percent. The latter
figures are quite close to the full-employment growth rates in the United States. In short, the substantial
growth rate advantage which the Soviet Union enjoyed in the 1950s and early 1960s has tended to diminish
and disappear. (1972, p. 812). The same passage appears in 1975 (1975, p. 897).
which continues for several editions. In 1978, McConnell finds evidence of [growth] convergence in recent
years: Soviet annual growth was 4.9 percent in the 1960 period while the United States enjoyed a 3.8
percent rate. Both economies performed poorly in the first half of the 1970s as reflected in a 3.5 percent
annual rate for the Soviet Union and a 2 percent rate here at home (1978, 933-34). The same passage is
found in the 1981 edition (1981, p. 886). In 1984, a new table shows Soviet growth falling to 2.7% in the
late 1970s (1984, p. 830) with the text telling us that Experts also agree that the Soviet growth rate has
generally exceeded the United States in the post-World War II period as a whole (1984, p. 830). The table
does not offer United States growth for comparison. In 1987, the question of the recent growth slowdown
is raised with Soviet growth having now fallen to 2.6% per annum for the 1981-83 years (1987, p. 905).
Yet none of these variations influences the visual presentations in the pie charts.
In 1990 McConnell and Brue provide estimates of US to the USSR growth from 1961-1965. Soviet
growth of 4.8% now differs only slightly from the US growth of 4.6% (1990, p. 856); the pie chart, however,
7
remains unchanged. Less dramatically, Soviet growth in the 1990 table has been revised downward from the
1987 table. What had been a 5.0% growth rate from 1971-65 in 1987 is now revised to 4.8%; a 3.7%
growth rate from 1971-75 is changed in 1990 to 3.1%; what was 2.7% for 1976-1980 is now revised to
2.1%. The 1990 text reports that from 1983 to 1988 the Soviet growth rate of 2% was overwhelmed by the
Samuelson
In 1961, Samuelson took a step beyond McConnell and devised a graph which provides a rough and
ready forecast of Soviet and American growth trajectories. Using different assumptions about Soviet and
American growth rates, Samuelson projects when the Soviet economy will overtake the US economy. His
first projection (a max-min overtaking point) is based on the maximum respectable Soviet growth assumption
and the minimum respectable American growth assumption. The second date, a max-max prediction, is more
cautious about when the overtaking will occur: it uses the maximum Soviet growth assumption and the
In the 1961 graph reproduced below the max-min year seems to be 1984; the max-max year is about
8
Like McConnells pie chart, Samuelsons overtaking
graph is always the first graph in the last chapter of the book.
There are however two editions, the 7th of 1967 and the 8th of
points. There are two regimes in the history of the graph. One
in the last two graphs does the ratio change. The claim of
considerably faster Soviet growth made by the graph is juxtaposed with an unchanging ratio of levels of real
output notwithstanding the obvious fact that sustained faster growth would have to imply a change in the
ratio.
3
From the 6th through the 10th editions Samuelsons inner lining has line graphs comparing many different countries. McConnell
has a table of National Income Accounts.
9
Samuelson Growth Forecast
Year Figure Max-Min Max-Max Start GNP
Overtaking Overtaking Ratio: US to
Time Time USSR
As noted above, the graphs appeared twice in Samuelsons 1967 and 1970 editions. The following
In the decade preceding 1970, the United States grew toward the top of its projected range of growth
rates. But the U.S.S.R., because of bad weather and crops and shortening of the workweek, seems to
have moved lower down on its projected range of growth rates (1970, p. 831)
Exogenous elements such as bad weather and an unforeseen political decision to increase the consumption of
The numbers in the chart above are derived from the graphics in the textbooks. Samuelson also
provides commentary about Soviet productivity and bad weather. In fifth edition (1961) he offers the
following discussion:
The decision of how to combine various productive factors land and labor, degree of
mechanization appears to depend on a mixture of purely technical considerations and adaptions to
the scarcity of various economic resources. A continual process of trial and error goes on. The
observer finds operations curiously uneven: on the one hand, he may see a military ballistic plant
which has achieved a precision of ball bearings and gyroscopes rivaling the best in the world; on the
other hand, he may find things being done an almost unbelievably primitive way, with the quality of
output practically worthless. (Example: A Soviet farmwoman may be assigned one cow to take care
10
of; on a Wisconsin dairy farm, a man and wife may take care of 30 cows, in addition to performing
countless other daily chores. (1961, p. 826)
The same paragraph with 30 cows appears in sixth edition (1964, p. 803). The graph in the 1964 edition is
From 1960 to 1964 it would appear that the United States has moved at the very top of its projected
range. But the U.S.S.R., because of bad weather and crops and shortening of the work week, may have
moved at the bottom of her projected range. (1964, p. 807)
The productivity paragraph appears in the seventh edition (1967, p. 786). In 1967 as well Figure 40-1, but
not 1-1, appears with the ending date above changed from 1964 to 1967.
Samuelson rewrote the productivity paragraph in the 8th edition, updating the example from 30 to 50
(Example: A Soviet farmwoman may be assigned one cow to take care of; on a mechanized Wisconsin
dairy farm, a man and wife may take care of 50 cows, in addition to performing countless other daily
chores. (1970, p. 827)
He accompanied the graphical information in 42.1, but not in 1.1, with this information:
In the decade preceding 1970, the United States grew toward the top of its projected range of growth
rates. But the U.S.S.R., because of bad weather and crops and shortening of the workweek, seems to
have moved lower down on its projected range of growth rates (1970, p. 831)
In the 9th edition the productivity paragraph is unchanged with 50 cows (1973, p. 879). The graph (1973, p.
883) is not qualified by bad weather although a footnote on the page before remarks In the last dozen years
In the 10th edition, the ratio of US to USSR output changed to 100:57 (1973, p. 883). The
Private allotments of land on the collective farm often have much higher, not lower productivity than
the collectivized sectors. (1976, p. 879).
Despite unfavorable weather, much-improved efficiency would seem technically feasible in the future.
(1976, p. 881).
11
In the 11th edition, the productivity paragraph italicizes higher (1980, p. 822); the ratio of US to USSR
output now falls to 100:55. (1980, p. 825). The edition drops the bad weather explanation and now simply
Despite this unfavorable past, much-improved efficiency would be technically feasible in the future
(1980, p. 824).
Bach
Not all the textbooks in the period assumed efficiency in the same manner that Samuelson and
McConnell did. We consider next two additional texts from the same era. The first is George L. Bachs
Economics: An Introduction to Analysis and Policy. Although this textbook was first published in 1954, it
descended from the 1940s text written jointly with Mary Jean Bowman. Instead of opening his discussion of
Soviet-American growth with a production possibility frontier, Bach discussed the details of the American
economy.
No other nation in history has industrialized at anything like the rate of the Soviet economy since the
early 1920s. From a backward, rural economy, in less than three decades Russia has become the
worlds second greatest industrial power. Her current military force may be the worlds greatest
(1954, p. 698).
The ranking continued through the 10th edition (1980, p. 674). In the third edition Soviet aggregate growth
was said to be something like double the American rate in the aggregate (1960, p. 826).
Yet in contrast with McConnell and Samuelson, Bach mentioned (1960, p. 841) dissenting voices in
the profession, noting that the NBER studies by Nutter and Gregory Grossman suggest that the spread
between Soviet and American growth rates may not be as wide as has been commonly supposed. In the sixth
edition, Bach reported that Soviet growth had in the last decade just about equaled that of the U.S.A.
(1968, p. 572). He noted: Comparing U.S. and U.S.S.R. growth rates is one of the favorite statistical
games of the generation .... (1968, p. 573). Per capita gross national product, however, solidly indicated a
12
discrepancy:
Our $3,900 per capita g.n.p. in 1967 compared with only about $1,700 for the U.S.S.R. Russian per
capita output is about two-thirds that in the major West European nations, and during the 1960s she
has gained on them and us little it at all. (1968, p. 573)
As a partial explanation, Bach pointed to unemployment caused by a failure of planning in the Soviet Union:
The Soviet central planners do not program men or machines into unemployment. If there is
unemployment, it is because planning has gone awry or because someone is not behaving according to
plan. But there is still the problem of keeping total spending power roughly equal to goods available
for purchase. (1968, p. 571)
In 1968 Bach adds a new table of hypothetical growth rates (1968, p. 574), beginning with a base of
100 for the US and 50 for the Soviet Union. Over the period of 1965-1995, the US growth numbers are
allowed to be 2, 3 and 4%. The Soviet numbers are allowed to be 4, 5, 6, 7%. Bach sees little need for alarm:
Unless we fall short of our historical 3 to 4 per cent growth rate, the Russians cant catch us before
the 1990s unless they growth at 6 per cent or better, a very high rate. (1968, p. 574).
The hypothetic table was removed from the 7th edition (1971) and replaced by a table showing Japan growing
In the ninth edition Soviet growth is said to have slowed even more (1977, p. 650) and black markets
have arisen:
The Russians are human beings too, and when there isnt enough to go around, they apparently tend
to plan a little more resources for all the demands than there are to parcel out. The result is a demand
pressure that tends to bid up prices all along the line as shortages occur; black markets spring up
everywhere. (1977, p. 651)
Per capita incomes ($7,000 v $2,700) were offered as evidence of a worsening of relative US / Soviet
well-being 2.3 in 1968 to 2.9 in 1977. Bach again noted differences of opinion on this matter: Some
observers put Russian per capita incomes as high as half ours, but not more. (1977, p. 651). The
Comparisons of American-Soviet per capita income become more complicated by 1980: $9,600 in
the United States, $3,500-$4,500 in the USSR. (1980, p. 675). In this edition, a new piece of information
13
is added, a Soviet cartoon showing a planning confusion and an anecdote a standard Russian joke about
incentives: 4
The accompanying cartoon shows the Russian wryly observing the problem. In a market system, the
profit incentive continually pushes managers to avoid such inefficiencies. Under quotas and physical
planning, the managers goal is to meet the quotas, not to question why. A standard Russian joke has
a factory turning out one huge one-ton nail as the cheapest way to meet its quota of one ton of steel
nails. (1980, p. 676).
In the new appendix the unemployment which was recognized in 1968 has a name: disguised
unemployment.
The Soviet central planners do not program men or machines into unemployment. If there is
unemployment, it is because planning has gone awry or because someone is not behaving according to
plan. And there has been very little official unemployment in the USSR. But there is much evidence
of disguised unemployment in the form of excess labor allocated to some industries. (1980, p. 690).
The textbook no longer predicted the Soviet Union overtaking the US and the fixed ratio of Soviet/US
output disappeared. The table which showed Soviet growth exceeding US growth appeared in only one
edition. Bach provided no explanation to accompany the specification; this would have required a PPF, which
Tarshis
Tarshis began his 1947 Elements of Economics with a clear statement that an unguided economy will
be inefficient:
It is, of course, not surprising that our economy sometimes fails to operate at peak efficiency.
Most of the economic institutions we have inherited were not designed by economists; certainly the
basic ones were not. In fact, they were not designed at all. Students of economic history can trace their
gradual evolution under the pull and tug of various interest groups: of the landlord and the
businessman, the merchant and the Church, the wage earner, the investor, and the bureaucrat. Anyone
who has studied the development of these institutions will not be surprised to find that they do not
always perform efficiently. After all, it is rarely enough that what we plan turns out as we planned it;
it would be remarkable indeed if something which grew without planning should perform in just the
way we want it to. If doctors had designed the human body, there would probably be no diseases.
Likewise, if economists had designed the economy, the chances are that there would be no economic
4
Peart and Levy 2005 discuss the anecdotal evidence aggregated in proverbial wisdom. Standard Soviet jokes are studied in Levy
and Peart (2006).
14
problems to worry about. As it is, the economist believes his job is to understand the existing
economy in order that he can properly guide efforts to make it work efficiently. (1947, pp. 4-5).
This provoked some controversy. Rose Wilder Lane correctly read the book as advocating political solutions
in lieu of voluntary solutions (1947). Yet Tarshis reformist point of view may have immunized his analysis
from an assumption of economic efficiency. 5 Indeed, the Soviet section in his much ignored Modern
Economics of 1967 contained no such assumption. Tarshis brief discussion there addressed the implicit
assumptions behind the perennial issue of the relative growth rates of the US and the Soviet Union (1967,
p. 663). He began by asking what index we ought to use. Output per capita was problematical because it
assumed a roughly constant and equal labor input across countries (1967, p. 661).
Tarshis table (1967, p. 663), reproduced below, illustrates the problem with all US and Soviet
comparisons. A simple switch of weights from US to USSR prices cuts the relative size of the Soviet economy
in half.6
5
Harcourt (1995) emphasizes the importance of Tarshis assumption of imperfect competition. Tarshis employs the kinked
demand model to argue for price rigidity in oligopoly (1947, pp. 182-4). Samuelsons chapter on the firm treats perfect and
imperfect competition together (1948, p. 491-17) and does not consider the possibility of oligopoly-induced price rigidity.
6
This consideration is noted in Samuelson as a technical index number problem involved that need only be indicated
which gets solved by simply splitting the difference in all the editions; (1961, p. 828); (1964, p. 806); (1967, p. 790);
(1970, p. 830); (1973, p. 881); (1976, p. 882); (1980; p. 824).
15
Tarshis then considered how to select time periods for the purposes of comparison, pointing out that
a short period analysis makes the choice of end points critical (1967, p. 661-62). Relying on Simon
Kuznets work, he compared growth rates of 19 countries. Since the time period spanned both Russian and
Soviet history (1870 1954), he chose to treat them as one country (1967, p. 666), a convention Nutter had
also followed that was widely and strenuously criticized (Brady 2008). Tarshis conclusion would not
surprise a reader of the 1st edition who remembered his emphasis on the economists role as reformer:
It is noticeable that most of these countries showed a decline in growth rate, comparing the two
periods. The exceptions were Italy and the Soviet Union, to which industrialization came late;
Sweden which succeeded in maintaining a high rate throughout an economist cannot refrain from
pointing out that Sweden; more than any other country in the group studied, has followed the advice
of its economists who incidentally have been exceptionally able. (1967, pp. 666-67)
This textbook, one notes with some regret, disappeared without a trace soon after it appeared.
The treatment of Soviet-American growth in Tarshis 1967 textbook suggests that the comparisons
depend very much on ones point of view. Tarshis makes no appeal to cross societal efficiency. He offers no
Heilbroner
Robert Heilbroners 1968 textbook positions itself farther than any other from Samuelsons
neoclassical synthesis. Heilbroner presupposed that market economies require a culture of self reliance free
of direction either by tradition or command. He divided the world into regions of command, markets and
tradition in a map shown here from the first edition inner liner (Heilbroner 1968). For Heilbroner the
Soviet Union must be viewed in terms of economic development in which its institutions evolve (1968, pp.
599). He questioned both the assumption of constant growth and that of fixed institutions, remarking that
growth was decelerating (1968, p. 628) and the Soviet Union was moving toward markets (1968, pp. 599).
Heilbroner predicted a convergence of systems (pp. 629-30) as institutions developed toward some
advanced form.
16
Samuelson captured the key features of economies using tradeoffs of guns and butter. By contrast,
Heilbroner discussed tradition, markets and command before he turned to guns and butter. For him, it was no
easy matter to compare economic activity in America with economic activity in the Soviet Union since one
Heilbroner occupies a distinct ideological position among textbook writers.7 Interestingly, Arnen
Alchian and William Allen shared Heilbroners reluctance to present an encompassing model for all
economies. Their University Economics comprised the Chicago-school alternative to Samuelson at this time.
Alchian and Allen explain why their book does not analyze any form of socialist economy: neoclassical theory
7
Heilbroner (1968, p. 3): no other branch of study holds such possibilities for the improvement of the human condition in a
world that is, in the main, still brutally poor. I do not mean that the rescuers of mankind must be economists, although I myself
believe that the appeal of economics is greatest to those who feel affronted at the miseries and inequities of the human
spectacle. Without minimizing Stalinist horrors he asks the student to reflect on the brutalities of capitalistic development
(1968, p. 595).
17
failed to characterize the Soviet economic system.8
Three major hostile reviews of the new generation of textbooks shaped the textbook landscape of the
1960s. Rose Wilder Lane reviewed Tarshis (Lane 1947), Orville Watts focused on a cluster of new
economics including Samuelson (Watts 1950), and William Buckley surveyed the textbooks used at Yale,
including those by Tarshis and Samuelson (Buckley 1951). Buckleys attack echoed those by Lane and
Watts but, as Elzinga (1992, p. 864) has noted, Buckley also asked why the positions of non-Keynesians were
Tarshis advocated reform within a particular economic framework. Samuelson, by contrast, took a
view that abstracted from any particular economy and so gave up the economists claim to the particulars that
might guide reform. Nor did Samuelson suggest that an economy cannot be efficient without direction by the
economists. Perhaps this is why the attacks on Tarshis ensured that the textbook would not survive into
immediately subsequent editions while the Samuelson textbook easily withstood the early criticism.
Between 1960 and 1980 it was widely believed that disinterested experts in the Soviet Union could
create a system of institutions such that the efficiency of market capitalism would be combined with the
ethical claims of socialism, the once-celebrated model of market socialism. The analysis assumed that those
directing the system were trustworthy so it was apparently plausible to write about the efficiency of
non-capitalist economies (Levy and Peart 2008). All of this implies that the economy which consumes least
romanticization of planned economies (Skousen 1997). Our account, however, suggests that the treatment
8
The portion of economics comprising the theory of exchange is applicable to a wider class of problems in a capitalistic
private-property economy than it is in a socialist society. This does not mean there is no exchange in the latter; there is, of
course, a great deal of it. ... In a socialist system ... political power and exchange of non private-property rights are used much
more widely to solve the economic questions. If were to devote primary attention to the socialist system, we would investigate
much more fully the processes of political exchange and political decision making. Alchian and Allen (1964, p. 6).
18
was not driven by ideology alone. Tarshis ideology was similar to that
(Nutter 1958, pp. 231-32, Nutter 1964, Lipsey 2008). In his letter to
October 1963).
Samuelson pioneered the use of the production possibility frontier, reproduced here from his first
edition, to conceptualize production in different societies. Frank Knight asked What, how and for whom
and Samuelson, his student, combined Keynes and Knight in a simple snapshot that addressed Knights first
question, the fundamental problem facing any economy, what shall be produced.9 In Samuelsons
formulation, abstracting from the possibility of involuntary unemployment (Keynes concern), all economies
are efficient. Thus Samuelson wrote about the Soviet economy in terms of the production possibility frontier
The Russians, having no unemployment before the war, were already on their Production-possibility
curve. They had no choice but to substitute war goods for civilian productionwith consequent
privation. Samuelson (1948, p. 20)
Tarshis and Samuelson believed in activist government policy to counteract what they saw as the
inherent instability and inefficiency in democratic capitalism; as a result, their books were attacked for being
9
What, How, and For Whom. Samuelson (1951, p. 14): These three questions are fundamental and common to all economies
The footnote credits the formulation of this approach to Frank Knights Social Economic Organization. The Knightian
foundation to Samuelsons text is discussed in Emmett (2008).
19
liberal and anti- market. They differed, however, on whether the economy might be represented by a PPF a
If the overstatement of Soviet growth was mainly driven by ideology we would expect Samuelson,
Tarshis and Heilbroner to overstate Soviet growth more dramatically than McConnell and Bach. They did
not. If the problem arose primarily because of the use of thin models, Samuelson and McConnell would
overstate Soviet growth more dramatically that the other texts. This is what we have observed above.
We noted above that Bach drew this students attention to the Nutter-Grossman research. Their
approach (Nutter 1957, 1962 and Rostow 1960), measured the years by which Soviet industry lagged
American industry. This required a belief that when Russia became the Soviet Union, its fundamental
institutions did not change. Tarshis skepticism about Soviet growth followed from a similar belief that,
The PPF
What drove the widespread adoption of the PPF by textbooks at this time? One explanation is that,
without the PPF, one cannot really model the Soviet economy at the level of a principles textbook. In
particular, the author cannot simply appeal to the historical record to illustrate the Soviet case because there
were two competing ways to read the historical record. The PPF allowed the author to accept one empirical
approach as opposed to the other. The implication of our account is that when the demand for Soviet analysis
in principles textbooks increased after Sputnik, textbooks came increasingly to rely on the PPF. An indication
20
of this transition are Rendig Fels 1961 purely empirical textbook, which contained no PPF, and Royall
The Challenge to the American Economy, whose very title refers to Khrushchevs boast that the
Soviet Union will bury American economically, dismissed Nutter and those who relied on Nutter's research.
After quoting Khrushchev and presenting standard growth comparisons, Fels turned to Henry Hazlitts use of
Nutters data:
The table appears to justify amply Hazlitts conclusion that the evidence has been
unmistakable that, far from there being any miracle of Communist production, the lands behind the
Iron Curtain are going through an economic crisis. These results are in striking contradiction to the
figures cited in the previous section. There it was proved that Communist output grows twice as fast
as American. Here it is proved that under Communism output lags farther behind. Plainly it cannot
do both at once. (Fels 1961, p. 11)
Fels (1961, pp. 11-12) criticized Nutter for using figures based in 1913 and Hazlitt for his blind
faith in the goodness of capitalism, a belief that reportedly biased his analysis:
Popular writing on economics is strewn with errors. Although it is perhaps unfair to expose
Hazlitt in one, since he generally maintains a high standard, nevertheless for educational purposes it
is valuable to do so. The fact that one of the best has fallen into a trap is a warning to read everything
including his book with a healthy degree of skepticism. The probable cause for his going astray is
likely to infect anyone. Hazlitt is a stronger believer in capitalism and a vigorous critic of any other
economic system (Fels 1961, p. 12)
Fels textbook was in some respect thick; it contained no PPF and in other ways it was less abstract
than Samuelsons textbook. But as a thick textbook, it contained no abstract model with which to coherently
predict continued rapid Soviet growth. He chose not to believe Nutters approach but that choice was
To illustrate why the PPF was so attractive at this time to textbook writers , consider how Royall
Brandis adopted the PPF midway through his textbook run as a way to model the Soviet economy. His was
perhaps the most elegant use of the PPF in the period. In the note to the instructor Brandis explained the
21
addition: the production- possibility curve
for the future more than consumer goods. Thus, higher investment brings about faster growth (Brandis 1968,
p. 34). The assumption of efficiency is critical here and is often viewed as the default assumption in the
Conclusion
Thin models yield crisp implications. Models that supposed cross societal efficiency implied that the
Soviet Union must overtake the US economy because Soviet consumption was lower than US consumption.
Faster growth over time yields overtaking. Bad weather or some such secondary explanation then freed the
model from falsification. Nutters joke about the endogenous past captures the difficulty.
Yet one reason for the simplicity of thin models, of course, is that complicating dimensions are
missing. Those textbooks which did not assume efficiency avoided the problems associated with assuming
away complications. In 1980, Bach reported a standard Soviet joke about the quota-making nail. The same
joke appeared a decade earlier in the 1970 edition of Heilbroners book. A cartoon in the Russian satirical
magazine Krokodil depicts a nail factory proudly displaying its record output: one gigantic nail suspended
22
from an immense gantry crane (1970, p. 627).
That books with different ideological viewpoints could come to the same conclusion about the Soviet
economy suggests that more than ideology was required to get the story right. Instead, the application of
thin models with no account of institutional details led researchers into what we now know was an overly
optimistic account of Soviet growth. The moral we draw from the treatment of Soviet growth in American
textbooks is that multiple points of view are potentially useful when we study non-transparent institutions.
When the voices of fine scholars such as Lorie Tarshis and Warren Nutter were disregarded because of their
dissenting points of view, the profession became less able to penetrate Soviet non-transparency than it might
otherwise have been. We are all constrained by means of models: we gain insight in one dimension by
blinding ourselves to events in other dimensions. Competition among models may be necessary to insure that
23
Bibliography
Alchian, Armen A. and William R. Allen. 1964 University Economics. Belmont: Wadsworth Publishing.
Bach, George Leland. 1954-1980. Economics: An Introduction to Analysis and Policy. Englewood Cliffs:
Prentice-Hall.
Bowman, Mary Jean and George Leland Bach. 1943-1949. Economic Analysis and Public Policy. New York:
Prentice Hall.
Brady, Gordon. 2008. The NBER Soviet Study. Summer Institute for the History of Economics. George
Mason University.
Buckley, William F., Jr. 1951. God and Man at Yale. Chicago: Regnery.
Colander, David C. and Harry Landreth. 1995. Editors. The Coming of Keynesianism to America:
Conversations with the Founders of Keynesian Economics. Cheltenhaum, UK: Edward Elgar.
Colander, David C. and Harry Landreth. 1998. God, Man, and Lorie Tarshis at Yale In Omar Hamuda.
Editor. Keynesianism and the Keynesian Revolution in America . Cheltenhaum, UK: Edward
Elgar.
Elzinga, Kenneth G. 1992. The Eleven Principles of Economics. Southern Economic Journal 58:4 (April):
861-79.
Emmett, Ross. 2008. Frank Knight and The Economic Organization. In Robert Leeson. The
Anti-Keynesian Tradition: Archival Insights into the Evolution of Economics. New York: Palgrave.
Fels, Rendig. 1961-1966. The Challenge to the American Economy: An Introduction to Economics. Boston:
Allyn and Bacon.
Gerschenkron, Alexander. 1978. Samuelson in Soviet Russia: A Report. Journal of Economic Literature
16:2 (June): 560-73.
Harcourt, G. C. 1995. 1995. Lorie Tarshis, 1911-1993: In Appreciation. Economic Journal 105:
1244-1255.
Heilbroner, Robert L. 1968-1970. The Economic Problem. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice Hall.
Lane, Rose Wilder. 1946. Review of Ludwig von Mises, Omnipotent Government. Economic Council Review of
Books 3 (August)
Lane, Rose Wilder. 1947. Review of Lorie Tarshis. Elements of Economics. Economic Council Review of
24
Books 4 (August)
Levine, Isaac Don. 1932. Red Smoke. New York. Robert M. McBride & Company.
Levy, David M. and Sandra J. Peart. 2006. The Fragility of a Discipline When A Model Has Monopoly
Power. Review of Austrian Economics 19: 125-36.
Levy, David M. and Sandra J. Peart. 2008. Socialist Calculation Debate. The New Palgraves Dictionary of
Economics. Edited by Lawrence Blume and Steven Durlauf. Second edition. New York: Palgrave.
Lipsey, Richard. 2008. Assessements of the Soviet Union: Who Got It Right and Who Got it Wrong.
Presented at the Summer Institute for the History of Economics.
http://www.gmu.edu/centers/publicchoice/SummerInstitute/si_schedule08.htm
McConnell, Campbell R. 1960-1990. Economics: Principles, Problems, and Policies. New York:
McGraw-Hill.
Nutter, G. Warren. [1958] 1983. Economic Warfare. In G. Warren Nutter. Political Economy and
Freedom: A Collection of Essays. Edited by Jane Couch Nutter, pp. 222-36. Indianapolis: Liberty
Fund.
Nutter, G. Warren. 1962. The Growth of Industrial Production in the Soviet Union. Princeton: National
Bureau of Economic Research.
Nutter, G. Warren. [1964] 1983. The Soviet Stir: Economic Crisis and Response. In G. Warren Nutter,
Political Economy and Freedom (ed). Jane Couch Nutter, pp. 181-88. Indianapolis: Liberty Press.
Nutter, G. Warren. 1969. The Strange World of Ivan Ivanov. New York and Cleveland: World Publishing.
Peart, Sandra J. and David M. Levy 2005. The Vanity of the Philosopher: From Equality to Hierarchy in
Post-Classical Economics. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Rostow, W. W. 22 October 1963. Letter to G. Warren Nutter. In the possession of Richard Ware.
Samuelson, Paul A. 1997. Credo of a Lucky Textbook Author. Journal of Economic Perspectives 11
(Spring): 153-69.
Skousen, Mark. 1997. The Perseverance of Paul Samuelsons Economics. Journal of Economic
Perspectives 11 (Spring): 137-152.
Tarshis, Lorie. 1947. The Elements of Economics: An Introduction to the Theory of Price and Employment.
25
Boston: Houghton Mifflin.
Watts, V. Orval. 1950. Review of New Economics Texts. Economic Council Review of Books 7 (August
& September.
26