Externalities, Environmental Policy, and Public Goods
Externalities, Environmental Policy, and Public Goods
Externalities, Environmental Policy, and Public Goods
1 of 36
CHAPTER
Learning Objectives
5.1
5.2
5.3
5.4
2 of 36
3 of 36
Externality A benefit or cost that affects someone who is not directly involved
in the production or consumption of a good or service.
4 of 36
Identify examples of positive and negative externalities and use graphs to show
how externalities affect economic efficiency.
5 of 36
6 of 36
7 of 36
8 of 36
Externalities and market failures result from incomplete property rights or from
the difficulty of enforcing property rights in certain situations.
9 of 36
Discuss the Coase theorem and explain how private bargaining can lead to
economic efficiency in a market with an externality.
Ronald Coase of the University of Chicago, winner of the 1991 Nobel Prize in
Economics, argued that under some circumstances, private solutions to the
problem of externalities will occur. To understand his argument, it is important to
recognize that completely eliminating an externality usually is not economically
efficient.
10 of 36
Connection
Test your understanding by doing related problem 2.3 on page 153 at the end of
this chapter.
Copyright 2015 Pearson Canada Inc.
11 of 36
Only when the reduction is at 1.5 million tonnes is the marginal benefit equal to the marginal cost.
This level is the economically efficient level of pollution reduction.
12 of 36
Test your understanding by doing related problem 2.2 on page 153 at the end of
this chapter.
Copyright 2015 Pearson Canada Inc.
13 of 36
Figure 5.4
The Benefits of Reducing Pollution to the
Optimal Level Are Greater than the Costs
Increasing the reduction in sulphur
dioxide emissions from 1.0 million tonnes
to 1.5 million tonnes results in total
benefits equal to the sum of the areas A
and B under the marginal benefits curve.
The total cost of this decrease in pollution
is equal to the area B under the marginal
cost curve. The total benefits are greater
than the total costs by an amount equal to
the area of triangle A . Because the total
benefits from reducing pollution are
greater than the total costs, its
possible for those receiving the benefits
to arrive at a private agreement with
polluters to pay them to reduce pollution.
14 of 36
Making
The Fable
Connection of the Bees
the
In Washington State, farmers with fruit orchards had been renting beehives to
pollinate their trees since at least as early as 1917, and today honeybees
pollinate more than $14 billion worth of crops annually, from blueberries in Maine
all the way to almonds in California.
MyEconLab Your Turn:
Test your understanding by doing related problem 2.5 on page 153 at the end of
this chapter.
Copyright 2015 Pearson Canada Inc.
15 of 36
16 of 36
17 of 36
18 of 36
Figure 5.5
When There Is a Negative
Externality, a Tax Can Lead to
the Efficient Level of Output
Because utilities do not bear
the cost of acid rain, they
produce electricity beyond the
economically efficient level. If
the government imposes a tax
equal to the cost of acid rain,
the utilities will internalize the
externality. As a consequence,
the supply curve will shift up,
from S1 to S2. The market
equilibrium quantity changes
from QMarket, where an
inefficiently high level of
electricity is produced, to
QEfficient, the economically
efficient equilibrium quantity.
The price of electricity will rise from PMarketwhich does not include the cost of acid rainto PEfficient
which does include the cost.
Consumers pay the price PEfficient, while producers receive a price P, which is equal to PEfficient minus the
amount of the tax.
19 of 36
For more practice, do related problem 3.3 on page 154 at the end of this chapter.
20 of 36
Figure 5.6
When There Is a Positive
Externality, a Subsidy Can
Bring About the Efficient
Level of Output
People who do not consume
postsecondary educations can
benefit from them. As a result,
the social benefit from a
postsecondary education is
greater than the private benefit
to postsecondary students.
If the government pays a
subsidy equal to the external
benefit, students will internalize
the externality.
The subsidy will cause the demand curve to shift up, from D1 to D2.
As a result, the market equilibrium quantity will shift from QMarket, where an inefficiently low level of
postsecondary educations is supplied, to QEfficient, the economically efficient equilibrium quantity.
Producers receive the price PEfficient, while consumers pay a price P, which is equal to PEfficient minus the
amount of the subsidy.
21 of 36
Making
the
Connection
Test your understanding by doing related problem 3.5 on page 154 at the end of
this chapter.
Copyright 2015 Pearson Canada Inc.
22 of 36
Command-and-Control versus
Market-Based Approaches
Command-and-control approach An approach that involves the government
imposing quantitative limits on the amount of pollution firms are allowed to emit
or requiring firms to install specific pollution control devices.
23 of 36
Making
the
Connection
Although CO2 emissions rose slightly during the first few years of a cap-and-trade plan set up
in Europe in 2005, they should decline over time as the number of allowances is reduced.
MyEconLab Your Turn:
chapter.
Copyright 2015 Pearson Canada Inc.
Test your understanding by doing related problem 3.5 on page 154 at the end of this
24 of 36
Explain how goods can be categorized on the basis of whether they are rival or
excludable and use graphs to illustrate the efficient quantities of public goods
and common resources.
25 of 36
Rivalry The situation that occurs when one persons consuming a unit of a
good means no one else can consume it.
Excludability The situation in which anyone who does not pay for a good
cannot consume it.
Figure 5.7
Four Categories of Goods
26 of 36
27 of 36
Figure 5.8
The market demand curve for private goods is determined by adding horizontally the
quantity of the good demanded at each price by each consumer. For instance, in panel
(a), Jill demands 2 hamburgers when the price is $4.00, and in panel (b), Joe demands 4
hamburgers when the price is $4.00. So, a quantity of 6 hamburgers and a price of $4.00
is a point on the market demand curve in panel (c).
Copyright 2015 Pearson Canada Inc.
28 of 36
Figure 5.9
Constructing the Demand Curve
for a Public Good
To find the demand curve for a public
good, we add up the price at which
each consumer is willing to purchase
each quantity of the good.
29 of 36
30 of 36
Joe
Price
(dollars per hour)
$20
18
16
14
12
10
8
6
4
2
Quantity (hours
of protection)
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
Price
(dollars per hour)
Quantity (hours
of protection)
$20
18
16
14
12
10
8
6
4
2
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
Price
(dollars per hour)
Quantity (hours
of protection)
$8
10
12
14
16
18
20
22
24
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
31 of 36
Quantity (hours
of protection)
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
For more practice, do related problem 4.1 on page 154 at the end of this
32 of 36
Common Resources
Tragedy of the commons The tendency for a common resource to be
overused.
Figure 5.11
Overuse of a Common
Resource
For a common resource
such as wood from a forest,
the efficient level of use,
QEfficient, is determined by the
intersection of the demand
curvewhich represents the
marginal benefit received by
consumersand S2, which
represents the marginal
social cost of cutting the
wood.
Because each individual tree cutter ignores the external cost, the equilibrium quantity of
wood cut is QActual, which is greater than the efficient quantity. At the equilibrium level of
output, there is a deadweight loss, as shown by the yellow triangle.
Copyright 2015 Pearson Canada Inc.
33 of 36
34 of 36
35 of 36
AN
AN
INSID
INSIDE
LOOKE
LOOK
With the implementation of new pollution regulations, producers would bear more of the
external cost of pollution.
Copyright 2015 Pearson Canada Inc.
36 of 36