Indifference Curve
Indifference Curve
Indifference curve
From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Contents
1 History
2 Map and properties of indifference curves
3 Assumptions of consumer preference theory
3.1 Application
3.2 Examples of indifference curves
4 Preference relations and utility
4.1 Preference relations
4.2 Formal link to utility theory
4.3 Examples
4.3.1 Linear utility
4.3.2 Cobb-Douglas utility
4.3.3 CES utility
4.3.4 Biology
5 See also
6 Footnotes
7 Notes
8 References
9 External links
History
en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Indifference_curve
1/10
9/20/13
The theory of indifference curves was developed by Francis Ysidro Edgeworth, who explained in his book
"Mathematical Psychics: an Essay on the Application of Mathematics to the Moral Sciences, 1881,[3] the
mathematics needed for its drawing; later on, Vilfredo Pareto was the first author to actually draw these curves, in
his book "Manual of Political Economy," 1906;[4][5] and others in the first part of the 20th century. The theory can
be derived from William Stanley Jevons's ordinal utility theory, which posits that individuals can always rank any
consumption bundles by order of preference.[6]
2/10
9/20/13
en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Indifference_curve
3/10
9/20/13
It also implies that the commodities are good rather than bad. Examples of bad commodities can be disease,
pollution etc. because we always desire less of such things.
Indifference curves exhibit diminishing marginal rates of substitution
The marginal rate of substitution tells how much 'y' a person is willing to sacrifice to get one more unit
of 'x'.
This assumption assures that indifference curves are smooth and convex to the origin.
This assumption also set the stage for using techniques of constrained optimization because the shape
of the curve assures that the first derivative is negative and the second is positive.
Another name for this assumption is the substitution assumption. It is the most critical assumption of
consumer theory: Consumers are willing to give up or trade-off some of one good to get more of
another. The fundamental assertion is that there is a maximum amount that "a consumer will give up, of
one commodity, to get one unit of another good, in that amount which will leave the consumer
indifferent between the new and old situations"[9] The negative slope of the indifference curves
represents the willingness of the consumer to make a trade off.[9]
There are also many sub-assumptions:
Irreflexivity - for no x is xp x
Negative transitivity - if xnot-p y then for any third commodity z, either xnot-p z or znot-p y or both.
Application
Consumer theory uses indifference curves and budget constraints to
generate consumer demand curves. For a single consumer, this is a
relatively simple process. First, let one good be an example market e.g.,
carrots, and let the other be a composite of all other goods. Budget
constraints give a straight line on the indifference map showing all the
possible distributions between the two goods; the point of maximum
utility is then the point at which an indifference curve is tangent to the
budget line (illustrated). This follows from common sense: if the market
values a good more than the household, the household will sell it; if the
market values a good less than the household, the household will buy it.
The process then continues until the market's and household's marginal
rates of substitution are equal.[10] Now, if the price of carrots were to
change, and the price of all other goods were to remain constant, the
gradient of the budget line would also change, leading to a different point
of tangency and a different quantity demanded. These price / quantity
combinations can then be used to deduce a full demand curve.[10] A line
connecting all points of tangency between the indifference curve and the
budget constraint is called the expansion path.[11]
en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Indifference_curve
4/10
9/20/13
Figure 1: An example of
an indifference map with
three indifference curves
represented
Figure 2: Three
indifference curves
where Goods X and Y
are perfect substitutes.
The gray line
perpendicular to all
curves indicates the
curves are mutually
parallel.
Figure 3: Indifference
curves for perfect
complements X and Y.
The elbows of the
curves are collinear.
In Figure 1, the consumer would rather be on I3 than I2 , and would rather be on I2 than I1 , but does not care
where he/she is on a given indifference curve. The slope of an indifference curve (in absolute value), known by
economists as the marginal rate of substitution, shows the rate at which consumers are willing to give up one good in
exchange for more of the other good. For most goods the marginal rate of substitution is not constant so their
indifference curves are curved. The curves are convex to the origin, describing the negative substitution effect. As
price rises for a fixed money income, the consumer seeks less the expensive substitute at a lower indifference curve.
The substitution effect is reinforced through the income effect of lower real income (Beattie-LaFrance). An example
of a utility function that generates indifference curves of this kind is the Cobb-Douglas function
. The negative slope of the indifference curve incorporates the willingness of the consumer
[12]
to make trade offs.
If two goods are perfect substitutes then the indifference curves will have a constant slope since the consumer
would be willing to switch between at a fixed ratio. The marginal rate of substitution between perfect substitutes is
likewise constant. An example of a utility function that is associated with indifference curves like these would be
.
If two goods are perfect complements then the indifference curves will be L-shaped. Examples of perfect
complements include left shoes compared to right shoes: the consumer is no better off having several right shoes if
she has only one left shoe - additional right shoes have zero marginal utility without more left shoes, so bundles of
goods differing only in the number of right shoes they includes - however many - are equally preferred. The
marginal rate of substitution is either zero or infinite. An example of the type of utility function that has an
indifference map like that above is the Leontief function:
.
The different shapes of the curves imply different responses to a change in price as shown from demand analysis in
consumer theory. The results will only be stated here. A price-budget-line change that kept a consumer in
equilibrium on the same indifference curve:
in Fig. 1 would reduce quantity demanded of a good smoothly as price rose relatively for that good.
en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Indifference_curve
5/10
9/20/13
in Fig. 2 would have either no effect on quantity demanded of either good (at one end of the budget
constraint) or would change quantity demanded from one end of the budget constraint to the other.
in Fig. 3 would have no effect on equilibrium quantities demanded, since the budget line would rotate around
the corner of the indifference curve.[nb 2]
Preference relations
Let
be a set of mutually exclusive alternatives among which a consumer can choose.
and be generic elements of .
In the language of the example above, the set is made of combinations of apples and bananas. The symbol
one such combination, such as 1 apple and 4 bananas and is another combination such as 2 apples and 2
bananas.
A preference relation, denoted
is
The statement
is at least as good as
The statement
is described as ' is weakly preferred to , and is weakly preferred to .' That is, one is indifferent to the
choice of or , meaning not that they are unwanted but that they are equally good in satisfying preferences.
The statement
which are
6/10
9/20/13
of the set
and the
In utility theory, the utility function of an agent is a function that ranks all pairs of consumption bundles by order of
preference (completeness) such that any set of three or more bundles forms a transitive relation. This means that
for each bundle
there is a unique relation,
, representing the utility (satisfaction) relation associated
with
. The relation
is called the utility function. The range of the function is a set of
real numbers. The actual values of the function have no importance. Only the ranking of those values has content for
the theory. More precisely, if
, then the bundle
is described as at least as good as
the bundle
. If
, the bundle
is described as strictly preferred to the
bundle
.
Consider a particular bundle
Examples
Linear utility
en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Indifference_curve
7/10
9/20/13
and
Cobb-Douglas utility
If the utility function is of the form
is
. The slope of the indifference
CES utility
A general CES (Constant Elasticity of Substitution) form is
where
and
marginal utilities are given by
.) The
and
8/10
9/20/13
risk involved in obtaining it. The indifference curve is drawn to predict the animal's behavior at various levels of risk
and food availability.
See also
Budget constraint
Community indifference curve
Consumer theory
Convex preferences
Endowment effect
Indifference price
Level curve
Microeconomics
Rationality
Utilitypossibility frontier
Footnotes
1. ^ The transitivity of weak preferences is sufficient for most IC analysis: If A is weakly preferred to B meaning that
the consumer likes A at least as much as B and B is weakly preferred to C then A is weakly preferred to C. [8]
2. ^ Indifference curves can be used to derive the individual demand curve. However, the assumptions of consumer
preference theory do not guarantee that the demand curve will have a negative slope. [13]
Notes
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.
9.
10.
11.
References
Beattie, Bruce R.; LaFrance, Jeffrey T. (2006). "The Law of Demand versus Diminishing Marginal Utility".
Appl. Econ. Perspect. Pol. 28 (2): 263271. doi:10.1111/j.1467-9353.2006.00286.x
(http://dx.doi.org/10.1111%2Fj.1467-9353.2006.00286.x).
Binger; Hoffman (1998). Microeconomics with Calculus (2nd ed.). Reading: Addison-Wesley.
en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Indifference_curve
9/10
9/20/13
ISBN 0321012259.
Bhm, Volker; Haller, Hans (1987). "Demand theory". The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics 1.
pp. 785792.
Geanakoplos, John (1987). "Arrow-Debreu model of general equilibrium". The New Palgrave: A
Dictionary of Economics 1. pp. 116124.
Perloff, Jeffrey M. (2008). Microeconomics: Theory & Applications with Calculus. Boston: AddisonWesley. ISBN 9780321277947.
Silberberg; Suen (2000). The Structure of Economics: A Mathematical Analysis (3rd ed.). Boston:
McGraw-Hill. ISBN 0071181369.
Lipsey, Richard G. (1975). An introduction to positive economics (fourth ed.). Weidenfeld & Nicolson.
pp. 2147. ISBN 0-297-76899-9.
External links
Anatomy of Cobb-Douglas Type Utility Functions in 3D
(http://www2.hawaii.edu/~fuleky/anatomy/anatomy.html)
Anatomy of CES Type Utility Functions in 3D (http://www2.hawaii.edu/~fuleky/anatomy/anatomy2.html)
Retrieved from "http://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=Indifference_curve&oldid=567088348"
Categories: Consumer theory Household behavior and family economics Microeconomics Economics curves
Utility
This page was last modified on 4 August 2013 at 08:37.
Text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution-ShareAlike License; additional terms may apply.
By using this site, you agree to the Terms of Use and Privacy Policy.
Wikipedia is a registered trademark of the Wikimedia Foundation, Inc., a non-profit organization.
en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Indifference_curve
10/10