FPC Briefing: How Do International Economic Sanctions (Not) Work? DR Lee Jones Executive Summary
FPC Briefing: How Do International Economic Sanctions (Not) Work? DR Lee Jones Executive Summary
FPC Briefing: How Do International Economic Sanctions (Not) Work? DR Lee Jones Executive Summary
Adapted from Jonathan Kirshner, The Microfoundations of Economic Sanctions, Security Studies 6(3): 46-9.
Investment
Aid
Finance
Assets
and
Monetary
(currency
manipulation)
Arms
However, sanctions also spur a strategic response from socio-political forces that, over time, shifts
their distributional costs and mediates their political impact. Accordingly, one cannot simply target
sanctions at groups supporting the target regime and expect them to produce the desired effect:
dominant forces are often extremely good at recouping their losses and deflecting the burden of
sanctions onto subordinated groups.
Depending on their political orientation, capacity for collective action and relationship with
state managers, groups harmed by sanctions may resign themselves to their losses and
become focused on bare subsistence; seek compensation from their patrons; or defect to
the opposition.
A regime whose support base disintegrates as societys composition alters will need to
cultivate new supporters to stay in power. This will require ideological shifts and the
redeployment of resources, such as the cultivation of import-substituting industries or the
reallocation of state subsidies. This may in turn prompt protests or defections from other
members of the ruling coalition.
The same logic applies to opposition coalitions. Groups that are harmed by sanctions or
perceive lucrative opportunities in joining the ruling coalition in sanctions-busting activities
may defect from the opposition. A population consumed with the struggle for daily
subsistence may have little time, energy, or resources to devote to political activism.
In the longer term, these strategic responses to sanctions may themselves alter a societys
basic composition. For instance, the promotion of import-substituting industries or domestic
agriculture can strengthen industrial or agricultural working classes and bourgeoisies, which
may be incorporated into ruling or opposition coalitions.
It is in this strategic phase of sanctions cases that success or failure is determined. If the strategic
response of ruling and opposition coalitions involves political decisions that take the country closer
to the objectives sought by those imposing sanctions, success is possible, and vice-versa.
The implication of this framework is that sanctions are a rather blunt and unpredictable tool. Despite
the perception of precision that the phrase targeted sanctions may create, it is extremely difficult
to predict how actors harmed by sanctions will respond. They will often react in a way inimical to the
goals of sanctions regimes and, particularly if they enjoy access to state power, will frequently
displace the costs onto weaker social groups.
Case Studies: South Africa and Iraq
South Africa: Although widely feted as a great success story, sanctions against South Africas
apartheid regime were actually counter-productive in the 1960s and 1970s and only bit in the
1980s thanks to the emergence of forceful anti-regime opposition. The early oil and arms embargoes
merely stimulated massive import-substituting industrialisation: the formation of Armscor, which
transformed South Africa into a major arms exporter, and the creation of massive oil-from-coal
plants that supplied 40 percent of South Africas oil requirements. This strategy actually expanded
the regimes support base by increasing the size of the white bourgeoisie and professional and
working classes. It also fostered closer ties between the regime and the capitalist class in defence of
their commercial interests. Sanctions-busting networks also emerged that criminalised parts of the
South African state apparatus, particularly the military, which also drew closer to leading business
interests.
Sanctions only harmed the regime in the 1980s when decades of economic growth, coupled with the
effects of sanctions-busting had changed the composition of South African society. Most
importantly, the demands of industrialisation had bred a large, restive, non-white working class in
South Africas cities. By the 1980s, economic growth was insufficient to absorb South Africas
growing non-white population and the townships were becoming ungovernable. Meanwhile, the
Afrikaner bourgeoisie was outgrowing the cocoon of state patronage and began chafing against
apartheid restrictions on the labour market. Along with the expanded Afrikaner middle class, it
formed a social basis for reform. To preserve a ruling coalition, the regime responded to these
developments through domestic counter-insurgency and welfare improvements targeted at nonwhites, plus modest relaxations of apartheid strictures. However, the financial burden of busting the
arms and oil embargoes was compounded in the 1980s by a severe debt crisis (unrelated to
sanctions) and by additional, relatively modest sanctions on trade and investment. The apartheid
regime simply could not afford to finance repression, welfare and sanctions-busting all at once.
However, without repression and welfare spending combined, the dominant forces feared an
eventual black revolution. The white bourgeoisie increasingly distanced itself from the regime,
reorienting towards the opposition. Eventually the regime was compelled to seek a democratic
settlement to avoid the total destruction of white wealth and power.
Iraq: Despite being seen as an archetypal case of sanctions failure, the comprehensive embargo
imposed from 1990-2003 actually had dramatic consequences. It devastated the ruling coalition. The
economic collapse caused by sanctions rapidly destroyed the urban middle and working classes that
were the Baath regimes popular support base. Government revenues shrivelled, rendering
unaffordable the regimes previous strategies of rule: import-substituting industrialisation,
consumer subsidies and military spending. The regime was forced to abandon many erstwhile
supporters, concentrating its meagre resources on its inner core: a few Sunni tribes and around one
million public servants. It also had to cultivate alliances with newly empowered groups: Iraqs
resurgent tribal chiefs and landlords, to whom many state duties and privileges were reassigned, and
a newly emergent smuggler class, the fat cats of the embargo. These changes fostered enormous
social unrest: inter-tribal warfare; clashes between tribes and Baath party elites; struggles between
rival state apparatuses over control of smuggling routes; and at least five coup attempts from 19936. As internal regime documents also show, Saddams desperation to end the embargo also drove
significant concessions to those imposing sanctions, especially the effective compliance with United
Nations disarmament demands by the mid-1990s.
Nevertheless, sanctions did not produce the regime change that many believed to be their covert
goal, at least for Britain and the United States. This was because they had a similarly devastating
impact on Iraqs opposition forces, who were already weak, poorly organised and ideologically
fragmented. Sanctions drove two million Iraqis to emigrate. Those left behind were consumed in a
depoliticising daily struggle for survival, becoming dependent on state and tribal authorities for
subsistence and being unable to revolt without placing their survival in jeopardy. The opposition
Iraqi National Congress split over the question of sanctions. Most importantly of all, the Kurdish
Democratic Party effectively defected to the Baathist regime by collaborating in its lucrative,
sanctions-busting oil smuggling schemes. This fatally weakened the opposition, allowing regime
troops to oust the opposition from northern Iraq in 1995. The Oil For Food Programme then arrested
the regimes destabilisation and facilitated a modest recovery in its domestic fortunes, while the
opposition withered.
Lessons for Policymakers
Clearly, the effect of economic sanctions does not depend simply on their severity, or on who they
initially harm. What matters is how social and political forces in targeted societies change their
coalitional strategies in response. While this strategic response is hard to predict and it is difficult to
generalise across very diverse targets, Societies Under Siege identifies several key considerations.
The autonomy of social forces from state power matters. The degree to which social forces
can survive and thrive without state patronage is crucial to determining whether they will be
rendered politically defunct, draw closer to the target regime, or break from it. South
Africas relatively autonomous bourgeoisie and large industrial working class displayed far
greater political independence activism than Iraqs urban social classes, who were heavily
dependent on state contracts and employment.
The size, power and organisation of opposition forces is decisive. Partly because sanctions
effects are more destructive than creative, sanctions never mobilise opposition to a regime
where previously it did not exist. They do not create opposition out of thin air but must work
with what already exists. If an opposition coalition is already powerful and well organised, it
may be able to resist the fragmenting tendencies of sanctions. It may also make it impossible
for a ruling coalition to displace the costs of sanctions onto it, as in South Africa. The
opposite applies where oppositions are weak and fragmented, as in Iraq.
Targeted sanctions are not a panacea. Smart sanctions appear to avoid the worst
humanitarian consequences of comprehensive embargoes by targeting responsible elites
rather than entire populations. But because their effects are narrow, their costs are even
easier to evade or to displace onto others, meaning collateral damage still occurs. As the
case study of Myanmar in Societies Under Siege shows, regime leaders and their business
allies can easily generate new business activities to compensate for their losses, pass higher
costs onto consumers and citizens, and bust smart sanctions by operating through overseas
front companies or obtaining passports in fake names.
Each society is unique and demands devoted analysis. Sanctions are frequently imposed
because or called for with respect to the assumed (by some campaigners) moral
similarity of target regimes. In the 1990s, many anti-apartheid campaigners demanded
sanctions on the military regime in Myanmar because they had worked to hasten the
demise of another unacceptable regime in South Africa. Today, many campaigners calling for
Boycotts, Sanctions and Disinvestment measures against Israel draw parallels between its
situation and apartheid South Africa. Yet, simply because sanctions appear to have worked
in one country does not mean that even an identical package of sanctions will work in
another. Even countries with morally identical regimes have very different political economy
contexts, differently constituted ruling and opposition coalitions, and different alliances,
strategies and resource distributions.
Most crucially, by what mechanism is the imposition of economic hardship supposed to filter
through into political change?
o What are the forces contesting state power?
o What are their attitudes to the policy?
o What is their relationship to key economic sectors?
o How might damaging specific sectors affect different groups?
o How will this material impact condition political conflict and outcomes? For example, do
we wish to force the target regime to negotiate with us, or force it from office?
o If policymakers cannot specify a plausible, step-by-step mechanism by which the
infliction of economic pain will generate political gain, they ought not to impose
sanctions at all. Doing so merely imposes random suffering in the vain hope of positive
outcomes. This is deeply unethical, and poor public policy.
Given the difficulty in predicting social and political forces strategic responses, it is also essential to
monitor sanctioned countries very closely to determine whether the anticipated mechanisms are
actually being activated. The key considerations for an evaluation process are as follows:
Always seek to measure the degree of compliance with the stated goals of the sanctions
regime. Success means the achievement of these end goals, not simply the infliction of
damage. It is premature to declare that sanctions are successful simply because a countrys
economy is being harmed, or even if the social and political mechanisms seen as a route to
that end are apparently operating.
Is the anticipated mechanism for translating economic pain into political gain actually
operating as we intended?
o Have sanctions affected the groups we wanted, or others? Are the targets displacing
their effects onto others?
o Are sanctions changing the balance among domestic groups, and the strategies they are
pursuing, in a way that advances or impedes our goals?
o If the mechanisms are not operating as anticipated, return to the planning phase:
conduct fresh analysis and alter sanctions measures.
Currently the expertise and mechanisms required to conduct this analysis, planning and evaluation
simply do not exist within national governments or international organisations. Evidence suggests
that they often wrongly consider the mere imposition of sanctions as a foreign policy success. This
in turn suggests that they care less about the target state than their domestic constituents and
international standing. If policymakers are to avoid this conclusion and the associated implication
that they are merely instrumentalising foreign peoples for political ends they must develop the
capacity to think about sanctions more seriously and responsibly.
November 2015
Dr Lee Jones ([email protected]) is senior lecturer in international politics at Queen Mary,
University of London. For more information on his research, media activity and policy engagements,
see his website: http://www.leejones.tk. Societies Under Siege is available from Oxford University
Press at ukcatalogue.oup.com/product/9780198749325.do. Use code AAFLY7 at the checkout for a
30 percent discount.