To Build or Not To Build: Normative and Positive Theories of Public - Private Partnerships
To Build or Not To Build: Normative and Positive Theories of Public - Private Partnerships
com
University of Toulouse (IDEI, GREMAQ) and Institut Universitaire de France. Address: IDEI,
Manufacture des Tabacs, Bt. F, 21 Alle de Brienne, 31000 Toulouse, France
b
Ecole Polytechnique and University of Toulouse (IDEI). Address: Department of Economics,
Ecole Polytechnique, 91128 Palaiseau Cedex, France
Available online 5 December 2006
Abstract
This paper analyzes whether the two tasks of building infrastructures which are socially useful in providing public services and
managing these assets should be bundled or not. When performance contracts can be written, both tasks should be performed
altogether by the same firm if a better design of the infrastructure helps also to save on operating costs. Otherwise, tasks should be
kept apart and undertaken by different units. In incomplete contracting environments we isolate conditions under which either the
traditional form of public provision of services or the more fashionable publicprivate partnership emerges optimally. The latter
dominates when there is a positive externality and the private benefits from owning assets are small enough. Finally, we take a
political economy perspective and study how incentive schemes are modified under the threat of capture of the decision-makers.
Much of the gains from bundling may be lost in this case.
2006 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
JEL classification: H11
Keywords: Publicprivate partnership; Bundling/unbundling; Agency costs; Capture
1. Introduction
One of the most intriguing issues in modern industrial organization consists of delineating the optimal
0167-7187/$ - see front matter 2006 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.ijindorg.2006.10.004
394
395
396
14
16
e2
397
18
20
398
Because compensations are based on individual performances only, the externality between the two tasks does
not affect the agent's efforts. Of course, this externality
still plays a role because it affects the average cost and
thus how much profit is extracted from the operator
through the fixed-fee .
Assuming that the agents' profit has no weight in the
social welfare function, the local government induces
the agents to choose efforts {e1u, e2u} which are less than
their first-best values:
eu1
Sd
1
be and eu2
be :
1 rr2e 1
1 rr2g 2
399
4. General schemes
25
One can also adjust fixed-fees in each period to make this intertemporal contract robust to the possibility that the agent leaves the
relationship after having built the infrastructure.
26
Things are different in Section 5 below, where we model the
bargaining process between two separate units to jointly decide on
effort levels.
27
It is well-known that the second-best level of effort in a pure moral
hazard environment may not always be below its first-best level (see
Laffont and Martimort (2002, Chapter 5) for instance). However, the
lessons of the linear-CARA model la Holmstrm and Milgrom
(1987, 1991) capture the Folklore of the profession.
400
de1 r2e
;
r2g d2 r2e
This point is well-known from the collusion literature in multiagents environments. See Varian (1989) and Itoh (1993).
29
The consortium acts thus as a syndicate in the sense of Wilson
(1968).
a
a
and aB aO :
2
2
For a given incentive scheme offered by the government, optimal effort levels are thus still given by Eq.
(4). The consortium is efficient in the sense that it
perfectly internalizes the effort externality just like a
merger in Section 3. However, because the two firms
share risk equally, the aggregate risk-premium to be
paid to induce participation of such consortium is half
of what was paid in the case of the merger. Even when
there is no externality, a consortium strictly dominates
because it allows a better allocation of risk between
two otherwise identical risk-averse firms.
Proposition 3. There exists 0 N 0 such that an efficient
consortium dominates unbundling for N 0.
This result reinforces again our previous findings.
Certainly, bundling must be observed for a positive
externality. It also offers a justification for our earlier
assumption that a merger keeps the same degree of riskaversion as the agents. This assumption allows one in
fact to focus on the incentives benefits of bundling and
to disregard the issue of risk-sharing, which is another
advantage already well-known in the literature.31
6. Ownership and organizational forms
We have so far assumed that the perceived quality of
the infrastructure q was observable and verifiable and
could thus be used in any contract linking the
government and the builder. Let us now suppose that
this variable is itself non-verifiable. In this incomplete
contracting environment the only feasible way of
providing incentives consists of allocating ownership
rights of the assets to the builder. Of course, ex post,
30
401
402
The intuition behind this proposition is straightforward. When ownership by itself does not give enough
incentives to the builder to improve the quality of the
assets, bundling improves these incentives by making
the builder more eager to save also on operating costs.
Of course, for bundling to dominate, one wants to make
sure that ownership does not give too much incentive;
otherwise bundling would be suboptimal by worsening
an already suboptimal outcome.
When bundling dominates, one should note that
improving incentives on the first task requires also
pushing even further incentives on the second one.
Builder ownership also comes with cost reimbursement
rules which are closer to fixed-price contracts. Ownership and high-powered incentives go hand in hand.
37
403
404
1 rr2e 2
a g0 :
2
au g0 ; d au g0 ; d eu1 ;
12
p
1 1p
Dg0
au g0 ; d eu2 Nau g0 ; d
:
13
1 rr2g
p
Dg to maintain
m1p 0
1 rr2g 2
a g0
2
1 rr2e
ag0 dag0 2 :
2
Denoting the merged entity's information rent by
UBO g0 U BO g0 ; g0 , the relevant incentive compatibility and participation constraints are still Eqs. (10)
and (11). Both constraints are, again, binding at the
social optimum and, again, only the bonus (0) is used
to extract the costly information rent of the 0-operator.
14
ab g0 ; d eb1 Nab g0 ; dfdN0;
ab g0 ; d eb2 Nab
g0 ; d:
15
38
16
405
406
rr2e 2
a:
2
The builder's effort is thus given by Eq. (2). The fixedfee b chosen by the government extracts all the builder's
expected profit:
b
e21
rr2e 1:
2
A1
rr2g 2
a
2
A2
407
rS dr2g :
Taking into account the expression of these fixedfees, the local government optimizes under unbundling
the following expression of expected social welfare:
Pu :
e1 a
max
e1 ;e2 a2
W u e1 ; e2 ; duS de1
e2
e2
e2 1 1 rr2e 2 1 rr2g :
2
2
A3
rr2e 2 rr2g 2
a
a
2
2
where the effort levels are given by Eq. (4). The fixedfee B is then used by the principal to extract B O Vs
expected rent so that the government's problem can be
written as:
Pb :
W b e1 ; e2 ; duS de1
max
e1 ;e2 a2
e2 rr2
e2 1 e
e1 de2 2
e22
1 rr2g ;
2
A4
eb2
and
A5
r
e1 da V2 r2e a V2 r2g :
2
A7
(A7)
To better understand the comparison between organizational forms, it may be useful to optimize first over the
piece-rate parameter a and, from there, get an indirect
welfare function Wu(e1, e2, ) which depends only on
the effort variables (e1, e2). Doing so yields Eq. (6) and a
new expression of the principal's maximization problem
as:42
fu
max W e1 ; e2 ; d
e1 ;e2 a2
r
max b ae1 aVg0 e2 de1 we1 a2 r2e aV2 r2g :
2
S de1 e2
rr2e r2g
e21 e22 rr2g 2
e2
:
2 2
2
2r2g d2 r2e e21
A8
fu
fu
2W fu
2Wfu
2
We a l s o h a v e :
1 rr2 ,
2 1 rr ,
2
W
W
e 2
2 1 rrg2 ,
W e a l s o h a v e : e21e
e
2 1 rre ,
g
2 22
e
1
fu
fu
fu
fu
2
2
2
W
W
W
2W
0,
drr2e .
rd2 r2e r2g ,
0,
aV2
e1 e2
e2 aV
e1 aV
One can then check that the Hessian associated to the maximization
problem is negative semi-definite at the optimum.
42
42
408
r2e d2
rr2g
; eu2
1
:
1 rr2g
N0:
1 rr2e 1 rr2g
A.3. Proof of Proposition 3
J V maximizes the certainty equivalent of the
aggregate payoff of the firms subject to constraints aB
aO a and aB aO a which captures the fact that
the aggregate compensation risk is shared between these
firms. J V Vs problem can thus be written as:
max
rr2g
e2 e2 rr2
aaB 2 a2B :
1 2 e aaB 2 a2B
2 2
2
2
Because both firms have the same risk tolerance, they
share equally the risk of the aggregate compensation:
a
a
aB aO and aB aO :
2
2
For a given incentive scheme offered by the government,
optimal effort levels are thus the same as in Section 3:
e1 a da and e2 a:
The government's problem becomes thus:
max W c e1 ; e2 ; d
e1 ;e2 a2
e2 rr2
S de1 e2 1 e e1 de2 2
4
! 2
2
2
rr
e
g
2 1
:
2
2
rr2e
drr2
S d 2 e
2
rr2g
rr2
d2 rr2
1 2e 2 e
2
1
1
eb2G
1 dS d
:
1 rr2g d2
A9
(A9)
e21
f
b
;
Efe;f
exp
r
Pe
1
g
2
d
which is positive at eu2 when PVS d eu2 , i.e., P is small
2
enough.
rr2e 2 e21
P b;
2
2
S dP
e2
e22
2
P
1 rr2e
2
E f
f
e; g
We observe that:
WBb e2 ;
dWGb e2 ; d
1
2
P S dde2 1 rre P
2
b
when P is small enough.
which is positive at e2G
1 rr2g ;
We observe that:
e2
e2
g e2 de1 2
exp r Pe1 f
e 1 baf
;
2
2
WBu e2 ; dWGu e2 ; d S dP
which is negative when PN
Pe1
P2
e21
2
bag0 e2 de1
e22
2
rr2g
2
a2 ;
e b1af
g e2 de1 :
Efe;fg Ee1 f
1 rr2e 2
P
2
d2 e22
dPe2
dS de2
2
1 rr2e
Pde2
bP S d
2
b
A12
1 dS dP
:
1 rr2g d2
d
WBb e2 ; dWBu e2 ; d de2 S d e2 P
2
2S d
. Hence, government
1 rr2e
WBb e2 ; dWGu e2 ; d S dP
WBb e2 ; d S de1 e2
1rr2e 2
P
2
A13
409
fad;adg
1pW a g 0 ; a g 0 ; d:
u
410
fad;adg
g 0 ; a
g 0 ; d:
1pW b a
1 1p Dg0 1k u
f
g 0 ; d
Na g 0 ; d:
a u f
1 rr2g
p
A17
p
k1m
Dg0 1
1N
1p
m
which leads to
P
and:
p
S d1 rr2g d2 rr2e drr2e 1 1p
Dg0
1 rr2g 1 rr2e d2 rr2e
fdN0;
(A14)
ab g0; d eb2 Nab
g 0 ; d
P
p
1 rr2e 1 1p
Dg0 S ddrr2e
:
1 rr2g 1 rr2e d2 rr2e
A15
1 rr2g
dY0
Thus for small enough, we have b(0, ) b
u(0,
) and a contradiction. This is more likely as k increases.
For small enough, the optimum is achieved when
(0, ) =
u(0, ).
g0;
d Dg0 1pW b ab
g0;
d
a
b
g0;
d; ab
g0;
d;
dg
dab
d ; d
1mfpW u au g0; d ; au g0;
P
g 0 ; dDg0
a
u
g 0 ;
d ; au
g 0 ; d ;
d g
1pW u au
g0;
d au
g0;
dg:
k1mpDg0 maxf0; ab
A 16
b(0, ) and
u(0, ) under the threat of capture are
b
such that
(0, ) N u(0, ) so that there is a positive
stake of capture. Optimizing yields:
f
a b g 0 ;
d
p
S
d d rr2e
1 rr2e 1 1p
Dg0 1 k 1m
m
bab
g;
d;
1 rr2g 1 rr2e
d rr2e
411