The Multiplier Describes The Response of Output (GDP) To An Autonomous Change in Spending
The Multiplier Describes The Response of Output (GDP) To An Autonomous Change in Spending
The Multiplier Describes The Response of Output (GDP) To An Autonomous Change in Spending
The multiplier is the ratio of the final change in GDP to the initial change
in spending.
Mathematically, the multiplier is simply the ratio of the resulting
change in output to the initial change in spending. Using Y for out-
Liquidity-constrained. Describes a
household, business or other economic
unit that is spending less than it would
otherwise choose to because of a lack
of current access to cash or credit. This
is distinct from spending that is low
because of low income or wealth.
Y
A
(1)
Or equivalently,
Y = multiplier A
This second form is usually more relevant we normally use the
multiplier to predict or estimate the change in GDP resulting from a
given change in spending..
For example, suppose you think the multiplier is 2. Then if there
is an autonomous increase in spending of $ 100 billion (for example,
an increase in government spending, an increase in exports, or an
increase in investment), then you would expect GDP to increase by
$100 billion 2 = $200 billion.
Similarly, if we can observe or estimate the change in output that
results from a change in autonomous spending, we can calculate the
multiplier. For example, one study of the effects of 2009 stimulus
bill looked at how much federal health care spending had increased
in various states. They found that for each $2 million of additional
government spending, output in that state was about $3 million
higher. This implies a multiplier of 32 , or 1.5.
Equation 1 is the definition of the multiplier it is just what the
multiplier means.
Y = C + I + G + (X M)
Next we make some behavioral assumptions. First, we will take
government spending, exports and (for the moment) investment as
exogenous that is, fixed or determined outside the model. (To say
something is exogenous means that we are taking it as given our
model does not try to explain it. The variables a model does explain
are called endogenous. In this case, Y, C and M are endogenous.)
M = mY
The parameter m is the marginal propensity to import, or import
share. It represents the fraction of total spending that goes to imports.
For example, if m = 0.2, then 20 cents out of each new dollar spent
in the economy goes to imports, leaving the circular flow. So in this
case, if GDP increases by $50 billion, we would expect imports to
increase by $50 billion 0.2 = $10 billion. Notice that this equation
includes Y, not YD . Thats because imported goods may be used
for investment, government projects, or for exports, as well as for
consumption. So it makes sense to think of imports as a fraction of
total spending rather than a fraction of disposable income.
Next we substitute the equations for consumption, investment,
government spending, exports and imports back into the national
income identity:
Y = C + mpc YD + I + G + X mY = mpc(1 t)Y + I + G + X mY
Now we solve for Y:
Y mpc(1 t)Y + mY = C + I + G + X
Y=
1
(C + I + G + X )
1 mpc(1 t) + m
1
A
1 mpc(1 t) + m
(2)
1
A
1 mpc
1
mps+tmpst+m
1
A
mps + t mps t + m
(3)
For the US, a reasonable first guess for the multiplier might be around
1.5.
One reason to write the multiplier in terms of saving rather than
in terms of the marginal propensity to consume is that it makes it
clearer how the multiplier is connected to the circular flow of income.
Each of the terms in the denominator of Equation 3 corresponds to
a leakage out of the circular flow. Saving, paying taxes, and buying
imports are all alternatives to buying domestically produced goods;
they are all ways that income can be used that do not create income
for other households in the same country. So the greater the fraction
of income that is used in these ways, the fewer times a new dollar of
spending will circulate through the economy an the less additional
income it will create.
What we can see in Equation 3 is that the larger are the various
leakages, the smaller will be the multiplier. If savings, taxes and
imports are low, the multiplier will be large; if savings, taxes and
imports are high, the multiplier will be small. Its possible for the
multiplier to be less than one, but, in this simple model, it will always be positive. In other words, no matter how high are tax rates,
imports and saving, an increase in spending will always lead to some
increase in total output.
Lets fill in some plausible numbers for the US. Imports in the US
are about 15% of national income, but we know that the import share
reliably rises in booms and falls in recessions. In other words, the
marginal import propensity is higher than the average import propensity. Statistical evidence suggests that in the US, a 1% rise in income
typically leads to a 2% rise in imports. (In other words, the income
elasticity of imports seems to be around 2 in the US.) So a reasonable
value for m is around double the import share, or 0.3. Savings are
quite low in the US, and consumption responds strongly to current
income. In fact, some people will respond to an increase in income
by increasing their consumption by even more than the change in
income, implying a negative savings propensity. (This may happen
because a higher income makes it easier to borrow money, or because
some purchases, especially durable goods, are lumpy you have to
buy them all in one piece.) But overall, mps is certainly positive, especially since an important component of savings is retained earnings
corporate profits that are not paid out to shareholders. Overall,
mps = 0.2 is a reasonable first guess. Finally, federal taxes are around
15% of GDP, and state and local taxes are another 10%. Income taxes
of course vary with income. Some other taxes, like corporate profit
taxes, vary more than proportionately with income, while others, like
inheritance taxes, dont vary much with current income at all. Transfers also include payments that vary with income, like Medicaid and
unemployment benefits, and payments that dont vary with income,
including the two largest transfers, Medicare and Social Security.
Overall, a value of 0.2 seems reasonable for t as well.
Put these estimates together and we have:
Y = A(
1
1
) = A(
) A 1.5
0.3 + 0.2 + 0.2 0.04
0.66
And in fact, 1.5 is quite close to many recent econometric estimates of the multiplier based on historical data.