Concave Functions of Two Variables: X XX X
Concave Functions of Two Variables: X XX X
While we will not provide a proof here, the following three definitions are equivalent if the
function f is differentiable.1
Definition 1: Concave Function
The function f is concave on X
f ( x ) (1 ) f ( x0 ) f ( x1 )
f ( x1 ) f ( x 0 )
f 0 1 0
f 0 1
( x )( x1 x1 )
( x )( x2 x20 )
x1
x2
In the one variable case a function is concave if the derivative of the function is decreasing. We
can use this result and the following proposition to define a class of concave function in higher
dimensions.
Proposition 1: The sum of concave functions is concave
x ,
f1 ( x ) (1 ) f1 ( x0 ) f1 ( x1 ) and f 2 ( x ) (1 ) f 2 ( x0 ) f 2 ( x1 )
Define g ( x) f1 ( x) f 2 ( x) . You need to show that g ( x ) (1 ) g ( x0 ) g ( x1 ) .
C {x | U ( x) U ( x0 )}
Economists call this an indifference curve. The set of points that are preferred to x is called an
upper contour set.
CU {x | U ( x) U ( x)} .
Consider the figure below showing three contour sets of an increasing function. The upper
contour set is the shaded region.
Economists typically assume that upper contour sets are strictly convex. The following
result establishes that the is property holds for all convex function
Proposition 2: The upper contour sets of a concave function are convex
d
1
ln( x j )
. This is a decreasing
dx j
xj
Proposition 3: Sufficient condition for the upper contour sets of a function to be convex
Suppose that g () is a strictly increasing function and that h( x) g ( f ( x) is concave. Then the
upper contour sets of f are convex.
FOC
Proof: If f takes on its maximum at x 0 consider changes only in x j , j 1, 2 . This reduces the
problem to a one variable problem so we know that the FOC must hold.
f 0
f 0
(x )
(x ) 0 .
x1
x2
f 0 1 0
f 0 1
( x )( x1 x1 )
( x )( x2 x20 ) f ( x 0 )
x1
x2