SM
SM
SM
Management & Marketing Department, School of Business, University of Dayton, 300 College Park, Dayton, OH 45469, USA
Strategy and Global Management, Haskayne School of Business, University of Calgary, Calgary, Alberta, T2N 1N4, Canada
Universit Libre de Bruxelles Campus du Solbosch Avenue F.D. Roosevelt 42 B-1050 Brussels, Belgium
A R T I C L E
I N F O
Article history:
Received 14 May 2014
Accepted 24 March 2015
Available online
Associate editor: Sabina Siebert
Keywords:
Strategic management
Theory borrowing
Agency theory
Institutional theory
Transaction cost economics
A B S T R A C T
In many business schools, the eld of strategic management has been elevated to the same status as more
traditional subject areas such as nance, marketing and organizational behaviour. However, the eld is
rather unclearly delineated at present, as a result of the heavy usage of borrowed theories, a phenomenon we discuss in this article. For strategic management to become a legitimate subject area, truly at
par with the more conventional elds taught in business schools, we recommend much stronger selectivity when borrowing theories from other areas of scholarly inquiry than management, as the foundation
of empirical work. We propose a new model consisting of seven quality tests to assess whether proper
selectivity is being applied when importing concepts from other elds than management. Our perspective has major implications for both future, evidence-based strategic management research and for the
elds key stakeholders such as strategy teachers, practitioners and policy makers who rely on research outputs from strategy scholars.
2015 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
Introduction
Modern management research is struggling to combine effectively academic rigour and practitioner relevance. Chia (2014, p. 684)
has argued that a shift is necessary towards common sense scholarship so as to serve well the two above goals. Along the same lines,
Hernes (2014, p. 852) has suggested that scholars must cut loose
the shackles of misplaced scientic ideals and should instead focus
on, the localized, embedded, uid and contingent nature of managerial work.
In the present article, we propose an actionable approach that
should improve both the rigour and relevance of a particular organization and management subeld, namely that of strategic
management (SM), whereby we focus on the development and usage
of appropriate theory to guide research efforts. It has been suggested that: There is nothing so practical as a good theory (Lewin,
1951, p. 169). Van de Ven (1989, p. 486) extended this perspective
as follows: Good theory is practical precisely because it advances
knowledge in a scientic discipline, guides research towards crucial
questions, and enlightens the profession of management.
However, developing theory that is helpful to management is not
necessarily easy to achieve, and this is for at least two reasons. First,
what actually constitutes rigorous and relevant SM theory is debatable, but presumably it must have some type of predictive and
explanatory capacity that would support a broad area of practice.
A theorys predictive and explanatory power should hold across a
range of empirical phenomena in this area of practice, but such
generalizability may be dicult to establish. Indeed, knowledge creation efforts in SM seldom lead to generally accepted, cumulative
knowledge development, in contrast to what occurs in the hard sciences. Controlled experiments, accurately simulating/replicating
situational contexts from practice are often dicult if not
impossible to achieve, especially when addressing wicked management issues in the SM sphere (see below). Second, irrespective
of a high level of generalizability and cumulative knowledge development, SM theory can inform practice, but the transfer of
concepts and predictive templates from an academic setting to a
managerial environment is not necessarily easy to achieve. SM scholars may develop substantial insights on real world, managerial
phenomena, but few are the equivalent of, e.g., medical experts, who
combine academic research and clinical practice, whereby issues
arising in the latter area of work translate directly into identifying
critical questions and formulating testable hypotheses in the former.
In addition, few SM research outputs are read and used systematically by strategy practitioners. Only a fraction of SM research thus
combines a strong predictive and explanatory capacity, and usefulness as perceived by practitioners, because of the absence of
systematized back-and-forth between research and practice.
The scientic discipline of SM addresses the establishment and
pursuit of a rms long-term goals, as well as the ways in which
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.emj.2015.03.007
0263-2373/ 2015 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
Please cite this article in press as: Thomas P. Kenworthy, Alain Verbeke, The future of strategic management research: Assessing the quality of theory borrowing, European Management Journal (2015), doi: 10.1016/j.emj.2015.03.007
ARTICLE IN PRESS
2
business leaders or managers respond to and shape environmental forces, and orchestrate internal resources. Here, SM theorizing
can be important, to the extent that it allows for better prediction
and explanation of SM choices in clearly specied situational contexts. As a result, the SM practice becomes more intellectualized:
it can be understood not only by being actually engaged in it (learning by doing), but also through the mediating and framing force
of conceptual ideas (Kiechel, 2010).
SM theorizing can be important not only for purposes of immediate applicability in management practice, but also for business
school teaching because it transcends all functional areas of management, and addresses directly the rms long term survival,
protability and growth. However, as noted above, in addition to
the need for some level of predictive and explanatory power, and
for generalizability, effective interaction between scientic research and clinical practice in SM is a major challenge, especially
because of the wickedness of many SM problems, characterized
by discontinuous change, high technical and social complexity, management biases and conicts among multiple stakeholders that are
dicult to resolve (McMillan & Overall, 2015).
Given the above context, we address one specic question in the
present article that we consider critical to supporting the dual objectives of rigour and relevance: should SM scholars engaged in
empirical research, restrict themselves to testing (and possibly extending) eld-specic theories, or is there value in borrowing theories
from other elds of academic inquiry, as the basis of hypothesis formulation and testing? Recently, Oswick, Fleming, and Hanlon (2011)
assessed whether theory borrowing is commonplace in the broader
organization and management theory (OMT) research. They dened
theory borrowing as, the importation of coherent and fully formed
ideas that explain a phenomenon (or phenomena) into OMT from
outside the discipline (p. 319). Oswick et al. (2011) found that approximately two-thirds of OMT research is driven by theories
borrowed from other disciplines. The research revealed theory borrowing from relatively closely related elds such as sociology,
psychology and economics, but also from less proximate elds such
as biology, education, engineering, history, law, linguistics, mathematics, philosophy, and politics. Oswick et al. (2011, p. 328) voiced
serious concerns about the observed imbalance between eldspecic and borrowed theories. One key concern was that the
original nuance of borrowed theories, well understood when used
in their base eld, was in danger of being sacriced when applied
in an OMT context.
Other scholars have echoed such concerns. For example, Suddaby,
Hardy, and Nguyen Huy (2011, p. 237) argue that OMT:
has somewhat awkwardly imported theories, research questions, and methods from foreign disciplines without fully adapting
them to the new context. Rather than treating organizations as
a subject of inquiry in their own right, management theorists
appear to have treated organizations merely as new empirical
sites to test, prove, and tweak old theories.
In the OMT eld, the heavy borrowing practice has come at the
expense of indigenous theory development. Here, Markczy and
Deeds (2009, p. 1079) insist that OMT:
needs to build theories based on our unique position and understanding of management and organizational phenomena
rather than co-opting the theories of economics, psychology or
sociology or even of nance, accounting and marketing.
However, the potential benets of theory borrowing have also
been acknowledged:
organization theory is always empowered primarily by
methods and perspectives from the wider social sciences. Predominantly, it is informed by theories and methods from
anthropology, economics, psychology, and (especially) sociology. Thus, for many scholars, notions such as indigenous theorizing
in organization theory are anathema to the everyday reality of
research practice. (Hassard, Wolfram Cox, & Rowlinson, 2013,
p. 310).
What may therefore ultimately be more important than purity
in indigenous development is that SM scholars would follow an appropriate selection process when contemplating the borrowing of
theories, and would refrain from borrowing those theories that do
not meet a set of straightforward selection criteria (Ferraro, Pfeffer,
& Sutton, 2005).
The early years of SM research1, with SM being a scholarly subeld of OMT, were characterized by a small number of research
outlets publishing predominantly case-based analysis (Hoskisson,
Hitt, Wan, & Yiu, 1999). Today, the SM discipline claims several dedicated journals (Azar & Brock, 2008), and a host of other outlets
regularly publish SM research (e.g., Academy of Management Journal
AMJ, Academy of Management Review AMR, Administrative Science
Quarterly ASQ, Journal of Management JoM, and Journal of Management Studies JMS). The cumulative output of these research
efforts has elicited a variety of comments about the scientic status
and progress of the discipline. Some researchers have reported signicant progress (e.g. Hoskisson et al., 1999), whereas others have
voiced substantive concerns (e.g., Ghoshal, 2005; Jarzabkowski &
Whittington, 2008).
As noted above, our main focus in the present paper is the extent
to which the most frequently tested theories in SM research are indigenous, as opposed to borrowed from other elds.2 A theory can
be dened as:
a collection of assertions, both verbal and symbolic, that identies what variables are important for what reasons, specically
how they are interrelated and why, and identies the conditions under which they should be related or not related.
(Campbell, 1990, p. 65)
As we will demonstrate below, our investigation revealed substantial theory borrowing in SM prompting the development of a
screening model to permit proper selectivity in such borrowing. We
hope that the model (and possible future extensions thereof) will
serve the SM eld in terms of improving both the rigour and relevance of its empirical work. First, the model allows for an ongoing
open door policy to good theory from other elds (Hassard et al.,
2013). Second, it provides a reasoned defence to protect the indigenous body of rigorous and relevant SM theories against invasion
by theories from other elds that bring no value added at best and
negative value added at worst to the SM eld (Markczy & Deeds,
2009; Suddaby et al., 2011).
Explicit theory-driven research in strategic management
In order to examine the nature and extent of theory usage in SM,
we chose to limit our scope with respect to time period and content.
With respect to time period, we began our analysis in 1980 for two
reasons. First, SM arguably became a legitimate academic discipline around 1980 (Azar & Brock, 2008). Second, the long, but
manageable time frame allowed us to capture various trends and
mitigate the inuence of journal editorial policies on the ndings.
With regard to content, we limited our analysis to articles published in seven (out of a set of fteen) dedicated SM journals (Azar
1
Nag, Hambrick, and Chen (2007) provide insight into how the SM eld may be
dened.
2 This question has also been raised in other elds, such as retailing (Brown & Dant,
2009) and purchasing and supply chain management (Chicksand, Watson, Walker,
Radnor, & Johnston, 2012).
Please cite this article in press as: Thomas P. Kenworthy, Alain Verbeke, The future of strategic management research: Assessing the quality of theory borrowing, European Management Journal (2015), doi: 10.1016/j.emj.2015.03.007
ARTICLE IN PRESS
T.P. Kenworthy, A. Verbeke/European Management Journal (2015)
Table 1
Article counts by journal.
Journals
SMJ
JEMS
TASM
LRP
SO
BSE
JBS
Total
Total articles
Total empirical articles
Total theory-driven articles
Theory driven density
1643
1242
382
30.8%
495
145
27
18.6%
604
256
11
4.3%
1703
490
13
2.7%
130
65
25
38.5%
464
254
23
9.1%
278
160
27
16.9%
5317
2612
508
19.4%
Percentage
25.00%
20.00%
15.00%
10.00%
0.00%
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
5.00%
Year
& Brock, 2008) in order to avoid problems associated with identifying relevant articles in more broadly-focused, management
journals. The following seven dedicated SM journals the highest
ranked ones (Azar & Brock, 2008) were included for review: Strategic Management Journal (SMJ, 19802009); Journal of Economics
& Management Strategy (JEMS, 19922009); Technology Analysis &
Strategic Management (TASM, 19892009); Long Range Planning (LRP,
19802009); Strategic Organization (SO, 20032009); Business Strategy & the Environment (BSE, 19922009); and Journal of Business
Strategies (JBS, 19842009).
Identifying articles that made explicit use of theory involved three
key criteria. The rst criterion was that the article had to be empirical in nature utilizing a research method involving observation
and/or experimentation, rather than simulation or pure conceptualization. The second criterion was that the article had to include
at least one predictive hypothesis prior to a discussion of research
method(s). For the most part, research hypotheses were readily identied, often set apart and labelled as, for example, H1. In some cases,
the research hypotheses were formulated more implicitly, as part
of the main text. Such articles were only included in our study if
the related text claried the predictive nature of the statement in
question. The third criterion involved the explicit mentioning of a
theory used in the article. The task of identifying theories (at times,
more than one theory per article) was relatively easy and unambiguous for the most part. We did not attempt to assess whether
hypotheses were correctly derived from the theories utilized,
nor the extent to which the hypotheses were supported, since such
concerns had supposedly been addressed during the reviewing
process.
Finally, each theory that was mentioned explicitly was categorized in terms of its origins. In keeping with Oswick et al. (2011, p.
321), our assessment, of whether or not a given theory is borrowed is determined by whether or not the main proponent(s) is
(are) either located within the [SM] academic community or outside
of it (OMT replaced by SM). The total number of peer-reviewed articles for the seven SM journals was 5317. The total number of
empirical articles was 2612, as shown in Table 1.
3 In addition to those ten theories, another 184 theories were tested: 138 theories were tested only once; 21 theories twice; 15 theories three times; 2 theories
four times; 3 theories ve times; 1 theory seven times; one theory 8 times; 2 theories nine times; 1 theory ten times.
Please cite this article in press as: Thomas P. Kenworthy, Alain Verbeke, The future of strategic management research: Assessing the quality of theory borrowing, European Management Journal (2015), doi: 10.1016/j.emj.2015.03.007
ARTICLE IN PRESS
T.P. Kenworthy, A. Verbeke/European Management Journal (2015)
Table 2
Theories used in empirical research in strategic management journals (alphabetical order).
Absorptive capacity theory
Active investor hypothesis
Agency theory
Asymmetric theory
Asymmetric theory of joint ventures
Attractionselectionattrition framework
Attribution theory
Barriers to entry theory
Bases of social power
Behavioural agency theory
Behavioural decision theory
Behavioural theory of the rm
Belief systems theory
Career concern hypothesis
Cartel theory
Centre of gravity theory
Cluster theory
Collective action theory
Commitment theory
Competing values framework
Conguration theory
Congruence model of organizational behaviour
Conservative model of innovation
Contestable markets theory
Contextual interaction theory
Contingency theory
Control theory
Cooperative game theory of the rm
Corporate portfolio theory
Cultural dimensions theory
Cultural familiarity theory
Decision usefulness theory of accounting
Density-dependent theory of organizational evolution
Digestibility theory of joint ventures
Dual core model of organizational innovation
Dynamic capabilities perspective
Dynamic Multi-dimensional Performance framework
Economic theory of complementarities
Ecient market theory
Embeddedness perspective
Environmental scanning theory
Equity theory
Ethical decision making theory
Evolutionary theory
Expectancy Theory
External signals theory of regulation
Five forces model
Free cash ow hypothesis
Full range leadership perspective
Galbraith and Nathansons organization
diversication theory
Game theory
Gender socialization theory
Generic strategies theory
Goal theory
Human capital theory
Information integration theory
Information processing theory
Neo-institutional theory
Intergroup theory
Internalization theory
International structural stages model
Jungian theory of psychological type
Knowledge-based theory of the rm
Legitimacy theory
Life course theory
Life-cycle theory
Locus of control theory
Long-purse theory of predation
Loose coupling theory
Management control theory
Managerial discretion theory
Managerial entrenchment hypothesis/Managerial
hegemony theory/Managerial opportunism theory
Managerial succession theory
Managerial welfare hypothesis
Market orientation theory
Mental accounting framework
Merger contingency theory
Mobility barriers theory
Modern portfolio theory
Modernization theory
Modular systems theory
Motivating language theory
Multiple point competition model
Mutual forbearance hypothesis (theory)
Myopic institutions theory
Natural capital theory
Natural resource based view
Network theory
Niche development theory
Niche formation theory
Niche width theory
Optimal contracting theory
Option-pricing model of wage determination
Organizational imprinting theory
Organizational learning theory
Organizational types theory
Path dependence theory
Pecking order theory
Performance-feedback model
Personal construct theory
Politicaleconomical theory
Population ecology theory
Power dependence theory
Price discrimination theory
Procedural justice theory
Property rights theory of the rm
Prosocial behaviour theory
Prospect theory
Psychological contract theory
Real options theory
Reference group theory
Regulatory inuence theory
Relational exchange theory
Relational view
Relative absorptive capacity theory
Renegotiation theory of predation
Reputation theory of predation
Resource based view
Resource based view of diversication
Resource dependence theory
Resource partitioning model
Resource-based theory of market structure and
organizational form
Risk theory
Ritual scapegoating theory
Role-motivation theory of managerial effectiveness
Routine based perspective
Selection hypothesis
Shareholder interest hypothesis
Shareholder wealth-maximization hypothesis
Signal detection theory
Signalling theory
Situational theory
Social capital theory
Social choice theory
Social exchange theory
Social information processing theory
Social movements theory
Social network theory
Stages model of internationalization
Stages of growth theory
Stakeholder identication and salience
Stakeholder theory
Stewardship theory
Strategic balance theory
Strategic behaviour theory
Strategic choice and environmental determinism
framework
Strategic choice theory
Strategic factor market theory
Strategic issue diagnosis model
Strategic network perspective
Strategic positioning framework
Structural equivalence theory
Structural holes theory
Structural Inertia theory
Structure-conduct-performance theory
Symmetric Learning theory
Technological lock-in theory
Technology adoption model
Theory of competitive behaviour
Theory of competitive rationality
Theory of complex organization
Theory of Core competencies
Theory of heterogeneity
Theory of hypercompetition
Theory of interrm performance differences
Theory of internal labour markets
Theory of multipoint competition
Theory of network incentives
Theory of optimal money burning
Theory of planned behaviour
Theory of private benets
Theory of product diversity
Theory of reasoned action
Theory of reasoned risk taking
Theory of recombinant invention
Theory of relative standing
Theory of retail market structure
Theory of strategic groups
Theory of strategic information systems planning
Theory of the equilibrium structure of a competitive
industry with multiproduct rms
Theory of the market for corporate control
Theory of the multinational corporation
Theory of total quality management
Theory of weak ties
Theory of yardstick competition
Token status theory
Tournament theory
Transaction cost economics
Transformational leadership theory
Uncertainty reduction theory
Upper echelon theory
Value-added hypothesis
Value-based planning theory
Vicious circle theory
Five of the top ten theories, which account for 202 instances of
explicit theory testing originated at least partly from within the discipline of management, with some of the key substantive
contributions to contemporary theory originating from within the
SM eld itself. These ve theories can be considered indigenous
Please cite this article in press as: Thomas P. Kenworthy, Alain Verbeke, The future of strategic management research: Assessing the quality of theory borrowing, European Management Journal (2015), doi: 10.1016/j.emj.2015.03.007
ARTICLE IN PRESS
T.P. Kenworthy, A. Verbeke/European Management Journal (2015)
Theory
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
Number of Times Used
80
90
theories, even if some foundational elements may have been developed in another discipline: transaction cost economics (e.g., in
the realm of studying diversication, selecting governance modes,
and transferring knowledge), the resource based view, upper echelon
theory, contingency theory and stakeholder theory. As regards transaction cost economics, it could (correctly) be argued that this theory
was rst created in the economics discipline (Coase, 1937;
Williamson, 1975) rather than in management, but a number of SM
thinkers of the past fty years have provided intellectual value added
that has signicantly extended the theory in substantive terms,
whether directly or indirectly. These scholars include, inter alia, Alfred
Chandler (e.g., Chandler, 1962), Jean-Franois Hennart (e.g., Hennart,
1988), Alan Rugman (e.g., Rugman & Verbeke, 2003), Harbir Singh
(e.g., Dyer & Singh, 1998), David Teece (e.g., Teece, 1986), Alain
Verbeke (e.g., Nordberg & Verbeke, 1999), and so on. Following
Williamson (1991), a number of scholars have even argued that
adopting a transaction cost economizing logic can amount to strategy optimization (see, e.g., Nickerson & Zenger, 2004; Verbeke &
Kenworthy, 2008).
The economics discipline accounted for two theories in the top
ten: agency theory and signalling theory. These two theories represent 89 instances of explicit theory testing. The sociology discipline
accounted for three of the ten theories: institutional theory, resource dependence theory and social capital theory. It should be
noted that the second and third theories also have roots in the political science discipline. These three theories account for 53 instances
of explicit theory testing. Overall, the theories originating at least
partly from within the SM discipline account for 59% of explicit
theory usage amongst the top ten theories, with economics and sociology representing 41%. In other words, amongst the top ten
explicitly-used theories, the ratio of indigenous theory to borrowed theory usage instances is 1.42 (202 to 142).
In addition to identifying the frequency of testing the most commonly named theories, it is also useful to explore the disciplinary
origins of all 194 theories included in Table 2, irrespective of frequency of use; see Table 3. Here, the testing of indigenous theories,
i.e., theories derived directly from SM research, represents only 37%
of total explicit theory testing. The elds of economics, psychology and sociology represent approximately 27%, 14% and 13% of used
theories, respectively.
The share of indigenous theory use, representing 59% of testing
among the top ten most frequently used theories, and approximately
Table 3
Disciplinary origins of explicitly tested theories.
Field
Total theories
% of total
Strategic management
Economics
Psychology
Sociology
Biology
Marketing
Communication
Finance
Information systems
Accounting
Cybernetics
Innovation
International business
Law
Public policy
72
52
27
25
3
3
2
2
2
1
1
1
1
1
1
37.11
26.80
13.92
12.89
1.55
1.55
1.03
1.03
1.03
0.52
0.52
0.52
0.52
0.52
0.52
Please cite this article in press as: Thomas P. Kenworthy, Alain Verbeke, The future of strategic management research: Assessing the quality of theory borrowing, European Management Journal (2015), doi: 10.1016/j.emj.2015.03.007
ARTICLE IN PRESS
T.P. Kenworthy, A. Verbeke/European Management Journal (2015)
Table 4
Seven tests to assess the quality of theory borrowing.
Borrowed theorys contributions to its own base discipline
Predictive power
Explanatory power
Absence of strong
competing theories
Does the borrowed theory consistently demonstrate statistically signicant, predictive power in its base discipline?
Does the borrowed theory have practical predictive signicance in its base discipline?
Does the borrowed theory possess substantial explanatory power in its base discipline (that is, how much of the disciplines
phenomena can it explain)?
Are there strong rival theories (providing alternative explanations) in the base discipline?
Are the key phenomena and problems studied reasonably similar in the borrowed theory discipline and the borrower discipline?
Are the key issues central to the borrowed theory also salient within the borrower discipline?
Are the key concepts used in the borrowed theory consistent with and meaningful in the borrower discipline?
Are the key underlying assumptions in the borrowed theory consistent with the underlying assumptions in the borrower discipline?
Is there extant evidence in the borrower discipline to support (or refute) the key propositions of the borrowed theory?
Is there extant evidence in the borrower discipline to support (or refute) the peripheral propositions and logical inferences of the
borrowed theory?
Is there extant theoretical support for the salience of the borrowed theory within the borrower discipline?
4 This does not preclude the use of theories from other elds, assuming that adapting them to SM does not compromise the original integrity of theories (Suddaby et al.,
2011).
Please cite this article in press as: Thomas P. Kenworthy, Alain Verbeke, The future of strategic management research: Assessing the quality of theory borrowing, European Management Journal (2015), doi: 10.1016/j.emj.2015.03.007
ARTICLE IN PRESS
T.P. Kenworthy, A. Verbeke/European Management Journal (2015)
Table 5
Strength of the borrowed theory in the base discipline.
Theory
Review studies
Quality test 1:
Predictive power
Agency theory
Weakness
(Neo-)institutional theory
Perrow (1985)
Perrow (1986)
Powell (1991)
Fligstein (1991)
Tolbert and Zucker (1994)
Tolbert and Zucker (1996)
Selznick (1996)
Barley and Tolbert (1997)
Hirsch and Lounsbury (1997)
Lewin et al. (2004)
Donaldson (2006)
meaning that the imported concepts are not only novel but also
useful (Mayer, 1999), and thus represent more than merely an original act whereby borrowing novel concepts would actually not be
useful.
The sixth quality test for a borrower discipline is to compare the
underlying assumptions in the borrowed theory, with the generallyagreed-upon assumptions in the borrower discipline. As Amundson
(1998) suggests, applying this test may not be easy, because a borrowed theorys underlying assumptions may be viewed as selfevident in the base discipline, and may therefore not be clearly and
fully communicated in any of the canonical literature describing the
theory. However, Amundson (1998, p. 354, brackets added) views
this quality test as critical, since:
The examination of underlying assumptions for t will be a long,
slow, iterative process, but will ultimately lead to greater insights and improved research skills. Because this is an important
long term issue, [borrower eld] researchers simply should do
as well as they can at this, learning along the way from inevitable mistakes and errors.
Finally, the seventh quality test involves the in-depth search for
extant scholarly work in the borrower discipline that addresses the
legitimacy of the borrowed theory. More specically, if prior published evidence strongly rejects the key propositions or predictions
of the borrowed theory, whether explicitly or implicitly, there should
be little reason to pursue this theory further.
For purposes of illustration, we will now apply the above model,
consisting of 7 quality tests, to two theories borrowed from other
elds of scientic inquiry and applied regularly by SM scholars. These
two theories, namely agency theory and institutional theory, also
feature prominently in many inuential SM textbooks taught in business schools. Here, we highlight concerns raised in scholarly analysis
about these borrowed theories. We present the two dimensions of
the quality-testing model, namely the strength of the borrowed
theory in its base discipline (quality tests 13) and the applicability of the theory in the borrower discipline (quality tests 47), see
Tables 5 and 6. The references in these tables mainly consist of
popular review and critique articles, spanning a number of decades,
which means that the challenges identied are not new. We do not
intend to be exhaustive in terms of criticism voiced, but we simply
wish to illustrate how the proposed quality tests could be applied.
Quality test 2:
Explanatory power
Quality test 3:
Competing theories
Weakness
Weakness
Weakness
Weakness
Weakness
Weakness
Weakness
Weakness
Weakness
Weakness
Weakness
Weakness
Weakness
Weakness
Weakness
Weakness
Weakness
Weakness
Weakness
Weakness
Weakness
Table 5 above illustrates that several scholars have voiced concerns regarding the quality of both agency and institutional theory,
as used in their own base discipline and when applied in another
one. The following two sections briey discuss the main concerns.
Quality testing of borrowed theory in base discipline
Agency theory (AT)
AT purports to describe and prevent/solve conicts between principals (e.g., shareholders) and their agents (e.g., managers). ATs
predictive power (quality test 1) in the context of compensation has
been called into question by economists Jensen and Murphy (1990,
p. 243): Our task is made dicult by the fact that the theory offers
few sharp predictions regarding the form of the contract other than
predicting that wages generally increase with observed output. These
scholars nd that their empirical results are:
inconsistent with the implications of formal agency models
of optimal contracting. The empirical relation between the pay
of top-level executives and rm performance, while positive and
statistically signicant, is small for an occupation in which incentive pay is expected to play an important role. (Jensen &
Murphy, 1990. p. 227)
A number of economists have also challenged ATs explanatory
power5 (quality test 2). A substantive concern is the extent to which
the theory accurately characterizes human behaviour. A fundamental assumption of AT is the strong-form, self-interest-seeking nature
of human beings. This strong form, self-interest-seeking assumption is conducive to mathematical modelling. However, the validity
of the assumption, as well as the generalizability of inferences
derived from using the assumption in theory-testing applications,
has been questioned by, among others, Becker (1976) and Sen (1987).
On this issue, Akerlof (1983, p. 54) states: this assumption is made
for reasons of convenience, not because economists empirically
assume that all persons act only out of selshness. However,
Sen (1987, p. 16, brackets in original) adds in this context: To try
to use the demands of rationality in going to battle on behalf of the
5
ATs predictive and explanatory powers have also been critically assessed by management scholar Sumantra Ghoshal (2005).
Please cite this article in press as: Thomas P. Kenworthy, Alain Verbeke, The future of strategic management research: Assessing the quality of theory borrowing, European Management Journal (2015), doi: 10.1016/j.emj.2015.03.007
ARTICLE IN PRESS
8
6 NITs predictive and explanatory powers have been called into question by a
number of scholars who are not neo-institutional scientists, namely economists and
management scholars (e.g., Chakravarti, 2012; Davis, 2010; Kraatz & Zajac, 1996).
Please cite this article in press as: Thomas P. Kenworthy, Alain Verbeke, The future of strategic management research: Assessing the quality of theory borrowing, European Management Journal (2015), doi: 10.1016/j.emj.2015.03.007
ARTICLE IN PRESS
T.P. Kenworthy, A. Verbeke/European Management Journal (2015)
Table 6
The applicability of borrowed theory in the adopting discipline.
Theory
Review studies
Quality test 4:
Issue match
Agency theory
Ghoshal (2005)
Donaldson (1995)
Davis et al. (1997)
Lubatkin et al. (2001)
Fontrodona and Sison (2006)
Daily et al. (2003)
Ghoshal (2005)
Bruce et al. (2005)
Weakness
Weakness
(Neo-)institutional theory
Quality test 5:
Consistent concepts
Quality test 6:
Assumptions match
Quality test 7:
Knowledge t
Weakness
Weakness
Weakness
Weakness
Weakness
Weakness
Weakness
Weakness
Weakness
Weakness
Weakness
Weakness
Weakness
characteristics of MNCs limit the applicability of neoinstitutionalism to these organizations. Although subject to
institutional forces, MNCs have a very different institutional story
that better ts the conditions of equivocality, ambiguity, and
complexity.
The extent to which the assumptions in NIT are consistent with
those in the eld of management (quality test 6) has been widely
debated. For example, NIT assumes the persistence and homogeneity of institutions. However, Dacin, Goodstein, and Scott (2002,
p. 45) nd that:
institutions change over time, are not uniformly taken-for
granted, have effects that are particularistic, and are challenged as well as hotly contested. Thus, we acknowledge that
although institutions serve both to powerfully drive change and
to shape the nature of change across levels and contexts, they
also themselves change in character and potency over time.
NIT also assumes a subjective/relativistic perspective, but Bresser
and Millonig (2003, p. 221) argue that such perspective conicts
with the functionalist lens used by SM scholars.
The nal test included in the model (quality test 7), addresses
knowledge t. Donaldson (1995, p. 127) expresses concern over the
theoretical support for NIT in management, e.g., because empirical research in management does not support NITs focus on the
importance of myths and symbols. Hambrick, Finkelstein, Cho, and
Jackson (2005, p. 343) voice specic concerns about the salience and
generalizability of isomorphism. Based on a historical analysis of
American industries during the 20th century, the authors nd that
a managerially relevant theory must acknowledge and incorporate in its primary iteration that isomorphic pressures sometimes
weaken, thereby fostering heterogeneity among organizations.
Again, NIT appears to fare better than agency theory in the sense
that pressures for homogeneity appear to be consistent with at least
some empirical observations in the management sphere. However,
NIT still exhibits an incomplete understanding of the rm-level quest
for heterogeneity and uniqueness, and the related relative intensity of pressures for homogeneity versus heterogeneity over time,
and the impact thereof on managerial behaviour (see, e.g., Verbeke
& Tung, 2013). Business rms typically do not exist to serve the exigencies of legitimacy, but to achieve survival, protability and growth
through creating value.
Conclusions
The historical roots and the evolution of the SM discipline have
been widely studied. The present paper contributes to this body of
Please cite this article in press as: Thomas P. Kenworthy, Alain Verbeke, The future of strategic management research: Assessing the quality of theory borrowing, European Management Journal (2015), doi: 10.1016/j.emj.2015.03.007
ARTICLE IN PRESS
10
purposive decision-making and action in a context of imperfect information and limited information processing capacity (Gigerenzer
& Selten, 2002). The importance of BRat as a behavioural driver is
not just its plausibility vis--vis the practice of management, but
the fact that it has been measured and used in numerous empirical studies with substantial explanatory and predictive power.
Reecting on the micro-foundations adopted explicitly or implicitly in candidates for theory borrowing, and assessing these
foundations consistency with some notion of BRat, would provide
not only a partial answer to a number of quality tests, but would
likely also create a valuable bridge for facilitating subsequent knowledge transfer to and application in real world managerial settings.
Can a second micro-foundation be identied that would, similar
to BRat, transcend all seven quality tests for theory borrowing, and
facilitate ultimate usability in managerial settings? Neither variations of unbounded self-interest seeking, nor variations of trust
would appear appropriate candidates. The former do not respect
the simple observation that most organizational functioning, and
especially strategy formation, appears to serve organizational goals,
with self-interest seeking being a constraint, not the heart or soul
of purposive action by the organization (Verbeke, 2003). The latter
do not recognize that trust, and the vulnerabilities created because
of it, can easily be detrimental to organizations, and negatively affect
their chances of survival, protability and growth, which are critical especially in strategy formation (Verbeke & Greidanus, 2009).
The concept of bounded reliability (BRel) would appear more promising, meaning that scarcity of mind would be complemented by
scarcity of making good on open ended promises, much of it triggered by benevolent preference reversal, an often observed
phenomenon in managerial practice (Kano & Verbeke, 2014; Verbeke
& Kenworthy, 2008).
By focusing especially on the need for plausible micro-foundations
when applying the seven quality tests proposed in the present paper,
a promising pathway is opened for theory borrowing that will ultimately serve managerial relevance, and therefore the elds key
stakeholders such as strategy teachers, practitioners and policy
makers.
References
Aigen, K. (2005) Music-Centered Music Therapy. Barcelona, Gilsum, NH.
Akerlof, G. (1983) Loyalty lters. The American Economic Review 73(1), 5463.
Alvesson, M., & Sandberg, J. (2013) Constructing Research Questions: Doing Interesting
Research. SAGE Publications, London.
Amundson, S. D. (1998) Relationships between theory-driven empirical research in
operations management and other disciplines. Journal of Operations Management
16(4), 341359.
Arrow, K. (1985) The economics of agency. In J. Pratt & R. Zeckhauser (Eds.), Principal
and Agents: The Structure of Business (pp. 3751). Harvard Business School Press,
Boston.
Azar, O. H., & Brock, D. M. (2008) A citation-based ranking of strategic management
journals. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy 17(3), 781802.
Barley, S. R., & Tolbert, P. S. (1997) Institutionalization and structuration: Studying
the links between action and institution. Organization Studies 18(1), 93118.
Becker, G. S. (1976) Altruism, egoism, and genetic tness: Economics and sociobiology.
Journal of Economic Literature 14(3), 817826.
Berle, A. A., & Means, G. C. (1932) The Modern Corporation and Private Property.
Macmillan, New York.
Blaug, M. (1976) The empirical status of human capital theory: A slightly jaundiced
view. Journal of Economic Literature 14(3), 827855.
Boxenbaum, E., & Rouleau, L. (2011) New knowledge products as bricolage: Metaphors
and scripts in organizational theory. Academy of Management Review 36(2),
272296.
Bresser, R. K. F., & Millonig, K. (2003) Institutional capital: Competitive advantage
in light of the new institutionalism in organization theory. Schmalenbach Business
Review 55(3), 220241.
Brown, J. R., & Dant, R. P. (2009) The theoretical domains of retailing research:
A retrospective. Journal of Retailing 85(2), 113128.
Bruce, A., Buck, T., & Main, B. (2005) Top executive remuneration: A view from Europe.
Journal of Management Studies 42(7), 14931506.
Campbell, J. P. (1990) The role of theory in industrial and organizational psychology.
In M. D. Dunnette & L. M. Hough (Eds.), Handbook of Industrial and Organizational
Psychology 1 (2nd ed., pp. 3974). Consulting Psychologists Press, Palo Alto, CA.
Please cite this article in press as: Thomas P. Kenworthy, Alain Verbeke, The future of strategic management research: Assessing the quality of theory borrowing, European Management Journal (2015), doi: 10.1016/j.emj.2015.03.007
ARTICLE IN PRESS
T.P. Kenworthy, A. Verbeke/European Management Journal (2015)
Chakravarti, A. (2012) Institutions, Economic Performance and the Visible Hand: Theory
and Evidence. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham.
Chandler, A. D. (1962) Strategy and Structure: Chapters in the History of American
Industrial Enterprise. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.
Chia, R. (2014) Reections on the distinctiveness of European management
scholarship. European Management Journal 32(5), 683688.
Chicksand, D., Watson, G., Walker, H., Radnor, Z., & Johnston, R. (2012) Theoretical
perspectives in purchasing and supply chain management: An analysis of the
literature. Supply Chain Management: An International Journal 17(4), 454472.
Coase, R. H. (1937) The nature of the rm. Economica 4(16), 386405.
Cornforth, C. (2003) The changing context of governance Emerging issues and
paradoxes. In C. Cornforth (Ed.), The Governance of Public and Non-Prot
Organizations: What Do Boards Do? (pp. 120). Routledge, London.
Dacin, M. T., Goodstein, J., & Scott, W. R. (2002) Institutional theory and institutional
change: Introduction to the special research forum. The Academy of Management
Journal 45(1), 4356.
Daily, C., Dalton, D., & Cannella, A., Jr. (2003) Corporate governance: Decades of
dialogue & data. Academy of Management Review 28(3), 371382.
Davis, G. F. (2010) Do theories of organizations progress? Organizational Research
Methods 13(4), 690709.
Davis, J. H., Schoorman, F. D., & Donaldson, L. (1997) Toward a stewardship theory
of management. Academy of Management Review 22(1), 2047.
Donaldson, J., & Davis, P. (1990) Business ethics? Yes, But what can it do for the bottom
line? Management Decision 28(6), 2933.
Donaldson, L. (1995) American Anti-Management Theories of Organization: A Critique
of Paradigm Proliferation. Cambridge University Press, New York.
Donaldson, L. (2006) The contingency theory of organizational design: challenges
and opportunities. In M. Burton, B. Eriksen, D. D. Hakonsson, & C. C. Snow (Eds.),
Organization Design: The Evolving State-of-the-Art (pp. 1940). Springer, New York.
Doucouliagos, C. (1994) A note on the evolution of homo economicus. Journal of
Economic Issues 28(3), 877883.
Dyer, J., & Singh, H. (1998) The relational view: Cooperative strategies and sources
of interorganizational competitive advantage. Academy of Management Review
23(4), 660679.
Ferraro, F., Pfeffer, J., & Sutton, R. I. (2005) Economics language and assumptions:
How theories can become self-fullling. Academy of Management Review 30(1),
824.
Fligstein, N. (1991) The structural transformation of American industry: an
institutional account of the causes of diversication in the largest rms,
19191979. In W. W. Powell & P. J. DiMaggio (Eds.), The New Institutionalism in
Organizational Analysis (pp. 311336). University of Chicago Press, Chicago.
Floyd, S. W. (2009) Borrowing theory: What does this mean and when does it make
sense in management scholarship? Journal of Management Studies 46(6), 1057
1058.
Fontrodona, J., & Sison, A. J. G. (2006) The nature of the rm, agency theory and
shareholder theory: A critique from philosophical anthropology. Journal of
Business Ethics 66(1), 3342.
Ghoshal, S. (2005) Bad management theories are destroying good management
practices. Academy of Management Learning and Education 4(1), 7591.
Gigerenzer, G., & Selten, R. (Eds.), (2002) Bounded Rationality: The Adaptive Toolbox.
MIT Press, New Haven, CT.
Green, D. P., & Shapiro, I. (1994) Pathologies of Rational Choice Theory: A Critique of
Applications in Political Science. Yale University Press, Cambridge, MA.
Hambrick, D. (2007) The eld of managements devotion to theory: Too much of a
good thing? Academy of Management Journal 50(6), 13461352.
Hambrick, D. C., Finkelstein, S., Cho, T. S., & Jackson, E. M. (2005) Isomorphism in
reverse: Institutional theory as an explanation for recent increases in intraindustry
heterogeneity and managerial discretion. Research in Organizational Behavior 26,
307350.
Hassard, J., Wolfram Cox, J., & Rowlinson, M. (2013) Dialogue: Where are the old
theories of organization? Prospects for retrospection in organization theory.
Academy of Management Review 38(2), 309313.
Hennart, J. F. (1988) A transaction costs theory of equity joint ventures. Strategic
Management Journal 9(4), 361374.
Hernes, T. (2014) In search of a soul of relevance for European management research.
European Management Journal 32(6), 852857.
Hirsch, P. M., & Lounsbury, M. (1997) Ending the family quarrel: Towards a
reconciliation of old and new institutionalism. American Behavioral Scientist
40(4), 406418.
Hoskisson, R. E., Hitt, M. A., Wan, W. P., & Yiu, D. (1999) Theory and research in
strategic management: Swings of a pendulum. Journal of Management 25(3),
417456.
Ilgen, D. R., & Klein, H. J. (1989) Organizational behavior. Annual Review of Psychology
40, 327351.
Jarzabkowski, P., & Whittington, R. (2008) Directions for a troubled discipline: Strategy
research, teaching and practice. Journal of Management Inquiry 17(4), 266268.
Jensen, M. C., & Murphy, K. J. (1990) Performance pay and top management incentives.
Journal of Political Economy 98(2), 225264.
Johnson Lutjens, L. R., & Tiffany, C. R. (1994) Evaluating planned change theories.
Nursing Management 25(3), 5457.
Kano, L., & Verbeke, A. (2014). Uncovering Alfred Chandlers hidden contribution to
strategic management theory: The multiple facets of bounded reliability. Paper
presented at the annual meeting of the Strategic Management Society,
Copenhagen, Denmark.
Kiechel, W. (2010) The Lords of Strategy: The Secret Intellectual History of the New
Corporate World. Harvard Business Press, Boston.
11
Kostova, T., Roth, K., & Dacin, T. (2008) Institutional theory in the study of
multinational corporations: A critique and new directions. Academy of
Management Review 33(4), 9941006.
Kotowitz, Y. (1987) Moral hazard. In J. Eatwell, M. Milgate, & P. Newman (Eds.), The
New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics (pp. 549551). Macmillan, London.
Kraatz, M. S., & Zajac, E. J. (1996) Exploring the limits of new institutionalism: The
causes and consequences of illegitimate organizational change. American
Sociological Review 61(5), 812836.
Lan, L. L., & Heracleous, L. (2010) Rethinking agency theory: The view from law.
Academy of Management Review 35(2), 294314.
Lawrence, T. B., Suddaby, R., & Leca, B. (Eds.), (2009) Institutional Work: Actors and
Agency in Institutional Studies of Organizations. Cambridge University Press,
Cambridge, UK.
Lewin, A. Y., Weigelt, C. B., & Emery, J. D. (2004) Adaptation and selection in strategy
and change: perspectives on strategic change in organizations. In M. S. Poole &
A. H. Van de Ven (Eds.), Handbook of Organizational Change and Innovation
(pp. 108160). Oxford University Press, New York.
Lewin, K. (1951) D. Cartwright (Ed.), Field Theory in Social Science: Selected Theoretical
Papers. Harper & Row, New York.
Lubatkin, M. H., Lane, P. J., & Schulze, W. S. (2001) A strategic management model
of agency relationships in rm governance. In M. A. Hitt, R. E. Freeman, & J. S.
Harrison (Eds.), Handbook of Strategic Management (pp. 229258). Blackwell,
Oxford.
Malmi, T., & Granlund, M. (2009) In search of management accounting theory.
European Accounting Review 18(3), 597620.
Markczy, L., & Deeds, D. L. (2009) Theory building at the intersection: Recipe
for impact or road to nowhere? Journal of Management Studies 46(6), 1076
1088.
Mayer, R. E. (1999) Fifty years of creativity research. In R. J. Sternberg (Ed.), Handbook
of Creativity (pp. 449460). Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK.
McMillan, C., & Overall, J. (2015) Wicked problems and the misalignment of strategic
management design. Journal of Business Strategy forthcoming.
Merton, R. K. (1973) Social conict over styles of sociological work. In R. K. Merton
(Ed.), The Sociology of Science: The Theoretical and Empirical Investigations
(pp. 4769). University of Chicago Press, Chicago.
Murray, J. B., & Evers, D. J. (1989) Theory borrowing and reectivity in interdisciplinary
elds. Advances in Consumer Research 16(1), 647652.
Nag, R., Hambrick, D. C., & Chen, M.-J. (2007) What is strategic management, really?
Inductive derivation of a consensus denition of the eld. Strategic Management
Journal 28(9), 935955.
Nickerson, J., & Zenger, T. (2004) A knowledge-based theory of the rm: The
problem-solving perspective. Organization Science 15(6), 617632.
Nordberg, M., & Verbeke, A. (1999) The Strategic Management of High Technology
Contracts. Pergamon, New York.
Oswick, C., Fleming, P., & Hanlon, G. (2011) From borrowing to blending: Rethinking
the processes of organizational theory building. Academy of Management Review
36(2), 318337.
Perrow, C. (1985) Review essay: Overboard with myth and symbols. American Journal
of Sociology 91(1), 151155.
Perrow, C. (1986) Complex Organizations: A Critical Essay. Random House, New York.
Pfeffer, J. (1995) Mortality, reproducibility, and the persistence of styles of theory.
Organization Science 6(6), 681686.
Popper, K. (1963) Conjectures and Refutations. Harper, New York.
Powell, W. W. (1991) Expanding the scope of institutional analysis. In W. W. Powell
& P. J. DiMaggio (Eds.), The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis
(pp. 183203). University of Chicago Press, Chicago.
Rugman, A. M., & Verbeke, A. (2003) Extending the theory of the multinational
enterprise: Internalization and strategic management perspectives. Journal of
International Business Studies 34(2), 125137.
Salancik, G. R. (1995) Wanted: A good network theory of organization. Administrative
Science Quarterly 40(2), 345349.
Salanie, B. (1997) The Economics of Contracts, a Primer. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.
Selznick, P. (1996) Institutionalism old and new. Administrative Science Quarterly
41(2), 270277.
Sen, A. K. (1987) On Ethics and Economics. Blackwell, Oxford.
Solow, R. M. (1995) But verify. The New Republic 213(September), 3639.
Suddaby, R., Hardy, C., & Nguyen Huy, Q. (2011) Where are the new theories of
organization? Academy of Management Review 36(2), 236246.
Teece, D. J. (1986) Transaction cost economics and the multinational enterprise:
An assessment. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 7(1), 2145.
Tolbert, P., & Zucker, L. (1994) Institutional analyses of organizations: Legitimate
but not institutionalized. ISSR Working Papers in the Social Sciences 6(5), 1
46.
Tolbert, P., & Zucker, L. (1996) The institutionalization of institutional theory.
In S. Clegg, C. Hardy, & W. Nord (Eds.), Handbook of Organization Studies
(pp. 175190). Sage Publications, London.
Truex, D., Holmstrm, J., & Keil, M. (2006) Theorizing in information systems research:
A reexive analysis of the adaptation of theory in information systems research.
Journal of the Association for Information Systems 7(12), 797821.
Van de Ven, A. H. (1989) Nothing is quite so practical as a good theory. Academy of
Management Review 14(4), 486489.
Van Essen, M., Otten, J. A., & Carberry, E. J. (2012) Assessing managerial power theory:
A meta-analytic approach to understanding the determinants of CEO
compensation. Journal of Management 38(3), 396423.
Verbeke, A. (2003) The evolutionary view of the MNE and the future of internalization
theory. Journal of International Business Studies 34(6), 498504.
Please cite this article in press as: Thomas P. Kenworthy, Alain Verbeke, The future of strategic management research: Assessing the quality of theory borrowing, European Management Journal (2015), doi: 10.1016/j.emj.2015.03.007
ARTICLE IN PRESS
12
Verbeke, A., & Greidanus, N. S. (2009) The end of the opportunism vs trust debate:
Bounded reliability as a new envelope concept in research on MNE governance.
Journal of International Business Studies 40(9), 14711495.
Verbeke, A., & Kenworthy, T. P. (2008) Multidivisional versus metanational governance
of the multinational enterprise. Journal of International Business Studies 39(2),
940956.
Verbeke, A., & Tung, V. (2013) The future of stakeholder management theory: A
temporal perspective. Journal of Business Ethics 112(3), 529543.
Please cite this article in press as: Thomas P. Kenworthy, Alain Verbeke, The future of strategic management research: Assessing the quality of theory borrowing, European Management Journal (2015), doi: 10.1016/j.emj.2015.03.007