CIGI Debt Restructuring

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 28

CIGI PAPERS

NO. 64 APRIL 2015

SOVEREIGN DEBT RESTRUCTURING


ISSUES PAPER
SKYLAR BROOKS AND DOMENICO LOMBARDI

SOVEREIGN DEBT RESTRUCTURING:


ISSUES PAPER
Skylar Brooks and Domenico Lombardi

Copyright 2015 by the Centre for International Governance Innovation


The opinions expressed in this publication are those of the authors and do not
necessarily reflect the views of the Centre for International Governance Innovation
or its Board of Directors.

This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution Non-commercial


No Derivatives License. To view this license, visit (www.creativecommons.org/
licenses/by-nc-nd/3.0/). For re-use or distribution, please include this copyright
notice.

67 Erb Street West


Waterloo, Ontario N2L 6C2
Canada
tel +1 519 885 2444 fax +1 519 885 5450
www.cigionline.org

TABLE OF CONTENTS
iv About the Authors
iv Acronyms
1 Foreword
1

Executive Summary

Sovereign Debt Restructuring: The Basics

Whats New About Sovereign Debt Restructuring?

Reforming the International Debt Architecture: For and Against

What Types of Reform Are Needed?

12 New Proposals for Sovereign Debt Reform


16 Conclusion
16 Works Cited
20 About CIGI
20 CIGI Masthead

CIGI Papers no. 64 April 2015

ACRONYMS
ABOUT THE AUTHORS

Skylar Brooks is a research associate in CIGIs


Global Economy Program and a Ph.D. student at
the Balsillie School of International Affairs.

Domenico Lombardi is director of CIGIs Global


Economy Program, overseeing the research
direction of the program and related activities, a
member of the Financial Times Forum of Economists
and editor of the World Economics Journal.

iv CENTRE FOR INTERNATIONAL GOVERNANCE INNOVATION

CACs

collective action clauses

CETA

Comprehensive Economic and Trade


Agreement

CSOs

civil society organizations

DSA

debt sustainability analyses

ESDRM

European Sovereign Debt Restructuring


Mechanism

ESDRR

European Sovereign Debt Restructuring


Regime

ESM

European Stability Mechanism

Eurodad European Network on Debt and Development


HIPC

Heavily Indebted Poor Country

ICMA

International Capital Markets Association

IIAS

international investment agreements

IMF

International Monetary Fund

MDRI

Multilateral Debt Relief Initiative

SDAF

Sovereign Debt Adjustment Facility

SDF

Sovereign Debt Forum

SDRM

Sovereign Debt Restructuring Mechanism

SDT

sovereign debt tribunal

Sovereign Debt Restructuring: Issues Paper

FOREWORD
This paper is part of the Global Consultations on Sovereign
Debt, an initiative launched by the Centre for International
Governance Innovation (CIGI) and coordinated by the
New Rules for Global Finance Coalition. The consultations
seek to identify the full spectrum of proposals and ideas for
addressing sovereign debt crises, and organize these ideas
in a way that moves the debate forward. To do so, they
bring together and galvanize input from a diverse group
of stakeholders around the world, including academics,
civil society groups, government officials, lawyers and
legal experts, international organizations, practitioners,
think tanks and others.
Participation in the consultations is organized around
webinar discussions, video conferences, workshops,
meetings and submissions of written comments. This
issues paper extensively revised following the public
feedback received on an earlier draft aims to provide a
framework for the unfolding of the global consultations.
As part of its broader global engagement, CIGI has also
co-hosted a series of regional workshops on sovereign
debt restructuring (first in China, then Africa and next in
Latin America) to take stock of regional experiences and
perspectives. Once the consultations are concluded later
in 2015, CIGI will release a report that synthesizes the
contributions from these various stakeholders in a way
that can engage with and inform mainstream debates on
sovereign debt restructuring.

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
This paper provides an overview of the main issues,
debates and policy proposals that surround sovereign
debt restructuring. The first section outlines the basics of
sovereign debt restructuring, including what it is, how it is
done and when it has occurred. The second section reviews
the recent events and developments that have motivated
current discussions over how to better manage sovereign
defaults and debt restructurings. These developments and
the challenges they pose stem largely from the euro-zone
debt crisis and the recent litigation against Argentina. In
light of these challenges, the third section outlines the
major arguments for and against creating new institutional
arrangements to facilitate timely, orderly and fair sovereign
debt restructurings. The main arguments against reform
are that the current arrangements work relatively well
all things considered and that reforming the system
would encourage debtor moral hazard, which would in
turn raise sovereign borrowing costs and leave all parties
worse off. The arguments for reform reject this view, and
claim that creditor moral hazard, deadweight losses and
distributional inequity are current problems that justify
reform. Taking the case for reform, section four asks what
types of reforms are needed, and reviews three broad
approaches to sovereign debt restructuring: contractual,

statutory and arbitration. Section five provides an


overview of some of the more specific proposals that have
recently been put forward for sovereign debt reform.
These include: increasing the role of debt reprofiling in
certain circumstances; introducing state-contingent debt
such as GDP-linked bonds; creating a Sovereign Debt
Forum (SDF) to facilitate debtor-creditor cooperation and
preserve best practices; strengthening collective action
clauses (CACs); immunizing payments systems from
third-party interference; establishing a Sovereign Debt
Adjustment Facility (SDAF) in the International Monetary
Fund (IMF); and building a European Sovereign Debt
Restructuring Mechanism (ESDRM). The final sections
conclude and suggest a few topics for further discussion.

SOVEREIGN DEBT RESTRUCTURING:


THE BASICS
Sovereign debt restructuring is an exchange of
outstanding government debt, such as bonds or loans,
for new debt products or cash through a legal process
(Das, Papaioannou and Trebesch 2012). To constitute a
debt restructuring, one or both of the two following types
of exchange must take place: debt rescheduling, which
involves extending contractual payments into the future
and, possibly, lowering interest rates on those payments;
and debt reduction, which involves reducing the nominal
value of outstanding debt. Restructurings often occur
after a default, but it is also possible to conduct an early
debt restructuring that pre-empts default. In addition to
economic variables, the type, timing and terms of a debt
exchange are largely determined by negotiations between
the sovereign debtor and its creditors.
Sovereign defaults and debt restructurings have been
fairly commonplace since the early nineteenth century.
New data show that since 1950 alone there have been
over 600 individual cases of sovereign debt restructuring
worldwide (ibid.). Not surprisingly, the majority of
sovereign debt crises are clustered around major boombust cycles in international capital flows. Scholars have
identified nine distinct lending booms since the early
nineteenth century (Sturzenegger and Zettelmeyer 2006;
Reinhart and Rogoff 2009). All of these booms inevitably
ended in busts, during which some sovereign borrowers
were forced to default and/or restructure their debts.
In the past, sovereign debt has typically been restructured
through one or more of the following four channels: the
Paris Club (an informal group of creditor governments);
multilateral financial institutions (namely the IMF
and World Bank); the London Club (private creditor
committees); and exchange offers (in the case of dispersed

Skylar Brooks and Domenico Lombardi 1

CIGI Papers no. 64 April 2015


bondholders).1 Each channel deals with a different form of
debt. The Paris Club deals with bilateral loans from creditor
governments to debtor governments; the IMF, World Bank
and other institutions have provided multilateral debt
relief to some of their poorest member states; the London
Club deals with loans from banks to debtor governments;
and exchange offers target government bonds that are
held by a wide range of market actors. Sovereign bonds
have been the predominate form of debt affected in almost
all of the major waves of default, including in the post2008 period. Only during the defaults of the 1980s were
bank loans more important than bonds (Sturzenegger and
Zettelmeyer 2006).
More recently, the outbreak of the euro-zone crisis,
combined with the legal saga surrounding Argentinas
debt obligations, has sparked a lively debate on how
best to prevent and manage large-scale sovereign debt
crises, including, of course, defaults and restructurings.
The starting point for this debate is the recognition that
sovereign defaults and debt restructurings are often
messy, painful and unpredictable. A few basic questions
follow: Are sovereign debt restructurings too costly? Can
we reform the international debt architecture in a way
that makes sovereign defaults and debt restructurings less
likely to occur? Can we reform the architecture to ensure
that, when they do occur, sovereign debt restructurings are
handled in a more timely, orderly and fair manner? What
are the associated costs and benefits of doing so?

WHATS NEW ABOUT SOVEREIGN DEBT


RESTRUCTURING?
Although sovereign defaults and debt restructurings are
centuries old, the nature of these phenomena continues
to change, bringing a number of new aspects of sovereign
debt to the forefront of discussion and debate. Indeed, a
series of recent economic and legal developments in Europe
and the United States have reanimated the sovereign debt
debate last opened up after the 2001 Argentine default
and made sovereign debt restructuring a priority issue
on the IMFs agenda and one of the most talked about
issues in economic policy-making circles more generally.
All of this has, in turn, prompted a rethink of how best to
govern sovereign debt restructuring.

The Euro-zone Crisis and the Economic


Dimension of Sovereign Debt Restructuring
The euro-zone crisis kicked-off in 2009 when the newly
elected Greek government, led by then Prime Minister
George Papandreou, revealed that the reported fiscal

An exchange offer occurs when a sovereign bond issuer (who is in or


near default and seeking to restructure its debt) offers its bondholders
the opportunity to exchange their current bonds for new bonds or
financial instruments with different terms.

2 CENTRE FOR INTERNATIONAL GOVERNANCE INNOVATION

deficit of 6.5 percent of GDP was actually double that.


Unsurprisingly, Greeces borrowing costs spiked and its
bonds were downgraded, compounding the underlying
debt problem by causing the economy to contract and the
level of debt-to-GDP to rise.2
Before long, trouble started to spread to other economies
in the euro zones periphery. Governments in Portugal,
Ireland, Spain and Italy saw borrowing costs rise as
investors began to sell what now appeared to be risky
sovereign bonds to cover the losses incurred on their
Greek debt holdings. At the time, the IMF, in concert with
the European Commission and the European Central Bank
(the so-called Troika of official creditors), acted to stave
off a deeper and wider financial collapse in Greece and the
rest of the euro zone.
It was clear that Greece would need a lot of money and a lot
of help, but according to the exceptional access lending
criteria, the IMF could only lend to Greece if there was a
high probability of the countrys debt being sustainable
over the medium term. The problem was that there was
not. Still, the IMF wanted to help resolve the crisis and
was under mounting pressure from its powerful European
members to get involved.
Normally, a country like Greece (whose debt could not
be declared sustainable with high probability) would be
required to restructure its debt before it could access largescale IMF resources. But when faced with the prospect of
spillover effects from Greece and the heightened potential
for debt defaults and restructurings to trigger contagion in
a tightly linked economic and monetary union, the Fund
decided to offer Greece a more traditional bailout and
avoid restructuring.3
To enable the Fund to lend to Greece in the absence of a
restructuring, the IMF executive board approved in 2010
an amendment to the exceptional access framework,
allowing the debt sustainability criteria to be waived in
cases where there is a high risk of international systemic
spillover effects (IMF 2010, 20; see also Schadler 2013).

For an overview of the euro-zone crisis, and the role of Greece within
it, see Blyth (2013, chapter 2).

3 The euro-zone crisis highlighted the heightened potential for debt


defaults and restructurings to trigger large-scale systemic spillovers,
in particular in a currency union. This systemic risk is amplified by
the fact that sovereign bonds are increasingly integral to the global
financial system, which is highly integrated and prone to dominolike collapses (Schwarcz 2011). Since advanced economies bonds
have been considered risk-free assets, financial markets were able to
hold massive amounts of these bonds without having to set aside
sufficient capital to offset potential losses. During the euro-zone crisis,
the exposure of large, undercapitalized and overleveraged banks to
sovereign bonds meant that default and/or debt restructuring could
trigger a systemic crisis in European and global financial markets
(Blyth 2013).

Sovereign Debt Restructuring: Issues Paper


Unfortunately, the combination of external support and
internal adjustment provided by the IMF bailout failed to
put Greeces public debt on a sustainable footing; in fact,
its economy and debt position continued to deteriorate.
In 2012, the inevitable could no longer be postponed:
Greece underwent the largest sovereign default and debt
restructuring in history (surpassing Argentinas historic
2001 default).
Even though it achieved very large debt relief more
than 50 percent of 2012 GDP the restructuring was
not enough to restore growth and debt sustainability. In
retrospect, the Fund admitted that the Greek restructuring
was too little, too late (IMF 2013). If a sufficiently deep
debt restructuring had been required at the beginning of
the crisis, as the Funds pre-2010 lending rules specified,
Greeces return to economic health could have been much
sooner and stronger. The Fund also conceded that its
lending framework, even before the 2010 amendment, was
not optimally designed to deal with cases where there is
considerable uncertainty regarding the sustainability of a
countrys public debt.
Aside from failing to restore growth and debt sustainability,
the Greek debt restructuring was plagued by holdout
creditors i.e., creditors who refuse to participate in an
otherwise widely accepted debt restructuring and instead
litigate against the sovereign to recover the full face value
of the original bonds plus interest.4 While the Greek
restructuring enjoyed a high rate of participation among
bondholders (97 percent), those who refused to participate
were successful in recovering their investments in full,
which only strengthens the incentive for others to hold out
from future deals (see Buchheit, Gulati and Tirado 2013a;
Xafa 2014).
Partly in response to that, since January 1, 2013, all
new euro-zone sovereign bonds have been required to
include CACs, which are designed to facilitate creditor
coordination in the event of default and prevent holdouts.
But evidence on the actual effectiveness of CACs is mixed.
Moreover, CACs do nothing to address the too little, too
late problem a problem that many now consider more
challenging than holdout creditors (see IMF 2013).
Looking forward, as the influential economists Carmen
M. Reinhart and Kenneth S. Rogoff (2013) point out,
underlying debt dynamics suggest that in the coming years
more sovereign debt restructurings will prove necessary in

4 Sometimes holdout creditors have held the bonds they refuse to


restructure from the beginning; other times, they buy the bonds on
secondary markets for pennies on the dollar after default had already
taken place and then sue for full repayment of the original value of
the bond plus accrued interest.

the euro zones periphery.5 Other advanced economies do


not look much better, for that matter, as central government
debt across the developed world reaches a 200-year high
point (ibid.). So, while the Greek episode was in many
ways unique (Xafa 2014), it highlighted the contemporary
relevance of large-scale sovereign debt crises and the
challenges of resolving them. A broader message from the
euro-zone crisis is thus clear: sovereign debt crises, which
now affect relatively rich societies,6 are not going away any
time soon, nor are they getting any easier to handle. This
realization has sparked serious discussion and debate,
both inside and beyond the Funds walls, about how best
to prevent and manage such crises going forward.

The Argentina Case and the Legal Dimension


of Sovereign Debt Restructuring
Since the outbreak of the euro-zone crisis, sovereign
debt restructuring has become a hotly debated topic
in international scholarly and policy circles. Interest
increased further because of the recent legal battle between
Argentinas central government and a small group of
holdout creditors, led by New York-based hedge fund
Elliot Management, which refused to participate in either
of the countrys post-2001 restructurings. Since Argentinas
bonds were issued under New York law, they are subject
to the rulings of New York and higher US courts. In June
2014, the Supreme Court of the United States had the final
word in the dispute, denying Argentinas request that the
Supreme Court overrule the decision of the lower court in
favour of the holdouts.
The New York State judge based his decision on a peculiar
interpretation of the pari passu (equal treatment) clause
contained in Argentinas original bond contract. He ruled
that Argentina could not make payments to the 93 percent
of creditors who accepted restructured claims in 2005 or
2010 unless it also paid the holdouts the full face value of

5 For some countries in the euro zones periphery, and to a lesser


extent for developed countries more generally, current economic
outlooks suggest that the normal ways in which governments
reduce their debt may not provide sufficient relief to restore debt
sustainability. First, growth prospects in Europe and Japan appear
too weak for these economies to grow their way out of debt. Second,
fiscal adjustment (i.e., austerity) is growth depressing at worst and
insufficient to meaningfully reduce debt-to-GDP ratios in a lowgrowth environment at best. It is also difficult to implement because
it is so deeply unpopular (Mody 2013). Third, in the euro zone,
exchange rate and monetary policies are not available tools to assist
with national debt reduction. As a result of these challenges, many
governments may be forced to resort to sovereign debt restructuring
(Reinhart and Rogoff 2013).
6 The euro-zone crisis showed that, contrary to conventional wisdom,
advanced economies are not immune to severe sovereign debt crises.
Further, crises in advanced economies can pose larger systemic risks
than those in emerging and developing economies.

Skylar Brooks and Domenico Lombardi 3

CIGI Papers no. 64 April 2015


the bonds plus interest.7 If Argentina were to comply with
the judges ruling so far, it has not it would have to
pay roughly US$15 billion to holders of defaulted bonds,
a potentially devastating blow to its already depleted
foreign currency reserves (Devereux and Van Voris 2014).
The problem with the courts decision, beyond the severe
financial strain it puts on Argentina, is that it sets a legal
precedent under New York law the law governing a
large portion of sovereign bonds that threatens to make
it more difficult for all countries in the future seeking to
restructure their debt held in the form of bonds (Frankel
2014). By ruling that Argentinas holdout creditors, most
of whom bought their bonds on secondary markets after
default and at a deep discount, must be repaid in full if
anyone is to be repaid at all, the courts decision has
rewarded recalcitrant creditors referred to pejoratively
as vulture funds and punished cooperative ones,
thus creating a perverse incentive for all creditors to
hold out from future restructurings. The holdouts claim
they tried to strike a fair deal with Argentina on several
occasions but were ignored and offered only harsh takeit-or-leave-it bond exchanges. However, given the lack
of transparency in creditor-borrower negotiations, claims
made by both Argentina and holdout creditors are difficult
to substantiate. Still, as both Jos Antonio Ocampo (2014a)
and Joseph Stiglitz and Martin Guzman (2014) point out,
granting the holdouts full repayment via legal mandate
is questionable. Since the risk of default is already priced
into the bond vis--vis the interest rate or premium,
lenders should not be able to charge high risk premiums
and use legal mechanisms to enforce full repayment. Here,
the legal mechanism overrides the need for the market
mechanism for restructuring debt, and vice versa. The two
cannot co-exist. If there were a legal mechanism to enforce
full repayment, the risk of default and the premiums
charged to previously risky sovereign borrowers would
be low. In the absence of such a legal mechanism, markets
will continue to deal with the risk of default through the
market mechanism of risk premiums.
To say that Argentina is a uniquely recalcitrant debtor is
certainly not a fringe view. But in setting legal precedent
under New York law the law governing a large portion
of sovereign bonds the courts decision creates a
perverse incentive for all creditors to hold out from future
restructurings, essentially making them almost impossible
to achieve.

7 It is important to note that historically there has been no standard or


boiler plate pari passu clause, and that the language used in Argentinas
1994 Fiscal Agency Agreement was unique i.e., different from
almost all other pari passu clauses in sovereign bond contracts. The
point is that the judges interpretation of Argentinas pari passu clause
cannot necessarily be considered novel or unconventional, since there
is no standard version, and thus no standard legal interpretation, of
such clauses. (For making this point clear, the authors thank David
Spencer of the Tax Justice Network.)

4 CENTRE FOR INTERNATIONAL GOVERNANCE INNOVATION

As a recent IMF staff paper (2014b, 31-32) put it, by


allowing holdouts to interrupt the flow of payments to
creditors who have participated in the restructuring,
the decisions would likely discourage creditors from
participating in a voluntary restructuring, and by
offering holdouts a mechanism to extract recovery outside
a voluntary debt exchange, the decisions would increase
the risk that holdouts will multiply and creditors who are
otherwise inclined to agree to a restructuring may be less
likely to do so due to inter-creditor equity concerns." As
The Economist (2013) commented, strict adherence to the
pari passu clause would make restructuring sovereign
debt sold in New York impossible, since no one could be
paid without 100% participation in a swap. Clearly, then,
the decision has potentially made restructurings much
harder to agree to, let alone enforce.

Issues for Discussion


What new lessons on sovereign debt restructuring
has the euro-zone crisis offered? How can these
lessons help prevent or manage future crises?
What are the main challenges that arise from the
Argentina litigation? How might states and markets
respond to these challenges?
What types of legal contracts should govern sovereign
debt obligations? What types of provisions might
they include?

REFORMING THE INTERNATIONAL DEBT


ARCHITECTURE: FOR AND AGAINST
Against
The case for a new and/or improved approach to sovereign
debt restructuring rests on the assumption that the current
decentralized, market-based approach is deficient. But not
all observers share this assumption. Indeed, some contend
that the prevailing ad hoc approach has a remarkably
strong track record of success. Hung Tran, executive
managing director of the Institute of International Finance,
argues that all of the ad hoc bond restructurings (of which
there have been 34) since the first bond exchange of modern
times have worked reasonably well, with the exception of
Argentina in the 2000s (Tran 2014).8 On average, he notes,
restructurings were consummated within 10 months of the
announcement of a restructuring, within seven months of
starting negotiations and with high levels of participation
(95 percent). From this perspective, the current approach

For Tran, the first modern restructuring is Mongolia in 1997. Jo Marie


Griesgraber notes that Tran does not consider the cases of Zambia
and Greece.

Sovereign Debt Restructuring: Issues Paper


is successful and obviates the need for any substantive
reform of the international debt architecture.9
Advocates of the ad hoc approach also maintain that in
order to preserve well-functioning international debt
markets, sovereign bond contracts should be honoured.
When, for unavoidable reasons, contracts have to be
changed, there should be a process whereby the change
in contract is accepted by both sides of the contractual
agreement (Tran 2014). Although Tran (2014) admits that
the prevailing market-based approach is not perfect,
he contends that it should not be perfect, for breaking
contracts should not be made easy to do. The rationale
behind this view is not simply that breaking contracts is
wrong, but rather that failing to honour debt contracts
distorts incentives and would lead to more, not fewer,
sovereign debt crises.
Another argument against reform is that making sovereign
debt easier and less costly to restructure will encourage
imprudent borrowing by sovereign debtors, who will no
longer have the threat of a costly and painful restructuring
to deter them from borrowing more than they are able or
willing to repay. According to this view, sovereign defaults
and debt restructurings are supposed to be costly; if they
are made less costly, they will occur more frequently.
And if they occur more frequently, investors will be
increasingly reluctant to lend to sovereign debtors, raising
their external borrowing costs and making it harder for
developing and emerging market economies to finance
their development needs (Rieffel 2003; Tran 2014). In other
words, this argument posits that making sovereign debt
restructuring less costly will make international sovereign
borrowing more expensive.

For
The counter-argument to that view is that even if it
becomes easier or less costly to default or restructure,
countries will continue to face strong incentives not to,
including the incentive to avoid higher future borrowing
costs (Sturzenegger and Zettelmeyer 2007; Borensztein
and Panizza 2008). Another incentive for sovereigns to
repay their debt stems from the fear of losing access to
international capital markets. As Ugo Panizza, Federico
Sturzenegger and Jeromin Zettelmeyer (2009, 662)
document, a number of studies illustrate that the threat
of exclusion from future borrowing is sufficient to sustain
sovereign lending (see also Amador 2003; Eaton and
Gersovitz 1981). They note, however, that, according to the
evidence, fear of being barred from capital markets cannot
9 It should be noted that many apparently successful debt
restructurings are insufficient to restore debt sustainability and are
therefore followed by repeat defaults. In a review of distressed debt
exchanges, Moodys (2012, 1) reports that Thirty-seven percent
of the 30 sovereign distressed exchanges were followed by further
default events. (For this point the authors thank Bernhard G. Gunter
of the Bangladesh Development Research Center.)

be the only or even the main motivation for sovereigns to


repay their debts (ibid.). In addition to higher borrowing
costs and a loss of reputation in international credit
markets, the costs of default for a sovereign might include
sanctions and trade retaliations from bilateral official
creditors, costly litigation and legal rulings (as the recent
US Court ruling in favour of Argentinas holdout creditors
illustrates), and, if a high proportion of a sovereigns
bonds are held by its own residents, domestic financial
crises and recessions (ibid.). One study also examines the
political consequences of debt crises, concluding that they
are particularly bad for incumbent politicians and finance
ministers (Borensztein and Panizza 2008).
As many scholars and practitioners note, even the most
comprehensive reforms could not make defaults and
restructurings entirely painless for the sovereign. It follows
that even modest reforms, defaults and restructurings will
continue to inflict significant economic, political and social
damage on the countries that undertake them, and they will
thus continue to be seen as highly undesirable. From this
point of view, countries do not default and/or restructure
because they can or want to, but rather because they are
unable to repay their creditors. Accordingly, creditors
may even welcome the introduction of mechanisms that
facilitate timely and orderly restructuring when sovereign
debts are rendered unsustainable by circumstances not of
the debtors making (Eichengreen 2006, 446).
For these reasons and others, a number of observers remain
firm in their belief that the handling of sovereign debt
restructurings can be improved to the benefit of creditors
and debtors alike. The standard rationale for establishing a
more formal sovereign debt restructuring framework rests
on two economic considerations and one political concern
(Schadler 2012). From an economic perspective, it is argued
that better restructuring arrangements will help to reduce
creditor moral hazard and deadweight losses. From a
political standpoint, creating a system with formal rules
and procedures for restructuring unsustainable sovereign
debt rather than simply bailing out investors would
enhance the perceived fairness and thus the legitimacy of
crisis resolution strategies.

Creditor Moral Hazard


The problem of creditor moral hazard arises from the track
record of IMF lending, which creates an expectation among
creditors that the Fund will invariably bail out troubled
sovereign debtors and by extension their creditors in
order to avoid a costly default.10 With this safety net in place,

10 Some would note that the track record of IMF lending is not the only
source of creditor moral hazard. For example, a legal precedent or
court ruling that made debt repayment more likely, all else equal,
could also lead to what would otherwise be considered overlending
or overly risky lending. (This view was brought to the authors
attention by Jurgen Kaiser of Jubilee Germany.)

Skylar Brooks and Domenico Lombardi 5

CIGI Papers no. 64 April 2015


private creditors engage in excessive and risky lending
to sovereigns, allowing for the unsustainable buildup of
sovereign debt and contributing to the bankruptcy crises
that follow. Mitigating moral hazard requires a clear
and credible threat of losses through restructuring when
lending has been excessive (Schadler 2012, 13). But the
IMF has a hard time making credible commitments of
this sort because of the so-called dynamic inconsistency
problem that is, the potential for actions that may be
optimal before the fact to be suboptimal after the fact if
some condition is not satisfied. As James A. Haley (2013)
explains:
In the case of sovereign bankruptcy, the
commitment not to provide IMF (or other
official sector) resources is entirely sensible
in that it creates incentives for sovereign
borrowers and their private creditors
to come to a timely restructuring. But if
such a restructuring is not forthcoming,
and the result is a financial crisis that has
external effects on global markets, the
commitment not to provide financing may
look decidedly sub-optimal, particularly
for an institution whose mandate is global
financial stability.
The solution to this problem is to put in place formal
restructuring procedures that stipulate the conditions
under which restructurings will take place, and that
reduce the costs of pre-emptive restructurings enough to
be credible (Schadler 2012).
While many see it as a central concern, empirical evidence
on the existence of creditor moral hazard is inconclusive.
Some scholars find robust evidence in support of the moral
hazard thesis, while others find no empirical foundation for
this argument.11 The evidentiary ambiguity surrounding
this question is at least in part a result of the difficulty
of accurately identifying or measuring cases of moral
hazard.12

Deadweight Losses
Deadweight losses are essentially efficiency losses that
arise from information and coordination problems, and
that reduce general economic welfare. They are loselose in the sense that value is destroyed without an
offsetting benefit the debtors loss does not represent

11 Haldane and Scheibe (2004), DellAriccia, Schnabel and Zettlemayer


(2002) and McBrady and Seasholes (2000) find evidence of moral
hazard. Lane and Phillips (2000), Jeanne and Zettelmeyer (2001) and
Kamin (2002) find no evidence of moral hazard.
12 While the existence of creditor moral hazard may be in doubt, there
is evidence that creditors have been overcompensated for the risk of
default (Spiegel 2010). (The authors thank Barry Herman of The New
School for bringing this evidence to their attention.)

6 CENTRE FOR INTERNATIONAL GOVERNANCE INNOVATION

a corresponding gain for the creditor (Sturzenegger and


Zettlemeyer 2006, 270). Insufficient information about
a debtors willingness and ability to pay, for example,
can result in efficiency losses by encouraging creditors
and debtors to engage in protracted disputes, often
involving costly litigation, which ultimately wastes
resources and delays a restructuring agreement (Haley
2014). Coordination problems can also result in inefficient
outcomes when creditors fail to effectively cooperate with
one another, even when doing so would lead to better
outcomes for all parties (Schadler 2012; Blyth 2013).13 The
lack of a coordinating institution also allows for holdout
creditors. One of the core ways in which coordination and
information problems cause efficiency losses is by delaying
the restructuring process and, in doing so, postponing the
countrys return to economic health.
A delayed and disorderly restructuring can lead to a
prolonged period of economic stagnation. As Barry
Eichengreen (2006, 435) explains:
During this period, lenders receive no
interest, and the borrowing country has
no access to international capital markets.
An extended loss of access may cause
the exchange rate to collapse and banks
with
foreign
currency-denominated
liabilities to fall into crisis. This extended
loss of market access and the recession it
provokes have high costs for the country....
Officials in the borrowing country may
thus feel compelled to pursue costly
policies to avoid this plight, running
down reserves, raising interest rates,
and putting the economy through the
deflationary wringer.
Uncertainty on the part of sovereign debtors over the best
way to deal with a sovereign debt crisis can also be a source
of delay and thus inefficiency. Because it is notoriously
difficult to ascertain whether a distressed debtor is insolvent
or merely illiquid, it is sometimes difficult to determine
the appropriate, and necessary, policy response to a debt
crisis. In a climate of uncertainty, national authorities
may avoid or postpone taking politically unpalatable, yet
necessary, measures (such as sovereign debt restructuring)
because they cannot guarantee that these measures are
absolutely necessary. Governments thus gamble for
redemption, which can delay a necessary restructuring
and, in doing so, contribute to what the IMF has identified
as a particularly problematic aspect of the status quo: the
13 Blyth (2013, 63) describes one of the key dilemmas that results from
collective action problems: In such situations bond market investors
face a dilemma. If they believe that bonds are going to fall further
in value, they should get rid of them as soon as possible. But if they
do dump the asset in question, they run the risk that everyone else
holding these assets will do the same, with prices collapsing as a
result.

Sovereign Debt Restructuring: Issues Paper


tendency of distressed debtors to restructure too little, too
late (IMF 2013). The 2012 Greek debt restructuring came a
full two years after Greece lost market access and was put
on an IMF-supported adjustment program, even though it
was widely believed that Greece would eventually have
to restructure its sovereign debt (Xafa 2014). As the Greek
episode attests, pressure or assistance from the international
community can also influence a sovereigns decision and
ability to delay restructuring. This reality raises a further
problem with the current approach: leaving IMF lending
decisions to discretion rather than clearly defined rules
and procedures increases the likelihood that political
pressures within IMF membership will influence policy
decisions in a suboptimal direction.
Many argue that these costs could be minimized if
governments with unsustainable debts took early action
to restructure and were also able to secure the cooperation
of their creditors in doing so (IMF 2013). But early or
timely restructurings would solve only half of the too
little, too late problem. The other half, the fact that
debt restructurings are often too small to provide the
sovereign with sufficient debt relief, would remain a
pressing problem. In the domestic context, insufficient
restructurings are largely avoided vis--vis formal
bankruptcy procedures, which aim to provide viable firms
with a fresh start. Advocates of an international bankruptcy
mechanism therefore point out that, in the absence of
formal procedures, there is nothing to ensure that troubled
sovereigns, even after a default and restructuring, are
given a fresh start from which to launch their economic
recovery.14 For these observers, a more efficient and
effective mechanism for resolving the information and
coordination problems associated with sovereign debt
restructuring is badly needed.

Distributional Issues
Although it is often cloaked in technical language,
sovereign debt restructuring is in fact a politically charged
issue, inescapably wrapped up in deep-seated normative
judgements about equity and the appropriate balance of
public-private burden sharing during financial crises.
The accumulation of unsustainable debt by a government
can raise questions of intergenerational equity (Buccheit
and Gulati 2010). If a government borrows money to
invest in the productive capacity of its economy, then
that borrowing and investment will likely benefit future
14 An important goal of the IMFs and World Banks Heavily Indebted
Poor Country (HIPC) Initiative and Multilateral Debt Relief Initiative
(MDRI) was to provide the eligible countries with a fresh start by
relieving all (or almost all) of their debt. For an overview and analysis
of debt restructuring in Africa, including the role of the HIPC and
MDRI initiatives, see Brooks, Lombardi and Suruma (2014). Recently,
the idea of having a Heavily Indebted Middle Income Country
Initiative, specifically for the Caribbean countries, has been put
forward (see Ramcharan 2015).

generations. The fact that such generations will have


to manage and/or repay the debt that funded those
productive investments is inconsequential, because the
economy from which they draw their earnings (and
tax revenue) will likely be larger and more vibrant as a
result of the debt-financed investments made by previous
governments. In contrast, governments can accumulate
large amounts of debt for fundamentally unproductive
purposes, such as to fund projects that serve narrow
(special) interests or to buy votes that help secure reelection for incumbent politicians. If future generations
are left to service that debt, it is equivalent to a transfer
of wealth from the future to the present, since only the
current generation benefits from spending the money that
future generations will have to repay. Intergenerational
equity is thus one of the distributional issues tied up in the
broader issue of sovereign debt.
Intergenerational equity is not the only, nor the most
contentious, distributional issue at the core of sovereign
debt and sovereign debt restructuring. Inter-creditor equity
is also a key concern for those seeking to resolve crises in a
fair and efficient manner. Here, the main sources of tension
lie in balancing the interests of short-term and long-term
holders of sovereign debt, on one hand, and foreign and
domestic creditors, on the other. Current restructurings
tend to affect only holders of a particular bond issuance
or series, rather than all bondholders. Not being able to
bind all bondholders across different bond issuances to
a common restructuring agreement is referred to as an
aggregation problem. The practical implication of this
problem is that not all creditors are treated equally (Brooks
et al. 2015). For example, there is a key distinction between
creditors whose claims will reach maturity during a debt
crisis or IMF program (short-term claims) and those with
longer-term claims that will not mature for several years.
The distribution of losses between these two generic types
of creditor depends on the way in which a particular debt
crisis is resolved.
Debt crises have traditionally been dealt with through
IMF bailouts. When they are, short-term creditors escape
relatively unscathed. The IMF comes to occupy spots left
by the creditors it bailed out. Since the IMF is a de facto
senior or preferred creditor and is, therefore, almost always
paid back on time and in full, the longer-term creditors
who stayed in (often because they had little choice)
are pushed further down the creditor food chain (which
determines who gets paid, on what terms and when).
In crises that are dealt with through sovereign debt
restructuring or bail-ins, however, it is mostly the shorterterm claimants who bear the brunt of the restructuring,
because their claims mature (i.e., are supposed to be repaid)
at the same time the sovereign is experiencing difficulty
servicing its debt. They must therefore reschedule and/or
accept a nominal loss on their claim.

Skylar Brooks and Domenico Lombardi 7

CIGI Papers no. 64 April 2015


The nationality of bondholders in particular, whether
they are foreigners or domestic residents can also be
an important determinant in the differential treatment of
creditors. For example, domestic and foreign creditors were
treated differently in the last restructurings of Argentina,
Jamaica, Dominica, Russia and Uruguay, to name but a few
cases. There are a number of reasons why sovereigns might
want to discriminate for or against domestic creditors
in their debt restructuring strategies (Erce 2013). First,
residents are subject to the domestic legal and regulatory
system, making them easier to persuade or coerce into
participating in a debt exchange. Second, a sovereign
may choose to honour its external debt obligations while
restructuring its domestic ones in order to retain access to
international capital markets a particularly attractive
strategy for states with underdeveloped domestic
financial markets. Third, a sovereign may choose to
restructure its external debt obligations while remaining
current on its domestic ones in order to mitigate the
domestic financial fallout that could result from defaulting
on and/or restructuring claims held by local banks and
businesses. Finally, domestic residents may have more
influence than foreigners over their governments decision
making and, thus, a greater ability to shape outcomes that
favour domestic creditors (ibid.). For these reasons, intercreditor equity can be a contentious aspect of sovereign
debt restructuring, with a direct impact on the perceived
fairness and efficacy of various crisis resolution strategies.
There are also a number of distributional concerns that, in
a simplified form, break down along public-private lines.
For ideological and material reasons, many private sector
representatives and free-market advocates oppose the
creation of any regime or mechanism that would make it
easier for governments to restructure their debts because
sovereign debt restructuring represents a redistribution
of capital from creditors, often private bondholders, to
sovereign debtors. When a sovereign restructures its
debt, it is bailing in its creditors by not repaying them
in full and/or on time. This represents a financial loss for
creditors and a relative gain for debtors.
On the other hand, sovereign debt crises often follow
private sector financial crises because governments
choose to bail out insolvent financial firms at a time
when recession-induced government expenditures,
such as for unemployment insurance, are rising and tax
revenues are falling. Thus, private losses that generate
financial crises are often socialized and borne by the
public sector, representing a large redistribution of pain
from private financial actors to the population writ large.
Furthermore, when the IMF and bilateral official creditors
bail out countries with sovereign debt problems, they are
essentially bailing out the sovereigns private creditors. If

8 CENTRE FOR INTERNATIONAL GOVERNANCE INNOVATION

the sovereign is not insolvent but rather illiquid,15 there


is nothing necessarily wrong with the bailout strategy
from a crisis management perspective. This strategy does,
however, place responsibility for the crisis squarely on
the borrower instead of the lender. This is problematic
insofar as creditors that expect to be bailed out in the event
of a sovereign debt crisis have an incentive to lend in an
excessive and imprudent manner to sovereigns. There is
thus a compelling argument in favour of more burden
sharing between debtors and creditors during sovereign
debt crises. When liquidity support (i.e., a bailout) is
coupled with a domestic adjustment program, usually
involving painful austerity measures, this problem is
made more acute. In this case, domestic populations
in particular those at the lower end of the income
distribution, who rely most heavily on social services
are forced to bear the brunt of the crisis, while international
lenders escape unscathed. For many, this is a deeply unfair
distribution of the costs and benefits of sovereign debt and
sovereign debt crises. These concerns highlight the fact
that sovereign debt and the resolution of sovereign debt
crises are matters of social justice, not simply economic
efficiency.

Issues for Discussion


What are the potential costs and benefits of reforming
the international debt architecture? In a globalized
financial system, are sovereign debt crises inevitable
and bound to be costly, or are there certain types
of reforms that could reduce the frequency and
costliness of such crises?
How can we best balance the different distributional
concerns that arise from sovereign debt and sovereign
debt restructuring?
Are lenders and borrowers equally (or differentially)
responsible for the buildup of unsustainable debt?
What does that imply for burden sharing in the
resolution of sovereign debt crises?

WHAT TYPES OF REFORM ARE NEEDED?


Among those who agree on the need to improve the
handling of sovereign debt restructurings, there is much
debate over what types of reforms are required, with
opinions traditionally split between those who advocate
a market-based, contractual approach, on one hand, and
those who would prefer to see a more formal, statutory
15 If a sovereign is illiquid, it does not have the resources at its disposal
to meet its current debt obligations. But its medium- to long-term
debt burden could still be sustainable. If it is insolvent, its mediumto long-term debt burden or debt-to-GDP ratio is fundamentally
unsustainable. Put differently, illiquid sovereigns might only need
a short-term cash injection to continue servicing their debts, while
an insolvent sovereign has much deeper problems that require more
fundamental changes to restore its debt sustainability.

Sovereign Debt Restructuring: Issues Paper


mechanism, on the other. Recently, a number of alternative
proposals have been put forward, some of which do not fit
cleanly into the contractual-statutory dichotomy (Brooke
et al. 2013; Buchheit et al. 2013; Gitlin and House 2014; IMF
2014b).

The Contractual Approach


One perspective on why sovereign debt restructuring is
costly and unpredictable is that relations between creditors
are subject to incomplete contracts (Bolton and Jeanne
2002). From this perspective, a good way to ensure more
timely and orderly restructuring is to clearly outline the
procedures for restructuring when the bond is first issued.
Writing the terms of a restructuring into the bond contract
can help mitigate the collective action problems that lead
to deadweight losses by binding creditors to a common
and well-specified restructuring procedure.
CACs, a widespread feature of sovereign bond contracts,
embody the contractual approach to sovereign debt
restructuring. These clauses consist of legal provisions
that are written into the contracts that govern sovereign
debt obligations. They typically include provisions
that: establish a bondholders meeting in the event of
restructuring and specify procedures for selecting the
bondholders representative (collective representation
clauses); prevent individual bondholders from taking the
sovereign to court (majority enforcement clauses); and
specify the size of the (super) majority of bondholders
needed to amend payment terms (majority restructuring
clauses) (Das, Papaioannou and Trebesch 2012; Gulati and
Weidemaier 2014).
CACs have been a common feature of the London bond
market since the late nineteenth century (Das, Papaioannou
and Trebesch 2012). In the United States, however, CACs
did not become widely used until 2003, when Mexico
became the first major emerging market debtor to include
CACs in its sovereign bonds a move that precipitated
a rapid and widespread shift toward the use of CACs for
emerging markets. At the end of 2002, only about 30 percent
of emerging market sovereign bonds included CACs (and
most were issued in London). By 2004, close to 90 percent
of new international bonds issued included CACs, and
by the first half of 2005 the figure had approached close
to 100 percent (Helleiner 2009). In response to the eurozone crisis, Europe has introduced a new requirement
that all euro-zone sovereign bonds issued after January 1,
2013, include CACs (Bradley and Gulati 2013; Gulati and
Weidemaier 2014).
Although the more widespread use of CACs in sovereign
bond issuances seems to represent a step in the right
direction, many argue that the presence of CACs alone is
not enough to ensure a timely and orderly restructuring

process.16 Empirical evidence on the actual effectiveness


of CACs in past debt restructurings shows they are not
sufficient to address the problems (Das, Papaioannou and
Trebesch 2012). As mentioned, the Greek restructuring
enjoyed a high rate of participation among bondholders
(97 percent), but those who refused to participate
were successful in recovering their investments in full,
strengthening the incentive for others to hold out from
future deals. Indeed, the IMF (2013) notes that the Greek
restructuring highlighted the limitations of CACs in
addressing non-participating creditors. The recent US
court ruling in favour of Argentinas holdout creditors
may also make the problem more acute going forward
(IMF 2013; 2014). Lee C. Buchheit, Mitu Gulati and Ignacio
Tirado (2013, 1) are convinced that any future Eurozone
debt restructuring will be surely plagued by the problem of
non-participating creditors. More importantly, the Greek
restructuring was seen as a case of too little, too late a
problem that CACs are not equipped to handle (IMF 2013;
Gitlin 2014). In fact, some scholars go as far as to argue
that the inclusion of CACs in bond issuances can actually
increase incentives for some creditors to free ride on others
and, in doing so, further delay the resolution of a debt
restructuring deal (Pitchford and Wright 2010). For some,
the persistence and potential worsening of the holdout
creditor problem only reinforces the need to improve the
way sovereign debt restructuring is governed beyond the
contractual approach of CACs.
One of the most common criticisms of CACs is that they
are unable to aggregate all of the sovereigns creditors
and bind them, along with the sovereign, to a common
restructuring agreement. Since sovereign bonds are
typically restructured on a series-by-series basis, only
a portion of a sovereigns creditors are involved in any
given restructuring. And since CACs only apply to a single
series, it is relatively easy for holdout creditors to buy a
blocking position within a single bond series (typically
over 15 percent of the bonds in that series) and undermine
an otherwise widely accepted restructuring deal. In
response to this shortcoming, the International Capital
Markets Association (ICMA) has been promoting a new
version of CACs with a stronger aggregation feature. As
a recent IMF staff report (2014a, 1) states, Broad support
has emerged for CACs to include a single limb voting
procedure that will enable bonds to be restructured on the
basis of a single vote across all affected instruments, subject
to safeguards designed to ensure inter-creditor equity and
minimize the risk of sovereign manipulation. The new
ICMA CACs include this single-limb provision but also
allow for the adoption of a two-limb voting procedure,
enabling differential treatment among creditors.

16 See Bi, Chamon and Zettelmeyer (2011); Bradley, Cox and Gulati
(2010); and Das, Papaioannou and Trebesch (2012).

Skylar Brooks and Domenico Lombardi 9

CIGI Papers no. 64 April 2015

THE RISE AND FALL OF THE SDRM


In the wake of a series of large-scale emerging market crises, and with the 2001 Argentine crisis brewing, a few
top US officials began to consider proposals for an international sovereign bankruptcy regime. In September 2001
(just prior to the Argentine default), US Treasury Secretary Paul ONeill approached both senior IMF management
and the US Congress to suggest they give serious consideration to the idea of an international bankruptcy law for
sovereign debtors (Helleiner 2009, 8). In November 2001, then IMF First Deputy Managing Director Anne Krueger
formally proposed a sovereign debt restructuring mechanism. Housed in the IMF, the SDRM would provide a
formal bankruptcy procedure for sovereigns. In short, it would be a legal mechanism designed to approve payments
standstills for sovereign states experiencing severe debt servicing difficulties, and facilitate the restructuring and,
if necessary, writing down of sovereign debts (Fischer 2003). An SDRM, it was argued, would address the moral
hazard problem by minimizing private sector bailouts and, by establishing a more timely and orderly way of
resolving sovereign debt crises, it would provide benefits to both debtors and creditors (Helleiner 2009).
In the end, support for the SDRM was not strong enough to overcome the opposition of private creditors, emerging
market sovereign debtors (namely Mexico and Brazil) and key officials within the US government. Private creditor
associations lobbied key individuals within the US Treasury Department and the IMF and, when CACs emerged
as a potential alternative to the SDRM, they threw their weight behind this approach and even lobbied sovereign
debtors to do the same. The logic ran that the widespread adoption of CACs would render the SDRM unnecessary,
but sovereign debtors still worried that their support for any restructuring mechanism even CACs would
compromise their perceived creditworthiness. In the end, it took direct lobbying on the part of creditors to convince
the Mexican government that issuing CACs in its sovereign bonds would not compromise its access to affordable
external credit, whereas the SDRM would. Ultimately, Mexicos decision in 2003 to include CACs in its bonds was
a success, marking the SDRMs downfall (Gelpern and Gulati 2004).
These revamped clauses, which have been adopted by
Chile, Ethiopia, Kazakhstan, Mexico and Vietnam, are
intended to deal with this issue by aggregating and
binding all bondholders to a single restructuring process.
It should be noted, however, that even if these new CACs
are widely adopted and ultimately prove effective in
dealing with the aggregation problem, it could take up
to a decade for them to work their way into the existing
debt stock. In light of this challenge, Gregory Makoff
and Robert Kahn (2015) discuss how to speed up the
conversion of existing debt contracts to the new ICMA
format, including bond amendments and exchange offers.
As a way forward, they suggest that creditors and debtors
could be brought together to discuss active strategies to
accelerate the transition of outstanding stocks of debt to
the new format, and that the G20 could play a leadership
role in this type of initiative (ibid., 8).

The Statutory Approach


Many observers believe that CACs are insufficiently robust
to solve many of the problems associated with sovereign
debt restructuring. A number of them have called for
the creation of a more formal, statutory mechanism or
framework for restructuring sovereign debt something
akin to an international bankruptcy procedure for
sovereigns. The most concrete and high-profile proposal
of this sort was IMF First Deputy Managing Director
Anne Kruegers call in 2001 for the creation of a Sovereign
Debt Restructuring Mechanism (SDRM) (Krueger 2001).

10 CENTRE FOR INTERNATIONAL GOVERNANCE INNOVATION

Grounded in an international legal framework that would


bind all countries and supersede the provisions of private
loan agreements, this treaty-based approach would
require amending the IMFs Articles of Agreement, which
is intentionally difficult to do.
In general, a statutory restructuring mechanism would
presumably include four key features (Eichengreen 2006).
First, in the event of a restructuring, the mechanism would
impose hard restraints on litigation so as to prevent a costly
and time-consuming rush to the courthouse on the part
of creditors (Kolb 2011; Haley 2014). Depending on the
design of the mechanism, restraints on litigation could be
subject to approval by a supermajority of creditors. Second,
there would be a procedure for assigning creditor seniority
and ensuring that new private lending is protected from
restructuring. Third, a statutory mechanism would
allow a supermajority of creditors to vote to accept the
terms of a restructuring arrangement, and ensure that
minority creditors were bound by this decision. Finally,
the mechanism would include a venue and process for fact
checking information, resolving disputes and overseeing
the bondholder voting process. As Eichengreen (2006, 443)
explains, a statutory approach like the sovereign debt
restructuring mechanism elaborates the US-style courtled approach to debt restructuring by relying on statutes
to create a quasi-judicial process for debt reorganization,
while collective action clauses attempt to extend the
traditional UK-style approach that relies on contracting
and on self-organizing creditors, with little if any court

Sovereign Debt Restructuring: Issues Paper


involvement. Proponents of the statutory approach argue
that it would solve the aggregation problem of not being
able to bind all bondholders to a restructuring deal that a
supermajority of creditors agrees to. But critics claim that
a statutory arrangement would be arbitrary and would
unduly interfere with market mechanisms (Rieffel 2003).
They also contend that such an approach is politically
infeasible. It is indeed true that in the early 2000s the
SDRM proposal failed to receive sufficient support from
state and market actors.
Yet, the idea of a statutory approach to sovereign debt
restructuring has not been abandoned. On September
9, 2014, the United Nations General Assembly passed a
resolution that calls for the creation of a multilateral legal
framework for sovereign debt restructuring. One hundred
and twenty-four countries voted to pass the resolution.
Tellingly, almost all countries with major financial centres
voted against it, including the United States, the United
Kingdom, Germany and Japan. While the final outcome of
this resolution will not become clear for some time, it is a
significant development and, for many, an important step
in the right direction. Among other things, the resolution
indicates that the governments of most countries support a
more comprehensive, treaty-based approach to sovereign
debt restructuring. It also shows that many governments
do not see the IMF as the only or even the best channel
through which to pursue reforms to the international debt
architecture. Nor is the IMF viewed as the natural home
for any future debt restructuring mechanism once created.
To the contrary, several developing countries distrust the
IMF and question its legitimacy.17 Some also question
whether the IMF can be an objective arbiter of sovereign
debt disputes, since it is itself a creditor with a material
interest in the resolution of debt crises. For such a creditor
to act as an impartial judge would violate bankruptcy
standards of neutrality.

A Sovereign Debt Tribunal and Arbitration


Process
A number of scholars and civil society organizations
(CSOs) have advanced or endorsed proposals for a fair
and transparent sovereign debt arbitration process (Ruiz
Diaz 2003; European Network on Debt and Development
[Eurodad] 2009; Jubilee USA 2012) such as an international
sovereign debt tribunal (SDT). The proposal for an SDT,
as outlined by Christoph Paulus and Steven Kargman
(2008), starts from the conviction that a statutory SDRM is
ideal and desirable but not politically feasible at present.
As such, the SDT proposal seeks to incorporate certain
components of the SDRM without repacking the idea as
17 For example, the IMFs role in the aftermath of the 1997 Asian financial
crisis has earned it a poor reputation among many countries in East
Asia. Most recently, failure to ratify the 2010 IMF reform package by
the United States has put any governance reform of this institution on
hold.

a whole; namely, it looks to expand upon the SDRMs


Dispute Resolution Forum designed to adjudicate
disputes arising from the restructuring process.
According to its proponents, an SDT would have several
advantageous features. First, it would be based on
consensus among key stakeholders and would thus be
perceived as fair and legitimate. The decision to subject
restructuring disputes to an arbitration panel would be
based on a contractual agreement between the sovereign
debtor and its creditors and specified in the bond contract
or debt instrument at the time of issuance i.e., prior
to any debt servicing difficulties. Second, an arbitration
panel would serve as a neutral forum to resolve disputes
between and among creditors and debtors. To ensure such
neutrality, it would be important to establish the SDT
under the auspices of a multilateral institution that is not
itself a creditor. Paulus and Kargman (2008) consider the
United Nations the most appropriate institutional home
for such a tribunal. Third, an SDT would bind creditors
and debtors to common solutions and thus overcome
many of the collective action problems associated with
sovereign debt restructuring. Finally, an independent
arbitration panel could help build trust, confidence and
legitimacy in the debt workout process by cultivating a
general perception among sovereigns and their creditors
that there is a selected pool of expert arbitrators who
have the knowledge and experience to handle sovereign
debt disputes (ibid., 5).18
The SDT would not, of course, have any authority to initiate
and decide cases on its own. The tribunal would be granted
such authority by way of a prior contractual agreement
to arbitration by all of the relevant parties (ibid., 8). As
such, it would be necessary to include arbitration clauses
in sovereign bond contracts, much like CACs have been.19
Such clauses would delineate the tribunals jurisdiction
and specify the event that would trigger arbitration. In
purchasing these bonds, investors would be automatically
agreeing to the contractual provisions contained therein,
making any arbitration process binding for all parties.

18 Several CSOs also advocate a specifically human rights-based


approach to sovereign debt arbitration, whereby debt relief and
debt restructuring negotiations reflect fundamental human rights
concerns in the debtor country. (The authors thank Gina Ekholt of the
Debt Justice Network Norway for reiterating the importance for most
CSOs of a human rights-based approach to sovereign debt.)
19 It is important to note that while debtors and creditors must both
agree to arbitration, prior contractual agreement is not in fact a
necessary condition for such a process to take place. It may be seen as
ideal to agree to arbitration beforehand, but, if they agree, creditors
and debtors could also initiate an arbitration process during or after
the outbreak of debt difficulties, including default. It is also worth
noting that once it has been carried out, arbitration decisions are
legally binding under the New York Arbitration Convention of 1958,
to which 150 states are a party. (The authors thank Gina Ekholt of the
Debt Justice Network Norway for bringing these important points to
their attention.)

Skylar Brooks and Domenico Lombardi 11

CIGI Papers no. 64 April 2015


Proposals of the sort described above began to surface
after the SDRM was shelved in 2003. While they have not
yet been implemented or affected policy, there has been a
recent revival of calls for the creation of an independent
international arbitration process for resolving disputes
arising from sovereign debt restructuring (Latindadd
2014; Jubilee USA 2012; Eurodad 2009). It is important to
note that the SDT is but one model within the category
of arbitration. Several variations have been proposed. One
such proposal designed by Jose Antonio Ocampo (2014b),
is to model an arbitration process on the World Trade
Organizations dispute settlement mechanism, which
would unfold in three consecutive stages with clear
deadlines: voluntary negotiations between the debtor
and its creditors; mediation between the two parties; and,
if the first two fail, arbitration. Recent reports note that the
United Nations Conference on Trade and Development is
about to unveil its own proposal for a new sovereign debt
workout mechanism (Ellmers 2014).

Issues for Discussion


What are the pros and cons of the contractual,
statutory and arbitration approaches, respectively?20
Ostensibly, the statutory and contractual approaches
seek to achieve many of the same purposes
(overcome collective action problems, prevent
individual bondholders from pursuing litigation,
facilitate agreement on restructuring terms among
a [super] majority of bondholders). What, then, are
the real substantive differences between these two
approaches? Why is one seen as more ambitious
politically?
Does the arbitration approach fall somewhere in
between the statutory and contractual approaches?
Which actors are likely to support and oppose each
of these approaches? Why?

NEW PROPOSALS FOR SOVEREIGN


DEBT REFORM
In the wake of the euro-zone crisis, and in the midst of
the Argentina litigation, a number of new proposals
for handling sovereign debt restructuring have been
advanced, including the IMFs recent proposal to reform
its own lending framework.

20 It is important to note, as many have, that these different approaches


to sovereign debt restructuring are not mutually exclusive. In
fact, many advocate a multi-pronged approach that leverages
complementary aspects of statutory, contractual and arbitration
approaches. (The authors would like to thank Jurgen Kaiser of Jubilee
Germany for reminding them of this important point.)

12 CENTRE FOR INTERNATIONAL GOVERNANCE INNOVATION

The IMF and Debt Reprofiling


As mentioned, the outbreak of the euro-zone crisis,
combined with the legal saga surrounding Argentinas
debt obligations, has put sovereign debt restructuring
among the IMFs top priorities. In June 2014, the IMF
released a staff report suggesting a new approach to
the Funds exceptional access lending framework as
it relates to sovereign debt restructuring. The report
identifies key deficiencies in the Funds current lending
framework brought into stark relief during the eurozone crisis and outlines a new institutional approach to
managing sovereign debt crises.
Established in 2002 and amended in 2010, the current
IMF framework for exceptional lending stipulates that in
cases where there is a high risk of international systemic
spillover effects, a members debt sustainability does not
have to be assured with high probability to gain exceptional
access to IMF resources (IMF 2010: 20). The wisdom of
introducing this systemic exemption in 2010 has since
been scrutinized, as critics argue that it undermined the
frameworks ability to constrain IMF lending decisions to
the ultimate detriment of the Funds legitimacy and ability
to manage future crises (Schadler 2013). More generally,
others called on the Fund to restore the credibility and
consistency of the policies underpinning its crisis-driven
lending (Boughton, Brooks and Lombardi 2014, 1).
Whether or not the Fund heeded such criticism, the first
major recommendation of the June 2014 staff paper is to
eliminate the systemic exemption.
Once the systemic exemption is removed, the Fund is
left with its 2002 framework, which states that in order
to be granted exceptional access to IMF resources, a
rigorous and systematic analysis must indicate with high
probability that a members public debt will remain
sustainable in the medium term. If debt sustainability can
be assured with high probability, the Fund will rely on its
traditional approach: provide money to repay creditors
with maturing debt obligations (i.e., to bailout creditors)
as long as the borrowing country agrees to an economic
adjustment program.
If a countrys debt sustainability cannot be assured
with high probability, however, it must undergo a debt
restructuring sufficiently deep to restore sustainability
before it can receive IMF assistance. As a consequence of this
approach, debt restructuring will be required not only in
cases where there is a high probability of unsustainability,
but also where it is not clear with a high probability
whether the debt is sustainable or unsustainable; i.e., in
cases where there is uncertainty (IMF 2014b, 9).
As IMF staff now argue, the problem with this approach is
that there are many cases in which considerable uncertainty
exists (despite the increasing sophistication of the Funds
debt sustainability analyses [DSAs]); in these cases,

Sovereign Debt Restructuring: Issues Paper


requiring a deep debt restructuring, which imposes steep
costs on creditors and debtors, may be an unnecessary
and suboptimal outcome. As such, in cases where the
sustainability of a countrys debt cannot be determined
with high probability, Fund staff advocate an approach
that relies on reprofiling debt rather than restructuring.
Under a reprofiling, there would be an extension of
maturities on existing sovereign debt, but no change to
the interest or principal. According to IMF staff, in cases of
genuine uncertainty, reprofiling sovereign debt would be
more effective than the current crisis management strategy
for at least four reasons: it would be less disruptive to
financial markets and less costly to debtors and creditors
than a potentially unnecessary debt restructuring; it
would be more effective and fair than allowing creditors
with maturing claims to exit if a debt restructuring
does indeed prove necessary; it would buy more time to
implement necessary policy adjustments, better assess
debt sustainability as those policies go into effect, and, in
turn, reduce the likelihood of needing a restructuring in
the first place; and since Fund resources would not have
to be used to service maturing debt obligations, the IMF
could support a more growth-friendly (i.e., less austeritybased) adjustment program with a greater chance of
restoring debt sustainability (IMF 2014b).
In addition to genuine uncertainty, reprofiling would be
conditional upon a member country already having lost
market access; that way, reprofiling would not trigger a loss
of market confidence. Fund staff also note the importance
of securing broad creditor support for a reprofiling, and
thus the need to implement reprofiling in a way that, if
possible, avoids a payment default. Compared to the
status quo, argue IMF staff, providing a greater role for
debt reprofiling in the IMFs exceptional access lending
framework will allow the Fund to better tailor its policy
actions to the specific circumstances of a given country
and crisis (IMF 2014b).
Overall, the Fund is seeking a broader range of policy tools
for managing severe sovereign debt crises. To expand its
tool kit, the IMFs staff will have to obtain the consent
of its most powerful members. These include the United
States and Europe, whose officials may worry that even
reprofiling could threaten firms within their domestic
financial markets. It also includes increasingly influential
emerging powers such as China, whose officials do not see
reprofiling as a particularly potent option (House, Wang
and Xafa 2014). Even if the IMF adopts these proposals,
there is no guarantee that the reprofiling option will be
invoked.
The IMFs proposal is far from the only new idea for how
to improve the handling of severe sovereign debt crises.
In fact, the last few years have seen several new and
innovative proposals. The following describes a few of

the proposals that have received significant attention from


scholars and practitioners.

State-contingent Debt
Recently, the Bank of Canada and the Bank of England
released a joint study outlining the equity and efficiency
problems with the current approach to sovereign debt
restructuring, and arguing that to address these problems
private creditors should play a greater role in risk-sharing
and helping to resolve sovereign debt crises (Brooke
et al. 2013, 1). They propose the introduction of two
complementary types of state-contingent debt sovereign
cocos21 and GDP-linked bonds both of which are
extensions of the contractual approach. Sovereign cocos,
the authors explain, are bonds that would automatically
extend in repayment maturity when a country receives
official sector emergency liquidity assistance (ibid.).
By bailing in creditors in a transparent, predictable and
credible manner ex post, cocos would ostensibly temper
imprudent lending practices ex ante and thus reduce
creditor moral hazard and the likelihood of sovereign
debt crises erupting in the first place. In other words,
since creditors would no longer be able count on full
repayment by the official sector during crises, they would
be more risk averse in their lending practices, in turn
giving sovereign debtors less rope to hang themselves
with. In the past, commitments by the official sector to bail
in creditors have failed to reduce moral hazard because
they lacked credibility. But the automaticity of the bail-in
procedure specified in cocos would arguably make them
more credible, and therefore effective, in discouraging
imprudent lending and borrowing during normal times.
Furthermore, note Martin Brooke et al. (2013, 9), the
activation of sovereign cocos would significantly alter
burden-sharing between private creditors and the official
sector/taxpayers, reducing the required size of official
sector emergency loans. Arguably, then, sovereign cocos
would be more effective at preventing crises and more
equitable in resolving them. And while sovereign cocos
are apt to address liquidity problems rather than solvency
ones, the activation of cocos can help to buy time to make
a fuller assessment of debt sustainability and, if need be,
to undertake debt restructuring negotiations in an orderly
way (ibid., 9).
To optimize this contractual approach, Brooke et al.
(2013) argue that sovereign cocos could and should be
accompanied by GDP-linked bonds that is, bonds
that directly link principal and interest payments to the
nominal level of a countrys GDP (ibid.). GDP-linked
bonds ensure, in other words, that when a countrys GDP
is reduced, so too are the principal and interest payments
on its sovereign debt. Sovereign cocos and GDP-linked
21 Coco is short for contingent-convertible.

Skylar Brooks and Domenico Lombardi 13

CIGI Papers no. 64 April 2015


bonds are complementary insofar as the former helps
tackle liquidity crises while the latter helps reduce the
likelihood of solvency crises. As Brooke et al. (2013, 1)
explain, GDP-linked bonds provide a form of recession
insurance that reduces principal and interest payments
when a country is hit by a negative growth shock, and
this helps to both stabilize the debt-to-GDP ratio and
increase a sovereigns capacity to borrow at sustainable
levels. GDP-linked bonds are not an entirely new idea,
as a number of scholars have studied and highlighted the
benefits from their introduction (Schiller 1993, 2003; Barro
1995; Chamon and Mauro 2005; Ruban, Poon and Vonatsos
2008).22
Both sovereign cocos and GDP-linked bonds are statecontingent debt instruments, meaning that they are
defined as written into bond contracts at the time of
issuance. In terms of political acceptability, this point is
potentially important. While statutory arrangements (such
as the SDRM) have historically failed to generate sufficient
political support (Helleiner 2008), contractual mechanisms
have at least some record of success. As Brooke et al. (2013)
point out, the widespread adoption of CACs in the mid2000s provides historical precedent for changes to the
contractual terms of sovereign debt.

Sovereign Debt Forum


Another new idea that has received some attention is
Richard Gitlin and Brett Houses proposal for a Sovereign
Debt Forum (SDF). As a semi-formal institutional venue,
the SDF would, in the words of its proponents, provide
a centre for continuous improvement of the processes for
dealing with financially distressed sovereigns and a venue
for proactive discussions between debtors and creditors to
reach early understandings on treating specific sovereign
crises (Gitlin and House 2014, 7). The SDF would be a
non-statutory body modelled loosely on the London
and Paris Clubs, but with wider membership. Gitlin and
House (2014, 7) argue that by providing an independent
standing body to research and preserve institutional
memory on best practice in sovereign debt restructuring
as well as a meeting place for debtors, creditors, and other
stakeholders, the SDF would help to facilitate timelier and
more orderly resolutions of sovereign debt crises in a way
that complements, rather than competes with, existing
institutions and processes.
While sovereign cocos and GDP-linked bonds represent an
extension and improvement of the contractual approach,
the SDF breaks from the statutory-contractual dichotomy
altogether. Indeed, Gitlin and House (2014, 7) argue that
22 There may also be considerable problems with the idea of GDPlinked bonds. The most obvious relate to the questions of how GDP
is measured and whether it is a good indicator of a governments
capacity to service debt. (The authors thank Nathan Coplin for
raising this issue.)

14 CENTRE FOR INTERNATIONAL GOVERNANCE INNOVATION

the world has been stuck between a rejected proposal


for a statutory approach (the SDRM) and a working, but
inadequate, contractual approach in the form of CACs.
They argue that this impasse has resulted from a failure
to accurately diagnose the main problems associated
with resolving sovereign debt crises. Rather than holdout
creditors or the propensity of sovereigns to default
gratuitously, the core problem, as they and others see it,
is that sovereigns tend to delay restructuring their debts
and, when they do pursue a debt treatment, they are often
insufficiently ambitious in seeking to produce a debt
burden that is sustainable (ibid., 7). In their view, the SDF
is thus well positioned to handle the issue of delay, since
it provides a venue for proactive discussions between
debtors and creditors to reach early understandings on
treating specific sovereign crises (ibid.).

Proposals from the Committee on


International Economic Policy and Reform
A number of other notable ideas have surfaced, including
a series of proposals put forward by the Committee on
International Economic Policy and Reform, a group of
prominent experts.23 Similar to many others critics of the
status quo, these experts argue that the current ad hoc
approach to sovereign debt restructuring provides poor
incentives both ex ante and ex post and should therefore
be reformed (Buchheit et al. 2013b). They propose four
potential remedies, ranging in ambition and geographical
scope. The first two can be implemented unilaterally and,
as such, are less ambitious than the latter two, whose
implementation would require coordinated multilateral
action by states.
The first proposal is to strengthen the existing contractual
approach by adopting CACs with stronger aggregation
features CACs that give a supermajority of all
bondholders, rather than just the holders of an individual
bond series, the right to restructure against the will of a
minority of holdouts. The effectiveness of this approach
would ultimately depend on the degree and speed of
adoption of strong aggregation clauses in international
debt contracts (ibid., 44). Strengthening CACs to enhance
bondholder aggregation would entail only a small
amendment to the current approach, and so it would be
relatively easy in both technical and political terms. This
is indeed the approach that has so far been taken with the
design and adoption of the new ICMA model CACs.

23 The Committee includes, in no particular order, Lee C. Buchheit,


Anna Gelpern, Mitu Gulati, Ugo Panizza, Beatrice Weder di Mauro,
Jeromin Zettelmeyer (these six were the lead authors of the report
under discussion), Markus Brunnermeier, Barry Eichengreen,
Mohamed El-Erian, Jose De Gregorio, Takatoshi Ito, Philip Lane,
Eswar Prasad, Helene Rey, Dani Rodrik, Hyun Song Shin, Andres
Velasco and Yongding Yu. Domenico Lombardi is now a member
of the committee, but he was not when they published the report
referred to and cited in this paper.

Sovereign Debt Restructuring: Issues Paper


The second proposal also seeks to address the problem
of holdout creditors, who have been emboldened by the
success of non-participating creditors in the 2012 Greek
restructuring and by the recent court ruling in favour of
holdouts from Argentinas restructuring in the early 2000s.
In spite of sovereign immunity, holdout creditors have
managed to inflict collateral damage on sovereign debtors
by threatening to interfere with payments being made
by the sovereign to other creditors (third parties) under
performing debt contracts. Thus, to defang holdouts,
Buchheit et al. (2013b) argue that laws or regulations
could be introduced in major financial centres in order
to immunize payments and clearing systems from
attempts to target third-party payments streams. This
could be done in individual financial centres in isolation
from one another (there would, arguably, be first-mover
advantages in adopting this approach) or in multiple
centres in a more coordinated international effort.
However strong this approach could be in dealing with
holdout creditors, it remains limited as a comprehensive
solution to the problems of sovereign debt restructuring,
for it does nothing to address the perverse incentives that
contribute to unsustainable debt accumulation in the first
place (that is, ex ante issues).
The third, and more ambitious, proposal addresses both
ex ante and ex post concerns through the creation of a new
sovereign debt adjustment facility to be housed in the
IMF (ibid.). According to the Buchheit et al. (2013b, 32),
the SDAF would serve two related purposes: to create
a stronger commitment device for the Fund not to be
drawn into bailing out countries whose debts are likely
unsustainable unless these countries also restructure; and
to protect countries that undertake orderly restructurings
in the context of the SDAF from holdouts.
To achieve the first goal, the IMF would establish criteria to
determine the eligibility of a country for SDAF assistance.
Countries that qualify for, and want, this type of assistance
would not have access to IMF crisis lending except under
the SDAF (ibid., 32). If a DSA by the IMF indicates that the
debt burden of a country is unsustainable in the absence
of a restructuring, then IMF lending to that country will
be made conditional on a sovereign debt restructuring
that provides sufficiently deep debt relief to restore longterm debt sustainability. To achieve the second goal, the
assets and revenue streams of all IMF members could
be effectively immunized from interference by holdout
creditors. This proposal is certainly more ambitious
and seemingly more difficult politically, for it involves
coordinated multilateral action and, ultimately, an
amendment of the IMFs Articles of Agreement. Still,
the authors argue that the required amendment would
be minor, while the SDAFs impact in resolving the
problems of too little, too late restructurings and holdout
creditors could be major.

The final and perhaps most politically ambitious proposal


is the creation of a European Sovereign Debt Restructuring
Regime (ESDRR) a statutory approach of limited
geographical scope. In the midst of the euro crisis, eurozone member states created the European Stability
Mechanism (ESM): an intergovernmental organization
designed to provide financial assistance to euro-zone
members in times of need. Rather than create a new legal
entity, the authors suggest that the ESDRR could be made
an institutional feature of the ESM and brought into
existence through a simple amendment of the ESM treaty.
The conditions under which the ESDRR would trigger
or facilitate a debt restructuring would be guided by
the existing European fiscal framework: At debt levels
below 60 percent [of GDP], ESM lending would be largely
unconditional; but at 60 percent plus x (an upper threshold),
ESM lending would be conditional on debt restructuring
(ibid., 44). Such a framework would provide a credible
commitment to restructuring, thus reducing creditor
and debtor moral hazard while still providing sufficient
flexibility to account for large economic shocks. As the
authors argue, the euro area has both the largest need
and the best chances to implement such a comprehensive
solution (ibid.).
It is worth noting that, for many but not all experts,
there is a trade-off between the ambition or the
perceived political feasibility of a given reform and
its overall effectiveness. The more ambitious proposals,
if implemented, would arguably go further in solving
the underlying problems associated with sovereign
debt crises and restructurings. The comparatively less
ambitious proposals i.e., those that would be easier
to obtain political support for would still represent
an improvement over the status quo, but would not be
comprehensive enough to robustly address all of the key
problems associated with sovereign debt restructuring.

Issues for Discussion


From both a political and an economic point of view,
how could the pros and cons of the various proposals
on the table be assessed?
Does the IMFs proposal go far enough toward
resolving the core problems associated with sovereign
debt management and sovereign debt restructuring?
If debt reprofiling would have a similar effect as
sovereign cocos, which approach is preferable and
why?
Are the most ideal or desirable proposals also
politically feasible? Going forward, how should the
balance and/or tension between political, economic
and legal concerns be mediated?

Skylar Brooks and Domenico Lombardi 15

CIGI Papers no. 64 April 2015

CONCLUSION
The purpose of this paper has been to provide an overview
of the main issues, debates and policy proposals that
surround sovereign debt restructuring. While it seeks to
be relatively comprehensive in its treatment of these items,
the paper is in no way exhaustive of the many possible
ways of preventing and managing sovereign debt crises.
A few of the most prominent reform proposals namely,
those that have gained considerable attention within
scholarly and policy circles have been discussed in this
paper, but several other possibilities exist,24 whether or not
they have yet been considered. This paper is thus intended
to serve as a starting point, the beginning of a broader
conversation that will engage with and take us beyond the
current debate and menu of options for dealing with the
complex equity and efficiency problems that so often mire
sovereign debt restructurings. Only through inclusive
discussion and debate of this sort can we hope to move
toward sovereign debt restructuring arrangements that
work for all.

Issues for Further Discussion


Our ongoing consultations with various stakeholders point
to a number of important issues that go beyond the scope
of this paper, but that nevertheless deserve considerable
attention going forward. First, there is room for further
learning from detailed case studies and comparative
research on sovereign debt restructurings. While case
studies of selected past defaults and debt restructurings
do exist (see Sturzenegger and Zettelmeyer 2006), there are
still several new and previously underexplored cases that
warrant greater attention.25
Second, there is need for further discussion and analysis
of the role of domestic laws, jurisdictions and judicial
action on sovereign debt restructuring. Argentinas
ongoing saga highlights the importance of domestic law
within the United States more specifically, the state of
New York but it also opens up a potential avenue for
addressing sovereign debt problems: amending national
or subnational laws in key financial hubs. This approach
is not entirely novel. In 2010, the United Kingdom passed
the Debt Relief (Developing Countries) Act to prevent
holdout creditors from using UK courts to sue HIPCs for
debt repayment. Although this act is limited in scope,26 it
provides a useful example of how local legislative changes
in key jurisdictions can go a long way in addressing global
problems.

24 For another interesting proposal, see Paris and Wyplosz (2014).


25 For a list and detailed table of past debt restructurings since 1950, see
Das, Papaioannou and Trebesch (2012).
26 The act applies only to HIPCs and will expire with the HIPC Initiative.

16 CENTRE FOR INTERNATIONAL GOVERNANCE INNOVATION

Third, more attention should be given to the role of


international investment agreements (IIAs) in sovereign
debt restructuring. In a short article on this topic,
Kevin Gallagher (2012) discusses how sovereign debt
restructuring is seen as grounds for private bondholders
to file arbitral claims under IIAs, notes that safeguards
under IIAs are limited, and warns that if claims against
sovereign debt restructuring become more widespread
they could threaten the already fragile regime for financial
crisis recovery. Research on the role of IIAs in debt
restructuring is still in its infancy, but the early work
of Gallagher and others suggests that this is a crucial
area of inquiry and future action, especially if trade and
investment agreements continue to multiply.27
This paper has outlined the issues at the heart of sovereign
debt restructuring and the main proposals for improving
crisis prevention and management in this crucial area
with the aim of facilitating the global consultations. These
proposals, as well as the underlying assessments they are
based on, are the subject of serious debate and discussion
among scholars, policy makers, CSOs and private market
actors. In other words, this paper frames the broad
parameters of the current debate over how best to govern
sovereign debt restructuring. Understanding, engaging
with and advancing this debate are the necessary first
steps.

WORKS CITED
Amador, Manuel. 2003. A Political Economy Model of
Sovereign Debt Repayment. http://www.stanford.
com/~amador/debt.pdf.
Barro, R. 1995. Optimal Debt Management. NBER
Working Paper No. 5327.
Bi, Ran, Marcos Chamon and Jeromin Zettelmeyer. 2011.
The Problem That Wasnt: Coordination Failures in
Sovereign Debt Restructurings. IMF Working Paper
11/265. November.
Blyth, Mark. 2013. Austerity: The History of a Dangerous Idea.
New York, NY: Oxford University Press.
Bolton, Patrick and Olivier Jeanne. 2002. Sovereign Debt
Structuring and Restructuring: An Incomplete Contracts
Approach. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Borensztein, Eduardo, and Ugo Panizza. 2008. The Costs
of Sovereign Default. IMF Working Paper 08/238.
October.

27 The Comprehensive Economic and Trade Agreement (CETA)


between Canada and the European Union contains provisions related
to sovereign debt restructuring. See page 184 of CETA, available
at
http://trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2014/september/
tradoc_152806.pdf.

Sovereign Debt Restructuring: Issues Paper


Boughton, James, Skylar Brooks and Domenico Lombardi.
2014. IMF Lending Practices and Sovereign Debt
Restructuring. CIGI Policy Brief No. 41. June. www.
cigionline.org/publications/imf-lending-practicesand-sovereign-debt-restructuring.

Devereux, Charlie, and Bob Van Voris. 2014. Argentina


Seeks Talks with Bondholders to Avert Default.
Bloomberg. June 18. www.bloomberg.com/news/201406-17/argentina-seeks-to-skirt-court-decision-bychanging-bond-terms.html.

Bradley, Michael and Mitu Gulati. 2013. Collective Action


Clauses for the Eurozone: An Empirical Analysis
Review of Finance.

Eaton, Jonathan and Mark Gerssovitz. 1981. Debt with


Potential Repudiation: Theoretical and Empirical
Analysis. Review of Economic Studies 48 (2): 289309.

Bradley, Michael, James D. Cox and Mitu Gulati. 2010. The


Market Reaction to Legal Shocks and Their Antidotes:
Lessons from the Sovereign Debt Market. Journal of
Legal Studies 39 (1): 289324.

Eichengreen, Barry. 2003. Restructuring Sovereign Debt.


Journal of Economic Perspectives 17 (4): 7598.

Brooke, Martin, Rhys Mendes, Alex Pienkowski and Eric


Santor. 2013. Sovereign Default and State-Contingent
Debt. Bank of Canada joint study with the Bank of
England.
Brooks, Skylar, Martin Guzman, Domenico Lombardi and
Joseph E. Stiglitz. 2015. Identifying and Resolving InterCreditor and Debtor-Creditor Equity Issues in Sovereign
Debt Restructuring, CIGI Policy Brief No. 53. January.
www.cigionline.org/publications/identifying-andresolving-inter-creditor-and-debtor-creditor-equityissues-sovereign-de.
Brooks, Skylar, Domenico Lombardi and Ezra
Suruma. 2014. African Perspectives on Sovereign
Debt Restructuring. CIGI Commentary. August.
w w w. c i g i o n l i n e . o r g / p u b l i c a t i o n s / a f r i c a n perspectives-sovereign-debt-restructuring.
Buchheit, Lee C. and G. Mitu Gulati. 2010. Responsible
Sovereign Lending and Borrowing. Law and
Contemporary Problems 73: 6392.
Buchheit, Lee C., G. Mitu Gulati and Ignacio Tirado.
2013. The Problem of Holdout Creditors in Eurozone
Sovereign Debt Restructuring. Duke Law Working
Paper.
Buchheit, Lee C., Anna Gelpern, G. Mitu Gulati, Ugo
Panizza, Beatrice Weder di Mauro and Jeromin
Zettelmeyer. 2013b. Revisiting Sovereign Bankruptcy.
Committee on International Economic Policy and
Reform. October.
Chamon, M. and Mauro, P. 2005. Pricing Growth-Indexed
Bonds. IMF Working Paper No. WP/05/216.
Das, Udaibir S., Michael G. Papaioannou and Christopher
Trebesch. 2012. Sovereign Debt Restructurings 19502010: Literature Survey, Data, and Stylized Facts. IMF
Working Paper/12/203. August.
DellAriccia, G., I. Schnabel and J. Zettlemeyer. 2002.
Moral Hazard and International Crisis Lending: A
Test. IMF Working Paper 02/181. October.

. 2006. Policy Proposals for Restructuring


Unsustainable Sovereign Debt. In The New Public
Finance, edited by Inge Kaul and Pedro Conceicao. New
York, NY: Oxford University Press.
Ellmers, Bodo. 2014. United Nations Develops New
Debt Workout Mechanism. Eurodad, July 23. http://
eurodad.org/Entries/view/1546243.
Erce, Aitor. 2013. Sovereign Debt Restructuring and the
IMF: Implications for Future Official Interventions.
Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, Globalization and
Monetary Policy Institute. Working Paper No. 143.
Eurodad. 2009. A Fair and Transparent Debt Work-out
Procedure: 10 Core Civil Society Principles. December.
www.eurodad.org/files/Eurodad_debt_workout_
principles_FINAL.pdf.
Fischer, Stanley. 2003. Globalization and Its Challenges:
Richard T. Ely Lecture. American Economic Review 93
(May): 130.
Frankel, Jeffrey. 2014. Sovereign Debt at Square One.
Project Syndicate, July 24. www.project-syndicate.org/
commentary/jeffrey-frankel-explains-why-a-recentus-supreme-court-ruling-leaves-creditors-and-debtorsworse-off.
Gallagher,
Kevin
P.
2012.
Mission
Creep:
International
Investment
Agreements
and
Sovereign
Debt
Restructuring.
International
Institute for Sustainable Development. January 12.
www.iisd.org/itn/2012/01/12/mission-creepinternational-investment-agreements-and-sovereigndebt-restructuring-3/.
Gelpern, Anna, and Mitu Gulati. 2004. How CACs Became
Boilerplate, or the Politics of Contract Change, Working
Paper Series. IPD Task Force on Debt Restructuring and
Sovereign Bankruptcy.
Gitlin, Richard. 2014. Presentation to the IMFs Executive
Board, January 16.

Skylar Brooks and Domenico Lombardi 17

CIGI Papers no. 64 April 2015


Gitlin, Richard and Brett House. 2014. A Blueprint for
a Sovereign Debt Forum. CIGI Papers No. 27. March.
w w w. c i g i o n l i n e . o rg / p u b l i c a t i o n s / b l u e p r i n t sovereign-debt-forum.
Gulati, Mitu, Christoph Trebesch and Jeromin Zettelmeyer.
2012. The Greek Debt Exchange: An Autopsy.
September 11. http://av.r.ftdata.co.uk/files/2012/09/
The-Greek-Debt-Exchange-An-Autopsy.pdf.
Gulati, Mitu and Mark Weidemaier. 2014. A Peoples
History of Collective Action Clauses, Virginia Journal
of International Law 54: 1.
Haldane, A. and J. Scheibe. 2004. IMF Lending and
Creditor Moral Hazard. Bank of England Working
Paper No. 216.
Haley, James A. 2013. Sovereign Bankruptcy in the New
Age of Uncertainty. The New Age of Uncertainty (CIGI
blog). October 17. www.cigionline.org/blogs/newage-of-uncertainty/sovereign-bankruptcy-new-age-ofuncertainty.
. 2014. Sovereign Debt Restructuring: Old Debates, New
Challenges. CIGI Papers No. 32. May. www.cigionline.
org/publications/sovereign-debt-restructuring-olddebates-new-challenges.Helleiner, Eric. 2008. The
Mystery of the Missing Sovereign Debt Restructuring
Mechanism. Contributions to Political Economy 27:
91113.
Helleiner, Eric. 2008. The Mystery of the Missing
Sovereign
Debt
Restructuring
Mechanism.
Contributions to Political Economy 27: 91113.
. 2009. Filling a Hole in Global Financial
Governance? The Politics of Regulating Sovereign Debt
Restructuring. In The Politics of Global Regulation,
edited by Ngaire Woods and Walter Mattli. Princeton,
NJ: Princeton University Press.
House, Brett, Hongying Wang and Miranda Xafa.
2014. Chinese Perspectives on Sovereign Debt
Restructuring. CIGI Commentary. July.

. 2014b. The Funds Lending Framework and


Sovereign Debt Preliminary Considerations. IMF
Staff Report. June.
Jeanne, O. and J. Zettlemeyer. 2005. The Mussa Theorem
(and Other Results on IMF-Induced Moral Hazard).
IMF Staff Papers 52, Special Issue.
Jubilee USA Network. 2012. Towards a Lasting
Solution to Sovereign Debt Problems. November.
http://jubileeusa.org/fileadmin/user_upload/
Resources/2013_Jubilee_USA_Files/Joint_CSO_
statement_on_debt_workout_mechanism_nov_2012_
EN.pdf.
Kamin, Steven. 2002. Identifying the Role of Moral Hazard
in International Financial Markets. International
Finance 7 (1).
Kolb, Robert W., ed. 2011. Sovereign Debt. John Wiley &
Sons, Inc.
Krueger, Anne. 2001. International Financial Architecture
for 2002: A New Approach to Sovereign Debt
Restructuring. Address to the National Economists
Club Annual Members Dinner, Washington, DC.
www.imf.org/external/np/speeches/2001/112601.htm.
Lane, T. and S. Phillips. 2000. Does IMF Lending Result in
Moral Hazard? IMF Working Paper 00/168, October.
Latindadd. 2014. Fin a los fondos buitre.
Pagina/12, July 11. www.pagina12.com.ar/diario/
economia/2-250473-2014-07-11.html.
Makoff, Gregory and Robert Kahn. 2015. Sovereign Bond
Contract Reform: Implementing the New ICMA Pari
Passu and Collective Action Clauses. CIGI Papers No.
56.
February.
www.cigionline.org/publications/
sovereign-bond-contract-reform-implementing-newicma-pari-passu-and-collective-action-c.
McBrady, M. R. and M. S. Seasholes. 2000. Bailing-in.
[mimeo]. Harvard Business School.

IMF. 2010. Greece: Staff Report on Request for Stand-By


Arrangement. IMF Country Report 10/110 May.

Mody, Ashoka. 2013. Sovereign Debt and its Restructuring


Framework in the Euro Area, Bruegel Working Paper
2013/05. August.

. 2013. Sovereign Debt Restructuring Recent


Developments and Implications for the Funds Legal
and Policy Framework. April. www.imf.org/external/
np/pp/eng/2013/042613.pdf.

Moodys Investor Service. 2012. Investor Losses


in Modern-Era Sovereign Bond Restructurings.
Sovereign Default Series. August. www.emta.org/
WorkArea/DownloadAsset.aspx?id=8419.

. 2014a. Strengthening the Contractual Framework


to Address Collective Action Problems in Sovereign
Debt Restructuring. Staff Report. September.

Ocampo, Jos Antonio. 2014a. Guest Post: Implications


of the US Supreme Court Ruling on Argentina.
Beyond BRICS (Financial Times blog), June 23.
http://blogs.ft.com/beyond-brics/2014/06/23/guestpost-implications-of-the-us-supreme-court-ruling-onargentina/.

18 CENTRE FOR INTERNATIONAL GOVERNANCE INNOVATION

Sovereign Debt Restructuring: Issues Paper


. 2014b. Guest Post: The UN Takes the First Step
to Debt Restructuring Beyond BRICS (Financial Times
blog), September 10. http://blogs.ft.com/beyondbrics/2014/09/10/guest-post-the-un-takes-the-firststep-to-debt-restructuring/.
Panizza, Ugo, Federico Sturzenegger and Jeromin
Zettelmeyer. 2009. The Economics and Law of
Sovereign Debt and Default. Journal of Economic
Literature 47 (3): 651698.
Paris, Pierre, and Charles Wyplosz. 2014. PADRE:
Politically Acceptable Debt Restructuring in the
Eurozone. Geneva Reports on the World Economy
Special Report 3. International Center for Monetary and
Banking Studies.
Paulus, Christoph G. and Steven T. Kargman. 2008.
Reforming the Process of Sovereign Debt Restructuring:
A proposal for a Sovereign Debt Tribunal. Presentation
to the UN Workshop on Debt, Finance and Emerging
Issues in Financial Integration, New York, April 8-9.

Schadler, Susan. 2012. Sovereign Debtors in Distress: Are


Our Institutions Up to the Challenge? CIGI Papers No. 6.
August. www.cigionline.org/publications/sovereigndebtors-distress-are-our-institutions-up-challenge.
. 2013. Unsustainable Debt and the Political Economy
of Lending: Constraining the IMFs Role in Sovereign Debt
Crises. CIGI Papers No. 19. October. www.cigionline.org/
publications/unsustainable-debt-and-political-economyof-lending-constraining-imfs-role-sovereign-de.
Shiller, R. 1993. Macro Markets: Creating Institutions for
Managing Societys Largest Economic Risks. Oxford:
Oxford University Press.
Shiller, R. 2003. The New Financial Order: Risk in the 21st
Century. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Schwarcz, Steven L. 2011. Facing the Debt Challenge of
Countries That Are Too Big To Fail. In Sovereign Debt,
edited by Robert W. Kolb. John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

Pitchford, Rohan and Mark L. J. Wright. 2010 Holdouts in


Sovereign Debt Restructuring: A Theory of Negotiation
in a Weak Contractual Environment. NBER Working
Paper No. 16632. December.

Spiegel, Shari. 2010. Excess Returns on Emerging


Market Bonds and the Framework for Sovereign Debt
Restructuring. In Overcoming Developing Country Debt
Crises, edited by Barry Herman, Jose Antonio Ocampo
and Shari Spiegel. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Ramcharan, Veronica. 2015. Resolving Sovereign


Debt Distress in the Caribbean: Towards a Heavily
Indebted Middle Income Country (HIMIC) Initiative.
Presentation at the G-24 Technical Group Meeting,
Beirut, Lebanon, March 2-3.

Stiglitz, Joseph and Martin Guzman. 2014. Argentinas


Griesafault. Project Syndicate, August 7. www.projectsyndicate.org/commentary/joseph-e--stiglitz-andmartin-guzman-argue-that-the-country-s-default-willultimately-harm-america.

Reinhart, Carmen M. and Kenneth S. Rogoff. 2009. This


Time Is Different. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University
Press.

Sturzenegger, Federico and Jeromin Zettelmeyer. 2007.


Debt Defaults and Lessons from a Decade of Crises.
Cambridge, MA: MIT.

. 2013. Financial and Sovereign Debt Crises: Some


Lessons Learned and Those Forgotten, IMF Working
Paper 13/266. December.

The Economist. 2013. An Illusory Haven: What


Lessons Should Investors Learn from the Argentine
and
Greek
Restructurings?
The
Economist,
April 20. www.economist.com/news/finance-andeconomics/21576391-what-lessons-should-investorslearn-argentine-and-greek-restructurings.

Rieffel, Lex. 2003. Restructuring Sovereign Debt: The Case


for Ad Hoc Machinery. Washington, DC: Brookings
Institution Press.
Ruban, O., S. Poon and K. Vonatsos. 2008. GDP
Linked Bonds: Contract Design and Pricing.
http://ssrn.com/abstract=966436.
Ruiz Diaz, Hugo. 2003. The Creation of an Arbitration
Tribunal on Debt: an Alternative Solution? On
the Position to Take as the CADTM. June.
www.oid-ido.org/IMG/pdf/Ruiz_Diaz_Hugo_The_
Creation_of_an_Arbitration_Tribunal_on_Debt_an_
Alternative_Solution_.pdf.

Tran, Hung. 2014. Presentation at the Peterson Institute


for International Economics, Washington, DC, April 8.
www.iie.com/events/event_detail.cfm?EventID=318.
Xafa, Miranda. 2014. Lessons from the Greek Debt
Restructuring for Future European Debt Crises. CIGI
Papers No. 33. June. www.cigionline.org/publications/
sovereign-debt-crisis-management-lessons-2012-greekdebt-restructuring.

Skylar Brooks and Domenico Lombardi 19

ABOUT CIGI
The Centre for International Governance Innovation is an independent, non-partisan think tank on international
governance. Led by experienced practitioners and distinguished academics, CIGI supports research, forms networks,
advances policy debate and generates ideas for multilateral governance improvements. Conducting an active agenda
of research, events and publications, CIGIs interdisciplinary work includes collaboration with policy, business and
academic communities around the world.
CIGIs current research programs focus on three themes: the global economy; global security & politics; and international
law.
CIGI was founded in 2001 by Jim Balsillie, then co-CEO of Research In Motion (BlackBerry), and collaborates with and
gratefully acknowledges support from a number of strategic partners, in particular the Government of Canada and the
Government of Ontario.
Le CIGI a t fond en 2001 par Jim Balsillie, qui tait alors co-chef de la direction de Research In Motion (BlackBerry). Il
collabore avec de nombreux partenaires stratgiques et exprime sa reconnaissance du soutien reu de ceux-ci, notamment
de lappui reu du gouvernement du Canada et de celui du gouvernement de lOntario.
For more information, please visit www.cigionline.org.

CIGI MASTHEAD
Managing Editor, Publications

Carol Bonnett

Publications Editor

Jennifer Goyder

Publications Editor

Vivian Moser

Publications Editor

Patricia Holmes

Publications Editor

Nicole Langlois

Graphic Designer

Melodie Wakefield

Graphic Designer

Sara Moore

Executive
President

Rohinton Medhora

Vice President of Programs

David Dewitt

Vice President of Public Affairs

Fred Kuntz

Vice President of Finance

Mark Menard

Communications
Communications Manager

Tammy Bender

[email protected] (1 519 885 2444 x 7356)

You might also like