Davidsson Entrepreneurship Support
Davidsson Entrepreneurship Support
Davidsson Entrepreneurship Support
2008 EDITION
Introduction
In this manuscript I will argue a) that at least in developed economies the rate
of new firm formation is crucially important for economic development; b) that it
varies considerably over time and space; c) that policy programs aimed at increasing
or supporting entrepreneurial activity have a disappointing track record, and d) that
institutional reform aiming at the creation and maintenance of a transparent and
stable formal institutional framework that is conducive to entrepreneurial activity is
the most suitable task for entrepreneurship policy. In support of my argument I will
build heavily on experiences from my own research because it is what I know best
but even more heavily on the 'big names' in this branch of research because it
represents the most compelling evidence. I will only make cursory references to other
parts of the now relatively voluminous field we call 'entrepreneurship research'. In
order to enhance the credibility of my conclusions I would like to emphasize that for
the most part they do not reflect what my own research has tried to prove; neither do
they reflect any ideology I had as baggage when first entering the field. Rather, they
are a reflection of what the totality of knowledge development in this area over more
than twenty years has led me to believe.
Entrepreneurship is important
There is little doubt that entrepreneurship is important. In theory,
entrepreneurship understood as the entry of new firms in the market drives the
market process and develops the economy through the following mechanisms (cf.
Davidsson, 2003, 2004a; Kirzner1, 1973):
It provides buyers with new choices which some of them will consider better
than extant alternatives.
If successful, it attracts followers that further augment the two above effects.
Empirical research supports the notion that entrepreneurship is important.
Based on data from the Global Entrepreneurship Monitor (GEM) an estimated 500
million people around the globe are involved in on-going or recent business start-ups
at any one time (Reynolds2, 2007; Reynolds, Bygrave, & Autio, 2004). This sheer
volume of the phenomenon makes it very important. In the late 1970s, David Birch3
sparked much of the political and academic interest in entrepreneurship with his
(surprise) finding that small firms created the bulk of all new jobs (Birch, 1979). This
finding has since been replicated in many countries/studies including my own
(Davidsson, Lindmark, & Olofsson, 1994, 1996), which also singled out new firm
formation as an important driver of regional economic well-being. Importantly, later
works attribute the positive effects either to the influx of new firms or to a small elite
of rapidly growing young firms rather than to the population of established small
firms (Birch & Medoff, 1994; Davidsson, Lindmark, & Olofsson, 1998). Newness is
closely linked to innovation. Regarding this topic Arrow4 (1983) has provided
theoretical rationales why small, owner-managed organizations can be expected to
be over represented as innovators as long as development costs are not prohibitive.
Careful empirical analysis by Acs and Audretsch (1990)5 largely confirms his
predictions.
Importantly, it is not only the net additions to the economy that drive
development, but the churning and displacement as well. While this goes to the
heart of Joseph Schumpeter's (1934) ideas of creative destruction the first part of
that notion seems easier to embrace than the second part. New firms improve the
economy not only by introducing newness that is in one way or the other more
efficient or effective; they also force inefficient firms out of business so that their
resources can be redeployed for better use. Similarly, if no firms exited an economy
at full capacity there would be no affordable physical or human resources available
for new start-ups. In my research this importance of the churning has been
indicated by gross measures of regional economic dynamism explaining more of the
development of regional economic well-being than what net measures can explain
(Davidsson et al., 1998). In a more sophisticated analysis using unique, longitudinal
data, Aviad and Vertinsky (2008) have recently shown empirically that exits of old
firms increase entry and that on average new entrants are more productive.
Persistent high local rates of exit, however, deter entry.
This alleged importance of entrepreneurship is not based on idiosyncrasies of
a few studies. Through a careful review of 87 analyses in 57 recent studies of high
quality, van Praag and Versloot (2007) found support that young and small firms
contribute heavily to employment creation both directly and via regional spill-over
as well as to productivity growth and high quality innovations. However, as the
authors point out this does not mean that larger and more established firms are in
any way unimportant, it is just that different categories of firm perform different roles
in the economic system. The review by van Praag et al. demonstrates that there is
little doubt that in developed economies, entry of individuals into selfemployment/business ownership, and of independent firms into the market, are
major forces in economic development6.
variation perhaps manageable reasons and this leads us to the topic of the next
section.
It is very difficult to manage the variation in entrepreneurship
A very popular idea, which also directed much of the early empirical research,
is that entrepreneurs are a breed apart; that their entrepreneurial inclination is the
result of some unique entrepreneurial personality that most of them have in common.
By and large, this is a false conjecture. It is likely rooted in a general human tendency
to seek reasons for outcomes in the characteristics of the actors even when these
characteristics have no influence on the outcome whatsoever what psychologists
have called the fundamental attribution error (Ross, 1977). Consequently the early,
personality-focused research yielded meagre results and fell into disrepute (Gartner,
1988). More recent, conceptually as well as methodologically more sophisticated
research has shown that personality does play a role in entrepreneurship (Baum &
Locke, 2004 Ciavarella, Buchholts, Riordan, Gatewood, & Stokes, 2004; Collins,
Hanges, & Locke, 2004). However, stable personality characteristics provide at best
a small part of the full explanation. More importantly, personality is not manageable
so knowledge of such relationships could be used for selection at best. The results
suggest that even for that limited purpose they would be rather blunt and ineffective
tools.
A consistent finding in many studies is that many business founders have
self-employed parents (Davidsson, 2004b) More recent research has ventured into
investigating the exact mechanism of this parental role model effect (Aldrich10,
Renzulli, & Langton, 1998). However, the relationship is very far from deterministic.
It is probably true in most countries and eras that a majority of business founders do
not have a close, parental role model and conversely that most children of
business founders do not choose an entrepreneurial career. And again we are
dealing with an effect that is not very useful for policy purposes; people have the
parents they have.
The third major type of explanation of entrepreneurial behaviour and success
on the individual level is Human Capital (Becker11, 1964) the comprehensiveness,
quality and suitability for the task of peoples education and work experience. Arnold
Cooper12 was one of the first to research the role of human capital for
entrepreneurship (Cooper, Gimeno-Gascon, & Woo, 1994). The effects found were
usually positive. This has been confirmed by other studies (e.g., Dahlqvist,
Davidsson, & Wiklund, 2000). However, while there is overwhelming evidence that
investing in general human capital is a good idea for nations, it is hardly something
policy makers would do for the specific purpose of furthering entrepreneurship in the
form of independent business start-ups. In the hypothetical case that they did there is
no guarantee the policy would be effective because for people with more valuable
education and experience the non-entrepreneurial alternatives at hand would also
increase in attractiveness (Gimeno, Folta, Cooper, & Woo, 1997). Besides, many of
the positive effects in an entrepreneurship context are ascribed to specific rather than
general human capital e.g., prior start-up experience and experience from the
particular industry (Davidsson & Honig, 2003; Shane, 2000) and these are not easy
for policy-makers to invest in.
Overall, the individual level determinants of entrepreneurial behaviour and
success do not appear very useful from an entrepreneurship policy point of view. For
one thing, they explain at best who becomes an entrepreneur; not how many will do
so. Additional limitations have been discussed above. This gives reason to look more
closely at aggregate level determinants. While research on such determinants has
been comparatively successful in terms of explanatory power a main lesson learnt
from such research is also that influencing the amount or quality of entrepreneurial
activity on, for example, the regional level is anything but easy. In the
aforementioned, harmonised seven-country study the conclusions were summarised
as follows:
Analysis of the processes associated with new firm births across seven
advanced market economiesindicates three processes having a positive
impact on firm birth rates:
As a case in point our own research (Davidsson et al., 1994, 1996) suggested
that government business development expenditure per capita had a positive effect
on gross start-up rates but no effect on net start-up rates. On a more detailed level,
we found that in both time periods the economic upturn of the late 1980s and the
deep recession of the early 1990s a particular, sparsely populated region in the
northern inland of Sweden consistently made the 'top ten' list of regions for gross
start-ups and equally consistently ended up among the bottom ten in net start-up
rates. This was also one of the regions receiving the highest government investments
in direct government support for business development. More recently Greene, Mole
and Storey (2007) have provided much more comprehensive evidence of the same
kind. Following the development of the 'disadvantaged' northern English region of
Teesside over three decades they conclude that while some effects on financing and
business advice can be noted, the total effects of the varied and rather massive
business development support investments this region has received are very limited.
Findings like these illustrate the difficulty of achieving any real effects when more
fundamental factors like relative costs and local demand are not supportive.
Consequently, the level of investment is hard to defend from a cost-benefit
perspective.
to very impressive figures in the aggregate (Davidsson et al., 1994, 1996; Delmar &
Davidsson, 2006).
The true, relative importance of 'mice' vs. 'gazelles' is likely to vary across
time and space. However, one thing about the alleged job creation prowess of
'gazelles' is worth noting here. Almost no studies distinguish between organic growth
and growth obtained through acquisition. From a job creation point of view this
distinction is crucial. Our analysis showed that the majority of jobs 'created' by highgrowing firms were in fact jobs taken over via acquisitions. Somewhat larger and
older gazelles in particular were unlikely to show much organic growth arguably
'true' job creation at all.
In all likelihood the economy needs both the large pools of start-ups and a
significant sub-population of higher potential firms among them. The former is
important for keeping incumbents on their toes and facilitates the making of as many
important discoveries of new business opportunities as possible while the latter
ascertains that the full potential of the more important discoveries be exploited to the
full, often via copying or acquisition of what was first initiated elsewhere.
This brings us to the second aspect of what to support: How can we make
individuals more prone to create these two types of business start-ups? Perhaps by
trying to change the individuals themselves? Such an exercise in social engineering
would hardly be successful. As regards relevant personality and personal
background attributes people essentially are what they are; trying to change these
through policy measures would be hard or impossible (not to mention unethical). It
makes sense for a society to invest in general human capital but probably not for the
narrow purpose of increasing entrepreneurial activity in the form of independent
business start-ups.
As regards structural characteristics of regions we have noted that important
structural determinants do not easily lend themselves to effective policy making for
the purpose of increasing the number of start-ups. So what options remain? Perhaps
the cultural dimension should be the target? Research has demonstrated that
entrepreneurial activities seem to vary systematically with certain dimensions of
'culture' or prevailing attitudes in a society (e.g., Davidsson, 1995; Shane, 1992).
However, while ideological competition for the voters' hearts and minds lie at the core
of the democratic political system, effective 'brainwashing' through a ruling party's
total control over the media and the education system most certainly does not.
Moreover, the main findings from my own research into the issue were that a)
possible cultural and structural determinants of entrepreneurial activities were highly
correlated, and b) the structural determinants basically the current make-up of the
human and business populations were much more important than their cultural
counterparts in explaining variations in levels of entrepreneurial activity (Davidsson,
1995; Davidsson & Wiklund, 1997). This indicates that to a considerable extent,
'culture' is an epiphenomenon that is influenced by the more fundamental structural
(probably including institutional) conditions that are the more direct determinants of
entrepreneurial activity. If this is the case successful direct manipulation of prevailing
attitudes if it were possible would not in and by itself have the expected effects on
the number and type of business start-ups that emerge.
region. Second, while the level of support is quite substantial in some countries and
regions way above the optimum in large parts of Europe would be my guess its
possible effects are still dwarfed by more fundamental forces like population growth;
industry structure; macro-economic swings and major technological breakthroughs.
For this reason micro level policies can at best expect to contribute on the margin.
Third, because of human ageing; the logic of promotion in organizations, and the
nature of the democratic political system, policy makers at all levels are relatively
unlikely to have thorough experience in their current role. This in combination with
the intricacies of the economic 'eco-system' increases the risk that the measures they
suggest and implement, while enthusiastic and well intended enough, will in fact be ill
conceived. Greene et al. (2007) give multiple examples of how specific policies are
recycled or resurrected over time although they did not prove successful the last time
it was tried, either. Even if well conceived there is considerable risk that at the local
level front line the implementation will be handled by individuals who are either under
qualified, under paid and unengaged, or by local champions who are enthusiastic
enough but who have a tendency to tweak the intentions of the policy towards
benefiting the visible, local businesses that exist today rather than to the optimal
working of the economic system, including the more effective competitor that could
have emerged tomorrow had not the policy been biased against it.
For these reasons I have come to believe that direct, selective, tax-funded
support to business start-up activity that is economically efficient is largely a mission
impossible. We simply lack the evidence that the tax funds spent that way does any
more good to the economy than the spending or saving consumers or firms would
choose to do, had they not been taxed that amount of money. Commercial providers
and non-government organizations (NGOs) that offer selective, micro level
assistance do not face the same impossibilities; at least not to the same extent.
While the task at hand is difficult enough for them as well, market pressures and/or
voluntary work may lower costs to the point that a positive net result is more
achievable. At the very least they do not face the dilemma of possible sub-optimal
use of taxpayers' contributions.
Instead I have come to embrace the idea that the proper way for policy to
improve the contributions of entrepreneurial action lies in the development of sound,
formal institutions. This largely means laws and law enforcement regarding such
things as taxation, property rights, bankruptcy, employment contracts, etc. This
theme will be elaborated on in the next section.
Institutions are the answer
10
11
12
institutional framework cannot at this point rely solely on solid empirical evidence; it
also requires some faith in the logic of the underlying argument.
Economists and not only those who regard themselves institutionalists
have of course long argued that changes in taxes and regulations are the key to
increased entrepreneurship. However, arguments based on basic training in
economics rather than the current frontier of the discipline (which may be the case
with lobbyists and politically coloured journalists) are often based on assumptions of
a single type of greedy, self-interested actors and over confidence in immediate
behavioural effects among current business owner-managers. Developing to the full
a fruitful institutional approach is beyond the scope of this paper and the abilities of
its author. Besides, such work should start from a careful analysis of the institutions
currently in place in a particular country, along with their likely effects. However, as a
rough, first sketch; let us assume there are different types of potential entrepreneurs:
optimists, realists and pessimists. On another dimension, let us assume there are the
greedy willing to do anything for personal gain the average, and the altruistic
the latter prone to engage in good deeds despite personal monetary loss (or
opportunity cost) and sometimes even though the project may be doomed because it
is not financially sustainable. On a third dimension let us assume they have either
low, medium or high levels of general human capital. We can now ask the
fundamental questions that should guide the (re-)design of the institutional
framework.
1. Who do we want to engage in entrepreneurship? For example, what does it
mean for an economy if realists have very good, objective reasons to refrain from
engaging in business start-ups and only people with rose-colored glasses ever do it?
Is there any use in trying to convert pessimists at all? Should the framework entice
those with the highest levels of human capital to strike out on their own? Perhaps
they would get greater leverage from their talent as independents but then again
this might drain large, established organisations of so much talent that the leverage
from the resources these organisations represent is diminished so much that the
societal net effect becomes negative?
2. How will they define their role and their goals as a result of their early
experiences as entrepreneurs? An important insight is that the future orientation of
the firm is not carved in stone at inception. Rather, it will be shaped by early
experience in the entrepreneurial role as well as through learning from peers.
Entrepreneurs will gradually form or change their opinion as to whether it is worth the
effort to be innovative or to take on responsibility as an employer. Arguably, it is early
in their entrepreneurial career that these things are malleable; later on they may be
13
hard to change despite strong economic incentives to do so. In addition, the 'types'
as sketched above are not fixed; to a considerable extent the entire spectrum resides
within each individual. Consequently, aspects of the institutional framework can
appeal to and cultivate either the greedier or the more altruistic side of those who
venture into entrepreneurship.
3. How will they go about pursuing their goals? This speaks to Baumol's (1990) main
point. How can the institutional framework be shaped so that the way for the greedy
to achieve their goals is aligned with societal interests? So that the altruists find room
to do their thing in financially sustainable ways? And how can it entice not only
diehard optimists but also realists and perhaps even some pessimists to engage in
risky endeavours with outcomes that are highly uncertain but potentially very
beneficial for themselves and society?
Again, this is a sketchy outline by an amateur institutionalist. However, this is
where my experience from 20 odd years of entrepreneurship research has led me to
suggest policy makers look: to the experts in analysing the likely effects of current
and possible future institutional arrangements (see, e.g., Henrekson, 2007). This
advice comes with several caveats. First, there is reason to be alert to the possibility
of self-interested greed as the dominant assumption about humans underlying the
analysis. Importantly, a productive overview of institutions should not focus too
narrowly on the conditions for new and emerging firms in some 'absolute' sense but
also consider the 'other' alternative. That is, the self-employment option relative to
employment, studies, retirement or unemployment; staying self-employed without
employees relative to becoming an employer; the institutional conditions for start-ups
relative to those facing incumbent firms, etc. In addition, the analysis and possible
change should not only consider incentives for prospective entrepreneurs in a narrow
sense but also the incentives of various parts of the surrounding, supporting system
such as universities; private investors; venture capitalists, etc. For this purpose a
competence bloc perspective may prove fruitful (Eliasson, 2000).
Further, the secondary effects of institutional change in domains other than
entrepreneurship also need to be considered; otherwise what in a narrow
assessment looks like a successful change may in fact be detrimental in the bigger
picture. To have their full effect institutional arrangements also need to be
transparent and stable. Therefore, although initial changes are often likely to be
necessary it is imperative that the most fundamental of the conditions for
entrepreneurial activity achieve an almost 'constitutional' status. Therefore, overly
enthusiastic introduction of controversial measures that risk being reversed when
political majorities change may do more harm than good. Finally, no wonders should
14
be expected in the short run. Yes, the changes will likely affect at least marginally
the behaviour of some current business owner-managers. And yes again, others may
not change their behaviour directly but the outcome of their unchanged efforts may
change (for example, them may become more profitable) and this may indirectly
change their behaviour in the next time period. The main effect, however, is likely to
emerge over time as a change in the size and orientation of the population of
entrepreneurs and entrepreneurial ventures. Hence, considerable patience is called
for; there are no quick fixes.
References
Acs, Z. J., & Audretsch, D. B. (1990). Innovation and Small Firms. Cambridge, MA:
MIT Press.
Aldrich, H. E., Renzulli, L., & Langton, N. (1998). Passing on privilege: Resources
provided by self-employed parents to their self-employed children. In K. Liecht
(Ed.), Research is Social Stratification and Mobility. Greenwich, CT: JAI
Press.
Arrow, K. (1983). Innovation in small and large firms. In J. Ronen (Ed.),
Entrepreneurship (pp. 15-28). Lexington, MA: Lexington Books.
Aviad, P., & Vertinsky, I. (2008). Firm exits as a determinant of new entry: Is there
evidence of local creative destruction? Journal of Business Venturing, 23(3),
280-306.
Baum, J. R., & Locke, E. A. (2004). The relationship of entrepreneurial traits, skill,
and motivation to subsequent venture growth. Journal of Applied Psychology,
89(4), 587-598.
Baumol, W. J. (1990). Entrepreneurship: Productive, unproductive and destructive.
Journal of Political Economy, 98(5), 893-921.
Becker, G. S. (1964). Human capital. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.
Birch, D. L. (1979). The Job Generating Process. Cambridge, MA: MIT Program on
Neighborhood and Regional Change.
Birch, D. L., & Medoff, J. (1994). Gazelles. In L. C. Solmon & A. R. Levenson (Eds.),
Labor Markets, Employment policy and Job Creation. Boulder and London:
Westview Press.
Carlsson, B. (2002). Institutions, entrepreneurship, and growth: Biomedicine and
polymers in Sweden and Ohio. Small Business Economics, 19(2), 105-121.
Ciavarella, M. A., Buchholts, A. K., Riordan, C. M., Gatewood, R. D., & Stokes, G. S.
(2004). The Big Five and venture survival: Is there a linkage? Journal of
Business Venturing, 19, 465-483.
15
Collins, C. J., Hanges, P. J., & Locke, E. A. (2004). The relationship of achievement
motivation to entrepreneurial behavior: A meta-analysis. Human
Performance, 17(1), 95-117.
Cooper, A. C., Gimeno-Gascon, F. J., & Woo, C. Y. (1994). Initial human and
financial capital as predictors of new venture performance. Journal of
Business Venturing, 9(5), 371-395.
Dahlqvist, J., Davidsson, P., & Wiklund, J. (2000). Initial conditions as predictors of
new venture performance: a replication and extension of the Cooper et al.
study. Enterprise and Innovation Management Studies, 1(1), 1-17.
Davidsson, P. (1989). Continued Entrepreneurship and Small Firm Growth. Doctoral
dissertation. Stockholm: Stockholm School of Economics.
Davidsson, P. (1995). Culture, structure and regional levels of entrepreneurship.
Entrepreneurship & Regional Development, 7, 41-62.
Davidsson, P. (2003). The domain of entrepreneurship research: Some suggestions.
In J. Katz & D. Shepherd (Eds.), Cognitive Approaches to Entrepreneurship
Research (Vol. 6, pp. 315-372). Oxford, UK: Elsevier/JAI Press.
Davidsson, P. (2004a). Researching Entrepreneurship. New York: Springer.
Davidsson, P. (2004b). Role models and perceived social support. In W. B. Gartner,
K. G. Shaver, N. M. Carter & P. D. Reynolds (Eds.), Handbook of
Entrepreneurial Dynamics: The Process of Business Creation (pp. 179-185).
Thousand Oakes: Sage.
Davidsson, P., & Henrekson, M. (2002). Institutional determinants of the prevalence
of start-ups and high-growth firms: Evidence from Sweden. Small Business
Economics, 19(2), 81-104.
Davidsson, P., & Honig, B. (2003). The role of social and human capital among
nascent entrepreneurs. Journal of Business Venturing, 18(3), 301-331.
Davidsson, P., Lindmark, L., & Olofsson, C. (1994). Dynamiken i svenskt nringsliv
(Business Dynamics in Sweden). Lund, Sweden: Studentlitteratur.
Davidsson, P., Lindmark, L., & Olofsson, C. (1996). Nringslivsdynamik under 90talet (Business Dynamics in the 90s). Stockholm: NUTEK.
Davidsson, P., Lindmark, L., & Olofsson, C. (1998). Smallness, newness and
regional development. Swedish Journal of Agricultural Research, 28(1), 5771.
Davidsson, P., & Wiklund, J. (1997). Values, beliefs and regional variations in new
firm formation rates. Journal of Economic Psychology, 18, 179-199.
Delmar, F., & Davidsson, P. (2006). High-growth firms and their contribution to
employment: The case of Sweden 1987-96. In P. Davidsson, F. Delmar & J.
16
17
Reynolds, P. D., & Curtin, R. T. (2008). Business Creation in the United States:
Panel Study of Entrepreneurial Dynamics II Initial Assessment. Foundations
and Trends in Entrepreneurship, 4(3).
Reynolds, P. D., Storey, D. J., & Westhead, P. (1994). Cross-national comparisons
of the variation in new firm formation rates. Regional Studies, 28(4), 443-456.
Ross, L. (1977). The intuitive psychologist and his shortcomings: Distortions in the
attribution process. In L. Berkowitz (Ed.), Advances in Experimental Social
Psychology (Vol. 10, pp. 173-240). Orlando, FL: Academic Press.
Schumpeter, J. A. (1934). The Theory of Economic Development. Cambridge: MA:
Harvard University Press.
Shane, S. (1992). Why do some societies invent more than others? Journal of
Business Venturing, 7, 29-46.
Shane, S. (2004). Encouraging university entrepreneurship? The effect of the BayhDole Act on university patenting in the United States. Journal of Business
Venturing, 19, 127-151.
Small Business Economics (2005). Vol. 24, Iss. 3 (special issues devoted to
analyses of GEM data).
Small Business Economics (2006). Vol. 26, Iss. 4 (special issues devoted to
analyses of GEM data).
Storey, D. J. (1994). Understanding the Small Business Sector. London: Routledge.
Storey, D. J. (2000). Six steps to heaven: Evaluating the impact of public policies to
support small businesses in developed economies. In D. Sexton & H.
Landstrm (Eds.), The Blackwell Handbook of Entrepreneurship (pp. 176193). Oxford, MA: Blackwell Business.
van Praag, C. M., & Versloot, P. H. (2007). The economic benefits and costs of
entrepreneurship: A review of the research. Foundations and Trends in
Entrepreneurship, 4(2), 65-154.
Wennekers, S., Stel, A., Thurik, A. R., & Reynolds, P. D. (2005). Nascent
entrepreneurship and the level of economic development. Small Business
Economics, 24, 293-309.
Wong, P. W., Ho, Y. P., & Autio, E. (2005). Entrepreneurship, innovation and
economic growth: Evidence from GEM data. Small Business Economics, 24,
335-350.
Endnotes
18
10
11
12
Israel Kirzner was the 2006 recipient of the International Award for Entrepreneurship and Small
Business Research (from 2009 Global Award for Entrepreneurship Research); the most
prestigious award in this field of research.
Paul Reynolds was the initiator and coordinator of GEM and the 2004 recipient of the International
Award for Entrepreneurship and Small Business Research (cf. endnote #1).
David Birch was the recipient of the 1996 (inaugural) International Award for Entrepreneurship
and Small Business Research (cf. endnote #1).
Kenneth Arrow was (with J. Hicks) the 1972 recipient of The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in
Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel (generally known as he Nobel Prize in
Economics).
David Audretsch and Zoltan Acs were the recipients of the 2001 International Award for
Entrepreneurship and Small Business Research (cf. endnote #1).
However, this may not be true for developing economies. GEM analyses suggest that in lowincome countries, which tend to have very high and often necessity based self-employment,
investing in the management qualities of their population and fostering the exploitation of scale
economies through foreign direct investment and the growth of young businesses may be
relatively more important (Wennekers, Stel, Thurik, & Reynolds, 2005).
David Storey was the recipient of the 1998 International Award for Entrepreneurship and Small
Business Research (cf. endnote #1).
William Gartner was the recipient of the 2005 International Award for Entrepreneurship and Small
Business Research (cf. endnote #1).
William Baumol was the recipient of the 2003 International Award for Entrepreneurship and Small
Business Research (cf. endnote #1).
Howard Aldrich was the recipient of the 2000 International Award for Entrepreneurship and Small
Business Research (cf. endnote #1).
Gary Becker was the 1992 recipient of of The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in
Memory of Alfred Nobel (generally known as he Nobel Prize in Economics) .
Arnold Cooper was the recipient of the 1997 International Award for Entrepreneurship and Small
Business Research (cf. endnote #1).
19