Unique Option Pricing Measure With Neither Dynamic Hedging Nor Complete Markets
Unique Option Pricing Measure With Neither Dynamic Hedging Nor Complete Markets
Nassim Nicholas Taleb School of Engineering, NYU, & Former Option Trader
AbstractProof that under simple assumptions, such as constraints of Put-Call Parity, the probability measure for the
valuation of a European option has the mean derived from
the forward price which can, but does not have to be the
risk-neutral one, under any general probability distribution,
bypassing the Black-Scholes-Merton dynamic hedging argument,
and without the requirement of complete markets and other
strong assumptions. We confirm that the heuristics used by
traders for centuries are both more robust, more consistent, and
more rigorous than held in the economics literature. We also
show that options can be priced using infinite variance (finite
mean) distributions.
I. BACKGROUND
2 See also Green and Jarrow (1987) and Nachman(1988). We have known
about the possibility of risk neutral pricing without dynamic hedging since
Harrison and Kreps (1979) but the theory necessitates extremely strong and
severely unrealistic assumptions, such as strictly complete markets and a
multiperiod pricing kernel
1 Further,
in a case of scientific puzzle, the exact formula called "BlackScholes-Merton" was written down (and used) by Edward Thorp in a
heuristic derivation by expectation that did not require dynamic hedging, see
Thorpe(1973).
II. P ROOF
Define C(St0 , K, t) and P (St0 , K, t) as European-style call
and put with strike price K, respectively, with expiration t, and
S0 as an underlying security at times t0 , t t0 , and St the
possible value of the underlying security at time t.
A. Case 1: Forward as risk-neutral measure
Rt
1
Define r = tt
t0 rs ds,Rthe return of a risk-free money
0
t
1
market fund and = tt
t0 s ds the payout of the asset
0
(continuous dividend for a stock, foreign interest for a currency).
We have the arbitrage forward price FtQ :
FtQ = S0
(1 + r)(tt0 )
S0 e(r)(tt0 )
(1 + )(tt0 )
TABLE I
M AIN PRACTICAL DIFFERENCES BETWEEN THE DYNAMIC HEDGING
ARGUMENT AND THE STATIC P UT-C ALL PARITY WITH SPEADING ACROSS
STRIKES .
Black-Scholes
Merton
Put-Call Parity
with Spreading
Type
Continuous rebalancing.
Interpolative
static hedge.
Market Assumptions
1)
Continuous
Markets, no gaps,
no jumps.
1)
Gaps
and
jumps acceptable.
Continuous
Strikes,
or
acceptable
number of strikes.
2) Ability to
borrow and lend
underlying asset
for single forward
date.
3) No transaction
costs in trading
asset.
Probability
Distribution
Market
Completeness
Achieved
through dynamic
completeness
Realism of
Assumptions
Low
High
Convergence
Pointwise
(1)
by arbitrage, see Keynes 1924. We thus call FtQ the future (or
forward) price obtained by arbitrage, at the risk-neutral rate.
Let FtP be the future requiring a risk-associated "expected
return" m, with expected forward price:
FtP = S0 (1 + m)(tt0 ) S0 em (tt0 ) .
(2)
Fitness
Reality
to
and
P =
fP d2 ,
(4)
(5)
FtP
(11)
from Equation 5
Z
fC (K) d1
fP (K) d1 =
Ft dQ K
(12)
Ft dQ ;
for all K
Now a Call spread in quantities
(13)
expressed as
d2 = 1
AK
AcK
d2 .
C(St0 , K, t) P (St0 , K, t)
+
=1
K
K
for all values of K, so
Z
Z
d2 ,
d1 =
AcK
AcK
F ORWARD
F
S
WHERE THE
(8)
III. C ASE
1
K
(9)
(10)
COMMENT
Harrison, J. M., & Kreps, D. M. (1979). Martingales and arbitrage in multiperiod securities markets. Journal of Economic
theory, 20(3), 381-408.
Haug, E. G. and Taleb, N. N. (2010) Option Traders use
Heuristics, Never the Formula known as Black-ScholesMerton Formula, Journal of Economic Behavior and Orga S106.
nizations, pp. 97A