Tocqueville in The Ottoman Empi - Ariel Salzmann

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 265

TOCQUEVILLE IN THE OTTOMAN EMPIRE

THE OTTOMAN EMPIRE


AND ITS HERITAGE
Politics, Society and Economy
edited by

Suraiya Faroqhi and Halil Inalcik


Advisory Board
Fikret Adanir Idris Bostan Amnon Cohen Cornell Fleischer
Barbara Flemming Alexander de Groot Klaus Kreiser
Hans Georg Majer Irne Mlikoff Ahmet Yas ar Ocak
Abdeljelil Temimi Gilles Veinstein Elizabeth Zachariadou

VOLUME 28

TOCQUEVILLE
IN THE
OTTOMAN EMPIRE
Rival Paths to the Modern State
BY

ARIEL SALZMANN

BRILL
LEIDEN BOSTON
2004

This book is printed on acid-free paper.

Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data


The Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data is available on
http://catalog.loc.gov

ISSN 1380-6076
ISBN 90 04 10887 4
Copyright 2004 by Koninklijke Brill NV, Leiden, The Netherlands
All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, translated, stored in
a retrieval system, or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic,
mechanical, photocopying, recording or otherwise, without prior written
permission of the publisher.
Authorization to photocopy items for internal or personal
use is granted by Brill provided that
the appropriate fees are paid directly to The Copyright
Clearance Center, Rosewood Drive 222, Suite 910
Danvers MA 01923, USA
Fees are subject to change.
printed in the netherlands

To my mother and father

This page intentionally left blank

CONTENTS

List of Illustrations ......................................................................


Preface ........................................................................................
List of Abbreviations ..................................................................
Note on Transliteration ............................................................

ix
xi
xiii
xv

Introduction: Tocquevilles Ghost ..................................................


In Search of an Archive ....................................................
The Old Rgime through an Ottoman Lens ..................
Vocabularies of Early Modernity ......................................

1
6
13
24

I. On a Map of Eurasia ............................................................


Edges of Empire ..................................................................
From the Inside Out ..........................................................
Movements of People, Commodities, and Capital ..........
Eurasia in Transition ..........................................................

31
38
52
60
71

II. The Sublime Porte and the Credit Nexus .................................. 75


Palace, Porte and Patronage .......................................... 78
Hierarchies of Service ........................................................ 92
Corporate Patrimonialism and the Reproduction
of Power .......................................................................... 102
Deyn- Devlet (Debt and State): Islamicate
High Finance .................................................................. 110
Completing the Circle ........................................................ 118
III. Government in the Vernacular ..................................................
Questions of Jurisdiction ....................................................
At the Interstices of Rural Administration ......................
Government in the Vernacular ..........................................
Checks and Balances ..........................................................
Final Entries ........................................................................

122
127
139
150
163
172

IV. Conclusion: The Paths Not Taken ........................................ 176


The Common Origins of the Modern State .................... 179
A Federalist Alternative? .................................................... 187

viii

The Diyarbekir Commune of 1819 .................................. 191


Of Democracy and the New Despotism .......................... 194

Glossary ...................................................................................... 201


Bibliography ................................................................................ 203
Index ............................................................................................ 235

LIST OF ILLUSTRATIONS

Figures
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
6.

A double page of a malikne register ..................................


A map of eighteenth-century Eurasia ..................................
Detail of page of a malikne register ....................................
Flow chart of shares in a malikne contract ........................
Diyarbekirs provincial boundaries in ux ..........................
The nal page of a New Order register ............................

Color Plates (between 200 and 201)


1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
6.

A farmer leads the procession of the guilds


The sultan and the grand vizier
The hierarchies of state
Janissaries race for their portion of rice
French and Russian ambassadors view the festivities
The sultan distributes gold coins

2
32
123
124
130
173

This page intentionally left blank

PREFACE

Exotic painters, hack journalists, and impoverished academics have


picked over the relics of the Ottoman old regime. Yet for some the
empire has not died. Whether it is the Islamists dream of a compassionate theocracy, a Balkan nationalists vow to avenge a medieval
defeat, or an American presidents blueprint for the new Iraq,
there is reason to question those who seek to remake its past.
Rather than braving this unsettled history alone, I have invited a
more seasoned traveler to join me. Alexis de Tocquevilles specter
lends this project a comparative slant while furnishing a conceptual
anchor to an inherently unmanageable topic. Those familiar with
my dissertation, Measures of State: Tax Farmers and the Ottoman
Ancien Rgime, (16951807) (Columbia University, 1995) will recognize themes and sources. However, the aims of the present work
are quite dierent. From a study on the political economy of tax
farming, it has become an inquiry into the origins of government
under the old regime.
This essay trespasses across many disciplinary boundaries. Courses
in sociology, language and history at Binghamton and Columbia universities with Ca[lar Keyder, Rhoads Murphey, and Kathleen Burrill
introduced me to the Ottoman Empire. Richard Bulliet, Donald
Quataert, John Mundy, and Charles Tilly shaped my historical
method and tolerated my eclecticism. In proseminars, conferences,
workshops, and over coee in New York City and Cincinnati, many
colleagues have patiently considered my ideas; my students have
inspired me.
Countless hours in the archives and many gifted scholars have
transformed me into an Ottomanist. I remain deeply indebted to my
hocalarm Mehmet Gen and Suraiya Faroqhi. Murat izaka, Mbahat Ktko[lu, Engin Akarl, Cornell Fleischer, Halil Sahillio[lu,
Nejat Gyn, (dris Bostan, Thomas Goodrich, and Rifa"at AbouEl-Haj never failed to answer my questions; rahmetli Jean-Pierre Thieck,
Glden Saryldz, Caroline Finkle, Tony Greenwood, Ne{e Erim,
Caroline and Andy Finkle shared tea and wisdom. zer Ergen,
Rifat zdemir and Mustafa ztrk tutored me in urban studies.
Halil (nalck kindly read this manuscript before publication and

xii

pointed out my errors. Despite their best eorts, more remain.


Naturally, these defects are mine alone.
Special thanks are reserved for those who contributed very directly
to the preparation of the manuscript: my editor at Brill, Trudy
Kamperveen, Betty Seaver who groomed the text; Paula Hible whose
artistry polished the maps. Jane Kepp, Geo Porter, Yksel Duman,
Sabri Ate{, and Markus Dressler took on editorial tasks. Materially,
the author beneted from the support of the Pratt Institute and New
York University. Two National Endowment for the HumanitiesAmerican Research Institute in Turkey grants (in 1994 and 1999)
allowed me to continue archival research and a writing fellowship
from American Council of Learned Societies 19992000 gave me a
respite from nearly a decade of teaching.
Gratitude goes to an extended family of friendsNoosha Baqi,
Carolle Charles, Jenny White, Selcuk Esenbel, Waheguru Pal Singh
Sidhu, Faruk Tabak, Paula Hible, Serpil Ba[c, Selim Deringil,
Elizabeth Thompson, Gaynor Ellis, Dan Goman, Shala Baqi and
Randy Martin who have always been there. The Abbasis of Kabul
and Vancouver, the Ziyabaksh-Tabari of Teheran, the Salzmanns of
London, the Marchettis of Perugia, and the Hanio[lus of Istanbul
fed and sheltered me during my travels. I remember with admiration and love those who have not lived to see this works completion: my art teachers, Kalman and Doris Kubinyi, my second mom
and Harlem activist, Ruth Johnson, my buddy and prisoner-rights
advocate, Felix Reyes, and my ever-deant aunt Marsha Weiland.
In the end, as in the beginning, my parents have given boundlessly to this project. I dedicate this work to my mother, Audrey
Pastor Salzmann and my father, Harold I. Salzmann, my rst teachers.

ABBREVIATIONS

AA
Belgeler
Belleten
BSOAS
CA
CB
CD
CDp
C?
CM
CMRS
CT
CZ
CSSH
DA
EA
EI 2
D.B}M
D.MKF
D}S
(A
(FM
IJMES
IJTS
I}MS
JTS
JESHO
JOAS
KK
MMD
M}S
POF
RMMM
SA

Aleppo Ahkm Defterleri, Ba{bakanlk Ar{ivi.


Belgelerle Trk Tarihi Dergisi.
Trk Tarih Kurumu Belleten.
Bulletin of the School of Oriental and African Studies.
Cevdet Askeriye, Ba{bakanlk Ar{ivi.
Cevdet Belediye, Ba{bakanlk Ar{ivi.
Cevdet Dahiliye, Ba{bakanlk Ar{ivi.
Cevdet Darphane, Ba{bakanlk Ar{ivi.
Cevdet (ktisat, Ba{bakanlk Ar{ivi.
Cevdet Maliye, Ba{bakanlk Ar{ivi.
Cahiers de Monde Russe et Sovietique.
Cevdet Timar, Ba{bakanlk Ar{ivi.
Cevdet Zaptiye, Ba{bakanlk Ar{ivi.
Comparative Studies in Society and History.
Diyarbekir Ahkm Defterleri, Ba{bakanlk Ar{ivi.
Erzurum Ahkm Defterleri Ba{bakanlk Ar{ivi.
Encyclopaedia of Islam. New Edition.
Ba{muhsebe Kalemi, Ba{bakanlk Ar{ivi.
Bb- Defteri Mevkft Kalemi, Ba{bakanlk Ar{ivi.
Diyarbekir }eriye Sicilleri Milli Ktphane.
(slm Ansiklopedisi.
(stanbul niversitesi (ktisat Fakltesi Mecmuas.
International Journal of Middle East Studies.
International Journal of Turkish Studies.
Istanbul }eriye Mahkeme Sicilleri (microlm).
Journal of Turkish Studies.
Journal of the Economic and History of the Orient.
Journal of the American Oriental Society.
Kmil Kepeci, Ba{bakanlk Ar{ivi.
Maliye"den Mdevver Defterleri, Ba{bakanlk Ar{ivi.
Mardin }er"iye Sicilleri Milli Ktphane.
Prilozi za Orijentalnu Filologiyu i Istorija Jugoslavenskih Naroda
pod Turskom Valdavinom.
Revue du Monde Musulmane et de la Mediterrane.
Sivas Ahkm Defterleri, Ba{bakanlk Ar{ivi.

xiv
TKSA
TKSK
TTK
ZDMG

Topkap Saray Mzesi Ar{ivi.


Topkap Saray Mzesi Ktphanesi.
Trk Tarih Kurumu.
Zeitschrift der Deutschen Morgenldischen Geselleschaft.

NOTE ON TRANSLITERATION

English spellings have been used for commonly used Middle Eastern
terms (e.g. ulema, vizier, pasha) and place names. Terms with reference to the broader Islamic world (e.g. Naqshbandiyya, shah, waqf,
shaykh, etc.) have been transcribed from Arabic or Persian without
diacritics or italics.
I adhere to the New Redhouse Turkish-English Dictionary (Istanbul:
Redhouse Press, 8th Ed., 1986) for the transcription of Ottoman terminology with certain modications: to account for the Arabic soundand Persian plural, I use t and n respectively; and I have also
chosen to preserve the original Arabic articles (ul- al-) and Persian
ezafe (-i) instead of a compound: e.g. }eyh"l-(slam vs. }eyhlislam.
Throughout, I have attempted to reduce the number of diacritical
marks.
English readers unfamiliar with Turkish characters should note the
following: the is pronounced like the ch in church; the c
like j in jam; the { like sh in shoe. The [, though silent,
lengthens the preceding vowel. As for vowels: the is like the i
in slip; the as u in burr; and the is pronounced as the
u in French.

INTRODUCTION

TOCQUEVILLES GHOST

Distracted by the call to prayer that echoed across Divan Yolu from
the mosque at Sultan Ahmad, the guard did not notice as Alexis de
Tocqueville, the historian of the old regime and the scholar of modern government, slipped quietly past and entered the Prime Ministers
Archive.1
He strode briskly along the corridor and up a short ight of stairs,
then he turned left toward the reading hall. Heading toward the last
row of desks at the back of the room, he seated himself. The previous researcher had left at the desk a pile of red-bound registers.
Curious, Tocqueville opened the uppermost document (Fig. 1). He
bent over to get a better look at the unfamiliar handwriting before
realizing that what lay before him was a ledger of contracts issued
on village revenues in a remote province. Scrawled over its pages
were notations that spanned nearly a century, between 1697 and
1793.
As he peeled back the pages, tattered by time and use, Tocqueville
contemplated the profound changes in the style of the chancellery:
unlike the clear and comprehensive registers of the fteenth and sixteenth centuries, the ancien rgimes records seemed a patois of
script, cipher, and haphazard numbers.2 He sighed, thinking of the
clarity and intelligence of the men who compiled the rst cadastral
records of the early sixteenth century. These obscure, ill ordered,
incomplete, and slovenly pages did not bode well for the eighteenth-

1
Quotations are from The Old Rgime and the French Revolution, trans. Stuart Gilbert
(Garden City, N.Y.: Doubleday & Company, 1955). When meaning is unclear, I
have also checked Lancien rgime et la Rvolution, ed. J.-P. Mayer (Paris: ditions
Gallimard, 1967), and Franois Furet and Franoise Mlonios new edition of the
complete text and Tocquevilles notes, translated by Alan S. Kahan, 2 vols. (Chicago:
University of Chicago Press, 1998). Also see J.-P. Mayer, ed. Oeuvres compltes (Paris:
Gallimard, 1951) 12 vols.
2
For samples, see Mbahat S. Ktko[lu, Osmanl Belgelerinin Dili (Diplomatik)
(Istanbul: Kubbealt Akademisi Ktr ve San"at Vakf, 1998).

Fig. 1. A double page (reduced) from a malikne mukataa master register for the
province (eyalet) of Diyarbekir (MMD 9518:1718). On the right hand side there are
six entries; on the left, ve. The transactions between contractors, connected by
ourishes of the pen, span nearly a century. By permission of the Ba{bakanlk Ar{ivi.

century empire. They conjured up an image of a great power teetering


on the edge of an abyss.3
The Ottomans, he mused, once dominated the Mediterranean and
West Asia. Their neighbors regarded their political institutions as a
marvel of statecraft. The sultans civil servants formed tight administrative cadres, hierarchically organized, hardworking and honest.
His soldiers possessed an incomparable sprit de corps. What had
happened to this great state? The erce janissaries laid down their
muskets for pushcarts. Administrators, shunning their duties, distributed liberties and immunities far and wide. The sale of agricultural
tithes, internal taris, and oces impoverished the peasantry and
handicapped the merchant. Even the most powerful viziers and generals owed their political fortunes to Istanbuls Christian and Jewish
bankers.
Tocqueville felt as if he had entered a hall of mirrors: the semblances between prerevolutionary France and the Ottoman old regime
were uncanny. There was the strange synchrony of rise and fall,
reform and centralization that punctuated the eighteenth Christian
and the corresponding twelfth Islamic centuries. Administrative consolidation had begun under the absolutism of the Sun King, Louis
XIV, as well as under the reign of his contemporary, the HunterSultan, Mehmet IV. Similar to the scal reforms carried out by the
Bourbon minister Jean-Baptiste Colbert (d. 1683), the imperial program was pushed forward by a succession of Krpl viziers
(16561683) as well as by Sultan Ahmed IIIs Grand Vizier (brahim
Pasha (r. 17181730). As in France, years of dramatic innovation
were followed by decades of prevaricating, borrowing, special favors,
and venality. Stunned by the outcome of military engagements and
the nancial crises they wrought, the administrators of both regimes
threw themselves into a program of scal reform in the last quarter
century which culminated in the founding of a central treasury in

3
The progressive decay of the institutions stemming from the Middle Ages can
be followed in records of the period . . . In the thirteenth- and fourteenth-century
registers I examined, I was much impressed by the skill with which they were
drafted, their clarity, and the intelligence of the men compiling them, In later periods, however, there is a very denite falling o; the terriers become more and more
obscure, ill ordered, incomplete, and slovenly The Old Rgime, 16. Echoes of
Tocqueville ring through Bernard Lewis account of Ottoman decline (The Emergence
of Modern Turkey [Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1961, 3d ed., 2002]), 23.

France (1788) and the New Order sc ((rade-i Cedid Hazinesi ) in


Istanbul (1793). Yet this defensive centralization only hastened the
downfall of the ancien rgime and sealed the fate of both sovereigns,
Louis XVI in 1790 and Selim III in 1807.
Tocqueville suddenly grew disconcerted by his discovery: if the
policies and institutional patterns of the old regime were so similar
in character and so close in timing why did their paths suddenly
divide? Why did France cohere and the Ottoman Empire fall apart?
Tocqueville straightened his waistcoat and closed the ledger. Rising
from his seat, he turned his back on the reading room and walked
deliberately down the stairs, past the guards station and into the
street. A thin gure in quaint attire disappeared among the throngs
of tourists milling in the gardens and the teahouses of the Hippodrome.

Alexis de Tocqueville did not, of course, visit Istanbul or its archives.


Yet despite such imperious intellectual indierence to Frances
former ally, Tocquevilles ghost haunts the social scientic imagination of the Ottoman past.4 It is found in the model of the modern
state, whose genesis is encapsulated in his classic Lancien rgime et
la Revolution.5 As the popularizer of one of the most inuential
accounts of state centralization his thoughts about power and society

4
For a selection of his writings on Ottoman Algeria, see Alexis de Tocqueville,
De la colonie en Algrie, ed. Tzvetan Todorovo (Bruxelles: Editions Complexe, 1988);
and Tocqueville, Writings on Empire and Slavery, ed. Jennifer Pitts (Baltimore: Johns
Hopkins University Press, 2001). For one of the most sustained reections, Tocqueville,
Oeuvres complte, 3 pt. 1:129253.
5
On his life and works, see Andr Jardin, Tocqueville: A Biography, (New York:
Farrar Straus & Giroux, 1988); Cheryl B. Welch, De Tocqueville (Oxford and New
York: Oxford University Press, 2001). As Edward Shills notes (Tradition, Ecology
and Institution in the History of Sociology, in The Constitution of Society [Chicago:
University of Chicago Press, 1982], 359), the revival of Tocqueville in sociological
theory owes to Raymond Aron. See Raymond Aron, Les tapes de la pense sociologique. Montesquieu. Comte. Marx. Tocqueville. Durkheim. Pareto. Weber. (Paris: Gallimard,
1967), and Tocqueville retrouv, Tocqueville Review (1979): 823. I was grateful for
the opportunity to hear Cheryl Welch, Tocqueville between Two Worlds: France
and Algeria, and Joyce Appleby, Does It Matter That Tocqueville Got Some
Things Wrong? at the special colloquium on Sheldon S. Wolins Tocqueville Between
Two Worlds: The Making of a Political and Theoretical Life (Princeton: Princeton University
Press, 2001), held at the Institute of French Studies of New York University on
April 19, 2002.

in eighteenth-century Europe are still refracted across the canon of


political science and sociology.6 As an explanation for the rise of liberal government, his analysis rests on a uniquely European template of social and cultural institutions from which the prophets of
modernization have derived many of their most cherished theories
and policies.7 Extracting Europe from the interactive meridian of territorial states and oceanic empires and establishing the exceptionalism of the French political culture, the Tocquevillean model has also
misrepresented the nature of historical changethe modern state
could be implanted in foreign soils only through acculturation, capitalism, or colonialism.
There is, however, a paradox here. As our imaginary Tocqueville
discovers, France had no monopoly over the institutional features of
the ancien rgime. In rereading Tocquevilles classic through the
lter of a growing body of early modern European, Middle Eastern
and South Asian historiography, we nd abundant contradictions,
equivocations, and, at times, what seem to be willful misreading of
the past. As our understanding of the historical record broadens and
gains greater geographic equilibrium, so too the Islamic A.H. twelfth
or, alternately, the Christian A.D. eighteenth centuries come into
new focus, highlighting trends, processes, and phenomena that previous scholars once relegated to the margins. Comparison is not only
possible,8 it is also absolutely necessary to make sense of political
change in the past as well as to appreciate the peculiar stresses and
strains of regimes in transition.

6
The assumption that the state under the ancien rgime achieved a high degree
of institutional centralization appears to lter from Tocqueville through Marx to
modern social science, as David Waldner notes in State Building and Late Development
(Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1999), 31. See also Theda Skocpol, States and Social
Revolution: A Comparative Analysis of France, Russia, and China (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge
University Press, 1979), 178179. For Durkheim and the concept of centralization,
Bertrand Badie and Pierre Birnbaum, The Sociology of the State (Chicago: University
of Chicago Press, 1983), 12; and Charles Tilly, Reections on the History of
European State-Making, 64, in The Formation of National States in Western Europe, ed.
Idem (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1975).
7
The list is long. For some well known representatives in historical and political sociology, see S. N. Eisenstadt, Modernization: Protest and Change (Englewood Clis,
N.J.: Prentice Hall, 1966); and Lucian W. Pye and Sidney Verba, eds. Political Culture
and Political Development (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1965). See also Seymour
Drescher, Dilemmas of Democracy: Tocqueville and Modernization (Pittsburg: University of
Pittsburg Press, 1968).
8
Michael Mann (The Sources of Social Power [Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University

Far from rendering his study of the old regime obsolete, Tocquevilles
encounter with the Ottoman Empire might further our inquiry into the
inner workings of the early modern state while helping us to exorcize
a nineteenth ghost that still stalks the social scientic imagination.

In Search of an Archive
Like the terriers that provoked the real Tocquevilles exasperated assessment, the registers and loose documents of the Ottoman ancienrgime archive have disappointed and baed many researchers. Yet
this seeming unintelligibility or purported opacity is also a modern
aect, a result of the physical and ideological clean sweep of the historical record during the early nineteenth century. The selective purge
of history began well before the French Revolution and would become
part of the colonial project as well. During the Enlightenment, advocates of statistical knowledge tied numerical precision to the very
image of state power.9 Napoleons conquests in the Mediterranean
put these radical alterations to collective memory into eect.
Revolutionary engineers transformed the urban plan, beginning with
the razing of ghetto walls; and bureaucrats reshued the contents
of archives, from Papal Rome to Mamluk Cairo.10 By the early nineteenth century, historians too entered the fray, claiming the archives

Press, 1986] 1:502503) insists: Comparison fails . . . Consider for a moment one
obvious additional case, Islamic civilization. Why did the Miracle not occur there? . . .
One distinctive feature of Islam has been tribalism; another, that religious fundamentalism recurs powerfully, usually from desert tribal bases . . . The comparative
method has no solution to these problems, not because of any general logical or
epistemological defects it might have but because, in dealing with the problems we
simply do not have enough autonomous, analogical cases. For one response, see
Rifa'at 'Ali Abou-El-Haj, Formation of the Modern State: The Ottoman Empire Sixteenth to
Eighteenth Centuries (Albany: State University of New York Press, 1991). For some
important qualications of the comparative method, see R. Bin Wong, China
Transformed: Historical Change and the Limits of the European Experience (Ithaca: Cornell
University Press, 1997).
9
On the statistical school of Gttingen University, see Theodore M. Porter,
The Rise of Statistical Thinking, 1820 1900 (Princeton: Princeton University Press,
1986), 23. Ausgust Ludwig von Schlzer was an early student of the Ottoman
Empire and an exponent of the new scientic method.
10
On the impact on Italy, see Silvana Patriarca, Numbers and Nationhood: Writing
Statistics in Nineteenth-Century Italy (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press,
1996), 8.

as their own. Some, most notably Leopold von Ranke, who directed
the Prussian state archives, even busied themselves with reworking
the very raw materials of their craft.11 Already a symbol of the sovereignty of the modern nation state, industrial might and colonial
domination allowed the European archive to subsume the worlds
past.12
If revolutionary fervor remade the past, as Tocquevilles own disclaimer acknowledges (. . . [W]hen great revolutions are successful
their causes cease to exist and the very fact of their success has made
them incomprehensible), modern historians have had an even freer
hand in rewriting the history of states that failed to make the late
eighteenth-century transition.13 This is not simply because the historicist rewriting of the Ottoman past came from implacably hostile
and religiously-biased corners of the globe.14 Rather, the distortions
of the Ottoman past, owe rst and foremost to the empires loss of
sovereignty over the raw materials of memory. Unlike the defeated
colonizing nation-statesuch as France, which covered its retreat
from North American in 1763 and two century later from Algeria,15
clutching the g leaf of its archives de souveraintOttoman
archival materials were spoils that fell to the great powers or the
new states of the Balkans.16 After World War I, the Ottoman past

11
George G. Iggers, New Directions in European Historiography (Hanover, N.H.:
University of New England, 1984), 19.
12
E.g. Leopold von Ranke, The Ottoman and the Spanish Empires, in the Sixteenth and
Seventeenth Centuries (Philadelphia: Lea & Blanchard, 1845). This is not simply a question of ignoring the worlds history, but eectively of putting history itself on separate and unequal empirical and methodological tracks. Ranke justied very dierent
methods for classical, biblical, and non-Western history. Iggers, New Directions in
European Historiography, 1517.
13
Tocqueville, The Old Rgime, 5.
14
On the impact of orientalism on Ottoman history, see Suraiya Faroqhi, Approaching
Ottoman history: An Introduction to the Sources (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
1999); and for a critique of historicism on Indian historiography, see Dipesh
Chakrabarty, Provincializing Europe: Postcolonial Thought and Historical Dierence (Princeton:
Princeton University Press, 2000).
15
While robbing other peoples of their past, European states seem to have considered the return of archives to be part of the gentlemans rules of war. Article
22 of the treaty concluding the Seven Years War specied the return of French
administrative documentation. Zenab Esmat Rashed, The Peace of Paris, 1763
(Liverpool: University Press, 1951), 212229.
16
(smet Binark, ed., Ba{bakanlk Osmanl Ar{ivi Rehberi (Ankara: Turkish Republic
Ba{bakanlk Devlet Ar{ivileri Genel Mdrl[ Osmanl Ar{ivi Daire Ba{bakanl[,
1992), 1434.

was unceremoniously stripped away in colonial mandates. Just as in


the nineteenth-century Balkans, these materials would become the
contested inheritance of nation-states and the nations without states.
As many, often competing, national narratives superseded it, archival
dismemberment reinforced a partial and self-serving vision of the
features of a multicontinental and multiethnic state.17
Given the dispersal of the remains, the prospect of writing a comprehensive study of this Ottoman century, one that unies the disparate threads of provinces and center seems daunting indeed.
Although there is rapid growth in this eld, the historiography devoted
to the eighteenth century still falls far short of research carried out
on the empires earlier centuries.18 Together, the monographic research
devoted to the Ottoman past constitutes but a fraction of the accumulated studies on early modern Europe.19 Mindful of the long road
ahead and fully appreciating whence we have come, the task I propose is a very dierent one.
This study does not pretend to reconstruct the Ottoman Empires
political history as such. Rather, it seeks to construct a series of interpretive frames derived from the current state of Ottoman historiography that might scrutinize Tocquevilles legacy while reexamining
the paradoxes of power that obscure the past and remain an imped-

17
The literature continues to reinforce this divide by focusing on either provincial social and political history or on central-state institutional studies. For a sampling of studies that try to surmount this frontier, see Abdul-Karim Refeq, The
Province of Damascus, 17231783 (Beirut: Khayats, 1966); Stanford Shaw, Between Old
and New: The Ottoman Empire under Sultan Selim III, 17891807 (Cambridge: Harvard
University Press, 1971); Madeline Zil, The Politics of Piety: The Ottoman Ulema in the
Postclassical Age (16001800) (Minneapolis: Bibliotheca Islamica, 1988); T. Na and
R. Owen, eds., Studies in Eighteenth Century Islamic History (Carbondale: University of
Southern Illinois Press, 1977); Robert W. Olson, The Siege of Mosul and OttomanPersian Relations, 171843 (Bloomington: Indian University Press, 1975). One of the
most comprehensive studies to date on Ottoman scality is Yavuz Cezar, Osmanl
Maliyesinde Bunalm ve De[i{im Dnemi XVIII Yzyldan Tanzimat"a Mali Tarih (Istanbul:
Alan Yaynclk, 1986).
18
Leaving to one side Hamilton A. R. Gibb and Harold Bowens outdated
overview of the Arab provinces, (Islamic Society and the West: A Study of the Impact
of Western Civilization on Moslem Culture in the Near East, 2 vols. [London: Oxford
University Press, 1950 and 1957]) an introduction to the last generation of eighteenth-century studies may to be found in Bruce McGowan, The Age of the Ayan,
in An Economic and Social History of the Ottoman Empire, ed. Halil (nalck with Donald
Quataert (Cambridge UK: Cambridge University Press, 1994), 637743; and Robert
Mantran et al., Histoire de lEmpire Ottoman (Paris: Fayard, 1989).
19
A point well taken by Abou-El-Haj, Formation of the Modern State, 6.

iment to understanding modern political paths. By ltering one of


the classic narratives of socio-political change and revolution through
an unfamiliar lens, the Ottoman ancien rgime prods historians to
turn questions of socio-organizational change both inward and outward: inward, toward the complex social and economic relationships
between a center and its many peripheries; and outward, toward
ever greater integration of historical polities within and among adjoining, converging or colliding, cultural and political systems.
Even by reducing the scope of this inquiry and taking advantage
of a wide range of sources, both archival and published, this study
has required more than a decade of empirical and conceptual spadework. It began in 1986 with a study on the economic history of the
province of Diyarbekir, located in the Kurdish southeast of todays
Republic of Turkey. Only a year into that project, my focus began
to change. As I peered deeper into the Ottoman past and questioned the received wisdom of European political theory, I was drawn
into the larger puzzle of the eighteenth-century state. Realizing that
it was impossible to understand a part without a better grasp of the
mechanisms of the whole, I persevered in the archive. Repeatedly,
I have returned to Istanbul and Ankara to conduct research, to consult with colleagues, and to explore newly catalogued sources.20
The dissertation, Measures of Empire: Tax Farmers and the
Ottoman Ancien Rgime,21 reassessed the role of scal and administrative decentralization in early modern state formation. Conceptually
and methodologically, it was built on the foundation laid for eighteenth-century political economy by Mehmet Gen. Addressing the
large question of economic development from an Ottoman vantage
point, Gen devised a method for using Ottoman archival documentation for quantifying change in the empires domestic market.22

20
Despite casting my net wide, I have scraped only the surface of many of the
new collections in the Ba{bakanlk Ar{ivi in Istanbul. In 1994, I was able to consult the Ottoman judicial court records ({er"iye sicilleri ) for eighteenth-century Mardin
and Diyarbekir that had been transferred to Milli Ktphane in Ankara. For more
on the local court records found in the Republic of Turkey, see Ahmet Akgndz
et al., eds., }er "iye Sicilleri, 2 vols. (Istanbul: Trk Dnya{i Ara{trmalar Vakf, 1988).
21
Ph.D. diss. Columbia University, 1995.
22
Mehmet Gen, A Study on the Feasibility of Using Eighteenth-Century
Ottoman Financial Records as an Indicator of Economic Activity, in The Ottoman
Empire in the World Economy, ed. Huri Islamo[lu-Inan (Cambridge UK: Cambridge
University Press, 1987), 345373.

10

By adapting what had long been regarded as the quintessentially


old-regime type of revenue contracting, the quasi-proprietary, leasefor-life malikne contract to this end, he also furnished students of
the old regime with an acutely sensitive tool for retracing social relationships and political organization. Recognizing its promise for social
history, Jean-Pierre Thieck, who was working on a monograph on
Aleppo before his untimely death in 1990, cracked another key part
of the old regime puzzle.23 He employed tax-farming documentation
to reconstruct the economy and polity of northern Syria. By tracing connections between town and country through rural tax farms
and by identifying gentry-contractors, he illuminated a government
of the urban gentry forming in the shadow of the states policies of
extraction and redistribution.
Applying these conceptual and methodological insights to new data
and bringing an outline of the central-states redistributive structure
together with the evolving administrative system in the provinces,
my research pointed to concomitant processes.24 First, as the web of
contractual relationships emanating from contracting identied the
actors and interests that cemented the old-regime elite, I observed
that sectoral investments distinguished the state elite from non-investors
such as the religious establishment, as well as from more ordinary
contractors, members of what we might call the third estate, whose
portfolios were restricted to small scale agricultural holdings. Even
as this system of contracting networks grew more distended in space,
I speculated, the states monetary policy and regulation of credit
markets assured Istanbuls continued dominance over many of the
key imperial actors.25
23
Jean-Pierre Thieck, Dcentralisation ottomane et armation urbaine Alep
la n du XVIIIme sicle, in Mouvements communautaires et espaces urbains au Machreq,
ed. Mona Zakaria et al. (Beirut: Centre dtudes et de Recherches sur le MoyenOrient Contemporain, 1985), 118168. For an expanded version of this seminal
article as well as the journalistic writings of Michel Farrre) see Gilles Kepel, ed.,
Passion dOrient (Paris: ditions Karthala, 1992).
24
See Ariel Salzmann, An Ancien Rgime Revisited: Privatization and Political
Economy in the 18th Century Ottoman Empire, Politics & Society 21 (1993): 393423.
25
For more on Istanbuls arbitrage policies, see Halil Sahillio[lu, The Role of
International Monetary and Metal Movements in Ottoman Monetary History,
13001700, in Precious Metals in the Later Medieval and Early Modern Worlds, ed. J. F.
Richards (Durham, N.C.: Carolina Academic Press, 1983), 269304; and }evket
Pamuk, The Recovery of the Ottoman Monetary System in the Eighteenth Century,
in Kemal Karpat, The Ottoman Past and Todays Turkey (Leiden: E. J. Brill, 2000),
188211.

11

Second, by studying the devolution, transfer, and partnerships of


shareholders of tax farms, I noted that premodern privatization
did not necessarily contribute to economic and political disaection
with the state. Instead, it fostered a distinct form of sociopolitical
integration: vertically, as the rical- devlet, the Ottoman aristocracy of
service and courtiers cultivated extensive networks across the empire
in order to manage their assets; and horizontally, as gentry (e{rf ve
ayn) invested in smaller-scale tax farming as a means for creating
spheres of inuence within cities and the countryside. Not indirect
rule or the solvent of an imperial structure, tax farming should be
considered state formation by other means.
The dissertation, which oered an alternative model for eighteenthcentury Ottoman sociopolitical history, lent itself toward further quantitative and qualitative research. Rather than continue to quantify
these aspects of the imperial structure, the present work explores several of the more misunderstood facets of old-regime rule and governance. Thankfully, I did not have to start from scratch. Although
much of the material in chapter 1 is substantially new, the core of
my dissertation research, including a quasi-monographic account of
the political economy of an Ottoman province, provided raw materials for the present essay as well.
Despite its distance (approximately 1400 kilometers from Istanbul),
Diyarbekir was tethered to the imperial system in a peculiar logistical, social, and economic fashion. Like northern and central Syria,
northeastern Anatolia, and many of the Balkan provinces,26 political
relationships in Diyarbekir exemplify the old regime compromise. By
contrast, as recent monographs on eighteenth-century Cairo, Mosul,
Baghdad, Basra, and southern Syria/Palestine have shown, outerring Asian and African provinces were simply too far removed to
exhibit the more characteristic aspects of vernacular government
under the old regime. As Tocqueville himself found for Frances
southernmost provinces, the so-called pays dtats, these outlying zones
testify to the territorial limits of the early modern state: during much
of the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries, their actors responded
to the strategic concerns of the frontier or the opportunities aorded
by a competitive interstate system.27
26
For another example, see Michael Robert Hickok, Ottoman Military Administration
in Eighteenth-Century Bosnia (Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1997).
27
See, in particular, Richard van Leeuwen, Notables and Clergy in Mount Lebanon:

12

If beneting from earlier choices, the present study has presented


new documentary challenges. Ideally, I would have hoped to have
stumbled upon a rich cache of documents, such as the cahiers de
dolance or the diaries of provincial elites, that might help better
explain the political ideas of the gentry or the quotidian cultural and
social relations within and between a provincial city and the Sublime
Porte. Although I did not, there is every reason to believe that the
patient and creative researcher will yet nd them.28 But the records
I have used, although all too often drafted in Istanbul itself, do help
me reconstruct no less compelling features of the polity of the old
regime. In addressing issues of space, hierarchy, and government, I
have tried to diversify the witnesses and media of documentation,
teasing information from documents left by palace scientists, artists,
court historians, judges and bureaucrats. Despite eorts to broaden
my witnesses, readers will note many absences and silences. Few subalterns and no women, with the exception of a rare cameo appearance, are to be found within these pages.
While preoccupied with managing the scale of this endeavor, it is
no less true that even the most determined attempts to provide a
synthetic overview of an as yet unintegrated historical landscape will
fail without attention to more specic regional realities. To the extent
possible, I have tried to accomplish this by maintaining a critical
distance from the unparalleled but inherently biased vantage point
oered by the registers, edits, orders, and reports of the Sublime
Porte. In addition to another round of research in the eighteenthcentury court records for Diyarbekir and Mardin, I have gleaned
information from monographs on the provincial history of neighboring regions to build a composite picture. (brahim Ylmazeliks
ne study on Diyarbekirs late-eighteenth/early-nineteenth-century
capital district and city of Amid, a monograph that relies almost

The Khazin Sheikhs and the Maronite Church (17361840) (Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1995); Jane
Hathaway, The Politics of Household in Ottoman Egypt: The Rise of the Qazada[l (Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press, 1997); Thabit A. J. Abdullah, Merchants, Mamluks, and
Murder: The Political Economy of Trade in Eighteenth-Century Basra (Albany: State University
of New York Press, 2001); Dina Rizk Khoury, State and provincial society in the Ottoman
Empire: Mosul, 15401834 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997); Beshara
Doumani, Rediscovering Palestine: Merchants and Peasants in Jabal Nablus, 17001900
(Berkeley: University of California Press, 1995).
28
For Arabic sources, see Reinhard Schulze, Was Ist Die Islamische Augklrung?
Die Welt Des Islams 36 (1996): 277325.

13

exclusively on provincial documentation and narrative sources otherwise unavailable to me, keeps the provincial story from faltering.29
If the Ottoman Empire challenges students of the old regime in
an acute fashion, it is not simply a consequence of documentation.
The diculties of reading and interpretation are part and parcel of
modern notions of sovereignty.30 For modern sovereignty entails not
only a notion of a monopoly of powers and the mutual recognition
of its members within a club of nation-states, but also predisposes
the investigator to adopting a particular perspective within the polity
itself. As such, an interpretation of the Ottoman past has invariably
demanded that researchers choose a central point of perspective and,
by it, to predetermine the gravitational center of power between a
state elite and the populations of its many peripheries. By beginning
this study with a map in which the empire itself is embedded in
larger geopolitical landscape of Eurasia, I hope to remind myself as
much as my readers, that the picture I paint would be very dierent
had I limited my perspective to Belgrade, Cairo, Istanbul or Baghdad.
As historians and social scientists recover diverse facets of a common past, it is will not be enough to revise narratives or simply
scrap the dominant paradigm; we must also re-site historiography
itself.

The Old Rgime through an Ottoman Lens


The Ottoman Empire, the sociological axiom goes, is not a state; it
is an empire, to be exact, as Talcott Parsons would have it, an
intermediate empire.31 This classication conveys a preordained
course: a youth of precocious, albeit despotic centralization,

29
Dr. Ylmazelik kindly provided me with a copy of his dissertation, XIX.
Yzyln ilk Yarsnda Diyarbakr, 17901840, (Frat University, 1991) 2 vols., during my visit to Elaz[/Harput in 1992; given discrepancies in documentation, I cite
from both the dissertation as well as the resulting monograph, XIX. Yzyln ilk
Yarsnda Diyarbakr, 17901840 (Ankara: Trk Tarih Kurumu, 1995).
30
On revisions to the classic notions of sovereignty, see John Ruggie, Territoriality
and Beyond: Problematizing Modernity in International Relations, International
Organisation, 47 (1993): 13974; and Thomas J. Biersteker and Cynthia Weber, eds.,
State Sovereignty as a Social Construct (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996).
31
S. N. Eisenstadt, The Political System of Empires (New York: Free Press, 1969),
1723. For an early critique, see Norman Izkowitz, Eighteenth Century Ottoman
Realities, Studia Islamica 16 (1962): 7394.

14

middle years of social stasis, followed inevitably by institutional decay


and violent collapse. As new studies disabuse such generalizations,
Ottoman scholars are increasingly reluctant to accept the received
wisdom of nineteenth-century historiography and social science or to
reexively segregate a Eurasia and African state from the course of
modern political history.32 In fact, a healthy degree of skepticism
with regard to the authority of the Western canon has become an
indispensable tool of our trade.
Ironically, a student of Ottoman history who might peruse The
Old Rgime and the French Revolution today no longer sees in the budding state of Western Europe an alien, impossibly distant entity.
Quite the contrary, she nds herself at home in Tocquevilles description of the twists and turns in the old-regime plot and smiles with
familiarity at the recurrence of the comparable tropes. Tocquevilles
celebration of Louis XIVs role as the grand architect of French
absolutism (borrowed from Voltaire) begs for comparison with the
glorication of Sleyman the Magnicent (d. 1566) in the historiography of Ottoman statecraft or the line of continuity traced between
the programs of Westernization of Ahmet III and those of his
grandson Selim III (r. 17891807).33
Although the Ottoman historian might sympathize with an author
who tries sustain his central thesis despite the contradictory evidence
he examines, we can no longer ignore the ideological blinders that
fundamentally obstructed his eld of vision. Addressing the French
Revolutions sharpest critic in his introduction and proposing to trace
its roots to the genetic structure Western institutions and the specic
socioeconomic conditions of old-regime France, book 1 steers readers away from the territorial state system and the world economy.34
Outside of space, European institutional structures appear primordial.35 Teleology replaces contingency. Whether we call them paths
32

See Abou-El-Haj, Formation of the Modern State.


Emmanuel Le Roy Ladurie, The Ancien Rgime: A History of France, 16101774
(Oxford and Cambridge, MA: Basil Blackwell, 1996), 72, 266267, 273, 630635;
Halil (nalck and Cemal Kafadar eds., Suleyman The First and His Time (Istanbul: Isis
Press, 1993) and Cornell H. Fleischer, The Lawgiver as Messiah: The Making of
the Imperial Image in the Reign of Sleymn, In Soliman le Manique et son temps:
actes du colloque de Paris Galeries Nationales du Grand Palais 710 Mars 1990, ed. Gilles
Veinstein (Paris: cole des Hautes tudes en Science Sociales, 1992), 15977.
34
The Old Rgime, bk. 1, ch. 4.
35
Ibid., 1011. Franois Furet (The Old Regime, vol. 1, 99) voices frustration over
Tocquevilles lack of concern for the wars of religion.
33

15

or modes of production, only the nations des conns de la Polande


la mer dIrlande that arise from post-Roman, Christian Europe
plot a common course that leads through feudalism, parish communities, and aristocracy toward private property, capitalism and
modern government, irrespective of the interactive, interdependent
Eurasian and African state systems. In subsequent chapters we realize the signicance of these abstract claims: as the rudiments of the
modern state emerge from absolutist monarchy in the late seventeenth and eighteenth centuries, it is Christian civilization, the bonds
of the rural parish, and the residue of an autonomous aristocratic
hierarchy which guard European absolutism from lapsing into pure
despotism (one assumes of an oriental variety).36
Even if we accept a grain-of-truth argument about the political
constitution of medieval Europe, the peculiarities of the French clergy,
and the specicities of culture and cultivation, the fact remains that
Tocquevilles strongest interpretative arguments about the institutional and social structure of prerevolutionary France are at odds
with the ndings of most social historians.37 Despite Tocquevilles
insistence, claims that old regime laid the basic foundation for further centralization in areas of taxation, military recruitment, and justice, that Paris became maitre of the nation, or that the cultural
identity of its populations grew increasingly homogeneous ring hollow. France of the seventeenth and early-eighteenth centuries more
closely resembled the classic denition of an early modern empire
than a nation-state.38 It was a composite of regional governments
and near city-states, which zealously defended local languages, legal
codes and customs.39 Half of its revenues derived from indirect methods of nance and revenue collection, including tax farming and the
sale of thousands of venal oces.40
36

The Old Rgime, 27; bk. 2, ch. 11.


Charles Tilly, State and Counterrevolution in France, Social Research, 56
(1989): 7273. For references in The Old Rgime: on the inuence of Paris over the
provinces, 35, 6572; on the destruction of the nobility, 27, 7279; on the centralization process, 3438, 65 131, 204; on conscription, 104105; on the rule of
the intendants, 3638, 134135, 180.
38
George Rud, Europe in the 18th Century: Aristocracy and the Buorgeois Challenge
(Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1972), 85, 117119.
39
For the provincial dimension, see Charles Tilly, The Contentious French: Four
Centuries of Popular Struggle (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1986); and
more recently, Pierre Deyon, Ltat face au pouvoir local: un autre regard sur lhistoire de
France (Paris: Editions Locales de France, 1996).
40
George T. Matthews, The Royal General Farms in Eighteenth Century France (New
37

16

Despite his renewed popularity among certain schools of French


historiography,41 Tocquevilles archival database for the The Old Rgime
and the French Revolution was exceedingly shallow. While appreciating
Tocquevillean sensitivity toward the interplay of state and society,
we must recognize that his method of analysis is frequently contradictory and his conclusions are often inconsistent with his own evidence.42 Causality is elusive: in one section Tocqueville might attribute
the catalyst of change to the pressures of increasing state centralization; pages later, he will point to the role of forms of decentralization in mounting social tensions. In fact, struggles for what we
might dene as social and political rights do not necessarily owe to
confrontations with central authority. Rather, following the texts of
the Enlightenment, Tocqueville cites the arbitrary exercise of power,
the failure to pay creditors, the promiscuous sale of oces, and the
granting of immunities as the kindling that ignited intellectual dissent and inter-estate conict.
The Old Rgime, despite its authors insistence, does not sustain his
argument for a linear social and organizational progression from
absolutism to revolution and the modern nation-state. Moreover, the
institutional features of the old regime that he identied are not
unique to France, but are found in other settings, including the
Ottoman Empire. Yet, these contradictions should not detract from
what this essay did accomplish, if largely impressionistically. For even
as Tocqueville reinstated the old regime as an important stage in
modern political development, he was forced to grapple with the
paradoxical nature of the processes that characterized eighteenthcentury political transformation overall. Thus, unlike many of his
later interpreters, he remained keenly aware of the very tentative
nature of the infrastructural power of early modern polities and
relevance of the concessions made en route to consolidation:
York: Columbia University Press, 1958), 316; Isser Woloch, The New Regime:
Transformations of the French Civic Order, 17891820 (New York: W. W. Norton, 1994),
114118; and Eugen Joseph Weber, Peasants into Frenchmen: The Modernization of Rural
France, 18701914 (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1976).
41
Franois Furet (Penser la Rvolution franaise [Paris: Gallimard, 1978]) was one
of the main proponents of the Tocquevillean turn; see also Roger Chartier, The
Cultural Origins of the French Revolution, trans. Lydia G. Cohrane (Durhan: Duke
University Press, 1991); compare, George C. Comninel, Rethinking the French Revolution:
Marxism and the Revisionists (London: Verso, 1987).
42
Compare, Theda Skocpol, Introduction: Bringing the State Back In: Strategies
of Analysis in Current Research in Bringing the State Back In, ed. T. Skocpol, Peter
Evans, and Dietrich Rueschemeyer (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1985), 21.

17

While the central government was gradually taking over all the powers of local authorities and coming more and more to monopolize the
whole administration of the country, some institutions which it had
allowed to survive and even some new ones created by itself tended
to check this centripetal movement . . . it had no very clear idea of the
extent of its power. None of its rights was rmly established or unequivocally dened, and though its sphere of action was already vast, it had
to grope, so to speak in the dark and exercise much prudence.43

Of the features Tocqueville describes, scal and administrative decentralization remains one of the more intransigent components of the
old-regime paradox.44 It is ironic that precisely because of an errorridden social scientic paradigms on empires, decentralization,
along with its attendant state involution, have long taken center stage
in eighteenth-century Ottoman studies. Over the past quarter century, new political and socioeconomic investigations have shed the
anachronism and reductionism of functionalist sociology, furnishing
early modern historiography with a far more complex analysis of an
evolving institutional structure.45 Approaching the problem of decentralization from dierent points on the Ottoman map, Albert Hourani
and Halil (nalck have been at the forefront of this reassessment of
the old regime.46 Although neither scholar addresses Tocqueville
directly, their creative interpretation of Ottoman realities actually
helps us reconsider his classic account of state formation in the eighteenth century. For example, Houranis characterization of Istanbuls
43

The Old Rgime, 108109.


See Ian Copland and Michael R. Godley,Revenue Farming in Comparative
Perspective: Reections on Taxation, Social Structure and Development in the EarlyModern Period, in The Rise and Fall of Revenue Farming: Business Elites and the Emergence
of the Modern State in Southeast Asia, ed. John Butcher and Howard Dick (New York:
St. Martins Press, 1993), 4568. Helen Nader, Liberty in Absolutist Spain: The Habsburg
Sale of Towns, 15161700 (Baltimore and London: Johns Hopkins University Press,
1990); Muzaar Alam, The Crisis of Empire in Mughal North India: Awadh and the Punjab,
17071748 (Delhi: Oxford University Press, 1986); Gabriel Ardant, Financial Policy
and Economic Infrastructure of Modern States and Nations, in The Formation of
National States in Western Europe, ed. Charles Tilly (Princeton: Princeton University
Press, 1975), 164242; Susan Mann, Local Merchants and the Chinese Breaucracy,
1750 1950 (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1987); and Murat izaka, A
Comparative Evolution of Business Partnerships: The Islamic World and Europe with Specic
Reference to the Ottoman Archives (Leiden, E. J. Brill, 1996).
45
Note Virginia H. Aksan, Locating the Ottomans among Early Modern Empires,
Journal of Early Modern History 3 (1999): 132.
46
Albert Hourani, The Changing Face of the Fertile Crescent in the XVIIIth
Century, Studia Islamica 8 (1957): 89122, reprinted in Hourani, A Vision of History
(London: Constable & Co. Ltd., 1961), 3570; and Halil (nalck, Centralization
and Decentralization Ottoman Administration, in Studies in Eighteenth Century Islamic
History, 2752.
44

18

authority over old-regime Arab cities demonstrates that what Tocqueville calls Versailles tutelle administrative, did not subvert the
power of urban elites so much as complement it.47 The uneasy domination of the court over the provincial bourgeoisie, feudal lords, and
priests would be better considered within Halil (nalcks dialectical
framework, which posits an ongoing tug-of-war between the Sublime
Porte (Bab- li ), commanders in the eld, and particularly the provincial gentry.48
Conscious of the larger historical context, studies on Ottoman history have also rened our understanding of the questions that
Tocqueville summarily discarded, such as the impact of the world
market on state formation.49 Rescuing Ottoman economic history
from the anecdotal or unidimensional accounts that had lled in a
vast, undetermined space in world history, Mehmet Gen reconstructs a trajectory of economic growth during the rst three-quarters
of the century.50 His research demonstrates the intimate relationship
between global nancial trends and state development, as well as
between Istanbuls policies of military command and the relative
resiliency of Ottoman industry. Gens studies also reveal the fact
that the states ability to grant immunities and privileges expanded
and contracted with wars and scal exigencies.
By reimagining the space of the early modern state, recent studies shed light on the complexities of socio-organizational change in
the provinces and in the imperial capital. Research on Syria by JeanPierre Thieck and Karl Barbir points to the fact that Istanbul might
decentralize, even devolve military authority unto provincial agents,
while simultaneously building new nodes of state power throughout
the empire. Policies of decentralization were no less important for
the cohesion of the ruling elite. Rifa"at Abou-El-Haj documents how

47

Hourani, The Changing Face of the Fertile Crescent, 100.


See (nalck, Centralization and Decentralization.
49
For representatives of this school, see Huri (slamo[lu-Inan, ed. The Ottoman
Empire and the World Economy (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1987). For
a superb new monograph, see Edhem Eldem, French Trade in Istanbul in the Eighteenth
Century (Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1999).
50
Mehmet Gen, Osmanl Ekonomisi ve }ava{, Yapt 49 (1984): 5261, Tables
49: (1984): 8693; Gen Osmanl Maliyesinde Malikne Sistemi, in (ktisat Tarihi
Semineri, ed. Osman Okyar and nal Nalbanto[lu (Ankara: Hacetepe niversitesi
Yay., 1975), 23196; and Gen, Osmanl (mparatorlu[unda: Devlet ve Ekonomi (Istanbul:
tken, 2000).
48

19

a bureaucratic and military aristocracy, lacking hereditary title or


property, reproduced itself as an estate by extensive political households or patronage networks.51 As we will see in chapter 2, prime
access to information and resources, particularly scal favors, was
essential to sustaining these networks. The Istanbul aristocracy of
service, took advantage of a distinctly old-regime type of insider
trading or what the economist Joseph Stiglitz calls in a modern context asymmetric information.52
Ottoman historians have another advantage in a critical rereading of the Tocquevillean account of institutional change in the eighteenth century. As an ancien rgime writ large, Ottoman history has
demanded a complex and often fragmented approach to its parts;
indeed, it has never really been possible to investigate a polity, which
at one time encompassed lands from Yemen to Hungary, using a
single unit of analysis. Although modern notions of sovereignty ( just
as the ideology of absolutism and reason of state in the past) might
require that political scientists maintain this ction,53 there is no reason for the historian to accept the category of the unitary state at
face value.
As an anthropologist of law, Sally Falk Moore reminds fellow social
scientists that even the contemporary state is an organization of
organizations whose integration (and disintegration) over time occurs
through competition and negotiation.54 To put this in an early modern context, we might say that despite the growing concentration of
coercive powers, autonomous behavior, and increased agility in coordinating its parts, the pre-modern state, as Tocqueville conceded

51

The Ottoman Vezir and Pasha Households, 16831703: A Preliminary Report,


JAOS 94 (1972): 43847.
52
Compare, Philip T. Homan, Gille Postel-Vinay, and Jean-Laurent Rosenthal,
Information and Economic History: How the Credit Market in Old Regime Paris
Forces us to Rethink the Transition to Capitalism, The American Historical Review
101 (1999): 6994.
53
Nicholas Henshall, The Myth of Absolutism: Change and Continuity in Early Modern
European Monarchy (London: Longman, 1992), esp. Introduction. See also J. P. Nettl,
The State as a Conceptual Variable, World Politics 20 (1968): 559592. On the
morrow of WWI, Harold J. Laski (Studies in the Problem of Sovereignty [New Haven:
Yale University Press, 1917], 1) rendered it thusly: Hegelianwise, we cannot avoid
the temptation that bids us make our State a unity. It is to be all-absorptive. All
groups within itself are to be but the ministrants to its life; their relativity is the
outcome of its sovereignty since without it they could have no existence.
54
Sally Falk Moore, Law as Process: An Anthropological Approach (London: Routledge,
1978), 131.

20

above, operated within a limited range and with varying degrees of


eciency. Rather than a monopoly of powers in the Weberian sense,
the absolutist sovereign relied on a plurality of force: the early modern state ruled, but it did not govern.
In disaggregating the early modern state, the experience of Ottoman
historiography also warns us about repeating the error of merely
splitting a large territorial polity along what appears to be its most
obvious sociological and spatial seams. Instead, it is the very irregularities of rule that give us some idea of the complex division of
organizational and administrative labor, or of the split capacities
between center and periphery, as well as between cities and the
countryside. As Tocqueville himself conceded, this was not a zerosum game in which the center perpetually gained the upper hand
as peripheries surrendered powers. The governmental capacity of
the province might grow alongside the expanding powers of the central state. These powers might be adjunctive or complementary; on
other occasions local powers came into direct competition with the
central state.
Taxation remains one of the more sensitive economic and socioorganizational indicators of the gradual process of state consolidation which also helps to map this division of labor in space. There
is a fair degree of congruence among the old regimes of Europe and
Asia in the timing of the rst direct taxes. Although both the French
and Ottoman centers introduced a variety of taxes from the sixteenth century onward, scal obligations and rents (whether deemed
state or private) were still, in large part, diverted into local coers.
Ocially or unocially, this seepage was part of the equation of
rule. Even as statesmen attempted to impose more direct methods of taxation, they were forced to devolve other facets of government to local actors in order to forge alliances. Ironically, rather
than closing the power gap, increasing obligations also made for new
opportunities for exemptions. In both France and the Ottoman Empire
tax farming increased apace with direct taxation. The paradox remains: although tax farming dispersed state capacity, it also established uniform terms of contract between sovereign and a certain
stratum of the subject population; it standardized an important political relationship.
New research on questions of privilege and property within Europe
suggests that we should look to forms of decentralization and devolution of power to help us better appreciate the rise of modern gov-

21

ernment and changing political claims of subjects.55 Such agreements


were not merely economic transactions. Although privileges and
immunities were not rights in the classical sense, they were far from
ephemeral. In the Ottoman case, tax farming implicitly or explicitly
entailed a redenition of obligations and privilege, hence of political status. On a more abstract plane, long-standing privileges, like
property, established new boundaries between state and society.
Cumulatively, revenue contracting and venal oces often constituted
veritable forms of governance. Moreover, these privileges or contractual relations established a baseline from which subjects might
make new demands of central authority or, alternately, erect barriers against the further state encroachment on local authority.
By better appreciating variation within a single polity, disaggregating the premodern state also allows us to gauge the synchronicity and the contingency of state formation across the European and
Asian meridian of territorial states as well as appreciating multilateral relationships with respect to other territorial states.56 This
reorientation is particularly critical for states like the Ottoman Empire,
not only because of scale but also because of its geopolitical coordinates at the intersection of dierent regional systems.57 As the
hinge of Eurasia,58 the Ottoman state responded to diverse forms
of warfare, the pulse of discrete trade networks, and a multiplicity
of administrative forms. In the West, the Ottoman state remained a
critical guarantor, with France, of the balance of power within the

55
See Philip T. Homan and Kathryn Norberg, eds. Fiscal Crises, Liberty, and
Representative Government, 14501789 (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1994).
56
See Charles Tilly, Coercion, Capital and European States, AD 9901990 (Oxford:
Basil Blackwell, 1990); and Otto Hintze, The Formation of States and Constitutional
Development: A Study in History and Politics, in The Historical Essays, ed. Felix
Gilbert (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1975), 157178. Edward W. Soja (RePresenting the Spatial Critique of Historicism, in Thirdspace: Journeys to Los
Angeles and Other Read-and-Imagined Places [Malden, MA and Oxford: M.I.T.
Press, 1996], 164185) takes discursive analysis to task and Hayden Whites approach
in particular, for de-territorialing the same contexts they pretend to historicize.
57
The conation of so-called empires with the colonizing nation-states of the
nineteenth and twentieth centuries only further obscures the contrasts and similarities between historic polities. See Ariel Salzmann, Toward a Comparative History
of the Ottoman State, 14501850 Archv orientln (Oriental Archive) 66 (1998), special issue, Supplementa VIII, 35166.
58
Compare, William Hardy McNeill, Venice: The Hinge of Europe, 10811797
(Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1974) and McNeill, Europes Steppe Frontier,
1500 1800 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1964).

22

European state system until the end of the Seven Years War.59 It
was also an active participant in a very unstable West Asian system
of states.
If the empire was the hinge, then Iran might well be considered
the geopolitical epicenter of early modern European and Asian history. The protracted post-Safavid civil wars raged intermittently
between 1720 and the nal assumption of power by the Qajars after
1790. Spilling over into the Caucasus, Iraq, Central Asia, and India,
the wars of the Iranian succession facilitated Russian and British
expansion in Asia. The Ottoman Empires own increasing territorial vulnerability during the last quarter of the eighteenth century was
an indirect product of Nadir Shahs invasion of the Gulf and Mughal
India and a direct consequence of the new global parameters of
power after the Seven Years War. By the late eighteenth century
the Ottoman Empire had lost a French counterweight to Britain in
the Indian Ocean and to Russia in eastern Europe. Lacking a viable
framework for a West Asian order, it also remained isolated from
the emerging central European coalitions.60
Taking as a given the compound makeup of most premodern
polities and the multiplicity of geopolitical contexts in which such
entities operated, territorial scale becomes a historical, rather than
an institutional, ethnic, or demographic question. Whether we consider the multiple divisions of Poland, the relatively lax colonial
regime in North America or the administrative decentralization in
pre-revolutionary France, new lessons were learned on the relationship of state building and the degree of administrative consolidation
in the last quarter of the eighteenth century. To put the modern
state in historical perspective demands that we recognize that in both
59
See Paul W. Schroeder, The Transformation of European Politics, 17631848 (Oxford:
Clarendon Press, 1994); and Thomas Na, The Ottoman Empire and the European
State System, in The Expansion of International Society, ed. H. Bull and A. Watson
(Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1984), 143170.
60
There have been several attempts to come to come to terms with the early
modern Euro-Asian (Frank Perlins term) and African state system. See, for example, Marshall G. S. Hodgson, The Venture of Islam: Conscience and History in a World
Civilization. Vol. 3, The Gunpowder Empires and Modern Times (Chicago: University of
Chicago Press, 1974); C. A. Bayly, Imperial Meridian: The British Empire and the World,
17801830 (London: Longman, 1989; Sanjay Subrahmanyam, Connected Histories:
Notes towards a Reconguration of Early Modern Eurasia, Modern Asian Studies,
31 (1997): 735762; and Victor Lieberman, Transcending East-West Dichotomies:
State and Culture Formation in Six Ostensibly Disparate Areas, Modern Asian Studies
31 (1997): 463546, among others.

23

France and the Ottoman Empire the rst blow to the old regime
was not ideological agitation or mass mobilization but scal crises,
induced by prior military commitments.61 Yet both reached an impasse.
Ottoman vulnerability to uctuations in nancial markets was exacerbated by a political apparatus soldered by credit. As it began to
retract privileges and reached more deeply into provincial pockets,
Istanbul confronted resistance at many levels.
Summoning the will, neither the Ottoman Empire in 1793 nor
France in 1788, could call upon the political, coercive, administrative or legislative means to enforce it. Even a relatively compact
state, such as France (with a land mass that comprised a territory
smaller than even the Ottoman core in Asia Minor) came up short
at the end of the century. Although revolutionary mobilization in
the context of a European-wide war overwhelmed the opposition
and counter-revolution, the gap between the state apparatus and
local government in the Ottoman Empire could not be lled by the
emerging unitary state.
A rereading of the Tocquevillean investigation of the emergence
of modern government and correction for its myopia in matters of
geopolitics and world economy, suggests that the reasons for the
parting of political paths between Europe and Asia can be explained
only by considering the common conundrums of power left by the
nearly simultaneous dissolution of the old regime political order. In
all cases, the transition was rocky and protracted. Some states, Venice
and Poland, to name only two, fell by the wayside. The old regime
sputtered to a close over the course of four decades in the Ottoman
Empire. Interruptions and detours in state programs of scal centralization after 1793 allowed provincial elites and local governments
ample time to regroup and dig in their heels. With its many exposed
territorial edges and the uid geopolitical situation of the Napoleonic
Wars, provincial powers were able to renegotiate their relationship
with the central state with outside support. In sharp contrast to the
care with which statesmen crafted and restored Europe, including
61
Among many studies on this subject, see Larry Neal, The Rise of Financial Capitalism: International Capital Markets in the Age of Reason (Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press, 1990), 180214; and Frank Perlin, Financial Institutions and Business Practices across the Euro-Asian Interface: Comparative and Structural Considerations,
15001900, in The European Discovery of the World and Its Economic Eects on PreIndustrial Society, 15001900: Papers of the Tenth International Economic History Congress,
ed. Hans Pohl (Stuttgart: Franz Steiner, 1990), 257303.

24

the oending French state after 1815, was the refusal of the Great
Powers to extend equivalent recognition to Ottoman sovereignty or
to guarantee its territorial integrity. This summary dissolution of the
old-regime order and the expulsion of the Ottomans from the modern state system were rendered in a convenient euphemism: The
Eastern Question.62 In the decades that followed every successful
exit from the Ottoman Empire, including that of Greece in 1830
and Egypt after 1840, was mediated by foreign powers who not only
conferred the laurels of sovereignty on local leadership but also militarily imposed new territorial divisions.63

Vocabularies of Early Modernity


Tocqueville might have learned much from the Ottoman old regime
had he removed his geographical and cultural blinders. Yet he still
would have been stymied for lack of a suitable lexicon. Indeed, one
of the greatest handicaps for those who attempt comparative investigations of the early modern world, a world before the crude stamp
of colonialism and the nation-state took its toll on the diversity of
cultures and reduced the variations of political organization, has been
the absence of a common historical vocabulary.
For a handle on the premodern polity, we might borrow Tocquevilles own all-embracing notion of the ancien rgime (or old
regime)64 as a short hand for an amalgamated or, what Michael
Hanagan would call, an unconsolidated state found in both Europe
and Asia. If this term allows us to gather disparate facets of politics, society and economy under one historical umbrella, it also blurs
the distinction between capacities that were dispersed in space. Rather
than coining new terms, it might be best to modify existing terminology to acknowledge the inherent disjuncture of powers within the

62
Compare, Biancamaria Fontana, The Napoleonic Empire and the Europe of
Nations, in The Idea of Europe: From Antiquity to the European Union, ed. Anthony
Pagden (Cambridge, U.K. and Washington: Woodrow Wilson Center Press, 2002),
116138.
63
Consider, Albert O. Hirschmans Exit, Voice and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in
Firms, Organizations, and States (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1970).
64
For the history of the term, see D. Venturino, La Naissance de lAncien
Rgime, in The Political Culture of the French Revolution, ed. Colin Lucas (Oxford:
Pergamon Press, 1988), 1140.

25

premodern state and to emphasize the protracted and uneven historical process involved in their realignment in space and sociologically into what we now know as the modern state.
For the purpose of this inquiry, I use the term state in a relatively narrow sense: it corresponds to a limited set of institutions and
individuals within a territorial policy; it refers to actors who ruled
primarily from or through the capital city and via politywide institutions (e.g., the dynasty/palace/court, the judiciary and formulation
of imperial law, administrative and military hierarchies, the regulation of internal and external trade). During the early modern period,
even though domestic challengers remained, the autonomy of state
centers grew as a result of competition in an interstate arena. States
were armed with unprecedented stockpiles of weapons and standing
armies; they dressed each other in identiable cultural uniforms on
the battleelds and established patterns of alliances through an expanding web of diplomatic exchanges. Advancing at times and retreating
at others, socio-organizational elements of the state during the early
modern period permeated the periphery and were reproduced in
cognate forms, among and between them.
Having narrowed the sense and reference of the premodern state,
it is no less important to rename those dimensions of rule that escaped
its direct cultural, coercive, and socio-organizational reach. Rather
than conating the notion of those who rule with those who govern, we might reserve the terms governance or government specically
for the complex of distinct provincial capacities: the quotidian acts
of administration, adjudication, and enforcement. Not only was oldregime governance institutionally separate from many of the ocial
organs of the state, it was also highly localized.65 At the same time,
it assured a peculiar form of standardization owing to the fact that
government retained (in the case of the Ottomans) or gained (in
many European contexts) elements of an overarching state syntax.
This partial capacity, constituted of fragments of standard idiom amid
diverse languages of power, made each government a hybrid, a vernacular.66 Less inhibited by the ocially constituted and chartered

65
My sense of the local diers importantly from Cliord Geertzs (Local Knowledge:
Further Essays in Interpretive Anthropology [New York: Basic Books, 1983], 167234) concept of local knowledge.
66
By vernacular I appeal to the relationship between the Latinate languages and

26

hierarchies of the center, vernacular governments could act through


a variety of agents, including formally constituted bodies such as
urban parliaments and advisory councils. In other cases, governmental agency was vested in individuals drawn from the third estate
under special patents; or, in the absence of stronger claimants legitimized by the state, governmental powers were seized by rural lords,
religious leaders, or revenue collectors.
In addition to the reminting of two concepts, readers will nd
an eclectic mix of historical idioms. For instance: in place of the traditional, often reied, dyad, askeri/reaya (military order/subject), I
invoke the notion of the second and third estates. My intent is to
highlight the central importance of privilege and scal immunity in
the denition of status under the old regime, qualities that distinguished the Ottoman religious establishment, or ulema/ilmiye and its
aristocracy of service, the rical- devlet, no less than their French
counterparts.67 So too the non-class-based social umbrella conveyed
by the notion of the third estate is eminently serviceable in the
Ottoman context for the tax-paying reaya, a category that in theory
designated gentry, bourgeoisie, and peasantry alike. By drawing out
similarities, I can also better clarify what I regard to be the key
dierences between the European nobility and the Ottoman aristocracy of service. It is precisely the inability to guarantee their patrimony from one generation to the next that gave rise to an extensive
intra-generational form of accumulation (corporate patrimonialism)
through networks and fungible assets, like tax-farms.68

Latin during the Medieval period. Contrast, Jenny White, Islamicist Mobilization in
Turkey: A Study in Vernacular Politics (Seattle: University of Washington Press, 2003),
esp. Introduction.
67
Gail Bossenga (Society, in Old Regime France, ed. William Doyle [Oxford:
Oxford University Press, 2001], 76) comments that The legal system of the old
regime had its roots in a far more personal and paternalistic society that failed to
distinguish explicitly between personal status, political rule, and rights of property.
68
Carter V. Findley (Bureaucratic Reform in the Ottoman Empire: The Sublime Porte,
1789 1922 (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1980) stresses the singular importance of the political household in the formation of the Ottoman state. Although I
would not dispute the importance of networks in this or any political organization,
the specic strategies that I describe in chapter 2 are not uniquely Ottoman. In
fact, I believe that they are constitutive of the institutional changes that are associated
with political modernization. See Gernot Grabher and David Stark, eds. Restructuring
Networks in Post-Socialism: Legacies, Linkages, and Localities (Oxford; New York: Oxford
University Press, 1997).

27

Even in cases where the t may appear more dicult, French or


English equivalents have been used interchangeably with Ottoman
terms for the purposes of fostering comparative reection. (Indeed,
the Armenian dragoman, Mouragea DOhsson [17401807] readily
found French equivalents for Ottoman old-regime personnel and
scal institutions throughout his multivolume opus.)69 For example,
the duties and origins of the chief, scal ocer of a province, often
called voyvoda in Ottoman parlance might have diered throughout
the Ottoman Empire and was clearly not a replica of his next-ofkin in old-regime France, the intendant.70 However, there is broad
enough congruence on the social origins of these actors (members
of the third estate), the nature of these oces within the respective
old regimes and, no less importantly, the increasingly strategic position they occupied in the historical evolution of government-state
relations, to warrant this risky translation.71 In other cases, it seems
only appropriate to swap Ottoman buzz words for terms with no
less controversial baggage in their respective elds, such as the term
gentry for the collective noun, ayn- vilayet and judge for kad.72
The occasional importation of terminology (mainly of European
extraction) in this study does in no way minimize the specicity of
the old regime in North Africa and West Asia. Yet some exchange
of historiographical argot is necessary in order to furnish a medium
for comparison. Even as I attempt to translate parallel social and
political arrangements, I have also preserved terms that are of special import to the history of the Ottoman and the larger Islamicate

69
Tableau gnral de lEmpire othoman, divis en deux parties, dont lune comprend la lgislation mahomtane; lautre, lhistoire de lEmpire othoman (Paris, Imp. de monsieur [Firmin
Didot] 17871820), vol. 3, 370371. He translated eyalet as government; and the
life-lease (malikne) becomes ferme scale.
70
Tocqueville (The Old Rgime, 36) recounts a quip, made by John Law to the
Marquis dArgenson, to the eect that the administration of France rested in hands
of two dozen intendants. For France, see J. F. Bosher, French Finances 17701795:
From Business to Bureaucracy (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1970).
71
In many instances, the reluctance to translate reveals an ideological unease
with the consequences of equivalence rather than a penchant for historical specicity.
See Frank Perlin, Concepts of Order and Comparison, with a Diversion on Counter
Ideologies and Corporate Institutions in Late Pre-Colonial India, in Feudalism and
non-European Societies, ed. T. J. Byres and Harbans Mukhia (London: Frank Cass
1985), 87165.
72
See P. R. Coss, The Formation of the English Gentry, Past and Present 147
(1995): 3864. On attempts to redene the social sense and reference of these
groups, see Deena Sadat, Notables in the Ottoman Empire: The Ayan, (Ph.D.

28

world (e.g., ulema, waqf, timar, sipahi, malikne, etc.). These terms
should form part of the growing lexicon of world and comparative
early modern history. For general readers, in addition to the requisite glossary, I have tried cushioning the use of Ottoman terms with
explanatory context to make them comprehensible or have provided
a rough translation in parentheses. Finally, although I do from time
to time make use of the Islamic calendar for the dating of documents or manuscripts, for simplicitys sake as much as to engage the
standard, that is, Western, chronology of political change, I have
employed a single, common-era dating system.
Vocabularies and calendars are some of the more obvious impediments to reconceptualizing the modern political time line. In the
case of Islamic history, there has been a particularly insidious imbalance in the visual representation of the past, a veil over history created by the prolic output of nineteenth-century Orientalist painters.73
In searching for a new way to narrate socio-organizational change
in a distant time and place, over the past years I have made a concerted eort to locate new visual signposts. The result are the images
that I have inserted within these pages. They should not be regarded
as supplements to my text. Rather, these graphic references are an
integral part of the narrative.
Sandwiched between two attempts to reappraise the historiographical legacy of Tocqueville, are three sketches of the Ottoman old
regime. In chapter 1, questions of territoriality involve a dialogue
with the cartographer and artist who produced one of perhaps three
large polychromic maps on silk completed in the palace in Istanbul
between 1727 and 1728.74 Laden with both graphic and textual infor-

diss. Rutgers University, 1969); and Engin D. Akarl, Provincial Power Magnates
in Ottoman Bilad al-Sham and Egypt, 17401840, in La vie sociale dans les provinces
arabes a lpoque ottomane, ed. Abdeljelil Temimi, vol. 3, 4156 (Tunis: Publications
du Centre dtudes et de Recherches Ottomanes, Morisques, de Documentation et
dInformations, 1988).
73
There is a wealth of new studies on this subject following Edward Saids seminal Orientalism (New York: Vintage, 1979) and Alain Grosrichard, The Sultans Court:
European Fantasies of the East (New York: Verso, 1998). See for example, Asl irakman,
From the Terror of the World to the Sick Man of Europe: Images of Ottoman Empire and
Society from the Sixteenth Century to the Nineteenth (New York: Peter Lang, 2002).
74
Topkap Saray Museum Library (TKSK) H. 447. The map reproduced here
is a retouched photograph (by Paula Hible) of the outline published as an large
folded insert by Faik Re{id Unat without commentary in Tarih Vesikalar 1 (1941)

29

mation, this unusual map helps modern visitors explore the dimensions
of premodern territoriality and the historical and logistical meanings
of state domination. By setting the West Asian portions of the empire
amidst the space of Eurasia, it also helps to alternate an understanding of the geography of sovereignty that has largely been apprized
from its Mediterranean shores.
Chapter 2s discussion revolves around the portraits of the revelers
and participants in the pageant that preceded the circumcisions of
the sons of Ahmet III in 1720. As an introduction to the masks of
Ottoman absolutism, these portraits of courtly life contain oblique
references to the actual workings of the state. Evaluating position
and repetition of imagery we might discern the increasing concentration of powers, under the omnipresent gures of the grand vizier
and the bureaucracy, the Sublime Porte. We might also consider the
social characteristics of the rst and second estates, such as the
members of the religious establishment, or ulema, the military and
the bureaucracy seated at the table of the sultan. Hidden from
view, however, are the imperial circuits of distribution cemented by
the burgeoning market in life-leases (malikne mukatat) and the Islamicate nexus of nance capitalism that tied the ulema, courtiers, and
gentry-ocers to the Christian and Jewish bankers of Istanbul and
the merchants of Marseilles.
In chapter 3, we reexamine one of those infamous tax-farming registers produced by the clerks of the ancien rgime.75 Adjusted
for the parallax of modern expectations,76 this document becomes
an eloquent witness of the uidity of state-government relationships and administrative changes within the province of Diyarbekir.
Tracing the transfer of title from central-state to provincial actors
reveals the shift in the balance of powers. Meandering notations

between pages 160161. Thomas D. Goodrich provided much important bibliographic information and brought to my attention other copies of the map in Turkey
and Austria. Permission for reproduction of the outline was provided by the Trk
Tarih Kurumu.
75
Photocopy (and permission) from Ba{bakanlk Ar{ivi for the reproduction of a
page from register MMD 9518, Defter-i Mukatat- Malikneh-i Mezkre der Eylet-i
Diyarbekir, registering transactions on tax farms from 1697 to 1791. MMD 9519
spans the years 1792 to 1845 in the same province. Among the other examples,
are Tokat, MMD 9543; Athens, MMD 9512; Mosul, MMD 9611; Damascus, MMD
9530, 9538; and Erzurum, MMD 9517.
76
See James C. Scott, Seeing Like a State: How Certain Schemes to Improve the Human
Condition Have Failed (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1998).

30

across the page serve as an apt metaphor for the creative destruction of revenue contracting that dissolved the administrative boundaries between town and country laid down in the early centuries of
the empire. Venal oces bring into relief the vernacular government
of provincial cities and the role of the urban gentry, what Tocqueville
might have called a petty oligarchy, in perpetuating rule.
After exploring these facets of the old regime in West Asia, this
study returns to the writings of Alexis de Tocqueville and his Ottoman
contemporary, the religious scholar and pro-reform statesmen, Ahmed
Cevdet Pasha. In our conclusion, we consider one among the many
possible sequels to the old regime in the Ottoman Empire while raising new questions about the nineteenth-century imperatives and prejudices which continue to haunt contemporary social scientic thought.

CHAPTER ONE

ON A MAP OF EURASIA

There was no need to inscribe the words the realms of the exalted
Ottoman state (memlik-i Devlet-i liye-i Osmaniye) over the broad areas
of early modern maps of Europe and Asia.1 Literate audiences of
the period would have instantly recognized the outline of Ottoman
Empire. Over the span of four centuries the sultans had reassembled virtually all the territories that had once made up the Roman
Empire in Europe, Africa, and Asia, striking terror and awe in the
hearts of the sovereigns of Christendom. Of its continental territories, Ottoman Asia remained the empires largestnearly twice the
area of its European lands and roughly half of its entirety.2 Despite
letters, treatises, and reports by travelers, merchants, and an occasional natural scientist, Western scholars remained largely ignorant
of Ottoman economic, political, and social geography. Beyond the
sliver of terra rma bordering the Mediterranean and its major trading towns and highways, Dutch and Italian maps of the day lled
in these lacunae with classical and biblical references.3 Even an

1
In addition to well-known maps by Gerard Mercato (151294) and Jodocus
Hondius, Sr. (15631612), see Willem Blaeus 1617 maps of the Turcicum Imperium,
in Joan Blaeus widely circulating Atlas Major (1662); reprint, introduced and edited
by Johan Gross (London: Random House, 1997). In 1668, a copy of the Atlas was
presented to the Ottoman court by Justin Collier, the Dutch ambassador, and translated by Ebu Bekir b. Bahram al-Dimi{ki in 1685 (Ekmeleddin (hsano[lu, Ramazan
}e{en, M. Serdar Bekar, Glcan Gndz, and A Hamdi Furat, eds., Osmanl Co[rafya
Literatr [Istanbul: IRCICA, 2000], vol. 1, 111).
2
Donald Edgar Pitcher (An Historical Geography of the Ottoman Empire from the Earliest
Times to the End of the Sixteenth Century with Detailed Maps to Illustrate the Expansion of
the Empire [Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1972], 134) estimates the empires land surface in
1606 to have been 1,071,000 square miles, including vassals. See also Andreas
Birken, Die Provinzen des Osmanischen Reiches (Wiesbaden: Beihefte zum Tbinger Atlas
des Vorderen Orients, 1976) and logistical maps in Rhoads Murphey, Ottoman
Warfare, 15001700 (London: University of London Press, 1999). For comparison
with the Roman Empires frontiers along the Danube, Euphrates, and Rhine, C. R.
Whittaker, Frontiers of the Roman Empire: A Social and Economic Study (Baltimore: Johns
Hopkins University Press, 1994).
3
Ir. C. Koeman, Joan Blaeu and His Grand Atlas: Introduction to the Facsimile Edition
of Le Grand Atlas, 1663 (Amsterdam: Theatrum Orbis Terrarum, 1970), 84.

32

Enlightenment polymath who prided himself on an encyclopedic


knowledge of surveying techniques and the ability to classify ora
and fauna with Linnean precision, such as Count Luigi Ferdinando
Marsigli, in his 1732 encyclopedia of Ottoman military structure
deferred to the authority of the Muslim scientist Ebu Bekir Efendi
al-Dimi{ki, whose map provided Ottoman administrative divisions
(Beylerbati, Passalati, e Beylati [sic]).4 So, too, at the eve of the
Seven Years War, the French cartographer Jean-Baptiste Bourguignon
DAnville (16971782), famed for his geographies of Africa, Asia,
and the Americas, confessed his reliance on Katp elebis world
geography, Cihnum, in describing the lands between Afghanistan
and the Indus in his own claircissements Gographiques sur la Carte de
lInde (1753).5
We do not know the name or qualications of the Ottoman cartographer who at some point between 1727 and 1728 completed the
large map of Eurasia reproduced in black and white outline in gure 2.6

Stato Militare dellImpero Ottomanno (Amsterdam and Hague: Herm. Uytawerf &
Franc. Changuion, 1732; reprint, Graz-Austria: Akademische Druck Verlagsanstalt,
1972), vol. 1, 910, insert. On Ebbekir b. Behrmn Nusretl (slms (ad-Dimaski)
maps, see G. J. Halasi-Kun, The Map of }eki-i Yeni Felemenk Maa (ngiliz in
Ebubekir Dimi{kis Tercme-i Atlas Mayor, Archivium Ottomanicum 11 (1988): 5170.
On Marsigli, see John Stoye, Marsiglis Europe, 16801730: The Life and Times of Luigi
Ferdinando Marsigli, Soldier and Virtuoso (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1994).
5
La pluspart des lieux marqus sur ma carte entre Kandahar & lIndus, je les
dois a la geographie Turque, conpile par Kiatib-shelebi, sous le titre de GehanNuma (le miroir du Monde), confesses Jean-Baptiste Bourguignon DAnville in his
Eclaircissements Geographiques su La Carte de lInde (Paris: De lImprimerie royale, 1753),
20. For DAnvilles place in the early cartography, Leo Bagrow, History of Cartography,
2d ed., revised and enlarged by R. A. Skelton (Chicago: Precedent Publishing, 1985),
18586.
6
TKSK H. 447. The map measures 210 cm. 150 cm. Faik Re{id Unat (Tarih
Vesikalar 1 [Istanbul, 1941], 160 insert) published an outline of it without commentary, which I have reproduced in Fig. 2; passing mention is made by Ahmet
Karamustafa in J. B. Harley and David Woodward, eds., Joseph E. Schwartzberg,
Gerald R. Tibbetts, and Ahmet T. Karamustafa, assoc. eds., The History of Cartography
vol. 2 pt. 1, Cartography in the Traditional Islamic and South Asian Societies (Chicago:
University of Chicago Press, 1992), 225; Thomas D. Goodrich, Old Maps in the
Library of the Topkap Palace in Istanbul, Imago Mundi 45 (1993): 12033. Professor
Goodrich calls TKSK H. 447 the rst modern political and economic Ottoman
map. He attributes the Iranian geography to a map of Iran found in J. B. Homans
Neuor Atlas, a copy of which is also in the Topkap Saray Library (H. 2740).
According to Goodrich, another copy of the same map, albeit lacking coloring, is
found in the Istanbul Archeological Museum. I am extremely grateful to him for
his attention to this chapter and for sharing photographs of a third copy, found in
the Kriegsarchiv in Vienna.

Fig. 2 An outline drawing of a map produced in the palace of Ahmed III. One of several
colored copies, the original is found in the Topkap Saray Museum Library (H. 447). After
Faik Reid Unat, ed. Tarih Vesikalar 1 (1941): 160161. By permission of the Trk Tarih
Kurumu and Topkap Saray Museum.

33

Clearly, however, he is a beneciary of an ongoing exchange of


scientic information between East and West. The science of cartography in the Ottoman Empire advanced with the arrival of
European manuals on geography and mapmaking.7 Translations of
new surveying methods and descriptions of unseen lands enriched
an already well developed Islamic scientic foundation. By the early
eighteenth century, in addition to manuscripts describing the New
World and portolan charts of the oceans, maps of Europe, the Black
Sea, and the Caspian rolled o the presses of the court engineer
(brahim Mteferrika (16741744). An ocer of Hungarian origin,
(brahims eorts were supported by sultans and viziers.8
Even by the rigorous scientic and artistic standards of the day,
the anonymous cartographers eort is prodigious, unique for its subject matter, scale, and artistry. On the original, an enormous canvas tableau (measuring three meters in length and a meter and half
in height), we would see an empire drawn across the Asia of
Ptolemy in the measure of Alexander the Great. In this rendering,
Eurasia stretches from the borders of Rumeli (Thrace) at the far left
to the Pamirs and the foothills of the Himalayas near its right border.9

7
Generally, Abdulhak Adnan Adivar, Osmanl Trklerinde Ilm (Istanbul: Maarif
Matbaasi, 1943). Katib eleb or Haci Halifa Mustafa ibn Abullah was familiar
with Mercators Atlas Major (Bagrow, History of Cartography, 210211). On the impact
of European science on the Ottomans during the rst half of the eighteenth century, see Ekmeleddin (hsano[lu et al., eds., Osmanl Co[rafya Literatr, vol. 1, 11143.
In 1732, (brahim Mteferrika published Katib elebs (Haci Halifa Mustafa b.
Abdullah) Kitab- Cihnnma (Constantinople). On the state of Islamic cartography,
see also David A. King, World Maps for Finding the Direction and Distance of Mecca:
Examples of Innovation and Tradition in Islamic Science (Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1999); and
Thomas D. Goodrich, The Ottoman Turks and the New World: A Study of Tarih-i Hind-i
Garbi and Sixteenth-Century Ottoman Americana (Wiesbaden: Harrassowitz, 1990). For
sixteenth-century European maps of the Ottoman Empire, see Jerry Brotton, Trading
Territories: Mapping the Early Modern World (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1998).
8
See Turgut Kut and Fatma Tre, eds., Yazmadan Basmaya: Mteferrika, Mhendishane,
Uskudar (Istanbul: Yap Kredi, 1996); William J. Watson, (brahim Mteferrika and
Turkish Incunabul, JAOS 88 (1968): 43541; Halasi Kun, (brahm Mteferrika
(A 5, pt. 2: 896900; (brahim Mteferrika published Katib elebs Kitab- Cihannuma
in 1732. On the exchange of information between Europe and the empire, Virginia
H. Aksan, An Ottoman Statesman in War and Peace: Ahmed Resmi Efendi, 17001783
(Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1995), 3442.
9
There is a Ptolemaic conception of Asia at work; note book 7 of Ptolemys
Geography (Lennart Berggren and Alexander Jones, Ptolemys Geography: An Annotated
Translation of the Theoretical Chapters [Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2000]).
See also Karl J. Schmidt, An Atlas and Survey of South Asian History (Armonk, N. Y.
and London: Missouri Southern State College, Sharpe: 1995), 19; and Serpil Ba[c,

34

Without betraying the secrets behind its commission, much less the
patrons political aims, the map still resonates with imagined deliberations in vizierial chambers concerning history, technology, and
territorial ambitions. The mottled colorings of provinces and territories contrast with one another in soft blue, red and yellow while
the pale green seas appeal to the aesthetic inclination of the viewer,
as well as enhancing the maps topographical and regional character.10
It is not improbable that map celebrated the empires newest military conquests. The armies of Sultan Ahmed III (r. 17031730) and
his son-in-law, Grand Vizier Nev{ehirli (brahim Pasha (r. 17181730),
were victorious in the lands of what had been their chief Muslim
rival, the Shii Safavid shah of Iran. Occupying the cities of Tabriz
and Hamedan, the sultan had annexed the provinces of Azarbayjan,
Kermanshah, and Luristan. The members of imperial council, the
divan, undoubtedly debated the czars strategy in the Volga region.
Looking east beyond Turanthe great middle ground between
the empiresthey might have contemplated the status of the country of Tibet (already under Manchu rule), which is proled in upperright corner.
In two large cartouches that obscure part of Arabia and Upper
Egypt, the cartographer puts his purposes in more modest terms:
The principal aim and object of this map is to render a pictorial and
written account in accordance with the principles of the science of
geography, the clime, or rather the continent of, Asia; its countries,
towns, territories, seas, mountains and rivers, from the felicitous seat
of the abode of the kingdom, the most excellent Istanbul, eastward to
the lands of India. And within this expanse [its objective] is [also] to
capture to the best of our ability, the breadth and length of the settlements, seas, countries, and lands over which the exalted Ottoman
state rules . . . to record in picture and text those of the land of Iran
otherwise known as Acem and those of [the lands of ] Turan, in the
vicinity of the Oxus river, as well as [the region of ] Transoxiana . . .

Osmanl Dnyasnda Efsanev Ynetc Imges Olarak Byk Iskender ve Osmanl


Iskendernamesi, in Humana Boskurt Gven e Arma[an (Istanbul: Kltr Bakanl[,
1994), 11131, for the geographical conquests and the later iconography of Alexander
the Great within Ottoman art.
10
Karen Pinto (American University in Beirut) gave me a brief introduction to
the importance of color in medieval Islamic world maps. Compare, Franois de
Dainville, Le langage des gographes: termes, signes, couleurs des cartes anciennes, 15001800
(Paris: A. et J. Picard, 1964).

35

where today reside the Uzbek, a[atay, Turks, Turkmen and Tatar
and other tribes and clans . . .11

The scale of this enterprise appears to intimidate the cartographer.


He seems unsure of his ability to do justice to the many kingdoms
and lands that he has been commissioned to depict. The legends,
commentary, and captions written over the map are more than ornament. They enhance his images with historical explication, orientation, and institutional relief, compensating in words for the limits of
his visual knowledge. In deference to his sovereign, Istanbul gures
prominently in the upper right of his canvas, but the cartographer
cannot but pay greater homage to Mecca and Medina. He embellishes the symbols for the Holy Cities of Islam and places them at
the nexus of many lines of trade and pilgrimage. Giving short shrift
to the birthplace of the Prophet Muhammad, he apologizes for his
omission of much of the Arabian peninsula by reminding his viewers that the areas inhabited by the beduins are so large that it takes
six and half months to travel the length and breadth.12
Words allow him to provide potentially useful logistical information beyond the empire. He oers the approximate distances between
Georgia and the Black Sea, the length, in farsakhs (farshakh/parasang,
a league or 3 miles) of the province of Azarbayjan. He inscribes
over the Persian Gulf the number of days, thirty-two, it takes monsoon winds to speed a dhow from the Makran coast to Oman.

11
The author is presently preparing a translation of the entire text with a detailed
analysis of the map for publication. Hakki buyurulmaya ki, asitane-i saadet a{iyane-i
belde tayibbe-i Konstantiniyeden ibtidaen olup, {arkta memlik-i Hindustana varinca mesafe-i mbeyinde vaki memlik ve bilad, yerar, bihar, cibel, ve enhar kaidei fenn-i co[rafya zre resm ve tahrir olunmak i{ bu haritada umde ve maksud ul-asl
oldu[una binaen, iklim-i Asya tabir olunur kitaya dahil ve mesafe-i merkumede vaki
olup, tulen ve arzen daire-i Devlet-i liye-i Osmaniyenin hakim oldu[u yer ve bihar
ve memlik ve bilad alel-kader l[ittikan ?] tersim ve te{kil olunup, Iran-Zemin
tabir olunur Acem dahi bitamam madud resm ve tahrir ve Nehr-i Ceyhunun
mavaresinde Turan Zeminde . . . hala mesken-i tavaif-i zbek ve a[atay ve Trk
ve Trkmen ve Tatar ve sair kabail ve a{air meskunlar olan memlik-i Maaverannehir . . .
12
(klim-i Ceziretl-Arap, bu iklim on iki kisma taksim olunup . . . bu iklimin
mesafesi ve devri alt buuk ay mesafe olup, i{ bu haritada tamamen resmine mesaha
olma(ma)[la, Mekke-i Mkereme ve Medine-i Mnvvera vaki oldu[u memleket-i
Hicazdan ve bdiyeden bir miktar resm iktifa olunmu{tur . . . For more on the
Hijaz during this period, see Abdulrahman S. M. Alorabi, The Ottoman Policy
in the Hejaz in the Eighteenth Century: A Study of Political and Administrative
Developments, 11431202. (Ph.D. diss., University of Utah, 1988).

36

Indeed, his lines are meant to convey movement as well as static


information. They represent the pilgrims, soldiers, and merchants
traveling in convoys along highways and linkages between cities. The
oceans surge: a galley sets sail on the Mediterranean. Yet as he proceeds eastward, the reliability of his comments falters and his information about the current state of aairs in the eastern regions of
Iran wears thin. And he seems unaware of the political disposition
of either Afghanistan or India.13
Although these inaccuracies may have troubled and certainly misled his contemporaries, they in no way detract from the maps cultural and historical value. As a densely coded document of a past
conception of space as much as a graphic description of the larger
Eurasian context of the empire, it is the combination of the textual
(tahrir) and the graphic (resm) that leads modern viewers closer toward
the multitude of intersections that qualify an Ottoman appreciation of territoriality in the early eighteenth century.14 Often these
mediums of conveying information take us in opposite directions. As
an image of mountains, deserts, and rivers, the map draws our gaze
toward the two great inland seas, the Black and the Caspian, and
to the foci of Russo-Ottoman conict during the eighteenth century.
The narrative, by contrast, describes the political and institutional
space of states. The legend leads our eye not from the center or
from the edges but from west to east, beginning with Anatolia, or
as the cartographer prefers, Asia Minor (Kk Asya, his translation from the Latin). In a landscape without graphic boundaries
or borders, the description of provinces and principalities in words,
not lines, slices through painstakingly rendered topographic details
depicting the high plateaus of Anatolia and Iran, the mountain ranges

13
See W. Bartold, An Historical Geography of Iran, trans., Svat Soucek (Princeton:
Princeton University Press, 1984). Khorasan is rendered as the clime (iklim) of
Hirandan, though correctly identied by its cities of Herat, Nishapur, and the
site of the tomb of Imam Rza (i.e., Mashhad). These and other mistakes lead me
to suspect that a painter, rather than a geographer, supervised and executed the
nal versions.
14
Henri Lefebvre, The Production of Space (Oxford: Blackwell, 1994), 33. For dierent
views on the historical meaning of space, see Edward Soja, Postmodern Geographies:
The Reassertion of Space in Critical Social Theory (London: Verso, 1989); Robert D. Sack,
Human Territoriality: Its Theory and History (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
1986); and David Harvey, On the History and Present Conditions of Geography:
An Historical Materialist Manifesto, Professional Geographer 3 (1984): 111.

37

and deserts of the Hindu Kush, and along the riverine systems from
the Nile to the Amu Darya.
This is a landscape of classical proportions, drawn in accordance
with modern, that is, mimetic, cartographic standards. As such, it is
not simply another, less familiar way of framing the Ottoman Empire
on a world map. Rather, by inserting this European and Asian state
in a contiguous meridian of state from the Mediterranean eastward,
it emphatically conveys to modern viewers the cultural artice of
Europe and of a natural division between Orient and Occident.
Ottoman Asia is not external to but hinges on an intersecting political geography. It serves as a check on European expansion in the
Balkans and continues to shape and constrain the ever-changing balance of power among the great powers of continental Christendom
that emerged in the aftermath of the Treaty of Utrecht in 1714.
Sitting out the exhausting series of dynastic squabbles of the rst
half of the eighteenth century, not only that of Spain but of Poland
(173135) and Austria (174048), the Ottoman military, though weakened, held its forward line in Europe, to the consternation of both
the Habsburgs and Russians.
Territorially, however, the gravitational center of this map is not
the Ottoman Empire per se. Rather, by dint of its rendering of
Ptolemaic Asia, it emphasizes Iran, the center of an unfolding drama
whose impact would reverberate globally. The collapse of the Safavid
state in 1722 with an invasion of its former Afghan vassals was not
simply another example of the fragility of dynastic regimes and the
tentative nature of the territorial state. As the opening salvo in a
series of devastating civil wars (resumed in 1747 and again in 1779),
or what should properly be called the Iranian Wars of Succession,
it also proved the tenacity of the Safavid political system, for the
ensuing seven decades of conict invariably brought forward a claimant
from among the dynastys former tribal confederates. Although the
initial phases of the war drew in Irans more powerful neighbors,
the Ottomans and Russians, the partition of Iran would not hold.
Moreover, between 1739 and 1741, the Iranian wars fatefully spilled
across the Indian Ocean.15
15
Virginia Aksans comments (Ottoman War and Warfare, 14531812, in War
in the Early Modern World, ed. Jeremy Black [London: University College London
Press, 1999], 14776) on the military constraints of the empire serve as a much
needed antidote to a rather sweeping and overly simplistic assessment of West Asian

38


Edges of Empires

The cartographer is rather tight-lipped about the extent of the


Ottoman incursion into its neighbor, Safavid Iran. Perhaps that is
because the sultan had only recently signed a new trade agreement
with Shah Sultan Huseyin II (r. 16941722).16 By setting aside the
rhetoric of Shi"i-Sunni sectarianism, nearly a century of peace prevailed between the two countries, lasting from the Treaty of Zuhab
(1639) until the Ottoman invasion of Luristan and Azarbayjan in
1724. Quiet on the eastern frontier had freed the Ottomans to continue their expansion into the Aegean and to launch a nal, illconsidered bid to pluck the red apple of Vienna from the center
of Catholic Europe in 1683. In the humiliating aftermath of the
Peace of Karlowitz (1699), which ceded Hungary to the Holy Roman
Emperor, this pattern of mutual recognition and peaceful negotiation with the shah of disputes over trade routes and taris allowed
the Ottomans to counter Peter the Great at Pruth in 1711 and to
salvage the Morea from Venice four years later.
Yet the death of Huseyin II with the Ghalzai invasion overturned
the West Asian order suddenly and radically. Proting from the
Afghan siege and occupation of Isfahan, Russian troops occupied the
silk-producing Caspian provinces of Dagestan and Shirvan. As the
surviving Safavid heir, Shah Tahmasb II (r. 17221732?), ed northward toward his Qizilbash confederates, the Afshars and Qajars,
members of the Ottoman imperial council (divan) weighed their
response.17 In an unusual meeting of minds, mediated by the French

geopolitics in the eighteenth century, including that of C. A. Bayly in Imperial


Meridian: The British Empire and the World, 17801830 (London: Longman, 1989). For
an inclusive and interactive approach to Europe-Eurasia, see Charles Tilly, Coercion,
Capital and European States, AD 9901990 (Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1990) and Paul
W. Schroeder, The Transformation of European Politics, 17631848 (Oxford: Clarendon
Press, 1994). For chronology, see (smail Hakk Uzunar{l, XVIII Yzyl, vol. 4, pts.
1 and 2, Osmanl Tarihi (Ankara: TTK Basmevi, 1983); and Peter Jackson and
Laurence Lockhardt, eds., The Timurid and Safavid Periods, vol. 6 of The Cambridge
History of Iran (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1986).
16
Mnir Aktepe, ed., 17201724 Osmanl-Iran Mnasebetleri ve Silah{r Kemani Mustafa
A[a"nn Revan Fetih-Namesi (Istanbul: Istanbul niversitesi Edebiyat Fakltesi Yaynlar,
1970), 68.
17
Ibid. For a pioneering study on the Ottoman policy during its occupation of
Iran, see Fariba Zarinebaf-Shahr, Tabriz under Ottoman Rule, 17251730 (Ph.D.
diss., University of Chicago, 1991). See also B. H. Sumner, Peter the Great and the
Ottoman Empire (Oxford: Blackwell, 1949); and Raoul Motika and Michael Ursinus,

39

ambassador, Ahmed III agreed to recognize Peter the Greats gains


in the Caspian. The czar, in exchange, acquiesced to the sultans
territorial ambitions in Azarbayjan and Georgia.18
The opportunity to push the Ottoman frontier forward into the
Caucasus and western Iran was not missed, although this military
gamble and potential overreach of manpower and supply lines was
still carried out within an overall geopolitical calculus of East-West
commitments. Yet, as the Russo-Ottoman agreement to partition
Iran demonstrates, force of arms was increasingly tempered with
diplomacy. From the outset of the century, West Asia was abuzz
with envoys and new diplomatic initiatives.19 The Ottoman court
received an embassy from the Kalmyk tribes of the eastern Volga
in search of an alliance that would protect them from the Russians
in Astrakhan.20 Viziers entertained ambassadors from the Uzbek ruler
of Transoxiana, the empires habitual Sunni partner and beneciary
of its military technology in containing the heretical Safavids.21
After years of silence, the new Mughal sultan, Farrukhsiya, dispatched
a plenipotentiary to Istanbul in 171213, in the rst of what appears
to have been several missions.22

eds., Caucasia between the Ottoman Empire and Iran, 15551914 (Wiesbaden: Reichert,
2000).
18
Aktepe, 17201724 Osmanl-Iran Mnasebetleri, 1932; J. C. Hurewitz, The Middle
East and North Africa in World Politics, 2 vols. (New Haven: Yale University Press,
1975), 1:6574; and Ernest Tuckers excellent analysis, The Peace Negotiation of
1736: A Conceptual Turning Point in Ottoman-Iranian Relations, TSA Bulletin 20
(1996): 1637.
19
P. Kahle, China as Described by Turkish Geographers from Iranian Sources,
Proceedings of the Iran Society, vol. 11 (London, 1940), 4859.
20
On the ill-fated negotiations initiated by Kalmyks with the Russians, the
Manchu, and the Ottomans between 1704 and 1714, Michael Khodarkovsky, Where
Two Worlds Met: The Russian State and the Kalmyk Nomads, 16001771 (Ithaca: Cornell
University Press, 1992), 139, 15355.
21
Sultan Ahmad II (r. 16911695) toyed with the idea of joint action against
the Safavids in 1691. However, the Uzbek dynasty itself was fractured. Undoubtedly
this is why the cartographer describes Balkh as a part of Khorasan [which] has
many rulers and towns. Currently, it is under the rule of Uzbeks. See also
J. Audrey Burton, Relations between Bukhara and Turkey, IJTS 5 (199091):
83103; and on the arrival of the Uzbek ambassador, Anonim Osmanl Tarihi
(1099 1116/16881704), ed. Abdlkadir zcan (Ankara: Trk Tarihi Kurumu
Basmevi, 2000), 222.
22
On Ottoman claims to the caliphate and relations with the Mughals, see
Naimur Rahman Farooqi, Mughal-Ottoman Relations: A Study of Political and Diplomatic
Relations between Mughal India and the Ottoman Empire, 15561748 (New Delhi: Idarah-i
Adabiyat-i Delhi, 1989), 671.

40

If contacts among West Asian states remained episodic, the rst


decades of the century witnessed a phase of sustained, multilateral
diplomatic relations with the empires Western neighbors, the Christian
nations (milel-i nasrani ). Throughout the century, France, which under
Louis XIV began casting its diplomatic net ever wider in eastern
Europe, the Black Sea, and the Indian Ocean, retained its place as
most favored ally. Yet Istanbul also recognized the need to diversify
its alliances in the Mediterranean and signed new treaties and commercial agreements with the British and Dutch.23 At war again
between 1737 and 1739 with Austria and Russia, to which he lost
the key Crimean fortress of Azov in 1736, the sultan tried to hem
in the czar diplomatically in the Baltic by concluding agreements
with both Sweden and Denmark.24
Certainly, friends like the king of France were able to wrest
unprecedented liberties in the Red Sea, with respect to Christian
holy sites in Palestine, in addition to expanding their commercial
privileges in Istanbul itself.25 However, the Sun King and his successors repaid the sultan in kind. French diplomatic nesse proved
invaluable in the complicated negotiations with Habsburg Austria
that resulted in the restoration of Ottoman control over the city of
Belgrade in 1739. After the heyday of Franco-Ottoman relations
under the embassy of the Marquis Louis Sauveur de Villeneuve

23

Halil (nalck, Imtiyzt, EI 2 3: 11781189. Ottoman missions to Europe


included Russia (172223, 174042), Austria (1719, 1730, 1748, 175758), France
(1721), and Poland (1730, 175758) (Faik Re{it Unat, Osmanl Serleri ve Sefaretnameleri
[Ankara: TTK Basmevi, 1987]). See also (brahim Mteferikas description of the
dierent forms of government in Europe, Usll-Hikem f Nizml-Umem, ed. Adel
}en (Ankara: Trkiye Diyanet Vakf, 1995); and the extremely interesting, though
anonymous, dialogue between a Christian and Muslim ocer from this period,
published by Faik Re{id Unat, Ahmed III devrine ait bir Islahat Takiri, Tarih
Vesikalar 1 (1941): 10721. For examples of reports and analysis of individual missions during the rst half of the eighteenth century, see Beynun Akyava{, ed.,
Yirmisekiz elebi Mehmed Efendinin Fransa Sefretnmesi (Ankara: Trk Kltrn Ara{trma
Enstits, 1993), and MubadeleAn Ottoman Russian Exchange of Ambassadors, annotated and translated by Norman Itzkowitz and Max Mote (Chicago: University of
Chicago Press, 1970). For an overview of Ottoman-European diplomatic practice,
see Maria Pia Pedanis meticulous study, In Nome del Gran Signore: Inviati Ottomani a
Venezia della Caduta di Costantinopoli alla Guerra di Candia (Venezia: Deputazione Editrice,
1994) and Aksans An Ottoman Statesman.
24
Charles of Sweden sought Ottoman help as early as 1709. Karl A. Roider, Jr.,
Austrias Eastern Question, 17001790 (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1982), 18.
25
France, too, dreamed of dividing the empire according to L. Darperon, Le
Grand Dessein scret de Louis XIV, Revue de Gographie 1 (1877): 43561.

41

between 1728 and 1741, Versailles regard for its ally, the Sublime
Porte, may have waxed and waned over the second half of the century. Nonetheless, the Portes military presence in the heart of Europe
as much as the prospect of furthering Russian territorial gains at
Ottoman expense in the East, remained a sobering thought for
Vienna. Peace held with Istanbul from 1740 to 1769.26
The increasing frequency of diplomatic exchange was bound to
have an impact on the way Ottoman statesmen saw other powers,
as well as on the way both sides came to view the still illusive concept of territorial sovereignty during this period.27 Certainly the battle cry in Europe to throw the Turk completely out of Europe,
remained as loud as ever and, invoking the spirit of the Crusades,
still enlisted the support of Pope Clement XII, who levied a special
tithe on Church properties within Austria itself in 1737. Yet depending on the context, one might discern that the Realpolitik between
states and the succession crises contributed to an overall muting of
traditional religious and sectarian overtones in favor of respect for
dynastic claims.28 Continued Ottoman negotiations with the last
Safavids (Tahmasp II [r. 172229] and 'Abbas III [r. 172936]),
although without issue, did have their political motivation. By begrudging recognition to both the Sunni Afghan and Tahmasp Kuli
Khan, the Afshar regent who would declare himself sovereign under
the name of Nadir Shah in 1736, indeed, condemning both as rebels,
Ottoman statesmen clung to the ction of the Safavid dynastic
legitimacy.29
Rather than trying to reconcile the semantic drift among historical accounts, diplomatic formulae, religious treatises, and internal

26
For more on Habsburg-Ottoman relations, see Roider, Austrias Eastern Question.
And for an introduction to Russias Iran question, see Muriel Atkin, Russia and
Iran, 17801828 (Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press, 1980).
27
Note the utterly contradictory reports of the extravagant Ottoman embassy to
Vienna in 1718. Roider, Austrias Eastern Question, 59.
28
Much to the unhappiness of Austria, the Ottomans took their inclusion in
intra-European diplomacy quite seriously: they tried to mediate the Austrian war
of succession and sent a protest to Maria Theresas after her decision to expel the
Jews of Prague whom she charged with collusion with Prussia. Roider, Austrias
Eastern Question, 77, 95.
29
Tucker, The Peace Negotiation of 1736, 22. Decades of war would eventually prod Istanbul into formal recognition of Nadir Shah. But the Safavids continued in egy: the last puppet shah, Ismail III, would die in 1773. See J. R. Perry,
The Last Safavids, 172273, Iran 9 (1971): 5970.

42

memos, we may defer to our cautious cartographer, whose words


and images match terminology with coordinates in space.30 However,
to reconsider sovereignty from this perspective does require modern
viewers to suspend their operating understanding of the unitary state
as it emerged in the nineteenth century and with Ratzelian notions
of political geography.31 Indeed, early modern rule was far from
even: from the center to its frontier, state control was a question of
degrees and forms. Above all, it was a matter of the mapmakers
perspective.
Describing the permutations of power from Istanbul, the cartographer naturally accords his own patrons the highest expressions of
stateness: it is the Ottomans who rule (hakim), enjoy the fruits of
(tassaruf ) or vanquish (zapt) territory. Dening the gradations between
direct institutional control conveyed by the Ottoman division into
provinces (eyalet) and military districts (sancak) or, for the Safavids,
into command units (tumen)and the myriad forms of suzerainty
remains an exercise in frustration: often on the maps face or in the
legend one reads the term tbi [dependent] in conjunction with a
dynastic title over lands, peoples, and cities. He thus recognizes lands
attributed to the Uzbeks, the Safavids, the czars (Moscow), and the
Mughals (Monarch of India).
Apparently, other considerations enter into our mapmakers evaluation of suzerainty, vassalage, and tributary polities. Before doubling back in his legend to acknowledge the Ottoman occupation of
Tiis and Kaht,32 the cartographer relates that Georgia, a non-trib-

30
Navigation and shipping terminology had long been received multiple inuences.
For an example of the hybridity of geographic idiom, see the treatise of Bartnl
(brahim Hamdi (Cengiz Orhonlu, XVIII Yzylda Osmanllarda Co[rafya ve
Bartnl (brahim Hamdinin Atlas, Tarih Dergisi 10 (1959): 11540). (brahim uses
such locutions as the European frontier, (hudud-i Avrupa) and translates the
papal state in Rome with the term hkmet (reserved in Ottoman parlance for
the enclaves ruled by Kurdish dynasties). This comparison, beyond the bounds of
the present work, must take as its point of departure Katib elebis Kitab- Cihnnma:
see Gottfried Hagen, Ein osmanischer Geograph bei der Arbeit. Entstehung and Gedankenwelt
von Ktib elebis Cihnnm. Ph.D. diss., Freie Universitt Berlin, 1996).
31
For a critique of the work of Friedrich Ratzel, the political geographer of
Bismarcks Germany, see Lucien Febvres La terre et lvolution humaine. introduction gographique lhistoire (Paris: Renaissance du Livre, 1922). The literature on sovereignty
is also relevant. For an introduction to European thought on the subject of sovereignty, see Jens Bartelson, A Genealogy of Sovereignty (New York: Cambridge University
Press, 1995).
32
The legend makes no mention of the Russian occupation or the the Afghan

43

ute-paying but politically subordinate principality, is itself subdivided


into dierent countries (lke).33 Large expanses of steppe and desert,
such as Transoxiana and Arabia, where uid relationships among
nomadic pastoralists may or may not obey a proximate agrarian
hegemon, are left to the imagination.34 Above all, what seems to
matter, in every quarter of the map and every verbal qualier, is
history. Time pervades space. It justies the recognition of neighbors, whether or not their claims are granted equality with those of
the sultan. Time also accounts for the layering of jurisdictions,
exemplied by the recurrence of the word realm (or country)
(memlikat, pl. memlik), which does not so much beg the question of
independence as of prior or concurrent political identities.35
For those habituated to reading sovereignty from the political and
ethnoreligiously coded maps drafted in western Europe ateliers during this period or from the pen of a pope who with one stroke
divided the Americas between the Spanish and Portuguese crowns
under the Treaty of Tordesillas (1494), the Ottoman cartographers
reluctance to encapsulate dynastic claims and nations with graphic
lines seems strange. Indeed, given the sultans undiminished assertion
of universal sovereignty, the lack of an apparent nes ottomanorum in

siege of Isfahan. The cartographer does volunteer logistical information and in the
case of Shirvan, described by its sixteenth-century Ottoman name, Demrkap,
admits that it has been redivided into seven military districts. (. . . nevah-i Demrkap
Devlet-i liye canibinden zabt olundukta yedi sanca[a taksim olunmu{, sancaklar
bunlardr, }abur, Da[istan, Dahti, Be{ker, Dur, Berrak, Destab). As for Georgia,
we are nally told that it is half under the rule of the Ottomans. (Memlik-i
Grcstan bilada tahrir oldu[u zre bu memleketlerin nisf miktar teden ber
Devlet-i liye"e tbi ve nisf-i ahri Aceme tbi olup, Aceme tbi olan yerleri Tiis
ve Kaht eyaletleri bir ka tmen ad olunur . . .) For military appointments to
Tabriz, Erdilan, Genc (Ganja), Rumiye, and Mara[a, see Fahameddin Ba{ar, Osmanl
Eylet Tevciht (17171730) (Ankara: TTK Basmevi, 1997).
33
Pitcher, An Historical Geography, 140.
34
Over the face of the map, in the vast, uncharted regions of the Kara and
Kzl Kum, he simply writes, The tribes of the Tatar, Turk, Turkmen, Kalmyk
and Kalamak, Mongol, Kazak, and other nomadic peoples.
35
Bartnl (brahim Hamdi (Orhonlu, XVIII Yzylda Osmanllarda Co[rafya,
139) attempts to use terminology with a certain consistency: e.g., empire applies
to Spain while Austria and Venice are distinguished with the term clime (iklim). As
on our map of Eurasia, the parts that make up such compound polities are often
recognized as having a separate historical identity, such as the country (memliket)
of al-Andalus or bundles of semi-sovereign countries, such as the Germanys, memliket-i Cermanya. See also Henry Kahane, Rene Kahane, Andreas Tietze, The Lingua
Franca in the Levant: Turkish Nautical Terms of Italian and Greek Origin (Urbana: University
of Illinois Press, 1958), 59497.

44

Asia might strike the viewer as overtly menacing.36 Yet in this simple and telling act, the Ottoman cartographer betrays one of the
great secrets of absolutism. True bordersfully surveyed, mapped,
and continuously demarcated with ditches, fences, and walls, and
monitored by a network of stations and fortresseswere still a rarity and would remain so even in western Europe until the nineteenth century. Part of the blu and bluster of colonizers, they were
hardly relevant to imperial claims or the actual disposition of colonies,
including those in the Americas.37 Thus, despite the obsessive reection
on the territorial state after the Peace of Westphalia (1648), on many
fronts, including that between Russia and the Ottomans, the cessation of conict often meant retaining whatever territories and fortresses
were in hand, in accordance with the venerable Roman principle of
uti possidetis.38
Recently, some exceptions had appeared.39 An unusual clause in
the Treaty of Karlowitz (1699) which dictated the formation of a
commission to survey and physically dene a border stretching the
entire length of the Croatian-Ottoman frontier to an exactitude of
two hours from either side, did constitute, as Rifaat Abou-El-Haj
notes, an unambiguous declaration of territorial integrity.40 But
even the foremost scientists of the day, Count Marsigli being one of

36
For reections on the ideology of expansion, see Pal Fodor, In Quest of the
Golden Apple: Imperial Ideology, Politics, and Military Administration in the Ottoman Empire
(Istanbul: Isis Press, 2000).
37
Compare the gradual formation of frontiers between New World empires in
Richard White, The Middle Ground: Indians, Empires, and Republics in the Great Lakes
Region, 16501815 (Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press, 1991);
and their claims to sovereignty, in Anthony Pagden, Lords of the World: Ideologies of
Empire in Spain, Britain and France, c. 15001800 (New Haven: Yale University Press,
1995), 78.
38
The territoriality of the state remained of utmost concern for political thinkers
in Europe of the seventeenth and early eighteenth centuries. For more on Hobbes,
Spinoza, Locke, and von Pufendorf, among others, see Quentin Skinner, The Foundation
of Modern Political Thought, vol. 2 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1978);
Stoye, Marsiglis Europe, 101; and Roider, Austrias Eastern Question, 4459.
39
Compare Peter Sahlins, Boundaries: The Making of France and Spain in the Pyrennees
(Berkeley: University of California Press, 1989), 27475; Stoye, Marsiglis Europe,
18183.
40
Rifa"at 'Ali Abou-El-Haj, The Formal Closure of the Ottoman Frontier in
Europe, JOAS 89 (1969): 467; see also Stefanos Yerasimos, Questions dOrient: Frontiers
et Minorits des Balkans au Caucase (Paris: Editions de Decouverte, 1993), and Gunter
E. Rothenberg, The Austrian Military Border in Croatia, 15221737 (Urbana: University
of Illinois Press, 1960). For important new studies on Ottoman borders, see Dariusz

45

them, found their astrolabes and surveying instruments inadequate


to the task. Ottoman and Hapsburg representatives alike returned
to time-honored methods of judging the edge between empires: they
neglected mountainous regions entirely and readily deferred to natural markers, such as rivers. Indeed, the frontiers remained as they
had been since antiquity: zones of continuous passage and exchange
as much as of regulation and military control.41
There were nonetheless other man-made solutions to the problem
of frontiers between political units.42 Recasting the modern image of
the state, it is helpful to think of early modern polities not only as
bundles of realms but as packages containing multiple cores and
variegated edges. The wide margins or edges that separated larger,
dominant powers were themselves composed of more loosely controlled zones and subordinate polities, qualied in Ottoman Turkish
with salyane or haracguzar, and often rendered, unhappily, with modern terms such as vassal-state, client, tributary, or protectorate. Looking
at the maps rendering of the Black Sea, we must envision the cluster of such semiautonomous polities that formed an active, at times
mobile, frontier between the Ottoman heartland, Russia, and Poland.
It was composed of peoples, including the Nogay Tatars and Zaporozhye Cossacks, as well as the principalities of Moldavia, Wallachia,
Transylvania, and briey, Podolia-Ukraine.
Although all parties established pragmatic policies with regard to
their more dominant neighbors, specic constitutional terms dened

Kolodziejczyk, Ottoman-Polish Diplomatic Relations (15th18th century): An Annotated Edition


of Ahdnames and Other Documents. Ottomans, Hungarians, and Habsburgs in Central Europe:
The Military Connes in the Era of Ottoman Conquest (Leiden: E. J. Brill, 2000); and
Daniel Power and Naomi Standen, Frontiers in Question: Eurasian Borderlands, 7001700
(Basingstoke: Macmillan, 1999). In The Ottoman-Venetian Frontier (15th18th
Centuries), in The Great Ottoman-Turkish Civilization, ed. Kemal iek, Ercmen
Kuran, Nejat Gyn, (ber Ortayl, et al. (Ankara: Yeni Trkiye, 2000), 1: 17177,
Maria Pia Pedani Fabris makes a case for an earlier prototype in the Adriatic.
41
Stoye, Marsiglis Europe, 17576. On the subject of frontiers, see also Whittakers
comments (in Frontiers of the Roman Empire, 6672), which are based on the conceptual framework of Lucien Febvre (La Terre et lEvolution Humaine).
42
Owen Lattimores discussion (Inner Asian Frontiers of China [New York: Oxford
University Press, 1940], 244) suggests a dual frontier, a concept that recognizes both
the ecological limits of territorialization and need for political demarcation. By contrast, David Moon (Peasant Migration and the Settlement of Russias Frontiers,
15091897, The Historical Journal 40 (1997): 859893) speaks of three frontiers
beyond the political: between forest and steppe, between peasant and tribesman,
as well as between peasant village and Russian administration.

46

relationships and the extent of reciprocity within the Ottoman political umbrella. The Orthodox principalities submitted to Muslim
suzerainty, rather than that of Christian Russia or Catholic Poland,
in order to safeguard their own religious autonomy. In exchange for
logistical services, notably provision of grain for the Hungarian campaigns and tributary payments to Istanbul in war and peacetime,
they retained the right to select their prince from among the landholding elite and to refuse the indignities of having Muslim soldiers
or merchants quartered in their cities.43 In the Crimea, the Giray
Khans played a parallel territorial role. However, by virtue of their
status as Muslim military allies, their receipt of sizable subventions
from Istanbul, as well as protection money from their Christian neighbors, they retained a far greater degree of independence in the conduct of internal and external aairs. The Crimean Khan proclaimed
his hegemony over weaker Tatar groups such as the Nogay.44 Notable
for the Black Sea region as a whole during the rst decades of the
eighteenth century was the increasing rigidity of the relationship
between frontier-state and suzerain power. In a period of rising
Russian inuence, Tatar deance of Istanbul resulted in blunt intervention in the Crimean khanate in 1703.45 As for the principalities,
Istanbul bypassed the local elite altogether after 1716, selecting new
hospodars and voyvoda from the prominent Greeks of the Fener quarter of Istanbul, the so-called Phanariote.46
Religious animosity electried other perimeters of the empire.
Beyond the bounds of our map, in the Magrib, the largely inde-

43
Uzunar{l, Osmanl Tarihi, vol. 4, pt. 2, 4177. }erban Constantin, La
suzerainete Ottomane a lgard des pays roumains dans le contexte des relations
internationales Europenes (Sec. XVIXVII), Tarih Dergisi 32 (1979): 21118; M. M.
Alexandrescu-Dersca Bulgaru, Lapprovisionnement dIstanbul par les Principauts Roumaines au XVIIIe siecle: Commerce ou Requisition? RMMM 66 (1992):
7378; compare Bistra Cvetkova, Les celep et leur rle dans la vie conomique des
Balkans lpoque ottomane (XVeXVIIIe s.), in Studies in the Economic History of
the Middle East, ed. M. A. Cook (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1970), 17293.
44
A. W. Fisher, Les rapports entre lEmpire ottoman et la Crime: Laspect
nancier, CMRS 13 (1967): 36881, notes the increased dependency of the khanate
because of the curtailment of the Crimean slave trade in the rst decades of the
century; see also Uzunar{l, Osmanl Tarihi, vol. 4, pt. 2, 137.
45
Abou-El-Haj, The Formal Closure, 47274. For French mediation between
Poland and the khans, see Gilles Veinstein, Les Tatar de Crime et la seconde
lection de Stanislas Leszczynski, CMRS 11 (1965): 2492.
46
For an Ottoman perspective, Mnir Aktepe, ed., Mehmed Emni Beyefendi Pa{a"nn
Rusya Sefareti ve Sefaret Namesi (Ankara: TTK Basmevi, 1989), 52.

47

pendent and hereditary Deys of Algiers, Tunis, and Tripoli faced o


against their perennial foes, Spain, the Knights of Malta, and Catholic
buccaneers.47 In eastern Europe, the Catholic borderlands of the
Balkans, Croatia, Hungary, and Slovakia, and after 1721, Venetian
Dalmatia, parried the Muslim-ruled Balkans. The Wars of the Iranian
Succession also rekindled sectarian hatreds between Sunni and Shi'i
Qizilbash although the newly crowned Nadir Shah (r. 173647) tried
to distinguish his own reign by declaring his veneration of Ja"far,
the sixth, rather than of Reza, the eighth, Imam.
Yet it would be a mistake to see religious antagonism as an indelible mark on the geopolitical map. As the common-cause alliances
between Cossack and Tatar in previous centuries and the TunisianEuropean treaties struck in the rst decades of the eighteenth century demonstrated, political empathy and commercial concerns still
transcended confessional lines.48 In fact, it was Catholicisms resurgent anti-Protestantism, in Hungary and in France, the revocation
of the Treaty of Nantes in 1691, that more accurately characterized
the changing nature of religious frontiers. As western European attitudes toward the other at home hardened, the multiconfessional
enclaves of Albania, Bosnia, and Mount Lebanon made the Ottoman
Empire appear as more incidious threat: a permeable frontier of
shaded contrasts rather than stark contraries.49 Indeed, extraterritorial rights clouded borders; between Karlowitz (1699) and the Treaty
of Kk Kaynarca in 1774, dynastic sovereignty was enhanced by

47
Uzunar{l, Osmanl Tarihi, vol. 4, pt. 2, 25358; Abdallah Laroui, The History
of the Maghrib: An Interpretive Essay (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1977),
26270.
48
See Charles Frazee, Catholics and Sultans: The Church and the Ottoman Empire,
14531917 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1983). Gregory L. Bruess
(Religion, Identity, and Empire: A Greek Archbishop in the Russia of Catherine the Great
[Boulder: East European Monographs, 1997], 61) notes that Russia insisted on the
dissolution of the Zaporozhian Cossak Host in 1774, precisely to subsume this
nation under the larger banner of religion. On the religious frontier in another
setting, see Richard M. Eaton, The Rise of Islam and the Bengal Frontier, 12041760
(Berkeley: University of California Press, 1993), 22867.
49
Conversion to Islam in Albania was a continous process, according to Ferit
Duka, XVXVIII. Yzyllarda Arnavut Nfusunun Islamla{mas Sreci zerine
Gzlemler, Ankara niversitesi Osmanl Tarihi Ara{trma ve Uygulama Merkezi Dergisi 2
(1991): 6372. On Bosnia, see Michael Robert Hickok, Ottoman Military Administration
in Eighteenth-Century Bosnia (Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1997); and on Lebanon, Richard van
Leeuwen, Notables and Clergy in Mount Lebanon: The Khazin Sheikhs and the Maronite
Church (17361840) (Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1995).

48

extraterritorial claims, not only for the Habsburg emperor over


Catholics and for the czar over Orthodox populations with the
Ottoman lands but also with respect to the sultans caliphal authority over Muslims living in Christendom.50
Precisely because nationalism has tended to color the boundaries
between states in ethnic as well as confessional hues, it has become
dicult to appreciate the fact that the internal edges of empire, as
well as the edges abutting constitutionally tributary powers, also
molded themselves to new geopolitical and institutional conditions.
Just as the Ottomans reached forms of accommodation with both
Christian and Muslim subordinates along the frontier with Christendom,
they also accommodated Muslim elites within. In fact, accommodation was built into the administrative architecture of Asia. Logistics
alone demanded an administrative system with ample institutional
seams and wide political perimeters. The road from Istanbul to
Baghdad is more than twice the length of that to Belgrade.51 As the
premier Muslim power in the West, the sultan had earned the designation and responsibilities of the servitor of the Holy Cities,
guardian of Mecca and Medina. However, with normal communications requiring three to four weeks to relay information between
Egypt and Damascus alone,52 the supervision of the yearly pilgrimage, which in the measure of the day entailed 316.5 hours journey
from Istanbul to Damascus and nearly equal time, 379 hours, to
Mecca (150 days of normal travel), was increasingly delegated to the
pashas of Damascus and the janissary serdar in Cairo.53
In the Red Sea region, the age of gunpowder weaponry had only
accentuated the inherent obstacles to direct rule. After local powers

50

D. Sourdel, Khal fa, EI 2 4: 946.


Murphey, Ottoman Warfare, 22; Halil Sahillio[lu, Drdnc Muradin Ba[dad
Seferinin Menzilnamesi, Belgeler 2 (1965): 136.
52
Antoine Abdel Nour, Le Rseau Routier de la Syrie Ottomane (XVIeXVIIIe
sicle), Arabica 30 (1983): 174.
53
TKSK MS. H. 446 (17621763) is a record of the post-stations (menzilhane)
and the distances between them in hours from Uskudar to Mecca. According to
Marsigili (Stato Militare, vol. 1, 9) The Turks measure distances between places by
the hours that a horse can traverse at a good pace which corresponds to three
Italian miles. Murphey (Ottoman Warfare, 65) estimates a typical 45 hour day
of riding to average 22 kilometers. For general orientation, see Suraiya Faroqhi,
Pilgrims and Sultans: The Hajj under the Ottomans (London: I. B. Taurus, 1994), 15662.
On the Egyptian caravan, Jane Hathaway, The Politics of Household in Ottoman Egypt:
The Rise of the Qazada[l (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997), 134.
51

49

gained access to artillery, muskets, and other ordinance, the Ottoman


armada, once the lords of the Horn of Africa and southern Arabia,
relinquished Yemen denitively in 1636, and by the end of the century, its presence had receded to the coastline.54
The Egypt proled in our map also required a new type of ruling formula. Until the rise of Ali Bey al-Kabir after 1757, the large
garrisons of Cairo, regular circuits of intra-imperial commerce, highlevel appointments (to the governorship and the elite mterrika corps),
as well as the large yearly payment (salyne), secured strong ties to
the Istanbul court. At the same time, Cairo witnessed the rising
inuence of local military households aspiring for the de facto power
of the beylicate, particularly under the Qazda[l party and competition for leadership of the seven regiments. As in the Balkans these
developments, it may be argued, owed less to a slackening of Ottoman
rule than to a local economy swollen with commerce. In Cairo,
wealth revolved around the coee trade and state contracts issued
for the endowed grain lands benetting the Holy Cities.55
Similarly, the West Asian reaches of the empire, with their low
population density, relative to that of western Anatolia and the
Balkans, and with their widespread nomadic or seminomadic populations, continually confounded attempts to impose an overarching
imperial apparatus and, for the purposes of security and war, to allocate resources eectively.56 Although the road network of western
and northern Anatolia permitted wheeled trac, from the Euphrates

54
Halil (nalck, The Socio-Political Eects of the Diusion of Fire-Arms in the
Middle East, in War, Technology and Society in the Middle East, ed. V. J. Parry and
M. E. Yapp (London: Oxford University Press, 1975), 2036.
55
See Hathaway, The Politics of Households; and Kenneth M. Cuno, The Pashas
Peasants: Land, Society, and Economy in Lower Egypt, 17401858 (Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 1992).
56
For a useful model, see G. William Skinner, Cities and the Hierarchy of
Local Systems, in The City in Late Imperial China, ed. Skinner (Stanford: Stanford
University Press, 1977), 275351. For an attempt to estimate the empires eighteenth-century population, see Bruce McGowan, The Age of the Ayan, in An
Economic and Social History of the Ottoman Empire, ed. Halil (nalck with Donald Quataert,
Cambridge UK: Cambridge University Press, 1994), 666; Following Daniel Panzac,
(La population de lEmpire ottoman et de ses marges du XVe au XIXe sicle: bibliographie (194180) et bilan provisoire, Revue de lOccident Musulmane et e la Mditerrane.
31 [1981]: 11937) and others, McGowan estimates the population of the empire
as a whole, circa 1800, to have been between 25 and 32 millions, with all parts
of the empire, but particularly the Asian provinces, lagging behind growth in western Europe.

50

southward convoys of donkeys, horses, and camels would remain the


chief mode of transport for cargo and people toward destinations in
Syria and Iraq.57 Neither the Euphrates nor the Tigris was fully navigable until the advent of the steamship. Only in spring and summer when the water was at its highest, could barges, laden with
timber, grain, and copper, depart Diyarbekir on the upper Tigris
for Basra, arriving two months later.58 Thus despite the presence of
the janissary corps, the award of scal contracts, and ongoing cooperation in maintaining the security of the imperial highway,
powerful local regimes were needed to contain the festering frontier
with Iran, one of the causes of rural unrest, as tribes, mercenaries,
bandits, and lawless provincial ocers competed for resources. An
Istanbul appointee to the governorship of Baghdad, Hasan Pasha
(r. 170224) founded a new dynasty that, perpetuated by his son,
Ahmad (r. 172447), and subsequently by their administrative corps,
slaves of Georgian origin, guarded Ottoman interests while holding
on to regional power until the early nineteenth century.59
As the cartographer put the nal touches on the geography of
Asia, Istanbuls direct control over provincial administration in West
Asia was probably at its highest point in decades. Even so, as he
arrives at the easternmost edge of the empire, the border with the
Iranian shah, a distance of more than four hundred hours from
the army encampment in Uskudar, he indulges in an uncharacteristically long digression on the region of Kurdistan that helps us
to put the nature of territorial sovereignty under this old regime in
its proper perspective.60

57

Suraiya Faroqhi, Camels, Wagons, and the Ottoman State in the Sixteenth and
Seventeenth Centuries, IJMES 14 (1982): 52339, 55354; and F. Taescher, Das
Anatolische Wegenetz nach Osmanischen Quellen, 2 vols. (Leipzig: Mayer & Mller, 192426).
58
Cengiz Orhonlu, Osmanl (mparatorlu[undaunda Derbend Te{kilt (Istanbul: Eren,
1984), 12833. Additionally, many of the Euphrates ports were fortied with heavy
artillery according to (nalck, The Social-Political Eects of the Diusion of FireArms, 214.
59
For an appreciation of local dynamics, see Tom Nieuwenhuis, Politics and Society
in Early Modern Iraq (The Hague-Amsterdam: Studies in Social History of the
International Institute of Social History, 1982); Percy Kemp, Territoire de lIslam: le
monde vu de Moussoul au XVIII e sicle (Paris: Sindbad, 1982); Hala Fattah, The Politics
of Regional Trade in Iraq, Arabia and the Gulf, 17451900 (Albany: State University of
New York Press, 1997); and Dina Rizk Khoury, State and Provincial Society in the
Ottoman Empire Mosul, 1540 1834 (Cambridge; New York: Cambridge University
Press, 1997).
60
To be exact, it took 408.5 hours for the route between Uskudar and Tabriz.

51

The region (vilayet) of Kurdistan, he relates, begins in area of


Hormuz [in the Persian Gulf ] and comprises Malatya and Mara{;
its northernmost region is Yerevan (Armenia) and its southernmost,
Mosul and Iraq.61 Without mentioning its population or ethnicity,
the cartographer continues his description of this vaguely cultural
geography by noting the centrality of a magnicent mountain range,
which begins at the frontier of the [Safavid] provinces of Fars and
Kerman and stretches as far as Van and the mountain of Erzurum
[Ararat?].62 Although an ambiguous rendering of space, it is such
ecological details that evoke both peculiar sociological adaptations to
this region as well as a physical and economic remoteness that permitted its myriad populations alternately to evade and comply with
the proximate agrarian-based state.63
Yet there remain other details that capture the dierence between
the Ottoman frontier and the lands properly belonging to its neighbor,
the Safavids. Kurdistan is not simply an ecological zone between
states. Rather, it is a vast region whose constituent societies are given
peculiar coordinates in space by dominant powers. Here, the cartographer does not attempt to reduce these internal sociological divisions to sectarianism, although this was indeed a factor historically
in fostering allegiances between Kurdish tribes, sultans, and shahs.
Instead, he distinguishes political allegiance in the very forms of
autonomous and semiautonomous organization. Thus, those loyal to
the house of Osman reside in places [that] go by the name of sancak [fully surveyed, command districts], hkmet [hereditary counties
granted to a tribal leadership] and ocaklk [semiautonomous but non-

Suleymaniye Library, Esad Efendi MS. 2362 pt. 8 (n.d.) Anonymous, Menzilname,
folios 15759. Special envoys and couriers traveled at a much faster pace. For
example, the Ottoman ambassador who left the capital on 29 May 1724 arrived
in Yerevan on 17 June (Aktepe, 17201724 Osmanl-Iran Mnasebetleri, 3132).
61
In contrast to the eyalet, Marsigli (Stato Militare dellImpero Ottomanno, 9) translates vilayet, credibly, as all large countries (tutti i paesi vasti).
62
Vilayet-i Krdistan: vilayet-i Hrmzden ibtida Malatya ve Mara{ hududunda
mntehi olur; {imalisi Revan, cenubisi Musul ve Irak- Arabdr. Ve asl- Cebel-i
Krdistan Acem diyar[n?]da Fars ve Kirman hududundan [ahiz ?] edp, Vana
ve Erzurum cebeline ula{r. Cebel-i azime silsile ve muttasldr. Bazi yerleri sancak
hkmet ve ocaklk nvanlaryla li Osmana tbi, bazi yerleri serhad- }ah- Acemde
vaki olmu{tur. On sekiz miktar vilayet ad olunur.
63
From the perspective of the state, this was a zone of economic marginality,
as Lattimore in Inner Asian Frontiers notes, but it also featured a symbiosis between
pastoralism and agriculture. On this point, see A. M. Khazanov, Nomads and the
Outside World (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1984).

52

hereditary enclaves]. An organized and bounded autonomy, as much


as formal administrative division, closes the Ottoman edge, separating it from Kurdish tribes, which, as he says elsewhere, are found
within the borders [serhad ] of the shah.64

From the Inside Out


Without drawing a line on the map, the cartographer uses text to
establish the mettle of a state, its organizational logic, and the sociopolitical relationship between subject and sovereign.65 This preference
for depicting space in numbers and words is not a surprising response
from a servant of an early modern state famous for leaving an
astounding paper trail. In the sixteenth century, the Ottomans established sovereignty by quill as well as by sword: assembling a regions
inhabitants and notables, a bureaucrat worked with the local kad

64

Martin van Bruinessen, The Ottoman Conquest of Diyarbekir and the


Administrative Organization of the Province in the 16th and 17th Centuries, in
Evliya elebi in Diyarbekir, ed. Van Bruinessen and Hendrik Boeschoten (Leiden: E. J.
Brill, 1988), 1328. The 1555 treaty between the Ottoman sultan and the Kurdish
}erif Han of Bitlis (Nazmi Sevgen, Krtler V, Belgeler 3 [1968]: 70) dened a
hkmet as a hereditary ef that included fortresses, cities, villages, and elds; Hezarfen
Hseyin Efendi (Sevim Ilgrel, ed., Hezarfen Hseyn Efendi Telhisl Beyan Kavanin-i
Al-i Osman [Ankara: TTK Basmevi, 2000], 132) qualies hkmet with such expressions as free from accounts and possessor of all its fruits (mefruzl-kalem ve
maktl-kadem olup evbab- mahsulat her ne ise hakimleri mutasarrfdr). The
legend gives the same breakdown for Diyarbekir that we nd in the mid-seventeenth century: ve hkmet (Cezire, E[il, Gen, Palu, and Hazzo)and eight ocaklks
(Sa[man, Kulp, Mihrani, Tercil, Atak, Pertek, apakur, and ermik) that carried
no hereditary rights. See also, Chref-ouddne. Chref-Nmeh ou Fastes de la Nation
Kourde, trans. Franois Bernard Charmoy (St. Ptersbourg: lAcadmie Impriale des
Sciences, 1873). Naturally, this did not guarantee autonomy in later centuries, as
Kann-nme-i Sultn li Azz Efendi: 'Aziz Efendis Book of Sultanic Laws and Regulation:
An Agenda for Reform by a Seventeenth-Century Ottoman Statesman (ed. and trans. Rhoads
Murphey [Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1985] makes clear; for the eighteenth century, see Mouradgea DOhsson Tableau gnral de lEmpire othoman, divis en
deux parties, dont lune comprend la lgislation mahomtane; lautre, lhistoire de lEmpire othoman (Paris, Imp. de monsieur [Firmin Didot] 17871820), vol. 7, 299; and DA
IV:45.
65
Jean Bodin (On Sovereignty: Four Chapters from the Six Books of the Commonwealth,
ed. and trans. Julian H. Franklin [Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1992],
56) denes sovereignty juridically and institutionally, not territorially, asserting that
the rst prerogative of sovereignty is to give law to all in general and to each in
particular, the latter part refers to privileges, which are in the jurisdiction of sovereign princes to the exclusion of all others.

53

and cavalry ocer to carry out the cadastration of each eyalet and
component sancak of the empire. These tomes were prefaced by a
kanunnme, a codication or compendium of customary law and imperial statute as well as relevant Islamic codes, describing the obligations and rights of subjects.66 Although the types of taxation changed
over the centuries, they overlay a fundamental relationship between
sovereign and subject established with the rst local administrative
codes.67 Preparation for war in the eighteenth century still entailed
mustering a wagon load of registers, from texts of treaties, tax receipts,
the numbers of taxable households, provincial complaints and remedies, to the timetable of installments from tax contractors and the
tribute from Egypt. With such guides, paymasters and commanders
could nd the names of ocials in exile, determine sources of cash
and raw material, and reference important security matters.68
Like a register, the cartographers legend guides us on another
tour of West Asia. Keenly aware of logistics, to the extent knowledge and page permit, his commentary is driven by the administrative space of the Caucasus, Iran, and Central Asia. Like an
architect, he rebuilds the empire itself, beginning with the inner
(Ktahya, Karaman, and Sivas) and then the outer (the Mediterranean coast and Cyprus) provinces of Anatolia. His geographical
narrative scans the limits of Anatolia on the Euphrates (the province
of Ayintab); then, after a detour through Syria, it returns to the

66
For the classical cadastral system, see mer Lt Barkan, Research on the
Ottoman Fiscal Surveys, in Studies in the Economic History of the Middle East, ed.
M. A. Cook (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1970), 16371; D. A. Howard, The
Historical Development of the Ottoman Imperial Registry (Defter-i Hakan): MidFifteenth to Mid-Seventeenth Centuries, Archivum Ottomanicum 11 (1988): 21330;
and H. (nalck, Suleiman the Lawgiver and Ottoman Law, Archivum Ottomanicum
1 (1969): 11724. Most tahrir were carried out in the sixteenth century and are now
housed in the Ankaras Tapu Kadastro Kuyd- Kadime Ar{ivi and the Ba{bakanlk
Osmanl Ar{ivi in Istanbul. For a late European example, Dariusz Kolodziejczyk,
The Defter-i Mufassal of Kaminie from ca. 1681: An example of Late Ottoman
Tahrir, Reliability, Function, Principles of Publication, JOS 13 (1993): 9198; and
for early-eighteenth-century Tabriz, Zarinebaf-Shahr, Tabriz under Ottoman Rule,
11520.
67
See H. (nalck, Osmanllarda Raiyyet Rsmu, Belleten 23 (1959): 575600.
68
Feridun M. Emecen, Sefere Gtrlen Defterlerin Defteri, in Prof. Dr. Bekir
Ktko[luna Arma[an, ed. Mbahat Ktko[lu (Istanbul: Edebiyat Fakltesi Basmevi,
1991), 24168. For a register that fell into enemy hands before Vienna in 1783,
see H. G. Majer, Das osmanische Registerbuch der Beschwerden (}ikayet Defteri) wom Jahre
1675: sterreichische Nationalbibliothek Cod. Mixt. 683 (Wien: Verlag der sterreichischen Akademie der Wissenschaften, 1984).

54

Northeast and the province of Erzurum, which he reminds us, was


formerly part of Ermeniye [Armenia]. From the Caucasus and the
eastern shores of the Black Sea, he completes the tour with a secondary tier of provinces in the region of the Tigris (Diyarbekir,
Mosul, }ehrizor), Iraq, and Arabia. Given the constraints of space,
the cartographer hardly pauses between his list of twenty-one provinces
and their constituent command units.69
There are times, however, when the need to add critical information overcomes economy. Without mentioning the Ottoman states
point of origin around the Byzantine cities of Bursa/Brusa and Iznik/
Nicea, the cartographer proceeds directly to the province of Ktahya,
where he provides a eeting glimpse into the politics of the states
early centuries. Reminding his readers that Ktahya enjoys a special position because its annexation to the Ottoman state took place
through divine assistance, he refers to the prestige of the Germiyan
dynasty from which the city was wrested and the dream that foretold the ascent of the Ottomans to world power.70 On a more mundane note, Ktahyas importance lay in its early incorporation as a
province in the last decade of the fourteenth century, the second
formal unit after Rumeli, the eastern Balkans. An institutional milestone, the introduction of this distinctively Ottoman administrative
structure saw the transformation of a loosely knit alliance between
a frontier lord and tribal armies, bound by oral agreements, honor,
and the spoils of raiding into a hierarchy headed by the provincial
commander, or beglerbe[i, and the subcommander, or sancakbe[i.71
Armed with estimates of agricultural production and the disposition

69
Compare the cartographers list of twenty-one provinces with gures and dates
found in Halil (nalck, The Ottoman Empire: The Classical Age, 13001600 (New York:
Praeger Publishers, 1973), 10418 and Ayn-i Ali Efendi (Tayyib Gkbilgin, ed.,
Kavnin-i l-i Osman der Hlsa-i Mezmin-i Defter-i Divn [Istanbul: Enderun Kitabevi,
1979].) DOhsson, Tableau gnral, vol. 7, 27879, speaks of twenty-six government
generaux (malikne-i miri ) and eighteen hundred ressorts de justices (nahiye) in the
Middle East.
70
Eyalet-i Ktahya ibtidaen talu gkse Devlet-i liye ebed-i kyyamdan buna
gelince merat olunan kaide-i mustahsna zre avn ve inayet-i hak ile feth ve teshiri
myesser olan memlik taksim olundukta be[lerbe[li[e . . . bir memleket eyalet itibar
olunup, ol eyalet dahi nice elviye itibar olunageldi[ine binaen, eyalet-i Ktahya on
yedi sancak itibar olunmu{tur.
71
Cemal Kafadar, Between Two Worlds: The Construction of the Ottoman State (Berkeley:
University of California Press, 1995), 89, 7677; compare, Isenbike Togan, Flexibility
and Limitation in Steppe Formations: The Kerait Khanate and Chinggis Khan (Leiden: E. J.
Brill, 1988).

55

of elds and villages, viziers, commanders, and bureaucrats assigned


taxable units of land (timar) in lieu of salary to the cavalry while
oering a deed of hereditary usufruct to the peasant.
Although the temptation is great for historians to measure the
eciency and order of Ottoman statecraft by the yardstick of the
classical sancak military hierarchy, changing tactics and technologies
of warfare, especially in the European theater, would soon reduce
the emphasis on cavalry in favor of musket-bearing infantry. An
enduring aspect of rural administration, the timar would change in
function and number while the janissaries, once a special guard,
levied from the Balkans and assigned to the palace, became a standing army of tens of thousands, domiciled in the capital, in large
cities, and frontier garrisons.72 Beginning in the early seventeenth
century, the full-time infantry was seconded by battalions of mercenaries (sekban, levend ) and, eventually, large militias (mkemmel kap)
maintained by provincial governors and viziers.73
With an appreciation of such enormous changes in the structure
of the empire, the cartographer pauses again at Syria. Perhaps, this
is a sign of respect to the former seat of the Umayyad caliphs. It
also provides him the pretext to emphasize the continuities, and not
only the dierences, between Sunni dynasties. His contemporaries
would have been well aware of the signicance of the conquest of
Damascus, particularly when, within the space of a year, the conquest of Mamluk Egypt made the sultan the preeminent Muslim
power of the Mediterranean. The addition of these large, rich provinces
tilted the demography of European and Asian empire toward its
Muslim subjects. It is no coincidence that the ourishing of Hanete
legal thought and especially the outpouring of fatwa from the pen of
Suleyman the Magnicents chief jurist, Ebu Su"ud Efendi, occurred
as the state integrated this Muslim intelligentsia. Syrian and Egyptian
lawyers questioned the status of land designated as eminent domain

72
Hseyn Efendi Hazarfen (Hezarfen Hseyn Efendi Telhsl Beyan f Kavanin-i Al-i
Osman, ed. Sevim Ilgrel [Ankara: TTK Basmevi, 2000], 143) distinguishes between
salaried and nonsalaried forces. On the janissaries generally, see (. H. Uzunar{l,
Osmanl Devleti Te{kilatndan Kapkulu Ocaklar. Acemi Oca[ ve Yenieri Oca[ (Ankara:
TTK Basmevi, 1943); for Cairo, Andr Raymond, Le Caire des Janissaires: Lapoge
de la ville ottomane sous Abd al-Rahman Katkhuda (Paris: CNRS Editions, 1995).
73
Murphey, Ottoman Warfare, 1642; and H. (nalck, Military and Fiscal
Transformation in the Ottoman Empire, 16001700, Archivum Ottomanicum 6 (1980):
283337.

56

(miri ) and disputed the onus of taxation.74 With or without the hairsplitting treatises of the ulema, Ottoman administrators took care to
ease the incorporation of Muslim elites with special inducements,
ranging from high position, the total exemption from bureaucratic
accounts and scal surveys (such as the tribal hukumet), and split-rent
agreements (malikane-divani ) to large military estates (zeamet) and longterm tax-farming leases.75
The cartographer credits Ottoman administration with remaining
faithful to the original territorial divisions of the Syrian lands, transforming such units as the province of Palestine (cund-i Filistin) and
other realms into full-edged Ottoman eyalet.76 He is not entirely
accurate. Once the dust had settled after early sixteenth-century conquests, the addition of an outer tier of provinces (vilyat- saire), stretching from the eastern Black Sea southward through the Fertile Crescent,
prompted Istanbul to reconsider its overall organization of procurement and recruitment. Provincial boundaries were drawn and redrawn.
The initial land surveys in the provinces of Syria, Kurdistan, eastern Anatolia, and Iraq dedicated a greater share of land to crown
lands and viziers estates (hass- hmayun) than in western Anatolia.77

74
Colin Imber, Ebu"s-su"ud: The Islamic Legal Tradition (Stanford: Stanford University
Press, 1997), 13537. For the debates, see Baber Johansen, The Islamic Law on Land
Tax and Rent (London: Croom Helm, 1988).
75
Irne Beldiceanu-Steinherr, Fiscalit et formes de possession de la terre arable
dans lAnatolie Preottomane, JESHO 19 (1976): 234322; I. Beldiceanu-Steinherr,
Malikne, EI 2 4: 22728; Abdul-Rahim Abu-Husayn, The Iltizam of Mansur
Faraykh: A Case Study of Iltizam in Sixteenth Century Syria, in Land Tenure and
Social Transformation in the Middle East, ed. Tarif Khalidi (Beirut: American University
in Beirut Press, 1984), 249256. For an exhaustive study of one of the provinces
where the Muslim elite went over to the Ottoman side, see M. Mehdi Ilhan, Amid
(Diyarbakr) 1518 Tarihli Defter-I Mufassal (Ankara: TTK Basmevi, 2000).
76
The legend explains that each cund ( jund [in Arabic, a military division or
army]) should be regarded as a separate realm (memliket): Beyan iklim-i }am.
Bundan akdem }am iklimine mutasarrf olanlar }am ikliminin muhit oldu[u memliki be{ ksma taksim edp, her ksmna cund tesmiye her cundi bir memlekete izafe
etmi{lerdir. Mesala cund-i Filistin, cund-i Ardan, cund-i Dima{k, cund-i Hums, cund-i
Kanasrin gibi. Ve cund dedikleri kurradr. Yani bir kita memliktir ki medden kasabat ve kariye m{temil ola. Devlet-i liye ebed-i kiyyam Osmaniye iklim-i
}ama mutasarrif oldukta resm-i sabik zre bir ka eyalet itibar eylemi{lerdir.) For
the original divisions, see Ruth Kark, Mamluk and Ottoman Cadastral Surveys
and Early Mapping of Landed Properties in Palestine, Agricultural History 71 (1997):
4670.
77
mer Lut Barkan, Timar, (A 12, pt. 1: 288. In comparison to Western
Anatolia, where 26 percent of cultivated lands was set aside for imperial domains
and more than half (56 percent) was held by individual cavalry ocers, in Diyarbekir,

57

Such estates functioned as a pool of discretionary scal units (mukatat)


for local treasuries.78 In this outer tier, the timar-cavalry coexisted with
functionaries assigned to imperial estates. In addition to the janissaries and urban ocials, Istanbul sent special scal agents (emin),
awarded contracts to tax farmers (mltezim), and allowed individuals
and entire companies to designate their own stewards and intendants
to collect the revenues assigned for their upkeep and salary.79
Yet there were myriad drawbacks to liquidity. At the turn of the
seventeenth century Istanbul bureaucrats introduced the rst universal, direct taxes, the avrz- divaniye and the bedel-i nzl, which
were levied on both rural and urban households. As a regular cash
ow that bypassed the cavalry, these funds could be utilized within
the region or forwarded, as need arose, to another province or the
imperial treasury.80 However, social upheaval also followed in the
wake of sharp increases in direct taxation. Swollen provincial treasuries provided the means for local pretenders to gain power. As
populations ed before demobilized mercenaries, and rebellions, such
as those launched by Fakhr al-Din Ma"n II, amir of Mount Lebanon
(15901635), and the Celalis (15951609) in Anatolia, the loss of
agricultural labor eectively dissolved many individual timar and
severely eroded the basis of the older system in which protection
services were bartered for peasant rents.
31 percent and in Syria (Aleppo and Damascus combined), 48 percent of lands of
the landed resources were designated as imperial domains and thus were often
administered with some form of revenue contract
78
Douglas Howards ne study of the changing timar system, The Ottoman
Timar System and Its Transformation, 15631656, (Ph.D. diss., Indiana University,
1987), establishes the causes for the dissatisfaction of the full-time cavalry. He also
notes the desire of Sultan Murad IV (162339) to balance payments in kind with
cash taxation or cash-units, which could be redistributed as stipends (ulufe, ocaklk)
and retirement income (arpalk or fodder money). Alternately, they could be eventually earmarked for expenses or for the salaries of individual ocers and battalions.
79
In 159697 (MMD 7637:24), the largest single component of cash taxes in
the provincial treasury was found under the heading of the muktat- vilyet-i
Diyarbekir, that is, 180,000 kuru{ of a total of 539,000 kuru{. Most of these tax farms
were collected by janissaries. See also Rhoads Murphey, Regional Structure in the
Ottoman Empire: A Sultanic Memorandum of 1636 A.D. Concerning the Sources and Uses of
the Tax-Farm Revenues of Anatolia and the Coastal and Northern Portions of Syria (Wiesbaden:
Otto Harrassowitz, 1987), Introduction.
80
Linda Darling, Revenue-Raising and Legitimacy: Tax Collection and Finance Administration
in the Ottoman Empire, 15601650 (Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1996), 81119. See also Halil
(nalck, Centralization and Decentralization Ottoman Administration, in Studies in
Eighteenth Century Islamic History, T. Na and R. Owen (Carbondale: University of
Southern Illinois Press, 1977), 2752.

58

As we will see in chapter 3, although the province of Diyarbekir


was particularly hard hit by these rebellions and continuing tribal
depredations along the lower Tigris broader, we must also attribute
changing patterns of administration to secular change in grain cultivation and urbanization. Former tribal areas, benetted from an
inux of cultivators, as did the districts closest to cities.81 Therefore,
even as the Ottoman state restored order in Syria and eastern
Anatolia, the new tax system allowed for seemingly contradictory
trends. Bureaucratic sleight of hand and changes in appointment
procedures gave the central state the upper hand over the provincial military hierarchy, all the while the central state devolved more
of the quotidian duties of administration and policing to regional
authorities.82
Although these details may not have concerned the mapmaker,
what he does draw attention to is how the Ottoman state resolved
these logistical problems and integrated the myriad changes into its
military and administrative structure. Cash could not resolve all of
the organizational problems caused by such dicult communications
and the resulting costs of forwarding basic supplies, from fodder
to foodstus, to the front.83 As Rhoads Murpheys studies make

81
On peasant ight during and after the Celalis, see Wolf-Dieter Hutteroth and
Kamal Abdulfattah, Historical Geography of Palestine, Transjordan and Southern Syria in
Late 16th Century (Erlangen: Frankische Geographische Ges., 1977); Mustafa Akda[,
Celali Isyanlarndan Byk Kagunluk, 16031606, Tarih Ara{trmalar Dergisi 2
(1964): 10.; and MMD 7637:2 (1596); and William Griswold, Political Unrest and
Rebellion in Anatolia 10001020/15911611 (Berlin: Klaus Schwarz Verlag, 1983).
The proportion of ruined (harabe) timar in the tahvil register KK 493, dating from
1694 is particularly high in the urban districts of Amid (22 percent) and Ergani (33
percent).
82
Both (brahim Metin Kunt (The Sultans Servants: The Transformation of Ottoman
Provincial Government, 1550 1650 [New York: Columbia University Press, 1983],
6869) and Rifa"at 'Ali Abou-El-Haj (The 1703 Rebellion and the Structure of Ottoman
Politics [Istanbul: Nederlands Historisch-Archaeologisch Instituut te Istanbul, 1984],
43) note a shift in control over appointments over full-time salaried positions toward
central state elites. Karl Barbir (Ottoman Rule in Damascus, 17081758 [Princeton:
Princeton University Press, 1980]) observes a parallel process in the province within
the capital city during the late seventeenth century and early eighteenth century to
centralize apparatus in the provincial cities under civil and military authority. At
the same time, a great many other duties devolved upon personnel. For an extreme
example of privatization, note the case of poststations and couriers: Colin J. Heywood,
The Ottoman Menzilhane and Ulak System in Rumeli in the 18th Century, in
Trkiyenin Sosyal ve Ekonomik Tarihi (10711920), ed. Osman Okyar and Halil Inalck
(Ankara: Hacetepe niversitesi, 1980), 18284.
83
Lt Ger, XVIXVII Asrlardan Osmanl Imparatorlu[unda Hububat Meselesi ve

59

clear,84 the state relied on a regional division of labor with West


Asia, and in particular a triangular inner bulwark formed by the
agriculturally and industrially rich provinces of Sivas-Tokat, Diyarbekir,
and Aleppo. The pivot of past Iranian campaigns,85 the province of
Diyarbekir remained a major source of grains and a center of textile manufacturing. It also possessed an important smelting plant for
copper in its capital, Amid, as well as iron and silver mines (in Kigi,
Ergani, and Keban).86
During the Wars of the Iranian Succession, these overlapping forms
of administrative organization moved into high gear. Areas far from
the front sent monies rather than manpower or, as we read in an
order sent to the northern frontier city of Erzurum, which redirected
income earned from commercial taxes for the purchase of beasts of
burden to supply the army.87 The organization of barley, wheat, and
hardtack, to be purchased at nominal rate from peasants or collected
in lieu of taxes, was often directed by Diyarbekirs voyvoda, an intendant, and in this case, the civil ocial in charge of revenues from
crown and vizier estates.88

Hububattan Alnan Vergiler (Istanbul: Istanbul niversitesi Yaynlar, 1964), 29; L.


Ger, XVIXVIII Asrlarda Osmanl Imparatorlu[unun Ticaret Politikas, 31.
See also Bruce Masters, The Origins of Western Dominance in the Middle East: Mercantalism
and the Islamic Economy in Aleppo, 16001750 (New York: New York University Press,
1988), 113.
84
For a logistical analysis of the Asian defense system, see Rhoads Murphey,
Functioning of the Ottoman Army under Murad IV (16231639/10321049): Key
to the Understanding of the Relationship between Center and Periphery in the
Seventeenth Century Turkey (Ph.D. diss., University of Chicago, 1979). Compare
with the Europe theater of war: Caroline B. Finkel, The Provisioning of the
Ottoman Army during the Campaigns of 15931606, in Habsburgisch-osmanische
Beziehungen/Relations Habsbourg-Ottomanes, ed. Andreas Tietze (Vienna: Verlag des
Verband der wissenschaftlichen Gesellschaften sterreichs), 10724.
85
Diyarbekir lay at mid-point between Basra and Istanbul; it was separated from
the other two important logistiscal cities by approximately ten days travel. Vital
Cuinet, (La Turquie dAsie: Gographie Administrative Statistique Dscriptive et Raisonne de
Chaque Province de lAsie-Mineure [Paris: Ernest Leroux, 18901894], vol. 1, 451), estimates the distance between Diyarbekir and Tokat at 377 kilometers (or Sivas, 302)
and between Diyarbekir and Aleppo at 312 kilometers.
86
Fahrettin Tizlak, Osmanli Devletinde Ham Bakr (sleme Merkezleri Olarak
Tokat ve Diyarbakir, Belleten 59 (1995): 64359. Murphey, Ottoman Warfare, 98101.
87
In 1736, the state ordered (D.MKF 1771) that 2,900 kuru{ from customs income
be used to purchase pack animals for the front. For the impact on the city of
Ayntab, see Cemil Cahit Gzelbey and Hulus Yetkin, eds., Gaziantep {erii Mahkeme
Sicillerinden rnekler (Cilt 81141, Miladi 17291820) (Gaziantep: Yeni Matbaa, 1970),
3435; on Damascus, Barbir, Ottoman Rule in Damascus, 36.
88
In 1701, Diyarbekirs voyvoda provided 15,000 Istanbul kile of wheat for

60

So too, the accordionlike layers of the Ottoman military expanded


as early oensive campaigns of the 1720s turned to defensive strategies in the 1730s and 1740s. The third arm of the Yerevan campaign of 172425, for example, assembled some 60,000 troops in
Georgia under the command of vizier Hasan Pasha. They included
regular cavalry from the provinces of Diyarbekir, Kars, Sivas, Mara{,
Hdevendigar, and Karahisar-i }arki, as well as from the districts of
Aksaray and Bayezid. They were followed by 27,000 janissaries, 1,000
specially-trained infantry, 2,500 technical personnel trained in cannon and other ordinance, and militias commanded by the governors
of Anatolia and Kars.89 When Nadir Shahs armies turned the tables
on the sultan (between 1730 and 1734, and again between 1741 and
1745), threatening Ottoman Iraq and Kurdistan, the Ottoman military activated its reserves: mercenary battalions and local condottieri.90 The defense of the city of Mosul was undertaken by its
governor, Abdlcelil-zde Hseyin Pasha, a prominent member of
the local gentry, who summoned Kurdish tribal armies from the
hkmet (which, according to the mapmaker, may have been those
in E[il, Palu, Cizre, Hazzo, and Genc) in addition to regular cavalry from Diyarbekir, Mosul, and }ehrizor.91

Movements of People, Commodities, and Capital


These territorial conicts with Iran cannot be separated from an
ongoing struggle to control and tax the movement of people and

Daltaban Mustafa Pasha to put down a revolt in Baghdad. (I thank Dina Khoury
for bringing MMD 3134:126 to my attention). For one of many examples during
the era of Nadir Shah, see MMD 10,168:252 (grain at the rate of, 30 sa[ ake per
kile or 22,112.5 kuru{ in 172526); and Cengiz Orhonlu, Osmanl (mparatorlu[unda
unda {ehirilik ve Ula{m zerine Ara{trmalar ((zmir: Ege niversitesi Edebiyat Fakltesi
Yaynlar, 1984), 130; and according to Stephen H. Longrigg (Four Centuries of Modern
Iraq [Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1925], 144), in July 1741, a single order to
restock the Baghdad fortress stipulated 36,150 Istanbul kile of wheat and 150,000
Istanbul kile of barley. See also Robert W. Olson, The Siege of Mosul and OttomanPersian Relations, 171843 (Bloomington: Indian University Press, 1975).
89
Aktepe, 17201724 Osmanl-Iran Mnasebetleri, 1820, 3334.
90
For the life and times of Nadir Shah, see Ernest S. Tucker, Religion and
Politics in the Era of Ndir Shh: The View of Six Contemporary Sources, (Ph.D.
diss., University of Chicago, 1992).
91
Mnir Aktepe, ed., }em"dni-zde Fndkl Sleyman Efendi Tarihi Mur"i"t-Tevarih
(Istanbul: Istanbul niversitesi Edebiyat Fakltesi Yaynlar, 1978) vol. 1A, 11314.

61

goods across West Asia. Of the highways for commerce and pilgrimage etched on the map, in 1722 the Ghalzai horsemen took the
one traversing the belly of southwest Asia. From their native Kandahar
they headed toward Khorasan, where they encountered another
Safavid vassal, the Abdali; from there they rode through Kirman
toward Isfahan, the Safavid capital and chief trading entrepot.92
The Ottomans, too, in response to the Russian occupation of the
silk-producing regions of the Caspian, launched their rst and second oensives through the heart of the East-West trading network.
The second front targeted the northern part of the silk route, which
ran from Tabriz, Irans second-most-important trading center, toward
Anatolia and Syria. Nadir Shah was more audacious still. After testing Ottoman defenses in Iraq, he launched a full-scale assault on
the West Asian trading system. In 173839 he marched on Delhi;
the new Iranian monarch and his Afghan ally and looted the imperial treasury of the Mughals. Upon his return in 1741, he targeted
the coee-rich state of Oman.
Unabashedly material motives did not, however, necessarily obtain
the desired results. The war derailed older trading linkages rather
than securing new ones, often driving away merchants and sending
shock waves through commodity markets as far west as Aleppo.93
Chaos within Iran forced merchants to change their routing while
ships avoided the Safavid ports in the Gulf. Conict choked the
lucrative Iranian silk trade through the Ottoman Empire. Indeed,
Ne{e Erims study of the customs post at Erzurum demonstrates how
quickly this conict extinguished the trans-Anatolian silk trade, which
once accounted for approximately 2 percent of imperial revenues
and furnished an estimated two thousand bales of Caspian silk yearly
for domestic and international markets.94 Mediterranean consumers
soon found alternatives to Iranian goods in Bursa, Syria, Bengal, and

92
The route, including the number of hours between Baghdad and North India,
may be found in an undated but, plausibly eighteenth-century manuscript, Suleymaniye
Library, Esad Efendi MS. 2362 pt. 8, folios 157r159v.
93
Katsumi Fukasawa, Toilerie et commerce du Levant au XVIII e sicle dAlep Marseille
(Marseille: Groupe de Recherche et dtudes sur le Proche Orient Centre Regional
de Publication de Marseille, 1985), 2224.
94
Ne{e Erim, Onsekizinci Yzylda Erzurum Gmr[. (Ph.D. diss., Istanbul
University, 1984), 1314. Generally on this trade, see Rudolph P. Matthee, The
Politics of Trade in Safavid Iran: Silk for Silver, 1600 1730 (Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 1999).

62

China.95 Only the czar translated annexation into commercial advantage. As the cartographers rendering of ships on the Caspian suggest, Russian merchants diverted Iranian silk production northward
through their entrepts at Astrakhan.96
If the merchants of the middle routes, particularly those intersecting with Safavid cities and their chief port of Bandar 'Abbas, felt
the negative impact of war for many decades, commerce in other
Ottoman cities and ports soon revived and even prospered from their
neighbors misfortunes. Pilgrims continued to bring a steady stream
of merchandise both small and large through Damascus. Although
the sub-Saharan gold trade between Takfur to Egypt was already in
decline, ships on the Red Sea and caravans along the Nile carried
coee and Indian goods as well as Chinese export porcelain.97
Commerce on the Black Sea, which remained an Ottoman lake until
1774, expanded rapidly after the Treaty of Belgrade (1739). Ottoman
captains transported Russian traders who were bringing furs and iron
and exchanged these goods in Syria and Istanbul for Indian cloth
and Arabian coee.98 Izmirs entrepreneurs shipped Ankara mohair,
Anatolia cotton twist, and a range of raw agricultural products.99
Throughout the eighteenth century, the Ottoman Mediterranean
ports of Salonika, Izmir, and Alexandria maintained a favorable balance of trade with their European partners.100

95
E. Hertzig, The Iranian Raw Silk Trade and European Manufacture in the
XVIIth and XVIIIth Century, Journal of European Economic History 12 (1990): 7391;
Masters, The Origins of Western Dominance in the Middle East, 196.
96
See Stephen Dale, Indian Merchants and Eurasian Trade, 16001700 (Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press, 1994).
97
There is an enormous literature on the subject, beginning with Andr Raymond,
Les commerants au Caire au XVIIIe sicle, 2 vols. (Damas: Institut Franais de Damas,
197374). For some interesting, recent additions, see Cheryl Ward, The Sadana
Island Shipwreck, in An Historical Archaeology of the Ottoman Empire: Breaking New
Ground, ed. Uzi Baram and Lynda Carroll (New York, Boston, Dordrecht, London,
Moscow: Kluwer Academic/Plenum Publishers, 2000), 185202; and Colette Establet
and Jean-Paul Pascual, Ultime voyage pour la Mecque: Les inventaires apres dces de plerins
morts a Damas vers 1700 (Damas: Institut franais dtudes arabes de Damas, 1998).
98
(dris Bostan, Rusya"nin Karadeniz"de Ticaret Ba{lamas ve Osmanl (mparatorlu[u (17001787), Belleten 59 (1995): 362.
99
Daniel Goman, Izmir and the Levantine World, 15501650 (Seattle: University
of Washington Press, 1990), 1011, 3638, 6970. For later developments, see
Necmi lker, The Rise of Izmir, 16881740 (Ph.D. diss., University of Michigan,
1974); Daniel Panzac, International and Domestic Maritime Trade in the Ottoman
Empire during the 18th Century, IJMES 24 (1992): 189206.
100
On Bursa, see Halil (nalck, Bursa and the Commerce of the Levant, JESHO

63

In addition to the pilgrims destination in the Hijaz, the cartographer defers to the commanding presence of Istanbul, one of the
Mediterraneans largest cities over the long-distance commercial system. Its population, rich and poor, consumed imported manufactures, raw materials, and foods in enormous quantities. In fact, the
city imported four times more than it exported.101 Istanbuls unbridled consumption spurred the growth of the local industries, including the textile manufacturing of Bursa, as well as spurring the
development of the Aegean port of Izmir. Although Istanbuls growth
after the sixteenth century dwarfed that of towns in western Anatolia,
long-distance trade percolated through the region on its way to the
Bosphorus.102 Cities and towns exchanged ready-made cloaks, belts,
embroidered pillow cases, and shawls. They depended on a steady
supply of local raw and seminished materials, such as dye stus,
henna, and soap, as well as locally prized items, such as the squirrel pelts that a merchant from Erzurum transported in addition to
his ne cotton and raw wool.103 In the eighteenth century, a booming trade in cotton twist and textile manufactures from Aleppo to
Mosul found foreign markets.104 To keep roadways open and safe
throughout Anatolia, unemployed mercenaries on contract functioned
as guardians (derbenti) while peasants were obligated to repair bridges
and caravansaries.105

3 (1960): 13147. Haim Gerber, Economy and Society in an Ottoman City: Bursa,
1600 1700 ( Jerusalem: Hebrew University Press, 1988). On Syria and Iraq, see
Amnon Cohen, Economic Life in Ottoman Jerusalem (Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press, 1989); Andr Raymond, The Ottoman Conquest and the Development of
the Great Arab Towns, IJTS 1 (19791980): 84101; and Antoine Abdel Nour,
Introduction lHistorie Urbaine de la Syrie Ottomane, (Beirut: Publications de lUniversit
Libanaise, 1982), 174.
101
Panzac, International and Domestic Maritime Trade, 193.
102
Leila T. Erder and Suraiya Faroqhi (The Development of the Anatolian
Urban Network During the Sixteenth Century, JESHO 23 [1980]: 284) speak of
great development. For a detailed study, see Usha M. Luther, Historical Route Network
of Anatolia (Istanbul-Izmir-Konya) 1550s to 1850s: A Methodological Study (Ankara: TTK
Basmevi, 1989); see also Suraiya Faroqhi, Towns and Townsmen of Ottoman Anatolia:
Trade, Crafts, and Food Production in an Urban Setting, 15201650 (Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 1984).
103
EA II:201.
104
Fukasawa, Toilerie et commerce du Levant, 2127. During the period of recovery,
cotton cloth represented 9.4 percent of cargo shipped from the Levant to France.
105
Orhonlu, Osmanl Imparatorlu[u"nda Derbend Te{kilt, 6063; and Orhonlu, Osmanl
(mparatorlu[unda {ehirilik, 1316, 48, 7173, 7879.

64

The eorescence of urban consumerism and manufacture within


the eighteenth-century empire has long been the focus of Mehmet
Gens research. Without his empirical studies and pathbreaking interpretation of Ottoman economic policy, it would be impossible to
appreciate the dynamism of, or the peculiar constraints on, the
Ottoman market during this period.106 Both external and internal
commerce were regulated by the Ottoman tari system (gmrk). More
than a means to skim o revenues from transit trade, the tari system was designed to channel goods and merchants in directions dictated by state priorities. In theory, commercial taxation favored the
subjects of the empire, with Muslims paying lower rates than either
Ottoman Christians and Jews or foreign merchants. Far from discouraging trade or sealing the empire o from foreign capital, the
terms of treaty (ahdname) aorded many European merchants and
tax-immune Ottoman traders (ocers, ocials, and patent holders
[beratl]) special privileges and opportunities.107 Indeed, state income
from commercial taxation and industrial production grew apace
between 1730 and 1768.108 The growing demand from internal cities,
despite the devastating epidemics of 1729, 175658, and 177274,

106
For the complete works in Turkish, see Mehmet Gen, Osmanl (mparatorlu[unda:
Devlet ve Ekonomi (Istanbul: tken, 2000).
107
(nalck, Imtiyzt, 118085; Masters, The Origins of Western Dominance, 19495;
Gen, Osmanl Imparatorlu[unda Devlet ve Ekonomi, in V. Milletleraras Trkiye
Sosyal ve (ktisat Tarihi Kongresi, ed. Hakk Dursun Yldz, (nci Enginn, and Emine
Grsoy Naskal (Ankara: TTK Basmevi, 1990), 1325; Zeki Arkan, Osmanl
(mparatorlu[unda (hrac Yasak Mallar, in Prof. Dr. Bekir Ktko[lu Arma[an, ed.
Mbahat S. Ktko[lu (Istanbul: Istanbul Edebiyat Fakltesi Basmevi, 1991),
279306; Rhoads Murphey, Conditions of Trade in the Eastern Mediterranean:
An Appraisal of Eighteenth-Century Ottoman Documents from Aleppo, JESHO
33 (1990): 3550.
108
Mehmet Gen,Osmanl (ktisad Dnya Gr{nn (lkeleri, Sosyoloji Dergisi
Istanbul niversitesi Edebiyat Fakltesi, 3rd ser. 1 (1989): 17685; idem, Osmanl Devletinde ( Gmrk Rejimi, in Tanzimattan Cumhuriyete Trkiye Ansiklopedisi (Istanbul:
(leti{im Yaynlar, 1985) 3:78689; idem, Osmanl Ekonomisi ve }ava{, Yapt 49
(1984): 5261, 8693; see also Lt Ger, XVIXVIII Asrlarda Osmanl
Imparatorlu[unun Ticaret Politikas, Trk Iktisat Tarihi Yll[, no. 1 (Istanbul:
Istanbul niversitesi (ktisat Fakltesi Trk (ktisat ve (ctimaiyat Tarihi Ara{trmalar
Merkezi, 1987), 155; and Roger Owen, The Middle East in the World Economy,
1800 1914 (London: Methuen, 1981), 123. On private control of the Istanbul
customs, see Sar Mehmed Pasha, Ottoman Statecraft: The Book of Counsel for Vezirs and
Governors of Sar Mehmed Paa (Nasa'ih ul-vuzera vel-umera), ed. and trans. W. L. Wright
(Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1935), 107. For the income in the rst half
of the eighteenth century from the Istanbul gmrk, see Ahmet Tabako[lu, Gerileme
Dnemine Osmanl Maliyesi (Istanbul: Dergh Yaynlar, 1986), 95, 232, 237, 269, 274.

65

also contributed to the rise of imported consumer goods, like coee


and tobacco.109 Appreciating these multilateral linkages, in the early
eighteenth century, the state placed new customs posts in secondary
cities like Urfa, in addition to long-standing tari stations at ports
and transit cities like Tokat, Erzurum, Trabzon, Aleppo, Damascus,
Baghdad, and Diyarbekir.110
Although Western European woolens and watches made inroads
into middle-class homes in the empire, the Indian subcontinent would
remain the empires single largest source of imported manufactures
and raw materials.111 Even Istanbul, the empires most avid consumer of things European, imported twice as many goods from the
Indian Ocean as it did from France, its leading Western trade partner. Taking into account the domestic market overall and re-exports
to Central and Eastern Europe, statistical data for Istanbuls commodity consumption must be considered as only the tip of an enormous iceberg of the Indian Ocean trac in textiles, coee, dyes,
and spices in the empire.112

109
On the trail of epidemics that accompanied expanded trade linkages, see
Daniel Panzac, La peste dans lempire ottoman: 1700 1850 (Leuven: Peeters, 1985),
10533. Between 1717 and 1788, the tax-farm on the transit gmrk station in Tokat
(mukataa-y amediye) rose tenfold in nominal terms from 6.6 million ake to 60 million ake, according to Mehmet Gen, A Study on the Feasibility of Using EighteenthCentury Ottoman Financial Records as an Indicator of Economic Activity, in The
Ottoman Empire in the World Economy, ed. Huri (slamo[lu-(nan (Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 1987), 363.
110
Mehmet Gen, Osmanl Devletinde ( Gmrk Rejimi, in Tanzimattan
Cumhuriyete Trkiye Ansiklopedisi, vol. 3, 78689; Tabako[lu, Gerileme Dnemine Girerken,
8485.
111
On the American coee trade, see Edhem Eldem, French Trade in Istanbul in
the Eighteenth Century (Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1999), 7576. For one perspective on elite
consumption, see Fatma Mge Gcek, Rise of the Bourgeoisie; Demise of Empire: Ottoman
Westernization and Social Change (New York: Oxford University Press, 1996).
112
Panzac, International and Domestic Maritime Trade, 191; Halil (nalck,
Osmanl Pamuklu Pazar, Hindistan ve Ingiltere, Pazar Rekabetinde Emek Maliyetinin
Rol, Orta Do[u Teknik niversitesi Geli{me Dergisi zel Says (197980): 166. Some
sense of the scale of the interstate transit trade may be gauged from the dispute
between the Austrian Paolo and the merchant Abdul Rahman over 13,500 kuru{ in
cash and coee in 176364 (DA III:44); as for the scale of domestic commerce,
see the complaint brought by an Ottoman Jewish merchant to the Diyarbekir judge,
Seyyid Halil, in 174849 concerning a robbery in Cizre, involving coee, nutmeg,
cloves, as well as Baghdadi and Indian cloth (DA I:150). For estimates of the early
nineteenth century, see E. Wirth, Aleppo im 19. Jahrhundertein Beispiel fr
Stabilitt und Dynamik sptosmanischer Wirtschaft, Osmanistische Studien zur Wirtschaftsund Sozialgeschichte. Im memoriam Van o Bokov, ed. Hans Georg Majer (Wiesbaden:
Otto Harrassowitz, 1986), 187206.

66

Much of this trade was funneled through the Ottoman port of


Basra, the greatest beneciary of the decline of Bandar 'Abbas after
1722.113 Monsoon winds carried ships bearing textiles, dyes, sugars,
cotton twist, spices, musk, and lac from Bengal, the Coromandel
coast, and Gujarat in addition to the commerce in slaves, ivory, and,
above all, coee, from Musqat, Oman, and Mukha.114 Smaller caravans picking up their goods after the long monsoon took merchants and their wares in spring via Baghdad and Diyarbekir to the
Ottoman capital.115 Others took the the meandering Euphrates highway toward Aleppo. But the shortest route to the Mediterranean
from the Indian Ocean cut directly across the Syrian desert. Departures
along the desert route were the least frequent because security
demanded larger convoyscomprising between 1,500 and 4,000
camels (each bearing more than 200 kilograms of goods). Caravans
traveled through Syria at the pace of 2530 kilometers a day.116
Ottoman administrators had spared no expense in realizing their
aim of reintegrating Basra into the empire at the turn of the century.117 They took into consideration the perspective of merchants,
who carefully calculated their options and prots on the basis of the
uctuating price of pack animals, tolls, and the seasonal risks to person and property in overland transport.118 To lure the merchants
toward the more highly taxed but better patrolled highways linking
Basra to Istanbul and Aleppo, they improved facilities and security.

113
Zarinebaf-Shahr, Tabriz under Ottoman Rule, 165. Thabit A. J. Abdullah,
Merchants, Mamluks, and Murder: The Political Economy of Trade in Eighteenth-Century Basra
(Albany, State University of New York Press, 2001), 49.
114
D.B}M 694. The textiles entering Baghdad in 1692, included both Iraqi and
Indian goods. Abdullah, Merchants, Mamluks, 58.
115
On the Diyarbekir route, the peak season for trac to and from the Gulf
was autumn (August, September, and October) in the early nineteenth century. KK
5594 (182324).
116
Masters, Origins of Western Dominance, 113. Abdullah, Merchants, Mamluks, 78.
On the routes through Syria, Abdel Nour, Le Rseau Routier de la Syrie Ottomane
(XVIeXVIIIe sicle), Arabica 30 (1983): 174.
117
For highlights of the reintegration of Basra into the empire between 1695 and
1701, see zcan, Anonim Osmanl Tarihi, 106, 14159.
118
From Baghdad, the route proceeded toward Kerkuk (8 days), Mosul (4 days),
Mardin (8 days), Urfa (7 days), and Aleppo (5 days), totaling 33 days in the 1750s.
Bartholomew Plaisted, The Desert Route to India Being the Journals of Four Travellers by
the Great Desert Caravan Route between Aleppo and Basra, 174551. Narrative of a Journey
from Basra to Aleppo in 1750 (London: Hakluyt Society, 1929), 1023. See also Ne{e
Erim, Trade, Traders, and the State in Eighteenth-Century Erzurum, New Perspectives
on Turkey 5 (1991): 12350.

67

To oversee operations at the lower conuence of the two rivers, the


}at"l-Arab, the state created a new oce, the conuence captain
( {at kaptan). Istanbul transferred experienced personnel from the
Danube to supervise dredging and other engineering operations in
the lower end of the Euphrates River near Dir, Ana, and Hit. State
largesse owed toward the construction of harbors and ports and
paid for skilled craftsmen to construct new dual-purpose trade and
military ships on the upper branch of the Eurphrates.119 Had such
eorts continued, they might have improved intra-imperial transport
within Asia.
As for protection, the regional and central-state administrations
responded to merchant complaints and pledged to pacify the main
axes linking Istanbul and Aleppo and the Persian Gulf. In addition
to tracking down notorious bandits, between 1690 and 1740, provincial commanders launched repeated campaigns to remove the Turkish,
Kurdish, and Arab tribes who raided transport in Kurdistan, Syria,
and Iraq and to forcibly resettle them in the western provinces of
Rakka and Adana, far from the trade routes. Yet the burgeoning
wealth in transit invited new interlopers. During the middle years of
the eighteenth century, only strong local regimes could eectively
contain the Kurdish lords of Cizre or the Milan tribe of the upper
Tigris, the Arab Shammar, and 'Anaza of the Middle Euphrates,
and the Ka'b and Khaza'il at the southern end of the trade routes,
much less counter the large and powerful confederate of the Muntaq
of Khuzistan.120
The ebb and ow of the central-states territorial control along
these commercial corridors prevented Istanbul from restraining the
political latitude of action of the provincial regimes of Baghdad and
Mosul. However, even without force of arms, Istanbul exerted a new

119
New ships and barges capable of carrying seventy persons and their cargo
were built at the dockyards of Payas near Ayntab and at Birecik. Orhonlu, Osmanl
(mparatorlu[unda }ehircilik ve Ulasm, 12833. Gzelbey and Yetkin, Gaziantep {erii
Mahkeme Sicilleri, 5, 1213, 94. In 1733, ocials at Payas (Ayntabs port) were
ordered to build 123 new boats, each at a cost of 297 kuru{ 33 para. The rowers
and dmenci were to be paid 98 kuru{ per year.
120
Abdullah, Merchants, Mamluks, 5060. Masters, The Origins of Western Dominance,
118; Longrigg, Four Centuries of Modern Iraq, 79. Yusuf Halao[lu, XVIII. Yzylda
Osmanl (mparatorlu[unun (skan Siyaseti ve A{iretlerin Yerle{tirilmesi (Ankara: TTK Basmevi,
1991), 4662, 7880, 113. Cevdet Trkay, Ba{bakanlk Ar{ivi Belgelerine gre Osmanl
(mparatorlu[unda Oymak, A{iret ve Cematlar ((stanbul: Tercman, 1979), 809.

68

form of hegemony over much of its Asian and at least part of its
North African empire for most of the eighteenth century. The
Ottomans, in contrast to the Safavid shahs, possessed both an organizational structure tempered by time and the indigenous sources of
silver needed to retrot this structure.121 These relatively favorable
circumstances cushioned the state against the Mediterranean-wide
nancial crises after 1695 and the sea change in the global monetary system at the end of the New World silver boom.122 The contraction of precious metal stocks resulting from the technological
impasse in South and Central American mining overcame the Old
Worlds reluctance to mine domestically.123 The Ottomans, as did
their neighbors in Central and Eastern Europe, began to rework
older mines in the Balkans and staked new claims in Anatolia, at
Gm{hane, Keban, Ergani, and Espiye.124
Ottoman reserves never approached those of Russian Siberia, but
they did provide self-suciency.125 After a century of currency manipulation, chipped and debased coinage, domestic supply nally suced
for the imperial mints: of some twenty-ve to forty metric tons of
metal mined between the 1730s and 1760s, 80 percent was turned
into coins. Even as the grand vizier rallied the troops for war in
western Iran, he was completing the nal phases of an overhaul of
coinage. The new standards for Ottoman specie emulated the most
stable currencies of oceanic commerce. Thus the new silver kuru{

121
See Willem Floor and Patrick Clawson, Safavid Irans Search for Silver and
Gold, IJMES 32 (2000): 34568. Consider too, the global impact of the changes
in funding state debt: Larry Neal, The Rise of Financial Capitalism: International Capital
Markets in the Age of Reason (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990), 46. Jack
Goldstone, Revolution and Rebellion in the Early Modern World (Berkeley: University of
California Press, 1991); for the critique, Sanjay Subrahmanyam, Precious Metal
Flows and Prices in Western and Southern Asia, 15001750: Some Comparative
and Conjunctural Aspects, Studies in History 7 (1991): 79105.
122
Halil Sahillio[lu (The Role of International Monetary and Metal Movements
in Ottoman Monetary History, 13001700, in Precious Metals in the Later Medieval
and Early Modern Worlds, ed. J. F. Richards [Durham, N.C.: Carolina Academic
Press, 1983], 269304, 28889) notes that Ottoman mines between 1640 and 1687
were inactive because of the abundance of silver arriving from the Americas. On
early modern monetary history, see also }evket Pamuk, A Monetary History of the
Ottoman Empire (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2000); and generally, Pierre
Vilar, A History of Gold and Money, 14501920 (London: Verso, 1984).
123
Ian Blanchard, Russias Age of Silver: Precious-Metal Production and Economic Growth
in the Eighteenth Century (London: Routlege, 1989), 16970.
124
Pamuk, A Monetary History of the Ottoman Empire, 16163.
125
Sahillio[lu, International Monetary and Metal Movements, 28690.

69

(from the German word groschen, also known as piaster) was modeled on the Dutch thaler and xed at the rate of 120 ake. The
Venetian ducat served as the measure for a new series of gold coins.126
Despite opportunistic intervention in monetary markets, particularly
to boost receipts into the treasury, Ottoman administrators generally let the value of gold uctuate in the market.127 The result of
this monetary policy was positive: a long period of stability for the
Ottoman monetary system and the kuru{, the principal unit of government accounting and market transactions.
Although one might interpret these reforms as evidence of an
increased conformity or even incorporation into the European market, Ottoman policy continued to defy the conventional wisdom of
mercantilism.128 There were advocates of controlling imports, and
voices among the Ottoman elite who saw danger in the imbalance
in trade relationships with India, to be sure.129 However, the idea of
restricting imports or dissolving the institutions for procurement of
basic urban and military supplies remained anathema to the empires
administrative ideology: provisionism, as Mehmet Gen denes it,
prioritized urban consumption in the empires major administrative
cities. To assure levels of comfort for the elite as well as to promote
social peace among Istanbuls working classes and the poor, it was
necessary to maintain a steady supply of goods and raw materials
from luxuries to food staples, regardless of cost or source.130
Although provisionism may well have aected the ability of domestic
manufacturers to compete with certain types of goods, particularly

126
Pamuk, A Monetary History of the Ottoman Empire, 16166. Sahillo[lu, The Role
of International Monetary and Metal Movements, 289.
127
Eldem, French Trade in Istanbul, 11319, 199.
128
For the debate, see Halil (nalck, The Ottoman Economic Mind and Aspects
of the Ottoman Economy, in Studies in the Economic History of the Middle East, ed.
M. A. Cook (London: Oxford University Press, 1970), 20718, and Fernand Braudel,
LEmpire Turc est-il une conomie-monde? in Mmorial mer Lt Barkan (Istanbul:
Bibliothque de lInstitut Franais dtudes Anatoliennes dIstanbul, 1980); compare
Sanjay Subrahmanyam, Of Imrat and Tijrat: Asian Merchants and State in the
Western Indian Ocean, 1400 to 1750, 37 (1995): 776. M. N. Pearson, Before
Colonialism: Theories on Asian-European Relations, 15001750 (Delhi: Oxford University
Press, 1988); K. N. Chaudhuri, Asia before Europe: Economy and Civilization of the Indian
Ocean from the Rise of Islam to 1750 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press 1990).
129
Naima was particularly concerned about trade imbalance with India. Lewis
V. Thomas, A Study of Naima, ed. Norman Izkowitz (New York: New York University
Press, 1972), 14445.
130
Gen, Osmanl (mparatorlu[unda: Devlet ve Ekonomi, 6886.

70

the ood of cotton stus from India, as a theory of commerce, even


mercantilism bore increasingly little relevance to real trade practices,
interstate ows of bullion, and credit systems. Despite the growing
clout of London, Amsterdam, and Marseilles in the Mediterranean
and beyond, credit systems remained highly decentralized.131 Few
states could claim true monetary sovereignty; even Britain resigned
itself to the use of Spanish coin within its North American colonies.132
The Ottoman state, at the juncture of dierent market and monetary systems, faced even greater diculties. With or without Istanbuls
massive trade decit, as long as silver had a greater purchasing power
in India and China (and even in eastern Europe) than it did within
the Mediterraneanthe ratio between gold and silver in Istanbul
was roughly equivalent to that in western European states133it would
be impossible to prevent the escape of specie through its eastern
land frontiers, the Black Sea, or the Persian Gulf.134
In constructing a nancial sphere of inuence, Ottoman solutions
were ingenious and enduring. Currency reform entailed not only
minting coins with a high degree of metallic purity but also sharply
reducing the number of mints operating in the empire. Although
provincial cities continued to produce small coppers, the large silver
and gold coins that serviced major transactions were minted only in
Istanbul, Cairo, and for a time, it seems, Tabriz.135 Using the principle of arbitrage to ensure the capital citys preeminence in specie,
orders to Cairo set a standard for the silver content of coin that was
slightly inferior to that employed in Istanbul.136 Gradually, the Istanbul

131
On the bullionist tendencies, see Om Prakash, Bullion for Goods: International
Trade and the Economy of Early 18th Century Bengal, Indian Economic and Social
History Review 13 (1976): 15987. On the copper coinage used in Europe and Eurasia
during the 1680s, Vilar, History of Gold and Money, 21921; Neal, The Rise of Financial
Capitalism, 1117; Sahillo[lu, The Role of International Monetary and Metal
Movements, 288; and Frank Perlin, Unbroken Landscape: Commodity, Category, Sign and
Identity: Their Production as Knowledge from 1500 (Aldershot: Variorum and Brookeld,
V.T.: Ashgate Publishing, 1994), 129.
132
Edwin J. Perkins, American Public Finance and Financial Services, 1700 1785
(Columbus: Ohio State University Press), 1328.
133
Eldem, French Trade in Istanbul, 11718. The ratio in the Istanbul market averaged 14:1, uctuating between a high of 15:1 and a low of 12.5:1.
134
Ahmet Rek, Hicri On (kinci Asrda Istanbul Hayat (11001200) (Istanbul: Devlet
Matbaasi, 1930), 39, 6263.
135
Zarinebaf-Shahr, Tabriz under Ottoman Rule, 203.
136
Sahillio[lu, The Role of International Monetary and Metal Movements,
279. Pamuk, A Monetary History of the Ottoman Empire, 18089.

71

kuru{ edged out rival currencies, both foreign and domestic, in the
cities of Syria, as well as in the Balkans, Anatolia, and parts of
Kurdistan and Iraq, though the Gulf managed to elude its nancial
hegemony (as it did Britains).137
Yet it should be remembered too that a successful monetary hegemony complemented the scal system of empire, which was increasingly dependent on private contracts for tax collection and cash
advances on high oce, as we will read in the next chapter. Thus
the ow of silver linking Istanbul to an export entrept like Izmir,
constituted only part of a circuit of payments, in both bullion and
paper, that united the imperial center with its peripheries and, over
the course of the century, the empire as a whole to the global
nancial hubs of Marseilles, Amsterdam, and London.138
Eurasia in Transition
The Ottoman courtiers who studied this map might have regarded
West Asia as slate upon which they could still redraw the lines of
empire. Three centuries later this mapwitness to a past political
economy of space and the practices of sovereigntyinvites us to consider not only actual outcomes but also a counterfactual one: What
if the partition of Iran between the Ottoman Empire and Czarist
Russia had become permanent? Although the sultan and his advisors might not have dreamt of reconstituting Alexanders empire,
Azarbayjan was well on its way to becoming an Ottoman province.
Bureaucrats had carried out exhaustive cadastral surveys. Timars and
later, tax farms were distributed to Ottomans and local residents.
The third mint of the new monetary system was established in Tabriz
in 1725.139 If Irans division might have brought the czar one step

137
Basra was clearly a credit and monetary frontier, well integrated into the Indian
Ocean system (Abdullah, Merchants, Mamluks, 90). }evket Pamuk (The Recovery of
the Ottoman Monetary System in the Eighteenth Century, in Kemal Karpat, The
Ottoman Past and Todays Turkey [Leiden: E. J. Brill, 2000], 188211) conrms the
strong linkages forged by this currency policy, especially within the Black Sea,
Eastern Mediterranean, and Balkans. However, as we shall see in the following
chapter, this is only part of a complex nancial system, circulating paper (titles and
letters of exchange), tax, tribute, and remittances (endowments) in addition to coinage.
138
Pamuk, A Monetary History of the Ottoman Empire, 18890.
139
Zarinebaf-Shahr, Tabriz under Ottoman Rule, 11520.

72

closer to realizing a coveted southern port on the Indian Ocean, it


would have also allowed the Ottomans to achieve more immediate
goals. Istanbul could have shored up its position in the Black Sea
from the Caucasus, by relying on the Georgian principalities, rather
than on the erratic aid of the khans of the Crimea. Indeed, in 1774
at Kk Kaynarca, while the Russians retreated from Moldavia,
Wallachia, Bucak, and Georgia, the Ghiray khan nally secured the
desired degree of autonomy. Or so he thought, because the treaty
was but a preliminary to the total annexation of the Crimea by the
czarina in 1783.
Yet Irans repeated resurrection precluded a Russo-Ottoman territorial pact. Against all predictions, the old Safavid confederates
the Afshars (173647), then the Zands (175079), and nally, the
Qajars (1779 1924)rallied and restored much of the Iranian
empire.140 Nadir Shahs military adventures were felt across the
larger Indian Ocean system. The attack on Delhi in 1741 netted
him and his ally, the future Ahmad Shah Durrani of Afghanistan,
tremendous wealth but evisserated the nancial center of the distended Mughal state. This blow crippled Delhis ability to defend its
frontiers or aid its commanders in the eastern province of Bengal.
After the East India Companys victory at Plassey in 1757141 and
with the rival Dutch colony at Kharq Island and French establishments along the Indian coastline disbanded, the British eet
dominated the sea. Carrying on where Nadir Shahs hit-and-run
imperialism left o, British shippers took over not only long distance
transport but also the carriage or country trade in the western
Indian Ocean and Gulf. From bases in Bengal and Surat, its merchant capitalism reached deeply into the internal market, inltrating
distribution and manufacturing networks.142

140
Jos J. L. Gommans, The Rise of the Indo-Afghan Empire, c. 17101780 (Leiden:
E. J. Brill, 1995), 99101. For later developments, see John Perry, Karim Khan Zand:
A History of Iran, 17471779 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1979); Longrigg,
Four Centuries of Modern Iraq; and A. S. K. Lambton, Persian Trade Under the
Early Qajars, in Islam and Trade in Asia, ed. D. S. Richards (Oxford: Oxford
University Press, 1970), 21544.
141
Gommans, Rise of the Indo-Afghan Empire, 29.
142
See Ashin Das Gupta, Indian Merchants and the Decline of Surat, c. 17001750
(Wiesbaden: Franz Steiner Verlag, 1979). Sudipta Sen (Empire of Free Trade: The East
India Company and the Making of the Colonial Marketplace [Philadelphia: University of
Pennsylvania Press, 1998]) follows the impact of changing long-distance trade relationships on local distribution and production.

73

Beyond reasserting suzerainty over Afghanistan and replenishing


his own treasury, Nadir Shahs longer-term goals in South Asia
remain a mystery. One of them was certainly to gain formal recognition as the head of a dynastic state in the eyes of their western
neighbor, the Ottoman Empire. The Afshar leader, recognizing
Ottoman weakness in the North and West, pressed negotiations with
the sultan. After a decade of wrangling over the terms of sovereignty
and the rights of adherents to the Afshar-championed Jafari sect in
Mecca and Medina, in 1746 the Ottoman divan ratied the Treaty
of Kurdan. A landmark piece of diplomacy, this agreement oered
the framework for the territorial state system within Muslim Asia: a
multilateral order that respected Ottoman religious paramountcy, its
caliphal leadership, while recognizing the autonomy and legitimacy
of other, Muslim dynastic polities. As a harbinger of modern relations between the two states, one increasingly shorn of sectarian overtones, Ernie Tuckers argument that the dynamic of conceptual
change [which] transcended the rise and fall of dynasties in Iran,
may be correct. Nevertheless, Nadir Shahs assassination the following year had disastrous consequences for the region during the second half of the eighteenth century. It rendered the treaty a dead
letter and threw Iran, once again, into turmoil.143
During the decades between the Treaty of Kurdan and the death
of Nadir Shahs successor, Karim Khan Zand, in 1779, a palpable
asymmetry within Eurasia would emerge.144 The Treaty of Westphalia
(1648) and the Treaty Utrecht (1714) had been way stations on the
road to new terms of sovereign rule. However, it was the Treaty of
Paris (1763) that nally ended a half century of dynastic crises. It
sealed the edges of the early modern political map, including Prussias
critical annexation of Silesia in 1740.
Standing outside the general conagration of the Seven Years War
brought mixed blessings to the Ottomans. Although spared the expense

143

Tucker, The Peace Negotiation of 1736, 35.


Neither reducing dierence to matter of cultural perception and projection,
as Larry Wolf (Inventing Eastern Europe: The Map of Civilization of the Mind of the
Enlightenment [Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1994]) nor essentializing cultural
and social forms, such as pastoral nomadism, as C. A. Bayly contends (Imperial
Meridian, 1718) brings us closer to appreciating the growing imbalance between
European and Asian states during the second half of eighteenth century.
144

74

and buered by their enemies distraction between 1757 and 1768,


Istanbul also missed decades of rapid advances in martial organization and technique. Nor did the nal outcome favor the empire
within the new global balance, given Frances resounding defeat in
both the Atlantic and the Indian Ocean. Despite the promise of an
alliance with Prussia, the opening of a new Habsburg and Russian
front in 1768 presented the Ottomans with an even more dangerous territorial accord in central Europe.145 At the height of the conict,
after the loss of its navy at e{me in 1770 and in the face of coordinated actions between the rebel Egyptian bey Cloud-catcher Ali
and Moscow in Syria, Prussia joined the czar and emperor in the
Poland partition of 177275.146
Preoccupation with the ever-sharper edges of the European state
system and the entry of the Russian eet in the Black Sea may have
dampened the enthusiasm of Ottoman mapmakers for depictions of
Alexanders Asia during the last quarter of the century. As British
and French adventurers and cartographers traced real and imaginary lines in the legendary footsteps of Tamerlane and Nadir Shah
across Anatolia and Egypt to India, the Ottomans tried to secure
their western frontier. In addition to enlisting the support of the
lords of its agrarian heartlands, the derebey, Istanbul would muster
new resources and sponsor European advisors. To the east, goals of
reconsolidating its provincial structure along the long and fragmented
frontier of Kurdistan, seemed illusory. With Karim Khan Zands
siege of Baghdad and occupation of Basra in 1775, the Iranian war
again erupted into Ottoman lands and choked the vital commercial
channel that linked the capital with the Indian Ocean.
Although the Zand threat receded, it did not resolve the empires
fundamental dilemma: wedged between two increasingly incommensurate geopolitical systems, Istanbul sought other solutions. Ensnaring
provincial actors in a web of high nance and courtly networks, it
maintained the support of the urban gentry and rural lords while
anchoring its eastern perimeters by giving its tacit assent to the semiautonomous regimes that governed Egypt and Iraq.147

145
See Kemal Beydilli, 1780 Osmanl-Prusya Ittifk (Meydana Geli{i-Tahilili Tatbiki)
(Istanbul: Istanbul niversitesi Edebiyat Fakltesi Yaynlar, 1984).
146
Schroeder, European Politics, 17631848, 311.
147
Aksan, Ottoman War and Warfare, 14531812, 167.

CHAPTER TWO

THE SUBLIME PORTE AND THE CREDIT NEXUS

As the Ottoman armies crossed into Azarbayjan, the court turned


its attentions to the pleasures of the capital seated on the shores of
the Bosphorus, the strait connecting the Black Sea to the Mediterranean.1 Istanbul had been all but abandoned by Ahmed IIIs brother
and father for bucolic Thrace. Now the sultan, his viziers, and his
princesses embellished the city with new palaces, fountains, elds of
tulips, and mosques. They transformed the waterways of the Golden
Horn and the crowded thoroughfares of the inner city into a open
air court. Festivals celebrated the rites of passage of the dynasty
marriages of princesses, births of princes, and circumcisions. Public
ceremonies greeted the entry of foreign ambassadors and hailed the
birth of an heir to a Bourbon ally.2
Perhaps the most fabled of these public events was the fortnight
of feasting, parades, and entertainments that preceded the circumcision of the sultans sons in the fall of 1720. In his Ceremony
Treatise (Surnme-i Vehbi ), the poet Seyyid Hseyin Vehbi (d. 1736)
transcribed these festivities in verse.3 Court painters immortalized

1
On this period, see Ahmet Rek, Lle Devri (Ankara: Pnar Yaynlar, 1912);
Mary Lucille Shaw, The Ottoman Empire from 1720 to 1734: As Revealed in the Despatches
of the Venetian Baili (Urbana: University of Illinois Press, 1944). For other European
paintings of courtly life in Istanbul, see Jean-Baptiste Van Mour (16711737) (Remmet
van Luttervelt, De Turkse Schilderijen van J. B. Vanmour en Zijn School [Istanbul:
Nederlands Historisch-Archaeologisch Instituut in het Nabije Oosten, 1958]), a protg of the French Embassy.
2
Consider Voltaire, Candide or the Optimism (London: Penguin, 1947), 125. On
the concept of civilization under the old-regime and its discontents, see Norbert
Elias, The History of Manners (New York: Pantheon Books, 1978), 3940.
3
TKSK MS A. 3593. See Esin Atl and Omer Koc, eds., Levni and the Surname:
The Story of an Eighteenth-Century Ottoman Festival (Seattle: University of Washington
Press, 2000); Esin Atl, The Story of an Eighteenth-Century Ottoman Festival,
Muqarnas 10 (1993): 181211; E. Atil, Surnme-i Vehbi: An Eighteenth Century
Book of Festivals, 2 vols. (Ph.D. diss., University of Michigan, 1969); in addition
to the many manuscript copies found in Topkap Saray Mzesi Library, see Seyyit
Vehbi, Srnme: nc Ahmedin O[ullarnn Snnet D[n, ed. Re{ad Ekrem Kou
(Istanbul: igir Kitabevi, 1939).

76

them as well. Before 1732, Levni, the sobriquet of the celebrated


court artist Abdlcelil elebi, and the members of his atelier recorded
this event in two lavishly illustrated albums (Plates 16). The circumcision of the young princes provided the pretext to freeze the
activities of the bustling city and turn the eyes of its thousands of
shopkeepers, artisans, merchants, scholars, housewives, and grandees
on the dynasty.
Parades, reviews of troops, and receptions regimented the actors
of the rgime into clearly dened institutions. The solak, the bostanc
who patrolled the waterways and royal gardens, the armed silahdar
and peyk, and the mounted sipahi patrolled the line separating the
sovereign and his subjects. Surrounded by the eunuch-administrators
of the harem, pages, and chamberlains, the sultan, seated in his
palace, in a luxurious tent on the parade ground, or on a balcony
overlooking the Golden Horn, is the center of a swirling panorama
of activities. The populace, which peers from the sidelines at these
marvelous entertainmentsreworks, dancers, acrobats, jugglers, and
mock battles at seashares in the palaces merriment as well as its
acts of piety.
In contrast to the tiered, rigorously hierarchical portrait of the
high-ranking statesmen, the rical- devlet, or to the depiction of the
carefully choreographed procession that led the princes to Topkap
Palace, dispersed elements in Levnis pictorial narrative also preform
what is known as the circle of justice. Ibn Khaldun had traced
this theorem of redistributive government to Aristoles Politics.4 It is

4
Ibn Khaldn, The Muqaddimah: An Introduction to History, ed. and trans. Franz
Rosenthal (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1969), 41, attributes the circle of
justice to the Sassanian king Khosraw I and Aristotle. Ibn Khaldun claims that
Aristotle in his Book on Politics arranged his statement in a remarkable circle that
he discussed at length. It runs as follows: The world is a garden the fence of which
is the dynasty. The dynasty is an authority through which life is given to proper
behavior. Proper behavior is a policy directed by the ruler. The ruler is an institution supported by the soldiers. The soldiers are helpers who are maintained by
money. Money is sustenance brought together by the subjects. The subjects are servants who are protected by justice. Justice is something familiar (harmonious) and
through it, the world persists. The world is a garden . . . and then it begins again . . .
They are held together in a circle with no denite beginning or end. An Ottoman
translation of Ibn Khalduns Prolegomena was completed by the head of the religious
establishment, }eyh"l-(slam Mehmed Sa"ib Pirizde (d. 1749). On Ibn Khalduns
inuence, see Cornell Fleischer, Royal Authority, Dynastic Cyclism and Ibn
Khaldunism in Sixteenth Century Ottoman Letters, Journal of Asian and African
Studies 18 (1984): 21837. Notable Ottoman versions of the circle of justice include

77

a circle with no denite beginning or end, a circulation of obligations linking the longevity and prosperity of an agrarian state to
the quality of justice and protection that the sovereign oers those
whose toil creates the empires wealth.
The Ok Meydan, the archery range by the Golden Horn served
as the stage for the dramatization of the ideal earthy order. Fittingly,
the farmer (Plate 1), who guides a pair of oxen and a plowthe
symbol of the iftlik, the unit of land needed for a households subsistenceleads the way. He is followed by master craftsmen, journeymen, and apprentices of the trades that prepare food (butchers
and cooks) and those that process tallow and hide (candle makers
and tanners). Present too are barbers, grocers, quilt makers, and
nally, the dealers in luxuriesjewelers, makers of ne brocade,
and spice traders, all of whom bear samples of their wares, clever
and costly gifts for the sultan.
As the earthly magistrate, the sultan stands at the apex of social
hierarchies and at the nexus of the redistributive circuits of the realm.
He reciprocates his subjects gifts after his own manner. Ceremonial
banquets channel the empires bounty to those who render just decisions on disputes and to the ocials and ocers charged with safeguarding order. The rst round of feasts honors the ulema and the
jurists, the ilmiye, at whose head are the }eyh"l-(slam and two jurisconsults of Anatolia and Rumelia. Another banquet is hosted for the
imams of important mosques and those who call the people to prayer,
the hatips. In subsequent paintings, we see the palace pages waiting
upon the seyye, the men of the sword, among whom sit viziers,
provincial governors, and the commanders of the imperial regiment.
Although the sultan does not dine with his servants, leading members of the bureaucracy, the kalemiye, such as the defterdar efendi, the
imperial treasurer and the sultans deputy, the grand vizier, stand in
his stead.
Amid the political upheaval of the late seventeenth and early eighteenth centuries that roiled the city and overturned the regimes of
his father and brother, these masques of absolutism were not worn

the sixteenth-century Knalzade Ali Efendi, Ahlk- Ali (Cairo: Bulak, 1248), vol. 3,
49 as well as that by the early-eighteenth-century imperial treasurer, Sar Mehmed
Efendi, Ottoman Statecraft: The Book of Counsel for Vezirs and Governors of Sar Mehmed
Pasha (Nasa'ih ul-vuzera vel-umera), ed. W. L. Wright (Princeton: Princeton University
Press, 1935), 118.

78

lightly. Nonetheless, although the fall of Tabriz in 1730 would put


an end to Ahmed IIIs reign as well as to the Age of Tulips, the
Ottoman dynasty rested on rm foundations. The dangerous centuries of fratricidal struggles among princes had passed and dynastic succession passed predictably to the eldest male heir.5 Ahmed
IIIs reign of nearly three decades dened the basic institutional
modalities of the ancien rgime. Under the watchful eye of the vizier,
the Sublime Porte emerged as the regulatory force that oversaw the
circle of justice. Yet rather than a single circulatory system subject to rise and fall, it was composed of numerous circuits that assured
the redistribution of privilege and power among an aristocracy of
service and the empires religious establishment. While allowing points
of entry for new elements drawn from the wider society, the oldregime operated through an Istanbul nexus and the radiating spokes
of an empire-wide nancial system.6
Palace, Porte, and Fiscal Patronage
The art historian Esin Atl points to a shadow protagonist in Levnis
storybook of the 1720 ceremonies. It is the Nev{ehirli (brahim Pasha
(1662?1730), the probable patron of the manuscript, who often
shares the painters frame with the sultan.7 In these double portraits,
sultan and deputy are almost interchangeable, distinguishable less by
their features or dress than by the inferior position that the vizier
occupies on the page. (Plate 2)
The grand viziers notoriety owed to such presumptuosness: the
servant who dared to display his own image more frequently than
that of his sovereign, a deputy whose character and abilities are
extolled in the panegyric of Vehbi that adorns the large fountain

5
Mehmet IV was succeeded by his brothers, Sleyman II (r. 16871691)and
Ahmed II (r. 16911695) before his sons, Mustafa II (r. 16951703) and Ahmed
III (r. 17031730). Both of their reigns were cut short by janissary revolts. A. D.
Alderson, The Structure of the Ottoman Dynasty (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1956), 76;
Leslie P. Peirce, The Imperial Harem: Women and Sovereignty in the Ottoman Empire (Oxford:
Oxford University Press, 1993), especially 191218.
6
Norbert Elias, The Court Society (New York: Pantheon, 1983), 91.
7
Atl, The Story of an Eighteenth-Century Ottoman Festival, 200. The grand
vizier appears in forty-four scenes; the sultan in only forty-one.

79

standing before the Topkap Palace.8 In reality, vizier and sultan


were only two faces of the state: they might be considered gureheads
of merging institutional and political currents, between the palace,
the Gate of Felicity (Dar s-Sade) with its complex of private populations, pages, and patrimonial wealth, and the expanding resources
and personnel of the Sublime Porte, the Bb- li (an abbreviation of the Saraya- Sadr- li Divanhane-i Bb- li ).9
(brahim Pasha of Nev{ehir, the sultans son-in-law presided over
a decisive phase in the restructuring of state institutions.10 Like Frances
Jean-Baptiste Colbert, his tenure witnessed the consolidation of power
and especially the means of raising state revenues under the vizierate.11 The imperial council (Divan- Hmayun), once the locus of policy-making lost its monopoly; its chief tasks were surrendered to the
executive ocers who would take charge of both domestic and foreign aairs.12 The grand vizier, his chief of sta (kethda) and the
director of the imperial treasury (ba{ defterdar or defterdar efendi ) were
empowered to draft edicts, decrees, and certicates and to render
judgment in the sultans name.13 Deliberations concerning war and
peace took place in the viziers chambers.
Under (brahim Pasha, the Sublime Porte realized even greater
oversight over the empires certicates, legal records, cadastral surveys,

8
E. J. W. Gibb, A History of Ottoman Poetry (London: Luzac & Company, 1967)
vol. 4, 111.
9
Tayyip Gkbilgin, Bbli, (A 2:17477. Carter V. Findley, Bureaucratic Reform
in the Ottoman Empire (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1980), 47. For the composition of the Portes sta in the late seventeenth century, see the Anonymous
author of Anonim Osmanl Tarihi (10991116/16881704) (ed. Abdlkadir zcan
[Ankara: Trk Tarihi Kurumu Basmevi, 2000], 18485), who follows Hezarfen
Hseyin Efendi (Hezarfen Hseyn Efendi Telhsl Beyan f Kavanin-i l- Osman, ed.
Sevim Ilgrel [Ankara: TTK Basmevi, 1998], 132).
10
For an overview of the history of the bureaucracy, see Findley, Bureaucratic
Reform; idem., Ottoman Civil Ocialdom (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1989);
and Virginia Aksan, An Ottoman Statesman in War and Peace, Ahmed Resmi Efendi,
1700 1783 (Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1995), 114.
11
Colberts 1681 consolidation of the largest French tax farms into a single institution was dissolved one hundred ten years later by the revolutionary government.
See Vida Azimi, Un modle administratif de lancien rgime: les commis de la ferme gnrale
et de la rgie gnrale des aides (Paris: ditions du Centre National de la Recherche
Scientique, 1987).
12
Ahmet Mumcu, Hukuksal ve Siyasal Karar Organ Olarak Divan- Hmayun (Ankara:
Ankara niversitesi Hukuk Fakltesi Yaynlar, 1976), 69.
13
(smail Hakk Uzunar{l, Osmanl Devletinin Merkez ve Bahriye Te{kilat (Ankara:
TTK Basmevi, 1984), 33861; Halil (nalck, Re"is-l-kttb, (A 9:67283.

80

records of complaints, foreign correspondence, and ledgers. The


palace had already begun to shed the archive. Sleyman I (r. 1520
1566) ordered the physical removal of the registers of state lands
from the precincts of the imperial council to the imperial registry
(defter-i hakani ).14 Leaving the ceremonial head of the chancellery
(ni{anc) behind in the palace, the ocial who had been the viziers
chief clerk (re"is l-kttb) emerged as a new secretary of state, charged
with maintaining the records of laws, treaties, and awards of certicates
to oce. Rather than entrusting these records to the care of the
chief minister and thus, allowing them to pass from one administration to the next, two years before his death, (brahim Pasha gathered imperial records together in a permanent, central depository
located within the grand viziers chambers.15
As the vizierate grew, with its chancellery, the sc, and the state
archive, so did the ranks of its minions: ushers, messengers, special
assistants, accountants, clerks, special guards and ocers. Yet, Levnis
paintings remind us that there was at least one formidable redoubt
of power beyond the Porte. Hac Be{ir A[a (171746), the senior
black eunuch (dar s-sade a[as), who rarely leaves the sultans side
throughout the festivities, remained rmly in control of the palaces
assets. He, as many of his predecessors in oce, routinely intervened
in domestic and foreign aairs. Since the late sixteenth century, when
Habe{ Mehmed A[a succeeded in wresting control of both the position of kahya of the sultans treasury and chief administrator of the
endowments from the other corps of eunuchs, those of Eurasian
extraction, the senior black eunuch controlled vast resources throughout the empire.16 As protectors and heads of the harem sta and the
apartments of the sultans family and slaves, the eunuchs exercised
undiminished inuence over members of the dynasty.

14
See D. A. Howard, The Historical Development of the Ottoman Imperial
Registry (Defter-i Hakan): Mid-Fifteenth to Mid-Seventeenth Centuries, Archivum
Ottomanicum 11 (1988): 21330; and Klaus Rhrborn, Die Emanzipation der
Finanzbrokratie im Osmanischen Reich (Ende 16. Jahrhundert), ZDMG 122 (1972):
11839. In the 1750s, these documents were transfered to the palace of princess
Esma Sultan (R. Ekrem Kou, Bbli, (A 4:1446).
15
(smail Hakk Uzunar{l, Osmanl Devletinin Saray Te{kilt (Ankara: TTK Basmevi,
1945), 17377. On the lives and accomplishments of the senior black eunuchs living between 1574 and 1752, see Ahmed Resmi Efendi, Hamiletl-Kber, ed. Ahmet
Nezihi Turan (Istanbul: Istanbul Kitabevi, 2000).
16
Ahmed Resmi Efendi, Hamiletl-Kber, 45; Uzunar{l, Osmanl Devleteinin Saray
Te{kilt, 173.

81

Lest we reduce the dynamic of Ottoman polity to a perennial


contest between factions, or in this case, a tug-of-war between Porte
and palace, we must recall the similarities between the Ottoman
Empire and its counterparts in Europe and Asia. Notwithstanding
accounts of a relatively smooth and uncontested transition to absolutism and a seamless relationship between religion and state, consolidation of the key state institutions was fraught and indirect.17
Early sultans, no less than their feudal European neighbors, struggled mightily to subdue their allies as well as their enemies. The
religious aura surrounding the dynasty became an important component in the transition between a frontier principality and an early
modern tax state.18 Like European monarchs who preferred the
lawyers trained in Roman statutes to dependence on churchmen, the
sultans Murad I (136289) and Beyazid I (13891402) drew new
personnel from a pool of Byzantine and Ilkhanid administrators who
began the process of bureaucratizing the military order.19 Specialized
in scribal cipher, siyakat, Persian schoolmen reduced the empires
wealth to cadastral records and converted the sovereigns fth of the
spoils of war into the salaries for an infantry of palace-trained slaves,
the janissaries.
Vehbis festival book was also an instrument of state making. Just
as the exploits of the religious knight, the ghazi, once inspired the
empire builders of yore, the mirror of princes, manuals drafted by
courtly advisers and bureaucrats, laden with well-honed adages, moralizing verse, and allegories such as the circle of justice, were
integral to the ideology of a palace-centered state.20 The palace-state
in its most predatory form, during a period often associated with
the reign of Sultan Mehmet II (r. 14531481), enlisted such ideals

17

For two examples, see Cemal Kafadar, Between Two Worlds: The Construction of
the Ottoman State (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1995); and Linda Darling,
Revenue-Raising and Legitimacy: Tax Collection and Finance Administration in the Ottoman
Empire, 15601650 (Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1996).
18
Compare Peter-Christian Witt, The History and Sociology of Public Finance:
Problems and Topics, in Wealth and Taxation in Central Europe: The History and Sociology
of Public Finance, ed. Witt (Leamington Spa, UK: Berg Publishing, 1987), 118.
19
Kafadar, Between Two Worlds, 11113.
20
See Cornell H. Fleischer, Bureaucrat and Intellectual in the Ottoman Empire: The
Historian Mustafa 'Ali (15411600) (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1986),
100102; Abou El-Haj, Modern State; and Pal Fodor, State and Society, Crisis and
Reform in 15th17th Century Ottoman Mirror for Princes, Acta Orientalia Academiae
Scientiarum Hungaricae 40 (1986): 21740.

82

to consolidate absolutism, to detach his commanders from conicting


regional loyalties, and to radically curtail the accumulation of property by statesmen.21
In centralizing state institutions, Mehmet II also brought into existence a new division of labor, rst between the old and new palaces
and, later, among the orders composing the central state.22 Unlike
the oral compacts binding amirs and princes, the charters of incorporation and codes of administrative law, the Te{rifat-i Kanunnme-i
l-i Osman were copied and revised. They did not simply detail protocolduties, dress, ranks, and privilegesor rearm the division
between statesmen and subject. They also gave permanency to the
ruling estates and established a system of checks and balances between
them. It was the grand vizier, the bearer of the sultans seal and
deputy, who shared custody over state resources and tended its
nances alongside the chief treasurer, the defterdar efendi. Thus, despite
the seemingly impregnable fortress and, to outside observers, the hermetically sealed orders residing in the Topkap Saray, replete with
schools, atelier, nancial apparatus, kitchens, supreme court, and
divan, these organizational charters planted the seeds of other sophisticated hierarchies and established the basic parameters of privilege
and obligation for the ruling elite, as well as for other aspirants, individuals or groups, to state oce.23
The Istanbul bureaucracy grew alongside the geographical expanse
of the empire. However, by the early seventeenth century their numbers stabilized. For every clerk, accountant, and scribe in the centralstate bureaucracy, there were approximately one thousand salaried
soldiers and ten harem sta members.24 Linda Darling attributes this
compactness to the changing nature of its duties.25 The labor-intensive tasks of codication and cadastration had been accomplished.

21
Colin Imber, Ebu"s-su"ud: The Islamic Legal Tradition (Stanford: Stanford University
Press, 1997), 67.
22
Halil (nalck, Knnnme, EI 2, 4:56266.
23
For the origins of the provincial treasuries, Fleischer, Bureaucrat and Intellectual,
31213. On the nancial foundations of the rebel Canbulado[lus mini-state in
Syria, see William Griswold, Political Unrest and Rebellion in Anatolia, 1000 1020/
15911611 (Berlin: Klaus Schwarz Griswold, 1983), 122.
24
Rhoads Murphey, Ottoman Warfare, 15001700 (London: University of London
Press, 1999), 53; Peirce, The Imperial Harem, 122. Darling, Revenue-Raising and
Legitimacy, 70.
25
Darling, Revenue-Raising and Legitimacy, 6265. In 1613, the high point in her
study, there were 188 clerks and accountants.

83

A purely geographical division of bureaus and tasks gave way, to


greater standardization of process in terms of formulae, precedent,
universal forms of taxation, and contract. At its greatest extent, the
eighteenth-century the Istanbul civil service never seems to have
exceeded fteen hundred individuals, only a fraction of comparable
administrations in France and Russia.26
To a large degree the size of the Ottoman administration was
illusory. Certainly, Cornell Fleischer is correct in emphasizing the
role that bureaucrats themselves played in inhibiting the expansion
of the Istanbul orders and restricting entry to clients and kin, particularly, as we shall see, when state service constituted the sine qua
non for its quasi-aristocratic claims, what Rifa"at Abou-el-Haj calls
the sense of entitlement.27 However, we must look beyond the
ocial cadres in Istanbul to the thousands of contractors, subcontractors, and multi-tasking ocials in the provinces who put these
orders into eect. Without conceding the honor of ocial title or
the security of inclusion in their charters, imperial bureaucrats, increasingly specialized in communications and coordination of operations,
devolved many of the most labor-intensive duties, say, tax assessment and collection, on the provincial gentry and resident janissaries.
By the end of the eighteenth century, the inordinately large number
of viziers may also have been product of this shunting of responsibilities outside the ocial hierarchy.28
Comparing the number of internal to external state agents is
also a misleading gauge of institutional centralization. A more apt
measure might be found in the incremental merging of palace resources
and with it, the powers of patronage under the Porte.29 Rhetorically
the vast resources of the empire all belonged to the sultan, whether
from his personal wealth, from properties of the state and the commonweal (beyt "l-mal ), or from taxation; But in practice Ottoman
nances had long been divided into two separate entities. On one

26

Findley, Ottoman Civil Ocialdom, 2223.


Cornell Fleischer, Preliminaries to the Study of the Ottoman Bureaucracy,
in Raiyyet Rsumu, Essays Presented to Halil (nalck (Special Edition of Journal of Turkish
Studies), ed. Bernard Lewis et al. 10 (1986): 14041.
28
Findley, Ottoman Civil Ocialdom, 2223.
29
See Halil Sahillio[lu, }v{ Year Crises in the Ottoman Empire, in Studies
in the Economic History of the Middle East from the Rise of Islam to the Present Day, ed.
M. A. Cook (London: Oxford University Press, 1970), 23033; Uzunar{l, Osmanl
Devletinin Merkez ve Bahriye Te{kilt; Darling, Revenue-Raising and Legitimacy, 81119.
27

84

hand, there was the purely patrimonial treasury of the sultan (hazine-i
enderun), who served as trustee of the commonweal and religious
endowments. On the other hand, there was the true forerunner of
the sc, the operational treasury, called alternately, the hazine-i birn
or, more commonly, the hazine-i amire, devoted to the running of the
state, war and the management of the empires vast latifundia.30
As controller of the harem, the senior black eunuchs oversaw
palace nances. In eect, the palace treasury received the sultans
share of imperial wealth. This included war booty and slaves, the
routine conscation (msadere) of the goods of former ocials and
ocers, gifts, prots from the mint, earnings from mines, the yearly
payment from Egypt, and the tribute paid by conquered or vassal
countries, in addition to a steady stream of gifts ( pi{ke{) that were
mandatory for those ascending the highest rungs of the state hierarchy. The head of the harem possessed the ability to appoint and
dismiss scholars and preachers to posts in the pious endowments
(waqf/awqf ) founded by members of the dynasty as well as those
established for the benet of pilgrims to Mecca and Medina.
The vizier who retained the keys to both vaults, oversaw the operational treasury. Originally, it received the taxation created by statute
and much of the poll tax levied, usually in aggregate sums, from
Christian and Jewish communities. The vizier could draw upon revenues that were received from miri (state) lands, whether assigned as
timars or collected by nonresident ocials and tax farmers.31 In the
sixteenth century, the annualization of the rst direct levies, under
the heading of the avrz and the nzl bedeliyesi, brought in another
large stream of income into this treasury.32 Although established to
run the state and specically to pay for the upkeep and outtting

30
mer Lt Barkan,(166970) Mali Ylna ait bir Osmanl Btesi ve Ekleri,
(FM 17 (195556): 193347.
31
Sahillio[lu, }v{ Year Crises, 33033; Uzunar{l, Osmanl Devletinin Merkez
ve Bahriye Te{kilat, 32831.
32
For the history of the rst direct tax, known generically as avrz, see Darling,
Revenue-Raising and Legitimacy, 81118. On the application of the taille in France, see
James B. Collins, Fiscal Limits of Absolutism: Direct Taxation in Early Seventeenth-Century
France (Berkeley: University of California, 1988); and for the Turk tax in Austria,
Kersten Krger, Public Finance and Modernisation: The Change from the Domain
State to Tax State in Hesse in the Sixteenth and Seventeenth Centuries. A Case
Study, Wealth and Taxation in Central Europe: The History and Sociology of Public Finance,
ed. Peter-Christian Witt (Lexington Spa, UK: Berg, 1987), 4962.

85

of its military forces, the operational treasury continued to contribute


to palace expenses as well. Funds were set aside for the upkeep of
the royal household and for the pocket money of the sultan.
A summary of income and expenditures of the outer treasury
dating from 166970 helps us better appreciate the actual allocation
of imperial income. It reveals that the palace still commanded nearly
30 percent of the states total revenues, a little less than half of the
monies used to pay the salaries of infantry (both full-time salaried
corps and mercenaries), cavalry, sailors, and frontier guards, which
constituted 62.5 percent of total expenditures. Outright payment for
salaries due the civil bureaucracy amounted to less than 1 percent
of the imperial budget.33
Over the course of the seventeenth century, the operational treasury far outstripped the sultans coers in complexity of tasks and
sheer volume of transactions. The relentless demands of warfare
forced a steady expansion of the states economic claims on society
overall as well as on the sultanate. In addition to the new universal, direct taxes by the end of the seventeenth century, the Sublime
Porte imposed excise duties on formerly banned substances, such as
tobacco and coee.34 Minorities, who also bore the brunt of new
legislation in Europe and Mughal India, were subjected to the reformulated poll tax (cizye) of 1691, which would become one of the single most important sources of Ottoman state revenues by the early
eighteenth century.35
Bitter experience taught Istanbul ocials to choose their targets
with care. They staggered new taxation geographically, particularly
for peasants living close to the battle front or for residents of major
administrative cities.36 Yet many other types of taxation never reached
Istanbul. The central government turned a blind eye to the raising

33

Barkan, Mali Ylna ait bir Osmanl Btesi, 224.


Darling, Revenue-Raising and Legitimacy, 67, 7879. Ahmet Tabako[lu, Gerileme
Dnemine Girerken Osmanl Maliyesi (Istanbul: Dergh Yaynlar, 1985), 27273.
35
Halil (nalck, Djizya, EI 2, 2:563566; Tabako[lu, Gerileme Dnemine Girerken,
1045, 13643, 15761, 180. The poll tax became the largest single component
of direct taxation during the eighteenth century; it yielded between 22 percent and
40 percent of the total. By contrast, avrz income sharply declined.
36
On the deteriorating conditions in the countryside, Bruce McGowan, Economic
Life in the Ottoman Europe: Taxation, Trade and the Struggle for Land (Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 1981), 5455; Tabako[lu, Gerileme Dnemine Girerken, 14042,
274, 289; and M. Mnir Aktepe, Patrona Isyan (1730) (Istanbul: Edebiyat Fakltesi,
1958), 910.
34

86

of extraordinary levies in the provinces, such as the srsat bedeliyesi


and i{tira bedeliyesi, needed for military provisions or for salaries, as
well as to the arbitrary dues that commanders, sipahi, jannisaries,
and other ocers demanded from rural populations.37
Perhaps the most powerful catalyst of growth in the states capacity was debt. When tax receipts did not suce, bureaucrats reversed
the predatory relationship that had prevailed between the two treasuries.38 The grand vizier, when need arose, could withdraw funds
to pay for state expenses.39 A time honored practice, reliance on the
palace treasury in early centuries was timed with the nancial shortfalls occasioned by the leap months of the Islamic calendar.40 Although
the adoption of a solar calendar after 1710 for accounting purposes
remedied this particular problem, from the last decade of the seventeenth century onward supplements drawn from the palace treasury became a common occurrence in wartime. During the protracted
war with the Holy League (16831699), loans from the sultans treasury to the sc met about one-tenth of its annual expenses; during
the military campaign against Peter the Great (17101711), the palace
contributed nearly one-third of state expenses.41
Because little of these monies was ever repaid, the chief treasurer
devised subtler means of poaching upon palace wealth. A common
practice was for accountants to divide the revenues of receipts earmarked for the palace, such as the imperial mint, between the sc
and palace treasury.42 The conscated goods of former soldiers and
civil servants as well as intestate goods that were traditionally channeled toward the beyt "l-mal or commonweal (and thus entrusted to
the sultans keeping), also increasingly found their way into general
spending.43
Amid the worldwide nancial crises of the turn of the century,
sovereigns scoured their realms and populations for the means to
37

Tabako[lu, Gerileme Dnemine Girerken, 15361.


See Ariel Salzmann, An Ancien Rgime Revisited: Privatization and Political
Economy in the 18th century Ottoman Empire, Politics & Society 21 (1993): 393423.
39
Tabako[lu, Gerileme Dnemine Girerken, 3639.
40
Sahillio[lu, }v{ Year Crises, 33033.
41
Tabako[lu, Gerileme Dnemine Girerken, 16, 243.
42
MMD 9524:16.
43
Darling, Revenue-Raising and Legitimacy, 65. For a detailed study of the process
of expropriation, see Yavuz Cezar, Bir yann Muhallefat: Havza ve Kpr yan
Kr (smail-o[lu Hseyin (Msadere Olay ve Terekenin (ncelenmesi), Belleten 151
(1977): 4178.
38

87

meet scal exigencies.44 In the Ottoman Empire, the treasury deferred


cash outlays by bureaucratic sleight of hand: tagging the revenues
from agrarian sources to individuals in the form of retirement assignments, pin (shoe) money for princesses, or ocaklk (the taxes of villages or rural communities), which were devoted to the upkeep of
infantry units or frontier troops. The dynastys crown lands or hass
revenues, which included the large scal estates reserved for governors and commanders in such regions as West Asia (particularly,
Syria, Eastern Anatolia, Kurdistan, and Iraq, where the timar system
had never been applied in a comprehensive fashion) were increasingly reduced to scal units. These mukatat served as a quasimodular form of accounting; they aorded the bureaucracy a new
exibility in the assignment of distant resources, as well as the means
to anticipate revenues through revenue contracting.45 At times a central-state agent would be appointed to carry out the collection of
taxes; in many other instances, the scal bureaucracy would leave
beneciaries to their own devices.46
Borrowing took many forms. Revenue contracting, as Yavuz Cezar
reminds us, was probably one of the most common means of managing state debt. However, precisely because revenue farming entailed
a contractual relationship as well as a recycling of state resources
through multiple hands, the specic modalities merit closer examination.47 The edict of 1695, which authorized the use of leases for
life (malikne mukatat) on such scal units brought into being distinctive
sociopolitical arrangements while fullling multiple nancial and bureaucratic purposes.48 For the potential contractor, the treasury oered

44

Larry Neal, The Rise of Financial Capitalism: International Capital Markets in the Age
of Reason (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990), 1117.
45
Darling, Revenue-Raising and Legitimacy, 123.
46
Mukatat were either assigned as salary to be managed by tax farmers (mltezim), stewards (voyvoda), or revenue agents (emin) or directly to janissaries in lieu of
salary. Some were even awarded on a lifetime basis. Tabako[lu, Gerileme Dnemine
Girerken, 12628.
47
Yavuz Cezar, Osmanl Maliyesinde Bunalm ve De[i{im Dnemi (XVIII. Yzyldan
Tanzimat"a Mali Tarih) (Istanbul: Alan Yaynclk, 1986), 51.
48
The standard work on the subject remains Mehmet Gen, Osmanl Maliyesinde
Malikne Sistemi, in Trkiye (ktisat Tarihi Semineri, ed., Osman Okyar and nal
Nalbanto[lu (Ankara: Hacetepe niversitesi 1975), 231296. One does not have to
search far to nd reports of deteriorating conditions: KK 3105:11 (1721), for example,
concerns the plight of villages whose taxation, held in an ocaklk, had been farmed
out under short-term contracts. Given terms of contract, however, tax-farmers seemed
reluctant to assume all but the most lucrative contracts, such as Istanbuls snu tax

88

revenues with quasi-proprietary rights, including administrative autonomy and the possibility of passing shares to sons and male relatives.
For the treasury, the edit assured an immense infusion of capital.
Each successful bid brought in a large advance on future income in
the form of a surety (muaccele). Thereafter, the bureaucrats were
assured of regular installments of income (mal ) over decades.49 For
a strapped bureaucratic corps, it helped standardize procedure, lifted
the burden of repeated reassessment, and furnished longer-term agents
to collect revenues, particularly the many sources that formed the
oldest revenue bureaus, such as the ba{ muhasebe. Moreover, without
formal expansion of the Istanbul bureaucracy itself, the new contract harnessed a labor force for the state as it extended its powers
of scal patronage.50
By providing very competitive terms of contract and, even, dignifying the practice of tax farming, the malikne system facilitated
the merging of the two treasuries. Within two years of its promulgation, provisions were made for the application of the life-lease to
resources that formed part of the palace income.51 They included
the enormous crown estates set aside for the upkeep of the queen
mother, royal consorts, princesses, the admiral of the Mediterranean
eet, the grand viziers, the senior black eunuch, the steward of the
imperial stirrup (rikab- hmayun kaymakam), and the khans of the

(mukataa- resm-i duhan), which sold quickly (zcan, Anonim Osmanl Tarihi, 20). By
contrast, another document (D.B}M 624) reveals that many other contracts, including villages in Kars, the customs stations of Erzurum and Baghdad, crown estates
in Mar"a{, zeamets in Urfa, and a soap factory in Bosnia, found no bidders at a
169495 auction.
49
MMD 3423 (169598) contains copies of the certicates awarded to life-lease
contractors during the rst years of auctions.
50
In addition the document reported by Ra{id Efendi, (Mehmed Ra{id, Tarih-i
Ra{id [Istanbul: Matbaa-i Miri, 1282/186566] 2:28889), Gen (Osmanl Maliyesinde
Malikne Sistemi, 28488) has located two important decrees in the archive (KK
5040:12). Although Avdo Sueska (Malikane, POF 36 [1986]: 197229) may be
correct in attributing the edit itself to the reign of Ahmed II; however, as a policy, the life-lease system is testimony to a growing consensus among the elite of this
period concerning scal and administrative matters.
51
Tabako[lu, Gerileme Dnemine Girerken, 19496. Hass accounts are included in
the budget in 169091 and provides payments for the palace. On the malikne-hass,
that is, havass- hmayun, awarded under malikne contracts, see Cezar, Osmanl Maliyesinde
Bunalm, 3944, 4849, 66. Such estates constitute an important component of the
subventions given the Crimean khans. Among the many documents pertaining to
the estates of eighteenth-century princesses, see those for Saye Sultan (CS 868);
Alem{ah Sultan (CS 4207); Ay{e Sultan (CS 5433); and Hadime Sultan (CS 2902).

89

Crimea, to name only the some of the noble individuals involved.52


Once converted, the bureaucrats assumed the ultimate oversight of
these resources which allowed them to divert least part of the income,
from either the surety or annual remittance, toward general operating expenses.53
(brahim Pashas tenure, in particular, witnessed a marked expansion of the life-leases.54 State auctions designated taxes and duties
throughout the empire, such as the Balkans and the Aegean, regions
that technically fell well outside the scope of the original edict. A
wide variety of agentsfrom personal stewards (kethda), intendants
(voyvoda), revenue agents (emin), and nancial agents (sarraf ), to provincial soldiers and members of the gentryacted as on-site administrators.55 Contractors paid the executive ocers of the Porte and the
highest-ranking members of the judiciary special fees for awards and
transfers of shares in their contracts.56
Thus, the new contract added another weapon to the Portes institutional arsenal against the nancial independence of the palace.
There were other attempts to pry away its powers of patronage.
Shortly before Be{ir A[as promotion to head of the harem sta,
Grand Vizier }ehid Ali Pasha succeeded in establishing two new
accounting bureaus to oversee part of the imperial households vast
endowments, particularly those involving agricultural and tribal taxes
in northern Syria and Anatolia.57 But many areas of palace nance
withstood this assault. The valuable grain lands in Egypt, which
52

Cezar, Osmanl Maliyesinde Bunalm, 37, 4849.


Tabako[lu, Gerileme Dnemine Girerken, 104, 289. Cezar, Osmanl Maliyesinde Bunalm,
328. Many if not most contracts were awarded from the large nancial bureau of
the muhasebe-i evvel, which yielded between 18.8 percent and 38.7 percent of the
general income over the century.
54
Tabako[lu, Gerileme Dnemine Girerken, 134.
55
Hseyin zde[er, III. Ahmedin Varidt ve Defteri, Trk (ktisat Tarihi Yll[
(Istanbul niversitesi (ktisat Fakltesi Trk (ktisat ve (timiyt Tarihi Ara{trmalar
Merkezi, 1987), 1:30552. Whether these are the sultans own estates or those of
his sons, such revenues as hass- Be[pazar, hass- Haymana- Bzrk ve Kk, hass-
Menemen, hass- Boynu (ncel (taifesi), hass- Mukataa-i Malatya, hass- Esb-Ke{n ve BozUlus) do form part of the inner treasury. For another example of shares in hass of
princes veledn- sultan, see CS 5287.
56
Mouradgea I. DOhsson, Tableau gnral de lEmpire Othoman (Paris: M. Firmin
Didot Imp., 182024) vol. 3, 17576; 36870. For registration the treasury charged
a 10 percent fee, two thirds of which was paid to the grand vizier and one-third
to the director of the sc.
57
Tabako[lu, Gerileme Dnemine Girerken, 90, 104; Cezar, Osmanl Maliyesinde Bunalm,
100101.
53

90

supported pilgrims and the population of Mecca and Medina, would


resist reorganization until the 1740s.58 In other areas, the palace
gained ground. In 1716, the senior black eunuch assumed the oversight of nearly all of the endowments founded by members of the
palace, in addition to those of the eunuchs themselves. At his
Wednesday divan, Be{ir A[a discussed salaries, awards of revenue
contracts on the Egyptian villages, and appointments of professors
and imams at hundreds of mosques and religious institutions throughout the empire, including the prestigious mosques of Istanbul, Edirne,
and Bursa.59
In countering this inuence generally, and in an attempt to win
the hearts generally, of the empires ulema in particular, the Porte
summoned income from the largest revenue contracts, many of which
became life-leases, or later, state-managed bonds or esham.60 Stipends
( yevmiye) were allotted to three categories of recipients: pensioners
(mtek"idin), servants (hddm) and the ulema, or those who say
prayers (du"-gyn). These allotments constituted either pensions or
rewards for unspecied duties (vazife). Over the century, although
the pool of pensioners and servants remained fairly stable, the population of du"-gynscholars, imams, sayyids (descendents of the
Prophet), and leaders of Su orders, as well as members of their
familiesliving in Istanbul, Edirne, Izmir, Salonika, Mecca, Medina,
and Damascus multiplied.61 In 1738, for example, the tax farm on
the commercial taris of greater Istanbul, which included its suburbs, such as Galata and the ports of Gelibolu and Mudanya, supported only 550 mtek"idin and hddm but disbursed stipends to
approximately 6,000 du"-gyn.62 The yearly income from large provin58
Jane Hathaway, The Politics of Household in Ottoman Egypt: The Rise of the Qazada[l
(Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997), 13964.
59
Uzunar{l, Osmanl Devletinin Saray Te{kilt. See also Jane Hathaway, The
Role of the Kzlar A[as in Seventeenth-Eighteenth Century Ottoman Egypt, Studia
Islamica 75 (1992): 14158.
60
See H. Veli Aydin, Osmanl Maliyesinde Esham Uygulamas (17751840)
(Ph.D. diss., Ankara University, 1998).
61
The seventeenth-century Hezarfen Hseyin Efendi (Telhsl-Beyn, 98) states
that 136 yk 22,400 ake from the mukataa revenues in the hazine-i amire were set
aside for this purpose. But the historian Naima (d. 1716) (Lewis V. Thomas, A
Study of Naima, ed. Norman Itzkowitz [New York: New York University Press, 1972],
1045) insists that most ulema received stipends from endowments connected to
mosques and other religious institutions and that the customs revenues were used
for the salaries of other ocials.
62
KK 4264; KK 4308.

91

cial revenue contracts, such as Bursas silk tax, paid the salaries of
the ulema of the Holy Cities.63 Provincial tax farms, such as the
voyvodalk of Diyarbekir or the deftardarlk of Damascus, contributed
subventions in cash and grain to local professors and the members
of Su orders.64
One of the most important sources of ulema stipends were the
remittances from the excise tax on coee and tobacco, the so-called
sin taxes (resm-i bid"at). In 172223, the coee tax for Istanbul (including income from other major ports such as Salonika) paid out stipends
to 728 pensioners of the palace and 1,160 members of the ulema
(du"-gyn). Thirty years later the same tax farm made payments to
2,450 members of the ulema (of whom 665 were female relatives).65
As for the tobacco tax, awarded as a tax farm in 1691 and as a
life-lease in 174445, its revenues supported 1,586 individuals, of
whom 51 were women.66 In 177273, the 623 women who derived
stipends from this tax farm constituted more than one-third of the
total (1,761) number of those listed as members of the ulema.67
Naturally, the chief mufti of the empire also received his share: of
the tobacco regies annual income of 159,028.5 kuru{, 25,000 kuru{
was paid to him directly, in lieu of salary (bedel ).68
If the operational treasury under the supervision of the Porte was
as it could be arguedthe forerunner of the modern sc, then it
was the rhizome of nancial relations engendered by debt that
expanded and structured the social capacity of the emerging state.

63
A 1780 Summary (KK 4547) assigned 1.23 million ake to stipend holders and
7.09 million ake went for du"-gyn stipends. In 1802, the tax on silk sales in Bursa
(KK 4198) supported ulema resident in Mecca and Medina.
64
D.B}M 2071:29 11501154 (17371741). Provincial tax farm budgets were
much the same; of the three-year income (mal) from the voyvodalk of Diyarbekir,
totaling 31,391,793 ake, 1,396,461 ake were devoted to pensioners and du"-gyn.
65
In 1691, the coee tax yielded 204 kese, or 10.2 million ake according to
Tabako[lu (Gerileme Dnemine Girerken, 274); see KK 4520 (172223) and KK 4530
(175253) later income. In 1780 (KK 4557), 1.23 million ake were subtracted from
it to support pensioners and 7.09 million ake went to the ulema as stipends. They
included their wives and daughters such as Rakiya hanm (at 130 ake per day) and
Ay{e hatun (80 ake per day).
66
zcan, Anonim Osmanl Tarihi, 2021; KK 4471.
67
KK 4484. The tobacco taxes involved in this farm were collected at many
ports, including Salonika, Drac (Durazzo), Bo[az, Tekfur Da[, (negl, Edirne,
Tripoli, Istanbul, Aleppo, Damascus, and Jaa. In 176162, its gross income
for the sc was 2900 kese rumi ake or 145 million ake/1.21 million kuru{ (CM
26,858).
68
CM 21,369.

92

In many ways, the malikne contract epitomized the indirect strategy


of centralization under the old regime. It was a particularly eective
tactic in wresting away palace funds and placing all or part of those
assets under the aegis of the Sublime Porte. Although it applied to
only a fraction of central-state revenues as a whole, the leasing system generated a secondary apparatus consisting of thousands of contractors across the empire who seconded a small bureaucratic corps
based in the capital. From its introduction in 1695 to its gradual
phasing out after 1789, it fostered a complex circuitry of redistribution and scal patronage that bound members of court, the ulema
and the ruling estate to one another.

Hierarchies of Service
In a snapshot of the imperial hierarchy, Levni records the dignitaries and statesmen as they stand at attention in anticipation of the
sultan (Plate 3). Throughout the album, bureau chiefs, professors,
members of the divan, captains, ushers, the commander of the palace
doormenare all distinguished by dress, textiles, furs, and the number of ceremonial horsetails and plumes. In such small details as
headgear, the painter conjures up the myriad gradations of political
status. The head eunuchs of the palaces inner sanctum, the dar lsade a[as and the bab l-sade a[as (chief white eunuch), sport wide
conical hats (mcevveze). The tall, triangular-shaped hat bearing a gold
band distinguishes the vizier from the descendent of the Prophet,
who wears a large, round, green turban. The sultan himself bears
no crown. But, a confection made up of precious gems, the sorguc,
is clipped to the front of his kavuk, a cap encircled with precious
cloth.
It fell to the court to enforce these sumptuary distinctions.69 Displays
of status delimited the social borders between the men of the state
and the third estate, as well as between the Muslims, Jews, and
Christians of the city.70 Yet the display of rank took many forms.
The four governors, representing the provinces of Mosul, Aleppo,
Aydin, and Bursa, who will join the festivities later and who have
69
On this topic, see Donald Quataert, Clothing Laws, State, and Society in the
Ottoman Empire, 17201829, IJMES 29 (1997): 40325.
70
Bekir Sitki Baykal, Mustafa III, A( 8:702.

93

been diverted from their provincial posts for the occasion, demonstrate
another form of sociopolitical obligation. Their appearance at the
ritual is marked by the presentation of a lavish gift to the sultan.71
Far more intricate than mastering the details of status associated with
dress were the nuances of etiquette (te{rifat) that determined the value
and type of gifts exchanged between superior and subordinate.
Behind the curtain of ceremonial preformances, therefore, rank
and status are also revealed in the expense ledgers of pashas and in
entries under the terms blandishments (avaidat ), honoraria (caize),
and presents (hediye).72 A governorship in eighteenth-century Aleppo,
for example, demanded many such gratuities: to the secretary of
state, his purse-bearer, the chief usher of the Porte, and the director of the chancellery, among many other ocials and members of
court whose pockets were lled by his largesse. These payments were
over and above the enormous gifts to the grand vizier and his chief
of sta, personal accountant, and clerk.73 Not only did an incoming
governor pass out gifts up and down the Istanbul chain of command, he was also obliged to confer gratuities in cloth and cash on
the local commander of the fort (dizdar) and the sergeant of the
guard (karakullakina ba{), who in turn paid him homage in money
when seeking transfers or new appointments.74
In a hierarchy dened by service to the state and the presumption of merit and ability, the introduction of such vast sums into the
process of promotion and political mobility produced a tension to
be sure. These exorbitant expenditures for etiquettes sake, had become
the modus vivendi of the old regime, prompted contemporary observers
to voice their objections to practices that they felt transgressed the
boundaries between a gift and outright bribery or extortion.75 Yet

71
See Metin Kunt, Dervi{ Mehmet Pa{a: Vezir and Entrepreneur: A Study in
Ottoman Political-Economic Theory and Practice, Turcica 9 (1977): 197214.
72
D.B}M 3546 (1759); M. Zeki Pakaln, Osmanl Tarih Deyimleri ve Terimleri Szl[
(Istanbul: Milli E[itim Bakanl[ Yaynlar, 1983), 2:58. Uzunar{l, Osmanl Devletinin
Merkez, 199202.
73
D.B}M 5019 (17801781).
74
D.B}M 3546 (17591760). Registration fees included 8,467.5 kuru{ for the
grand vizier and 4,233.5 kuru{ for the imperial treasurer. Abdul-Karim Rafeq, The
Province of Damascus (Beirut: Khayats, 1966), 23439.
75
See Ahmet Mumcu, Tarih (indeki Genel Geli{imiyle Birlikte Osmanl Devletinde R{vet
zellikle Adli R{vet (Istanbul: Inkilp Kitabevi, 1985); compare Natalie Zemon Davis,
The Gift in Sixteenth-Century France (Madison: University of Wisconsin, 2000), 8599.

94

ination of the concept of the gift was inevitable. But this, too,
was relative to status: what might be considered a criminal oense
for an individual of a lower station would be perfectly respectable,
even obligatory for his social superior. Facing the greatly increasing
costs of oce and diminished incomes, most appointees to higher
oce necessarily fell back on entrepreneurial skills.76
The eighteenth century was a point of transition in imperial hierarchies. Nonetheless, it seemed for a time that despite the pressure
for material resources for entrance and promotion, good introductions and proper training could still propel a talented young man
into the orbit of the court and or the bureaucracy. Nev{ehirli (brahim
Pasha is a case in point. He found his way to the top through the
ceremonial helvaclar corps, a position that his father, an Anatolian
intendant for the palace, had secured for him.77 A good education
and eloquence must have brought the poet Hmi of Amid (b. 1679)
to the attention of Muhsinzde Abdullah Pasha, the grand viziers
chief of sta, in 1709.78 Selected to accompany Vizier Kprlzde
Abdullah Pasha on his tour of the poets native town in 1717, the
pasha entrusted him with the management of his mukatat.
Ultimately, it was business acumene that paid o. Hmi invested
his own money in malikne contracts. This income and experience,
must have eventually helped him, at the rather mature age of ftytwo, to attain a tenured position in the nancial department dealing with such contracts, the malikne halifesi. In reconstructing the life
of another talented man of provincial origin, Ahmed Resmi of Crete,
whose career began in 1730s, Virginia Aksan remarks on the apparent serendipity of many of the career paths, an elasticity at the upper
administrative levels in a system otherwise restrictive.79
Fluidity and serendipity were an even greater factor in appointments to provincial oce in the eighteenth century. In time of war,
the normal channels of promotion could be bypassed completely.
The distinguished eld commander eteci Abdullah Pasha, whom
we encountered during the rst decades of the Wars of the Iranian
76
Kunt, Bir Osmanl Valisinin Yllk Gelir Gideri, 4849; for the income and expenses
of a pasha serving in the Balkans in 1714, see Cezar, Osmanl Maliyesinde Bunalm,
50.
77
M. Mnir Aktepe, Nev{ehirli (brahim Pa{a, (A 9:23439.
78
Ali Amiri, Tezkere-i }u'ara-y Amid (Istanbul: Matbu'a-i Amidi, 1328/1910) vol.
1, 18793, 260; Gibb, A History of Ottoman Poetry, vol. 4, 111.
79
Aksan, An Ottoman Statesman, 1415.

95

Succession and who served valiantly in the Caucasus campaigns of


the 1720s as the captain of a mercenary battalion (levend ba{a[as), rose
quickly to the rank of beylerbeyi of Sivas in 1739 and shortly thereafter to vizier-governorships in Diyarbekir, Damascus, and Erzurum.80
More extraordinary still was the fortune of Osman Pasha, a
Georgian slave in the household of the gentry-governor of Damascus
who succeeded his master, one of the members of the powerful 'Azm
clan, to this oce between 1760 and 1771.81 This improbable situation came about after the disastrous pillage of the pilgrim caravan
in 1757, for which Grand Vizier Ragb Pasha ordered the execution of As"ad Pasha al-'Azm and the exile of his palace benefactor,
Ebukuf Ahmed A[a (r. 175558), the senior black eunuch. By leading ocials to the whereabouts of his masters treasures, the slave,
Osman was rewarded with the governorship of Damascus, the rank
of beylerbeyi of Tripoli, and 150,000 kuru{ in malikne contracts in
Hama and Hums. With his sons elevation to the governorship of
Tripoli shortly thereafter, Istanbuls intervention eectively turned a
gentry dynasty upside down.
Certainly this confusion of wealth and power, of rising provincial
stars and what appeared to be an unscrupulous central-state elite,
must have rankled the hardworking denizens of the central bureaucracy to whom we owe many court histories.82 After the overthrow
of Mehmet IV in 1687, internecine rivalries often took the form of
scal assaults by one chartered order on the privileges of another.83
In the decades of political upheaval and uctuating coalitions between
palace, Porte, soldiers, and populace that followed, all parties were
suspicious of innovation and any tampering with the perquisites of
rank.84 In this setting the new contract appeared to undercut the
80
}evket Beysano[lu, Diyarbakr Tarihi: Antlar ve Kitabeleri ile (Ankara: Neyir
Matbaas, 1993), 67981. With the exception of a posting in Syria and in Erzurum,
his assignments were close to home: initially Rakka at the rank of beylerbeyi, then
as pasha (vali ) of Diyarbekir in 1744, 1750, 1752, and 1759.
81
Rafeq, The Province of Damascus, 23439. D.B}M 3546 (175965) records
payments for oce, tax farms, and gifts on the occasion of the appointment of
Osman Pasha currently the Vizier of Damascus (pp. 118); and expenses for his
son Mehmet to assume oce in Tripoli (pp. 2021).
82
Bekir Ktko[lu, Vekynvis, A( 13:27187.
83
For more on the bedel-i timar, the special levy (cihet) on endowment income,
and other new impositions on wealth and privilege, Tabako[lu, Gerileme Dnemine
Girerken, 20712; 27073.
84
On the nature of politics, see Halil (nalck, Military and Fiscal Transformation,
and Rifa'at 'Ali Abou-El-Haj (The 1703 Rebellion and the Structure of Ottoman Politics

96

exclusivity of the statesmens privilege and immunity. By establishing


public auctions throughout the empire, a Muslim man, whether statesman or commoner, could tender bids on state resources. The malikne
(from a Persian-Arabic compound meaning as if to the owner)85
seemed to promise proprietary rights: it oered a long-term investment, freedom from administrative interference, and the opportunity
for reputable male heirs to lay claim to the shares after the previous
contractors death.
Commenting on the grand viziers decision to retract most contracts at the eve of the war with Venice in 1715 (an order that was
rescinded shortly before (brahim Pashas assumption of oce),86 the
court historian Ra{id Efendi vented his frustration. He denounced
those not deign of state resources and lacking even a trace of nobility [literally, absolutely not belonging to the state kati'an miri
olmiyan][such as] a common porter or boatswain, [who] could
upon reaching the rank of shaykh of any guild whatsoever, obtain
a malikne contract. The historian lamented that while the new contract was spreading throughout the empire it did not promote the
requisite sense of civic responsibility for the welfare of the empires
subjects. Rich men simply treated the malikne as another business
venture, using state assets as if they were their private property.87
Although it strikes many familiar, anti-corruption chords, Ra{id
Efendis diatribe does contains some distinctly eighteenth-century elements. In his eyes, the problem with the life-lease was not simply
that it allowed commoners to trespass beyond estate lines or that it
relegated landed resources to armchair administrators instead of to
soldiers. Rather, by his unusual use of the term miri (imperial) as
[Istanbul: Nederlands Historisch-Archaeologisch Instituut te Istanbul, 1984], 31);
compare Philip T. Homan (Early Modern France, 14501700, in Fiscal Crises,
Liberty and Representative Government, 14501789, ed. Philip T. Homan and Kathryn
Norberg (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1994), 25051.
85
F. Steinglass, Persian-English Dictionary 6th ed. (London: Routledge & Kegan
Paul, 1977), 1143. The term also referred to the early split-rent agreements
between landlords and the Ottoman state. See Irene Beldiceanu-Steinherr, Malikne,
EI 2 4:22728; and mer Lut Barkan, Malikne-Divn Sistemi, Trk Hukuk ve
(ktisat Tarihi Mecmuas 2 (1939): 11984.
86
Gen, Osmanl Maliyesinde Malikne Sistemi, 235 n. 34. For an example,
note the reinstatement of the farm held by a religious scholar in Mosul, Haydar
Efendi (MMD 6549:3233).
87
Rich individuals [kuvvet-i maliyesi olanlar] began taking malikne contracts on
everything they saw, using these resources as if they were their own personal property [kend mlk gibi mutassarif ]. Ra{id, Tarih-i Ra{id, 4:17677.

97

a qualier of persons as well as things, he seems to express the fear


that this particular contract threatened the very principle of agency
upon which the bureaucratic orders were founded.88 The life-lease
represented a bought privilege that diluted the dierences that distinguished the rical-i devlet from the third estate. While a commoner
gained quasi-ocial perquisites,89 ocials and ocers, the true servants of state, actually compromised their immunities when they took
up such contracts. Whether it was by paying the special enthronement tax (rsum-u clus) of 1703 or by contributing a percentage of
the surety as compensation for not taking up arms (cebel bedeliyesi)
in years of war, ocers and ocials had became tax payers as well
as contractors.90
Perhaps most grating for the civil servant who had patiently climbed
the rungs of the state hierarchy, was the potential for commoners
to amass state resources in an unregulated manner. This was, after
all, a ruling class that was dened not only by its privileges and tax
immunities but by its liabilities, chief among which were the forfeiture of all personal wealth upon death or dismissal from oce.91

88
Defterdar Sar Mehmet Pasha (Wright, Ottoman Statecraft, 23) chastises contemporaries about the misuse of state resources. For other abuses, see Abou-El-Haj,
The 1703 Rebellion, 116; Cezar, Osmanl Maliyesinde Bunalm ve De[i{im, 42, 51. The
perception of abuse is not unconnected to the rank and status of the actor. In the
sixteenth century, Mustafa Ali complained about the impudence of low ranking persons (Andreas Tietze, Mustafa Alis Counsel for Sultans of 1581 [Wien: Verlag der
sterreichischen Akademie der Wissenschaften, 1979] vol. 1, 58). In the late eighteenth century, similar sentiments are expressed by Selim IIIs advisor, Abdullah
Efendi Tatarck (see Selim-i Sni devrinde Nizm- Devlet hakknda mutl"at,
Trk Tarihi Encmeni Mecmuas 8 [1333/19141915]: 17).
89
The usual formula to confer such immunity is mefrzl-kalem ve maktlkadem; Gen, Osmanl Maliyesinde Malikne, 239; for examples in diplomas,
MMD 9486:6 and DA III:153.
90
Michael Kwass (A Kingdom of Taxpayers: State Formation, Privilege, and
Political Culture in Eighteenth-Century France, Journal of Modern History 70 [1998]:
300) suggests that privilege should have been incompatible with tax paying. The
Ottoman nobility of service had similar tax immunities but were forced to contribute in periods of crisis. The new lease brought new obligations. Lease holders
contributed to the clus bah{i{i, the ascension donation to the janissaries (Defterdar
Sar Mehmet Pasha, Ottoman Statecraft, 1045; Gen, Osmanl Maliyesinde
Malikne Sistemi, 247). In the years of war, they paid the cebel bedeliyesi, a levy
assessed on contracts at the rate of 10 percent or 15 percent of the bid price.
91
J. R. Jones (Fiscal Policies, Liberties, and Representative Government during
the Reigns of the Last Stuarts, in Homan and Norberg, Fiscal Crises, 6795) provides a useful discussion on the dierence between liberties, such as property, and
privileges, such as tax farming.

98

Although some courtiers and high ocials may have welcomed the
loophole furnished by the malikne edit which provided for some form
of intergenerational devolution,92 there was no reason to allow the
gentry and ulema to take advantage of this provision because they
had no legal barriers to inheritance. Every aspect of the new contract seemed to assure that the third estate would benet from such
special provisions or from any ambiguities arising from an overly
generous interpretation of Islamic laws on private property.93
The bureaucrats fears proved largely unfounded. Despite attempts
to conate contract and property, ordinary contractors rarely succeeded in gaining state recognition of their claims.94 Whether as
beneciaries of the income of high yielding revenue sources in their
lifetime or as a member of an elite network of shareholders, it was
the courtier and the high ranking ocer who beneted disproportionately from this scal dispensation. They, too, had the best chance
of converting, often in stages, a public resource into private property.95
Rather than the cause, the new contract may have been another
symptom of the pronounced closing of state ranks to outsiders that
occurred in the eighteenth century. A clique of households and

92
DOhsson, Tableau gnral, vol. 3, 36869. Although the principle of devolving
shares to a surviving male relative, the evldiyet {urtu, was a well-established
practice, disputes (note MMD 9494:23 [170203]) did arise.
93
The Hanete legal school recognizes overlapping but analytically distinct proprietary claims on the usufruct and ownership of assets, according to Chak Chehata,
Essai dune theorie gnrale de lobligation en droit Musulman (Cairo: Nury Publishers, 1936)
1:173.
94
For example, in 1696 (MMD 3426:56) the sons of a certain Yahya Beg (perhaps a janissary or a timar holder) petitioned the Porte for the life-lease on the dye
house in Aleppo, arguing that they were entitled to the lease because their father,
the previous tax farmer, had made substantial capital investments in the building.
Indeed, the brothers seemed to have proprietary claims. Jean-Pierre, Dcentralisation
Ottomane et armation urbaine Alep la n du XVIIIme sicle, in Mouvements
communautaires et spaces urbains au Machreq, ed. Mona Zakaria, et al. [Beirut: Centre
dtudes et de recherches sur le Moyen-Orient Contemporain, 1985], 129) came
across a complaint that had been brought against them in the court of Aleppo.
Craftsmen accused the sons of insisting that the new contract made them owners
outright of the dye house.
95
For the gradual privatization of the dye house of nk{, originally a tax
farm, MMD 9519:81 and D.B}M 1069 (n.d.) For other instances of converting contract into property, Abou-El-Haj, The 1703 Rebellion, 9, 51, 116. Of these attempts,
the conversion of contracts into endowments seems to have been the most secure
route: In 1710 Grand Vizier Ali Pasha converted a malikne holding into a pious
endowment (waqf ) that supported the building of a mosque-imaret-dershane complex
in Istanbul.

99

inuential bureaucratic families would dominate the major branches


of government service.96 The lower rungs of state service may have
traded size for security and exclusivity.97 In addition to securing life
tenure in oce, gedik (an analogue of the slots held by infantry),
which was conceded in 1732, bureaucrats were able to amend their
charter to assure that family members and protgs were given preference over apprentices in assignments for vacant posts.98
Although these developments did not preclude the possibility that
a Hmi or an Ahmed Resmi might still enter the ocial hierarchies
of service, in the later decades of the eighteenth century most positions did fall to the descendants of rical families or, in the case of
the judiciary, the children of former muftis, the so-called mollahzde.99
Wealth alone could not provide the insiders edge; a general literacy in the branches of state service and residence in the Istanbul
was also essential.100 Proximity to palace and Porte gave them access
to the most important tax-farm auctions, credit, and the ocers who
could make or break a candidates career. Over the century, the
administration would grow top heavy with vizierial-level appointees.
Rather than a pyramid, the state hierarchy, with its narrow middle
of intermediate-rank positions, such as the coveted cadre of the
bureau chiefs, the hcegn, grew hourglass shaped.101
Such assets also separated the Istanbul bureaucratic elites, who
assumed executive, military, and administrative provincial positions
with greater frequency, from the gentry-governors of the eighteenthcentury. One need only compare career paths to see the glaring
dierences in opportunities. In comparison to the wide range of

96
See Abou-El-Haj, The Ottoman Vezir and Pasha Households: Tlay Artan,
From Charismatic Leadership to Collective Rule, Toplum ve Ekonomi 4 (1993):
5394; Madeline Zil, The Politics of Piety: The Ottoman Ulema in the Postclassical Age
(1600 1800) (Minneapolis: Bibliotheca Islamica, 1988); Suraiya Faroqhi, Civilian
Society and Political Power in the Ottoman Empire: A Report on Research in
Collective Bibliography, 14801830, IJMES 17 (1985): 10917.
97
See Joel Shinder, Career Line Formation in the Ottoman Bureaucracy,
16481750: A New Perspective, JESHO 16 (1973): 21637.
98
Shinder, Career Line Formation, 22829, 23335.
99
See Madeline Zil, Elite Circulation in the Ottoman Empire: Great Mollas
of the Eighteenth Century, JESHO 26 (1983): 31820.
100
According to Aksan (An Ottoman Statesman, 1415, n. 47) there was little or no
tracking within the civil bureaucracy allowing clerks to acquire expertise in a variety of elds.
101
In 1793, the Porte issued a new kanunname aimed at reducing the number of
the top tier of rical, the pasha elite. Cezar, Osmanl Maliyesinde Bunalm, 34445.

100

appointments aorded the Istanbul-based aristocracy of service, the


Porte rotated a gentry-governors assignments within a restricted geographical radius, typically to regions adjoining to the appointees
place of origin. With the exception of tours of duty in Syria and
Erzurum, eteci Abdullah Pasha, an heroic defender of the empire,
spent most of his career close to his native town of ermik, in governorships in Rakka and in Diyarbekir (1744, 1750, 1752, and 1759).102
The practice of awarding the entire revenues of a province as a
block contract could only have reinforced this pattern, as well as
the tendency for gentry-governors such as the 'Azms of Syria, the
Jalilis of Mosul, and the Karaosmano[lu in the greater Izmir-Bergama
region, to pass these oces from one generation to another.103 To
the extent that the gentrys own economic and political ambitions
were circumscribed regionally, they may not have even considered
these dierences as inherent limitations. Gentry-governors reinvested
state-gained income in urban real estate, tax farms, plantations, loans,
and trade, a diversied portfolio of assets that remained well within
their political sphere of inuence.104
The Istanbul insider remained closely tethered to the capital. Short
tours of duty throughout the empire discouraged concentrated investments in a single province, unless they oered, as did many Balkan
and Aegean commercial revenues, particularly high rates of return.
Maintaining a full-time household in the capital was essential. Srr
Selim Pasha paid 925 kuru{ a month to support his skeletal administrative household in the capital while on duty in Baghdad between
1777 and 1780.105 This sta managed his portfolio in his absence.

102

Beysano[lu, Diyarbakr Tarihi, 67981.


The sons of Vizier Sleyman Pasha 'Azmzde (d. 1743), pasha of Damascus,
shared title to tax farms valued at 52,330 kuru{.
104
On gentry accumulation during this period, see Margaret Meriwether, Urban
Notables and Rural Resources in Aleppo, 17701830, IJTS 4 (1987): 5573; Yuzo
Nagata, Some Documents on the Big Farms (iftliks) of the Notables in Western
Anatolia (Tokyo: Institute for the Study of Languages and Cultures of Asia and
Africa, 1976); and Suraiya Faroqhi, Wealth and Power in the Land of Olives:
Economic and Political Activities of Mridzde Hac Mehmed Agha, Notable of
Edremit, in Landholding and Commercial Agriculture in the Middle East, ed. a[lar Keyder
and Faruk Tabak (Albany: State University of New York Press, 1991), 7796. For
an approach to accumulation in early modern South Asia, see Sanjay Subrahmanyam
and C. A. Bayly, Portfolio Capitalists and the Political Economy of Early Modern
India, in Merchants, Markets and the State in Early Modern India, ed. Sanjay Subrahmanyam
(Delhi: Oxford University Press, 1990), 24254.
105
KK 786. I am grateful to Mehmet Gen for sharing this record with me.
103

101

They recorded payments from the four corners of the empire: 42,060
kuru{ from Belgrade, sent by an agent, Osman Efendi; a down payment of 10,000 kuru{ on a tax farm from Kara Halil in Ktahya;
revenues from a plantation in Siroz, administered by Muhurdarzde
Hasan Pasha; and income on the shares in the recently reorganized,
state-run tobacco regie in Istanbul, among many other holdings and
ventures.
By reinforcing a divided hierarchy, the market in malikne leases
perpetuated the dominance of the Istanbul elite while, as we shall
see in the next chapter, extending a certain range of the benets of
state oce to the gentry. Such disparities were, however, build in
to the system. The initial commands establishing provincial auctions
explicitly restricted the type of tax contracts that could be sold outside the capital and discouraged provincials from obtaining shares
in another region. The most valuable commercial and aggregate taxgrants remained in the hands of the state elite.106 Istanbuls insatiable
demand for highly liquid revenues, such as customs and excise taxes,
undoubtedly dictated the extension of this form of contracting into
specic regions and economic sectors.107 By 1741, cumulative malikne
investments in the empire (as measured in surety payments) reached
4.3 million kuru{, of which fully one-quarter were located in the
Morea and the Aegean islands. Another third of the investments
were located in the Balkans.108 As the number of Istanbul investors
D.B}M 4666 records deposits from Aleppo made by polie to Istanbul between 1776
and 1781.
106
MMD 10,143:164 (pertaining to Diyarbekir); in Damascus (MMD 3423:570)
the auctioneer was restricted from oering ocaklk mukataa as proprietary contracts.
107
MMD 1637; MMD 730 (copy). Of 1,442 new contracts in 1703, more than
half (871 contracts) were awarded on Balkan resources. There were 571 contracts
in Damascus, Malatya, Diyarbekir, Mosul, Adana, and }ehrizor; the remaining contracts were held in the regions of Western Anatolia, Aleppo, and Tokat-Sivas. In
eect, of the 897,705 kuru{ taken in by the treasury in the form of cash advance
(muaccele) payments, less than half (361,835 kuru{) fell within the geographical zone
originally designated by the edit; one-third pertained to the Balkans (322,278 kuru{).
A little less than a quarter were on contracts in Anatolia (213,592 kuru{).
108
Forty-three percent were located in Anatolia, Syria, Kurdistan, and Iraq.
Tabako[lu, Gerileme Dnemine Girerken, 134, and CM 5001 (1741) provide gures for
the Balkans (172,610,160 ake); Anadolu, Damascus, Aleppo, Baghdad, Mosul, and
Diyarbekir (268,525,200 ake); Morea, Crete, and other islands (79,732,320 ake).
MMD 6981 provides a running tally of new contracts awarded between 1721 and
1723 for Aleppo (which rose by 67,905 kuru{); Tokat sales nearly doubled (15,181
kuru{, on top of an existing 16,391.5 kuru{ in contracts). Sales in Adana, Ayntab,
Malatya, Diyarbekir, Erzurum, Mosul, and Baghdad increased at slower rates. For
sales within Crete see also MMD 9511.

102

and partnerships rose from 771 in 1768 to 963 in 1789,109 their share
of the malikne market as a whole rose from approximately two-thirds
of the total (65 percent) to nine-tenths (87 percent).110

Corporate Patrimonialism and the Reproduction of Power


The portrait painters of the imperial elite rarely allowed rumblings
of discontent to disturb the varnished surfaces of their compositions.111
In Levnis paintings, the calvary parade gallantly; decorous ocers
and well-disciplined foot soldiers march in tight formation. In a rare
instance or two, some indication of countercurrents does break
through. Violent disorder may be is represented by the janissaries
who break formation and race wildly toward their plates of saronscented rice (Plate 4).112 It was the ritual overturning of the kettle
at the At Meydan that sent up the signal for a military insurrection. During the Edirne Incident of 1703 and again in 1730 under
the leadership of Patrona Halil, janissaries and guildsmen took to
the streets to demand the execution of corrupt ocials and an end
to oppressive taxation.113
Spectators at the circumcision ceremony in 1720 may not yet have
forgotten the ignominious fate of Feyzullah Efendi, who, after serving in two administrations, fell victim to the uprising of 1703. Feyzullah
Efendi was the tutor of the young Mustafa II (16951703) and served
as the nakib"l-e{rf under his father. The janissary coup of 1687 banished him to his hometown, Erzurum. Once his former pupil came

109
Murat izaka, A Comparative Evolution of Business Partnerships: The Islamic World
and Europe, with Specic Reference to the Ottoman Archives (Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1996), 173.
110
Ibid., 174. MMD 9524:10. By 1734, central state investors held 633 kese and
9 kuru{ in contracts and the provincials had invested about half as much, or 334
kese and 460 kuru{ (50,000 ake per kese). Gen, Osmanl Maliyesinde Malikne
Sistemi, 282. Note: the percentage (87) is based on records from 1789, not 1787.
111
See Serpil Ba[c, Priscilla Mary I{in, and Selmin Kangal, eds. The Sultans
Portrait: Picturing the House of Osman (Istanbul: Tkiye ({ Bankas, 2000).
112
TKSA MS 3593: 22b23a.
113
On the upheavals of the rst half of the century, see Abou-El-Haj, The 1703
Rebellion; Lavender Cassels, The Struggle for the Ottoman Empire (London: Murray, 1966);
Robert Olson, The Esnaf and the Patrona Halil Rebellion of 1730: A Realignment
in Ottoman Politics? JESHO 17 (1974): 32940; and idem, Jews, Janissaries, Esnaf
and the Revolt of 1740 in Istanbul: Social Upheaval and Political Realignment in
the Ottoman Empire, JESHO 20 (1978): 185207; and M. Mnir Aktepe, Patrona
Isyan (1730) (Istanbul: Edebiyat Fakltesi, 1958).

103

to the throne, however, the former tutor was recalled to Istanbul.114


Assuming the post of head of the religious establishment, the }eyh"l(slam, but a few months after the rescript authorizing the new malikne
contract, Feyzullah Efendi lost no opportunity to enhance his personal fortune. He seized gardens, farms, and villas in Edirne and
Istanbul for personal use. He laid claim to revenues from tax farms
on agricultural resources and villages across the empire, from Thrace
to the Caucasus.115 By the time of his death, his probate revealed a
fortune of 50 million ake in cash alone.116
Such rapacity, as well as his bold trespass over clearly marked
lines of service, earned Feyzullah Efendi the dubious distinction of
being one of only three chief muftis to be executed in oce.117
Though audacious and unbridled, his actions were far from impolitic.
Past experience had taught him the eeting nature of power. Although
he exploited the full potential of his oce, he also liberally handed
out positions and tax efs in Edirne, Rumeli, Sivas, and orum to
his retainers.118 He placed members of his family, even minors, in
important judicial posts; at one point, all of the top positions were
lled by relatives.119 Lacking money in hand, he prevailed upon other
members of the administration whenever a choice contract came to
auction.120
Because he was a member of the ulema, Feyzullah Efendis execution in 1703 and the subsequent conscation of his patrimony
were extraordinary events. Nonetheless, he exemplies the dilemma
of state elite as well as the breakdown of the boundaries between
privilege and property. For members of the military or bureaucracy,

114
Abou-El-Haj (The 1703 Rebellion) emphasizes this point. For other studies, see
Sabra F. Meservey, Feyzullah Efendi: An Ottoman Seyhlislam (Ph.D. diss.,
Princeton University, 1966); Suraiya Faroqhi, An Ulama Grandee and his Household,
JOS 9 (1989): 199208; and Ahmet Trek and F. etin Derin, Feyzullah Efendi"nin
Kend Kaleminden Hal Tercmesi, Tarih Dergisi 23 (1969): 2048; Tarih Dergisi
24 (1970): 6992.
115
zcan, Anonim Osmanl Tarihi, 22127.
116
Tabako[lu, Gerileme Dnemine Girerken, 297.
117
Mumcu, Osmanl Devletinde R{vet, 23233. See also idem, Osmanl Devletinde
Siyaseten Katl (Ankara: Birey ve Toplum Yaynlar, 1985).
118
zcan, Anonim Osmanl Tarihi, 224.
119
Ibid., 225. The author of this anonymous history attributes the origins of the
rebellion against Mustafa II to a squabble over a malikne lease in Adana that
involved one of Feyzullah Eendis followers, Telhisi Mehmet A[a.
120
Ibid., 224. He buys a malikne for 1000 kuru{ at auction, paying only half
the price, explaining that the vizier or defterdar would pay the balance.

104

expropriation was the inescapable conclusion to even the most illustrious career. Once justied because of the servile status of the sixteenth-century elite, the predominance of freeborn Muslims, including
many who were married to princesses, in state service may have
given pause to the administration in later years. Bureaucrats and historians clearly disapproved of the vindictive and opportunistic uses
of forfeiture so common during Feyzullah Efendis tenure and during the rst half of the reign of Ahmet III.121 Nevertheless, as the
reams of records documenting the estates of ocers found in the
probate section of the military court (kismet-i askeriye) of Istanbul and
other cities or the inventories of the possessions of ocials and,
increasingly in the eighteenth century, prominent gentry and townsmen, found in muhalefat registers of the central-state archive testify,
these rules were vigorously enforced throughout the century. Although
judges recognized the right of widows to reclaim their dowry and
even allowed children a xed share of inheritance in accordance
with Islamic law, ocials went to enormous lengths to ferret out
wealth and liquidate an ocers worldly possessionsfrom home furnishings, clothing, books, weapons, and beasts to gardens, outstanding debts, and urban real estate.
In short, what makes Feyzullah Efendis example particularly interesting to historians is not that his strategy for accumulating wealth
was unusual, but because it was considered untting for a member
of the ulema, the muftis practice of what we might call corporate
patrimonialism122 caught the attention of his contemporaries. Typically,
ocials made the utmost of their time in oce to insure the reproduction of family wealth and power. Given the restrictions on individual patrimony, it was necessary for the ruling elite to distribute
these assets, position as well as property, widely among family and
associates in the hope that at least part of these investments would
outlive them. And, in this, few had been more successful than the

121
Deftardar Sar Mehmed Efendi, Ottoman Statescraft, 70; Ra{id Efendi, Tarih-i
Ra{id, vol. 2, 1001, 122, 301, 424; 4:30, 284. Tabako[lu, Gerileme Dnemine Girerken,
29698; Abou-El-Haj, The 1703 Rebellion, 1213.
122
Charles Tilly reminds me that this form of accumulation is in many ways
analogous to guild practices in early modern England and Italy. For some thoughts
on how to rehabilitate the notion of patrimonialism, see Susanne Hoeber Rudolph
and Lloyd I. Rudolph, Authority and Power in Bureaucratic and Patrimonial
Administration: A Revisionist Interpretation of Weber on Bureaucracy, World Politics
31 (1979): 195227.

105

former chief mufti; although most of Feyzullah Efendis urban real


estate appears to have been seized and resold, at least part of his
wide-ranging investments slipped through the probate ocers reach.123
Personal disgrace notwithstanding, he established his family as one of
the great ulema lineages of the eighteenth century.124 His sons Mustafa
and Murtaza served as the empires chief judicial authority under
Mahmud I (r. 173054) and Osman III (r. 175457), respectively.125
Rifa"at Abou-El-Hajs research on political networks has brought
to light the fact that the social reproduction of power also depended
contacts and connections that reached across orders and the status
lines. The creation of lateral lines of accumulation of both capital
and connections was raised to a high art in the organization of an
ocials political household or kap.126 Composed of family, associates and retainers, the kap oered training to its members while
enhancing the political prospects of its head. In time of war, the
ocer with a well-appointed household might lend a battalion of
men to the sultan. In peacetime, his retainers, who numbered from
one hundred to one thousand persons, furnished the basis of a provincial administration as well as a permanent sta for his Istanbul base
of operations.127 In the end, the household was itself an insurance
policy and investment. Whether it took the form of seeding members of his kap through the bureaucracy and military, by distributing his wealth among them, or by oering a trusted associate his
daughter and making his servant a damad, the head of a household
created a party that extended his inuence as well as a medium for
perpetuating wealth beyond his own lifetime.
As Feyzullahs case also makes clear, corporate strategies for managing and reproducing wealth and power required assets that were
fungible. Not only the narrowly dened rical-i devlet, but other groups

123
He did retain a cash foundation. (smail Kurt, Para Vakar Nazariyat ve Tatbikat
(Istanbul: Ensar Ne{riyat, 1996), 163.
124
Tabako[lu, Gerileme Dnemine Girerken, 297.
125
Norman Izkowitz, Men and Ideas in the Eighteenth Century Ottoman
Empire, in Studies in Eighteenth Century Islamic History, ed. T. Na and R. Owen
(Carbondale: University of Southern Illinois Press, 1977), 19.
126
On the kap, see Abou-El-Haj, The Ottoman Vezir and Pasha Households,
16831703.
127
Uzunar{l, Osmanl Devletinin Merkez, 207. Onik Jamgocyan (Les nances
de lEmpire Ottoman et les nancirs de Constantinople, 17321853 [Thse de
doc., Universit de Paris I [Sorbonne] 1988], 23132) concludes that the size of
pasha households actually increased over the century.

106

including the court utilized these resources in building and maintaining their networks. Princesses cultivated their own variation on
the political household, consisting of circles of intimates, including
nieces, husbands, children, and female slaves. Revenue contracts were
ideal forms of capital in that they could easily be subdivided in shares
and distributed among members of the household.128 In the case of
Esma Sultan, the Elder (17261788), one of Ahmad IIIs daughters,
crown estates turned into malikne contracts were divided among her
protgs and managed by agents and subcontractors.129 The name
of one of her male associates appears as contractor in his own right.130
Although extant lists of the Istanbul tax farming elite tend to register shareholders or family partnerships separately, it seems likely
that many individuals were actually members of larger political
houses.131 Indeed, given the pervasiveness of corporate strategies of
accumulation, we might ask how many degrees of separation actually distanced the highest and lowest bidders in the Istanbul market? An incomplete register of malikne contractors who paid the
special war tax of 173738 lists 405 individuals, couples and partnerships, perhaps slightly less than half of the total investors in the
city.132 At rst glance, aside from the decided underrepresentation of

128
See (smail Hakk Uzunar{l, n Mustafann kz }ah Sultana Bor
Senedi, Belleten 25 (1961): 97; and idem, Sultan III. Mustafann Hzn Verici
Bir Bor Senedi, Belleten 22 (1968): 59598.
129
According to CS 4051, a document that Michael Hickok kindly brought to
my attention, princesses also operated their own rms of tax farms, dividing shares
among female and male household members. For other examples, see MMD
9565:1011, which contains the holdings of various royal women (Emine, Fatma,
and Zeyneb Hanm); TKSA D 4477 is the esham register of Hatice Hanm; TKSA
D 6573 is a register of Habibe Hanm, the wife of Moral Ahmed. In Egypt,
Mamluk women played an important role in preserving household wealth (See Susan
Staa, Dimensions of Womens Power in Historic Cairo, Islamic and Middle Eastern
Studies: A Festschrift in Honor of Professor Wadie Jwaideh, ed. Robert Olson et al.
[Brattleboro, Vt.: Amana, 1987], 6299). They invested in tax farms. In the rest
of the empire, however, local women were poorly represented. Only one woman
tax farmer appears in the local accounts for eighteenth-century Diyarbekir (MMD
9518:52) and she resided in Istanbul. The situation changes at the end of the old
regime. Between 1848 and 1860, three Diyarbekir women (MMD 9519:122, 130,
137) held shares in village tax farms.
130
MMD 9565, entry no. 655.
131
On the practice of assigning revenues to members of a ricals household, see
Thomas, A Study of Naima, 105 and Kunt, The Sultans Servants, 88.
132
MMD 367 is undated. Internal evidence (Ne{e Erim identied Sleyman
Efendi as one of contractors on the customhouse of Erzurum) suggests that it belongs
to the 173637 war period. Sleyman Pasha, another individual, was governor of

107

the ulema, the composition of contractors seems to reect a cross


section of ocialdom and palace sta.
Although subsumed under individual entries, it is still possible to
discern the outline, at times faint, of corporate strategies of accumulation. Partnerships based on blood relationships are frequently
clearly spelled out. Such is the case of the household headed by
Hac Mehmet Emin A[a, captain of the mounted palace guard, a[a silhdar, who together with his sons and brother held 75,340 kuru{
in malikne contracts.133 Others sought out investments for the purposes of retirement.134 Perhaps this may help explain the reverse
migration in the eighteenth century, as central-state bureaucrats
relocated to provincial cities or towns where they had invested in
tax farms or real estate.135 Few members of the gentry nd their way
onto the central-state rolls. However, the clan holdings of the brother
and sons of Vizier Sleyman Pasha 'Azmzde (d. 1743), governor
of Damascus were substantial enough to merit an entry. Collectively,
these shares valued at 52,330 kuru{ suggest that tax-farming partnerships might have served as a deterrent to probate ocers.
The vast majority of entriesinvolving the nine out of ten individuals who invested at levels of 10,000 kuru{ (equivalent to approximately 2,500 Venetian ducats) or less136are less forthcoming about

Damascus between 1734 and 1738 (Rafeq, The Province of Damascus, 119). 322 persons held investments (based on their muaccele) of less than 10,000 kuru{; 51 persons, between 1025,000 kuru{; 26 persons, between 2550,000 kuru{; three persons,
between 50100,000 kuru{; and three persons, above 100,000 kuru{.
133
MMD 367. One son, Mehmed, held a quarter share in Anatolia (in the
Voyvodalk of Tokat) valued at 10,850 kuru{.
134
MMD 367. For example, the sons of former Vizier Ali Pasha, (smail Bey,
Selim, Ahmed, and Mehmed, held 34,475 kuru{ in shares on various malikne farms,
principally located in the mainland Greece (the Morea). In the case of a civil bureaucrat, Kasariyeli Hac Ahmed Efendi, once head of a treasury bureau dealing with
accounts receivable (ruzname evvel ), held malikne contracts valued at 57,650 kuru{
together with his son Eb Bekir A[a, a nephew (or grandson) Mehmed A[a; a sonin-law, Mehmed; and an unidentied individual, Ahmed A[a (perhaps his steward
or head of household).
135
For the social uidity of the pool of provincial elites and return migration,
see Karl K. Barbir, From Pasha to Efendi: The Assimilation of Ottomans into
Damascene Society, 15161783, IJTS 1 (197980): 6883.
136
Investment distribution continues to be extremely skewed. Only one in ten
individuals held shares valued at 25,000 kuru{ or higher; four out of ve invested
far below 10,000 kuru{. A considerable sum of money, 10,000 kuru{ was the equivalent of 2,500 Venetian ducats and represented many times the lifetime wealth of
an ordinary ocer. Consider that the entire worldly goods of a low-ranking ocer
of the Arsenal in 176667 amounted to 3,040 kuru{ (I}MS K-A, 293:23); Esseyyid

108

their relationships to other investors. In some cases, however, the


clerk has noted the network. Belonging to a kap is explicitly indicated by such expressions as the dependent of (tbi-i ) or from
among the followers of (n etb-, n hulef, or n bb).137
Splitting contracts among a household combined payment and collective management. The size and distribution of shares may also
indicate the division of labor within a household. For example, the
household of the deceased director of the sc, Halil Efendi, suggests
a close intermingling, even parity, between kin and clients. His son,
Hseyin A[a (752.5 kuru{) and his personal attendant (mehter) Hasan
A[a (750 kuru{) possessed nearly equal allotments. Halil Efendi left
other retainers smaller portions in the same contracts: for his purse
bearer (kisedr), there was a share valued at 683 kuru{; for his deputy
(kethda), a 300 kuru{ share; for his ser mehtern, a 420 kuru{ share;
and his ser uhadar (head chamberlain), a 160 kuru{ share. His relationship with a scholar, Kadzde Elhac Sleyman, who possessed
the largest share (1070 kuru{) in these holdings, however, remains
undened.
Over the century, the disparities among the roughly 1,000 malikne
investors seem to mirror the stratication of wealth and power among
Istanbul political elite as a whole. A narrow group at the uppermost
tier of the shareholder pyramid appears to constitute the truly aristocratic level of the Ottoman bureaucratic and military elite.138 In
178788, this group comprised the fourteen individuals and family
partnerships whose assets exceeded 100,000 kuru{. Although representing only 2 percent of the total number of individuals registered
in Istanbul (833 individual entries, of which 133 were explicitly partnerships), their combined wealth, which totaled 3,264,282 kuru{, made
up roughly 30 percent of the value of malikne shares held by centralstate investors and 24 percent of the total investments in malikne
contracts in the empire. The largest malikne rm, that of Admiral
det Hseyin Pasha and his wife Emine, held shares that totaled

Ebbekir, the cavu{ a[as, head courier of the grand vizier, left an estate of 26,604
kuru{ (I}MS 181:13); a deputy judge, a naib (Ibid., 1112) in Rumeli owned goods
and a house together estimated at 9,498 kuru{.
137
MMD 367. For some examples: Ahmet A[a ve Kk Mehmed A[a, n
etb-i Sa"adullah Efendi, 4500 kuru{; Mustafa A[a, n mteferrikn- gedikluyn n
etb-i mtevea Karakulak Ali A[a, 312 kuru{.
138
izakca, Business Partnerships, 173.

109

829,201.5 kuru{ and was roughly equivalent to 8 percent of the total


malikne investments in the empire.139 They held almost exclusively
commercial revenues, such as those pertaining to the tari stations
at the ports of Chios, Iskenderiye, and Crete.140
Middle-range investors accounted for no more than 10 percent of
the total population of Istanbul contractors. It is conceivable that
the 26 (3 percent of the total) individuals who held shares valued at
between 50,000 and 100,000 kuru{ and the 62 individuals (7.4 percent of the total) who possessed shares valued at between 25,000
and 50,000 kuru{ may have had a degree of autonomy with respect
to the true aristocracy of service. However, it seems unlikely that
the remainder, still nearly nine out of every ten individuals listed (88
percent), whose holdings fell far below a 25,000 kuru{ threshold, could
have functioned without aliation to a larger corporate structure.
Without detailed studies, it is not possible to reconstruct their ties
to other shareholders.
As tax farming expanded over the century, so did the responsibilities of the members of the larger households. Transactions between
shareholders and transfers of money were best handled through the
Istanbul courts, as were procedures of ceding shares from one party
to another (kasr- yed or fera[ ), demands for repayment, and loans in
arrears, as well as the petitions to devolve shares to sons.141 They
processed petitions, made appearances at court, and bid at auction,
in addition to protecting their patrons political interests broadly;142
they secured credit and subnanced operations.143 The legal courts

139

MMD 9565:15.
Some of their shares might include crown estates. Many investments were
concentrated within discrete regions. For example, the shares of Vizier Gl Ahmed
Pasha and household members, including his kethda-i har, Mustafa A[a; his mehterdar, Sleyman A[a; and his children, Feyzullah Bey, Ali Bey, and (smail Bey,
were all held in the Aegeanthe Morea, Crete, and Izmir.
141
For examples of ceding (kasr- yed ) shares, see MMD 9896:138; MMD 9494:23.
On the legal methods of transferring/relinquishing title ( fera[ ), see the judges handbook (circa 1784) Sleymniye Library MS Izmir 782 no. 1, folios 66a67b.
142
In 17056, a Diyarbekir seyyid re-registered his contract through an Istanbul
intermediary (MMD 9896:138).
143
On the diculties of nance and credit in the provinces, see Araks }ahiner,
The Sarrafs of Istanbul: Financiers of the Empire, (M.A. thesis, Institute of Social
Sciences, Master of Arts in History, Bo[azii University, 1995), 30. Bartholomew
Plaisted, Narrative of a Journey from Basra to Aleppo in 1750 in The Desert Route to India
Being the Journals of Four Travelers by the Great Desert Caravan Route between Aleppo and
Basra, 174551, ed. Douglas Carruthers (London: Hakluyt Society, 1929), 104. Bruce
140

110

furnished notarial documents (hccet) attesting to payment and describing the ultimate recipient or recipients of the funds.144 As we have
seen, members of the Istanbul household coordinated the duties of
provincial employees, whether this involved a deputy on site,145 a
member of his household, a steward drafted from a prominent gentry family, or a subfarmer.146

Deyn- Devlet (Debt and State): Islamicate High Finance


For European visitors to the Ottoman Empire, even the seasoned
French and Russian diplomats whom Levni depicts enjoying their
special perch on the parade grounds, (Plate 5) Islamic society presented many oddities. There was the strange, that is, from the perspective of Western Europeans, relationship between din- devlet
(religion and state). On the one hand, there was no mistaking
Islams pride of place in the empire. At the ceremonies, palace
municence allowed thousands of Muslim boys to be circumcised
along with the princes. Before greeting all others, the sultan prepared a special reception for the dignitary representing the descendants of the Prophet Muhammed. In architecture, calligraphic arts,
and ritual, religion permeated the life of the city. The call to prayer
that resonated in every quarter gave the days their rhythms.
On the other, for visitors from Christendom who were accustomed to the sectarian rivalries between Catholic and Protestant that
not only segregated cities but had split entire countries, the relatively
unhindered interaction between religious majority and minority in
Masters,The Origins of Western Dominance in the Middle East: Mercantilism and the Islamic
Economy in Aleppo, 16001750 (New York: New York University Press, 1988), 15152.
144
Halil (nalck, Hawala, EI 2 3: 284; DOhsson, Tableau gnrale, vol. 1, 24849;
for examples of transfers of funds, see D.B}M 4666 (177680), a register belonging to Lala Mustafa A[a whose income was sent from Syria. For an example of a
payment by local administrators through the judge in Diyarbekir, D}S 360:35
(17391740).
145
Telhisi Mehmet A[a, for example, entrusted his malikne holdings to a subfarmer or his own deputy (suba{). zcan, Anonim Osmanl Tarihi, 225. On subcontracting, see Defterdar Sar Mehmet Efendi, Zubde-i Vekayiat (Sleymniye Library,
Ms. Esad Efendi, No. 2387) folios 288b289a, cited in Tabako[lu, Gerileme Dnemine
Girerken, 132 n. 30.
146
HA IV:1 (178182); although a 1715 order attempted to restrict subleasing,
absentee contracting was commonplace. In 1767 orders were issued to standardize
the practice. Avdo Sueska, Malikana. Prilozi za orientalnu lologiju 36 (1986):
209; Gen, Malikne Sistemi, 240, n. 17.

111

Istanbuls streets and marketplace could not have rendered Muslim


society more alien and repugnant. The preeminence of the religious
majority did not entail the banishment of the minority from much
of economic life or their connement within walled ghettos. The lack
of ability in languages and protocol compelled Catholic and Protestant
missions to engage Armenian and Sephardic dragomen to conduct
their business with the Sublime Porte. The Greek translators of the
imperial divan were entrusted with the empires most delicate political negotiations. In aairs of commerce it was the same: French,
Dutch, Swedish and English chartered companies in Izmir, Salonica,
Aleppo, Baghdad, or Cairo dealt with the Jew or Christian assigned
to the tari station who held the venal of oce of moneychanger
or broker.147 Along the Levantine coastline non-Muslim merchants
or bazirgn, including those special purveyors who worked for the
palace, the so-called beratl tccar, proved formidable rivals.148
Most shocking of all for the European was the conspicuous involvement of Jewish and Christian bankers in public nances, the sinews
of state power.149 Every ocial or ocer of any standing counted
on the backing of an Armenian, Greek, or Jewish nancier, accountant, or banker (sarraf ).150 At every step up the ladder of higher oce,
from the initial down payment on an oce to the funds needed buy
the gifts betting a princess, a rising candidate needed to borrow
ever greater amounts of money. Without a letter of guarantee from
a reputable nancier, provided only after a thorough credit check,
it was impossible for him even to bid on a tax farm.151
Credit was the life blood of ocialdom. A governor from Aleppo
spent 126,830 kuru{ for ten months in oce over the years 1781
and 1782. Of this 2,102 kuru{ a month or 20 percent of his income,
was paid in interest.152 His expenses might escalate sharply if, as we

147
For their social backgrounds, see Onik Jamgocyan, Les nances de lEmpire
Ottoman, and }ahiner, The Sarrafs of Istanbul.
148
See Ali (hsan Ba[s, Osmanl Ticaretinde Gayr Mslimler: Kapitlasyonlar-Beratl
Tccarlar, Avrupa ve Hayriye Tccarlar (17501839) (Ankara: Turhan Kitabevi, 1983),
2138.
149
Consider France, Janine Garrison, LEdit de Nantes et sa rvocation: Histoire dune
intolerance (Paris: ditions du Seuil, 1985).
150
Robert Olson, Jews, Janissaries, Esnaf and the Revolt of 1740 in Istanbul:
Social Upheaval and Political Realignment in the Ottoman Empire, JESHO 20
(1978): 199.
151
}ahiner, The Sarrafs of Istanbul, 24.
152
D.B}M 5019. Mouradgea dOhsson, (Tableau gnrale, vol. 3, 1756) historian

112

have seen, assuming oce also meant taking the responsibility for
the large malikne contracts.153
While the court was the focal point of status, and the Porte, the
source of patronage, the city itself furnished the personnel and services
for nancial capitalism within the empire. Over the century there developed a degree of regional specialization among the nanciers themselves. Greek inuence held sway in the Aegean and the Black Sea;
Jewish rms rose to prominence in Syria, Iraq, and for at time, Egypt.154
Armenian companies dominated the nancial hub of the empire. Members of the upper strata or amira class of their community, the Armenian nanciers served as personal agents for the upper echelon of the
aristocracy of service.155 They lled almost every one of the seventytwo fully accredited (gedik) posts allowed to deal directly with the sc.156
Yet, this number does not begin to capture the scope of imperial
high nance. In addition to the gedik-holding nanciers, a 1761 document records another 137 individuals who practiced some form of
nancial services (sarrak) under the title of purchasing agents (mubayaac),
silver dealers/silversmiths (gm{ciyn), or as their apprentices (mlzimler) in Istanbul alone.157 These bankers preformed duties that
of the Ottoman Empire and son-in-law of the nancier Abraham Kuleliyan, recorded
interest rates ranging between 12 percent and 24 percent. See }ahiner, The Sarrafs
of Istanbul, 33 and Jamgocyan, Les nances de lEmpire Ottoman, 28586.
Ronald Jennings notes (Loan and Credit in Early 17th Century Judicial Records,
The Shari"a Court of Anatolia and Kayseri, JESHO 16 [1973]: 184, 190, 214)
that interest rates ran as high as 2024 percent per year.
153
Tabako[lu, Gerileme Dnemine Girerken, 13435. Entire provincesAdana, Tripoli,
Rakka (Urfa), and the entire tax farm apparatus of a region, such as the muhasslk,
of the Morea, Cyprus, and Aydin, were awarded to local gentry or incoming governors. According to DOhsson (Tableau gnrale, vol. 6, 279), twenty-two sancaks (out
of sixty-three) were held directly as malikne-i miri (imperial malikne). For one example, see D.B}M 3546 (175960).
154
The Carmona, Aciman, and Gabay family rms were associated with the
janissaries. For more on this connection, see Robert W. Olson, Jews in the Ottoman
Empire in Light of New Documents, Jewish Social Studies, 41 (1979): 7588.
Syrian Christians served as bankers of the Egyptian elite, after Ali Bey who had
broken his Jewish bankers. See John William Livingston, Ali Bey al-Kabir and the
Jews, Middle Eastern Studies 7 (1971): 22128.
155
Many sarraf families traced their origins to northeastern Anatolia, near the
cities of Van, Sivas and Harput, at the crossroads of the long-distance transit trade
in silk and proximate to the silver mines of Gm{hane, Keban, and Ergani. Hagop
Levon Barsoumian, The Armenian Amira Class of Istanbul. (Ph.D. diss., Columbia
University, 1980), 90. DOhsson, Tableau gnrale, vol. 3, 17576; Jamgocyan, Les
nances de lEmpire Ottoman, 28586.
156
}ahiner, The Sarrafs of Istanbul, 71. CDp 193.
157
Ahmet Rek, Hicr On (kinci Asrda Istanbul Hayat (11001200) (Istanbul: Devlet

113

ranged from money lending to keeping accounts. As bankers or merchants who redeemed the transfer of funds in the form of bills of
exchange, or police, they were essential links in the chain of credit
throughout the empire.158
Sealed by shared risks, the relationship between banker and pasha
remained close. It is no wonder that ocers and ocials petitioned
for special privileges for their non-Muslim protegees.159 Yet, as elsewhere, wealth and prominence made minorities the objects of scorn
and resentment. Muslim writers accused nanciers of enriching themselves by fraudulent means, such as passing adulterated coin, and
disguising illegal investments in revenue contracts.160 There is no reason to minimize their role in this system. With tax farming an integral part of the credit nexus within the empire and interest rates
running as high as 24 percent, they could be considered, after a
fashion, silent partners in most transactions.161 Nonetheless, given the
constraints under which they operated, non-Muslim nanciers in the
Ottoman capital cannot be considered truly autonomous entrepreneurs or comprising a fully private sector.

Matbaas, 1930), 19394. Credit for monetary reform in the eighteenth century
must also be given to the nanciers. The Armenian Duzian family assumed the
position of intendant (emin) of the imperial mint in 1757.
158
(nalck, Hawala, 28385; M. Zeki Pakaln, Osmanl Tarih Deyimleri ve Terimleri
Szl[ (Istanbul: Milli E[itim Bakanl[ Yaynlar, 1971) vol. 2, 58. izakca, Business
Partnerships, 141. See also Halil Sahillio[lu, Bir Mltezimin Zimmet Defterine gre
XV. Yzyl Sonunda Osmanl Darphane Mukataalar, IFM 23 (1963): 145218.
Jamgocyan, Les nances de lEmpire Ottoman, 308. After 1788 the state tried
to borrow directly from the nanciers. Rates of interest varied (}ahiner, The Sarrafs
of Istanbul, 33, 55) according to the relationships between the parties. Financiers
also borrowed (or invested) monies from high ocers and courtiers. On Selim IIIs
policies concerning credit for contracts, see Ycel zkaya, III Selimin Imparatorluk
Hakkndaki Bazi Hatt- Humayunlar, Ankara niversitesi Osmanl Tarihi Ara{trma ve
Uygulama Merkezi Dergisi 1 (1990): 34142.
159
CS 884 (1743) is a petition from Seyyid (brahim, cuhadarba{ of the palace
requesting special exemptions for Mikail, son of Bo[az, in recognition of twenty
years of loyal service.
160
zcan, Anonim Osmanl Tarihi, 22. A century later we hear the same complaints and accusations. Abdullah Efendi Tatarck (Selim-i sni devrinde Nizm-
Devlet hakkinda mutl"at, Trk Tarihi Encmeni Mecmuas 8 (1333/19141915): 17),
an advisor to sultan Selim III (r. 17891807), made a blanket accusation: Every
Armenian from Kemah or E[in who possesses a few thousand kuru{, uses a Muslim
front for their own operations; for this thousand they are able to milk the peasantry of 300500 kese of ake [125,000 to 208,000 kuru{] in an iltizam. See also
Cezar, Osmanl Maliyesinde Bunalm, 14448.
161
DOhsson, Tableau gnral, vol. 3, 17577. From 12 to 24 percent interest,
depending on the circumstances.

114

In fact, Christian and Jewish nanciers had lost ground in most


areas of domestic nance and tax collection over the course of the
previous century. Better armed and connected, the janissaries, who
had been redeployed to provincial cities during the seventeenth century, outbid them on agrarian and commercial tax farms.162 A de
facto withdrawal from the tax-farming market was made ocial in
1714, when imperial decree barred non-Muslims from bidding on
malikne contracts.163 Nonetheless, non-Muslim nanciers continued
to perform indispensable services for the treasury. Minority nanciers
helped liquidate probated estates.164 They furnished stop-gap loans
to the state, interest that appears in columns under the Persian
euphemism gze{te or the Turkish compound senelik nem.165
In the eighteenth century, they were often assigned to tari stations
as ocial money changers, or as paymasters and forwarding agents
at the site of mining operations. Typically, the wartime cebel bedeliyesi,
a heavy cash outlay for the statesmen and an urgently needed infusion of cash for the state, was submitted by the hand of the sarraf.166
}emdan-zde Fndkl Sleyman Efendi, a court historian writing
in the latter half of the eighteenth century,167 betrayed his own
ambivalence toward the credit system as a whole, as he weighed the
justness of the decision of }eyh"l-(slm Drr-zde Mustafa Efendi
to execute four E[inli (Akn, present-day Kemaliye in Turkey) bankers
who had been convicted of bribing an ocial in 1765. He acknowledged that their infraction would have been considered only a slight
breach of etiquette for a member of the Muslim elite and that their
crime did not deserve the death sentence.168 Because it did con-

162

izakca, Business Partnerships, 15558.


Tabako[lu, Gerileme Dnemine Girerken, 131, n. 28. A 1714 rescript prohibited
the sale of malikne mukataa to non-Muslims.
164
Ahmet Kala, Ahmet Tabako[lu, Salih Aynural, et al. eds., (stanbul Ahkm
Defterleri (stanbul Finans Tarihi (17421787) (Istanbul: Istanbul Ara{trmalar Merkezi,
1998) vol. 1, 61.
165
Hamilton A. R. Gibb and Harold Bowen, Islamic Society and the West: A Study
of the Impact of Western Civilization on Moslem Culture in the Near East (London: Oxford
University Press, 1950 and 1957) vol. 1, pt. 2,24, n. 4; Wright, Ottoman Statecraft,
77; zde[er, III. Ahmed"in Varidt ve Defteri, 321, 331, 343.
166
MMD 9613 (18091810), n yed-i sarraf.
167
Sleyman Efendi, }em"dni-zde Fndkl Sleyman Efendi Tarihi Mur"i"t-Tevarih,
ed. M. Mnir Aktepe (Istanbul: Istanbul niversitesi Edebiyat Fakltesi Yaynlar,
1978) vol. 2A, 6869.
168
Mumcu, Osmanl Devletinde R{vet, 226, 237.
163

115

stitute a serious breach of the boundaries of status, he agreed that


severe punishment was warranted lest other wealthy Christians and
Jews take to comporting themselves as if they were Muslims (Lkin
sarraar murad etti[i i{i "ile ve vcda getrd[nden ok kimesne
kavlen ve kiyfeten geri mslmandr).
This was not, however, the real ethical dilemma. Finally, the historians invective nds its true target. He cannot fault the Christians
alone. Didnt the upper-ranking ocials who encouraged such impropriety by their delicate and deferential (mahrem ve dost ittihaz)
treatment of social inferiors share the blame? Even the greatest of
statesmen (ricl-i devletin kbers), brushed aside their indulgence with the excuse [I do this] because he serves my interests
(zir i{ime yarar dey).169
Although Fndkl Sleyman Efendi stopped short of condemning
the tax farming system itself, others did question its morality. Ottoman
jurist had in past centuries considered tax farming (iltizam) a necessary evil. It was tolerated because Christians and Jews were the main
practitioners.170 Writing in the mid-seventeenth century as Muslim
involvement in tax farming increased appreciably, the Syrian Hanete
scholar al-Ramli took a rm position again the practice, arguing that
because tax farming involved a speculative investment to gain an
undetermined amount of prot it was analogous to money lending.171
But, his objections were not shared by the juridical establishment
in Istanbul which was well disposed toward the reconciliation of
sharia with kanun. Without so much as a comment on the concept
of faiz (prot) with respect to long-term tax farming, the chief mufti
of Istanbul }eyh"l-(slam Mehmed Sadk in 16941695, joined by the
jurisconsults of Anatolia and Rumelia, issued an opinion in Arabic
alongside the 1695 imperial edict. They placed their seal of approval
on the new malikne contract for the good order of the Islamic
state.172 Malikne contractors, it was said, could appeal their cases
169
. . . Geri bu hususda bunlar {er"an katle mstahak de[iler-idi, Sleyman
Efendi, Mur"i"t-Tevarih, 2A: 6869.
170
See Joseph E. Matuz,Contributions to the Ottoman Institution of the (ltizam, JOS 11 (1991): 23749; Bistra Cvetkova, Recherches sur le systeme daermage
(Iltizam) dans LEmpire Ottoman au cours du XVIe XVIIIe s. par rapport aux contres Bulgares, Rocznik orentalistyczny 27 (1964): 11132 and Bruce McGowan,
Economic Life in the Ottoman Europe, 61.
171
Khaled Abou El Fadl, Tax Farming in Islamic Law (Qibalah and Daman
of Kharaj): A Search for a Concept, Islamic Studies 31 (1992): 532.
172
KK 5040:2.

116

to the chief mufti himself, who would represent their interests before
the sultan.173 Given ulema involvement at all levels in the tax farming system, by the time of the Hanete scholar Ibn Abidin
(d. 183637) the very question had become moot.174
Formative, too, was the role of the religious establishment in creating the legal foundations for private nance in Istanbul and Bursa,
as well as other Anatolian and Balkan cities. The debate surrounding the innovation of vakf al-nukud, that is, a foundation or trust
(waqf ) based on liquid capital remains one of the stranger chapters
in Hanete jurisprudence. The debate raged between jurists and professors during the rst half of the seventeenth century. Here, the
contravention of Islamic law was scarcely a matter of interpretation.
The laws on endowments dedicated to pious or family ends specically
dictate the use of rents from xed capital, such as urban real estate
or agricultural lands.175 These discrepancies had not troubled Ottoman
elites and by the time the practice came to the notice of leading
jurists, the practice was widespread, particularly in Istanbul and
Edirne. In addition to pleasing their patrons, Istanbul ulemas willingness to bend the rules may also speak of a certain degree of altruism. Coinciding with a period of rising taxation, the cash endowment
might have functioned as a type of credit union that oered craftsmen, traders, and town residents needed loans as well as providing
support for orphans and widows.
Istanbul Muslims established an average of ve new cash endowments a year in the period between 1685 and 1781. Many, perhaps
most, of these endowments functioned as investment banks. They
realized rents by furnishing Jewish and Christian nanciers with
capital at prime rates of interest, ranging between 6 and 15 percent.176

173
DOhsson, Tableau gnral, vol. 3, 17576. On transfer of title or ceding shares,
the fees were set at 2 percent for the chief herald or avu{ba{, 2.5 percent for the
kadasker (chief judge) of the Balkans, and .75 percent for the kadasker of Anatolia.
174
See Abou El Fadl, Tax Farming in Islamic Law. For an example of how
malikne-iltizam contracts were used privately, Kal"a et al. eds., (stanbul Ahkm Defterleri,
vol. 1, 147.
175
Jon E. Mandaville, Usurious Piety: The Cash Waqf Controversy in the
Ottoman Empire, IJMES 10 (1979): 29198.
176
}ahiner, The Sarrafs of Istanbul, 3233, 3839, 45. After 1763, the rate of
interest oered by endowments appears to have been xed at 7 percent. See also
Haim Gerber, The Monetary System of the Ottoman Empire, JESHO 25 (1982):
308324.

117

Many of the 1,624 cash endowments at the end of the century were
located in neighborhoods closest to the Porte and state oces.177
State debt involved the religious authorities in other ways. As
judges, the ulema were actively involved in many transactions between
lender and debtor.178 They ruled on disputes between nanciers.179
Together with local military authorities, judges helped collect principal and interest on Islamically sanctioned loans (cihet-i karz-i {er"yle)
owed to non-Muslim bankers.180 In general, they carried out their
duties with fairness and stood by the credit system regardless of the
rank of the borrower.181 Whether it be the governor who owed 16,565
kuru{, the business transaction of the wealthy merchant (bazirgn)
named Sarkis,182 or far more modest debtors,183 the entire centralstate and provincial apparatus was set into motion to make sure that
some payment was made. Months of correspondence and investigation were often needed to disentangle layers of credit and debt complicated by subfarming.184
Given state supervision of nancial institutions and collection, it
should come as no surprise that Ottoman ocials initially balked
when it came to accepting foreign instruments of credit and payment, despite having signed an article governing letters of exchange

177
Kurt, Para Vakar Nazariyat, 91, 162. In a half century Istanbul added 886
new cash waqfs.
178
Jamgocyan, Les nances de lEmpire Ottoman, 22633.
179
DA III:55. In 176364, orders were sent from Istanbul to collect funds in the
amount of 10,000 kuru{ from a Mardin resident, Sama"ano[lu Karbas Yorgi.
180
A hkm (DA III:231) sent on behalf of two Armenian nanciers in Istanbul
to ocers overseeing the city of Mardin ordered the payment of balance 5,750
kuru{ on a debt that was being repaid in installments between 1757 and 1762. In
another case we nd a certain Agop in pursuit of a Mardin resident by the name
of }eyhzde Hac Ahmed (DA IV:77 [178384]); the text speaks of an Islamically
contracted loan (cihet-i karz-i {er"iyle) of which 5,100 kuru{ remained outstanding.
For other examples of collection through the state, see DA III:267, DA II:6, and
DA II:282.
181
A hkm (DA III:267) was issued in 1775 to the governor and the kad of
Mosul on behalf of Anton, resident in Istanbul, who was seeking repayment of 1500
kuru{ from the probate estate of the former governor of Tripoli, Abdlfattah Pa{azde
Mir Abdrrahman, who had been the borrower.
182
DA III:231.
183
DA II:6; DA II:282.
184
Ohannes and Mardus (DA II:191) from Istanbul demanded 9,485 kuru{ from
the voyvoda of ar{nacak, Osman A[a. The voyvoda in turn claimed his own remittance was delayed because the subfarmers had failed to pay him; for examples from
Sivas and Aleppo, see respectively SA XIII:28 and HA IV:11, 72; for loans between
non-Muslims, see Kal"a et al., eds., (stanbul Ahkm Defterleri, vol. 1, 25.

118

in the Franco-Ottoman Treaty of 1740.185 Ocial reluctance notwithstanding, the old-regime elite could not remain indierent to foreign
creditors and instruments of exchange indenitely. European letters
of credit circulated with greater facility and frequency in the empire,
particularly along the Levantine coastline, during the second half of
the century. Merchants balanced their accounts between the main
Ottoman ports of call in the Aegean, Syria, and Istanbul with a
combination of bullion and letters of exchange. Commercial capital
and state borrowing merged with the Mediterranean markets. Subject
to laws of demand, such instruments of credit also drew the Ottoman
treasury, minority bankers and pious Muslim investors, into the orbit
of global nancial capitalism.186
Completing the Circle
Winding their way through the crowded streets of Istanbul, architects cleared a path for the procession of janissaries, judges, chamberlains, gatekeepers, surgeons, and the military band that heralded
the young princes, including the future Mustafa III (17171774) to
the Topkap palace. In his nal pair of paintings Levni captures the
Ottoman dynasts in the palace after the festivities have ended. The
grand viziers ministrations to the convalescing princes ll one scene.
Facing it is a last, lingering image: a full-length portrait of the sultan (Plate 6). Standing before a pool of water, Ahmed III stares out
from the page. His left hand rests by his side. His right hand is
raised and clutches a stful of gold. At his feet attendants and pages,
enderun a[alar, scramble to collect the tossed coins that roll across
the oor.187
185
Edhem Eldem, The Trade in Precious Metals and Bills, in V. Milletleraras
Trkiye Sosyal ve (ktisat Tarihi Kongresi, ed. Hakk Dursun Yldz, Inci Enginn, and
Emine Grsoy Naskal (Ankara: TTK Basmevi, 1990), 57989 and idem, Le
Commerce Franais dIstanbul au XVIIIe Sicle (Thse de doc., University of
Provence, Aix-Marseille I, 1988), 13137, 199. On letters of exchange, see also
Pierre Vilar, A History of Gold and Money (London: Verso, 1984), 21621, 24243,
27376.
186
See Edhem Eldem, The Trade in Precious Metals and Bills, 57989.
187
Michael Gilsenan noted the parallels with the Roman sparsio. See Alain
Caille and Jean Starobinski, Critique de la Raison Utilitaire: Manifeste du Mauss (Paris:
La Dcouverte, 1989). For gold policy under Ahmed III, see Edhem Eldem, French
Trade in Istanbul in the Eighteenth Century (Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1999), 11319; and Ekrem

119

More than symbolic, Ahmed IIIs reign did bequeath his nephew,
Mahmud I (r. 17301754), a state on solid nancial foundations,
thanks in part to his viziers staggering fortune that passed into the
states coers. Yet the solidity of the empires political economy was
not only the product of currency reform and good accounting. It
owed to the gradual merging of two treasuries under the aegis of
the Portes administrative apparatus. A complex system of contracts
and patronage helped orchestrated this gradual integration while delegating many duties to the upper-ranking members of the ruling
estate and, as we shall see in the next chapter, to the provincial
gentry.188
Fiscal patronage anticipated formal bureaucratization of the state.
The contracting system expanded rapidly over the rst half of the
century, although oversight lagged.189 Under Ahmed IIIs son Mustafa
III (17571774) and his vizier Koca Ragp Mehmed Pasha (17571763),
the pace of nancial consolidation picked up speed. One of the last
redoubts of palace autonomy, the crown endowments for the Holy
Cities, nally surrendered to the grand viziers oversight and the
once powerful kahya of the palace was banished. Yet the challenge
to the consolidation of the state remained: on the one hand, to
circumscribe the autonomy of those who controlled the privy purse
of the sultan and, on the other, to cultivate the nancial ties among
and beyond the aristocracy of service all the while maintaining the
political subordination of the cadres, individuals, and clans who carried out the tasks of provincial administration.190 With the pretext of
pressing military and nancial needs, in the wake of the disastrous
defeat by the Russians in 1774, the bureaucracy would withdraw
some of the most valuable revenues from the malikne market entirely.

Kolerkili, Osmanl (mparatorlu[unda Para Tarihi (Ankara: Do[u{, 1958), 99100; Anonim
Osmanl Tarihi, 250.
188
The treasury was swollen with sureties from the malikne. Tabako[lu, Gerileme
Dnemine Girerken, 298.
189
Already in 169899 (KK 4050:3738) there were complaints about subadministrators (muba{ir) who were remiss in their payment of the nominal mal, that
was due in three installments annually. A mnavebe or rotation system was
adopted later in the century, making one of the largest shareholders responsible for
collecting the rents and dividing the prots among the partners. Mehmet Gen,
Iltizam, Islam Ansiklopedisi (Istanbul: Trkiye Diyanet Vakf, forthcoming), cited in
izakca, Business Partnerships, 174.
190
Cezar, Osmanl Maliyesinde Bunalm, 100101.

120

In place of a few high bidders, hundreds of small shares were auctioned to women, members of the ulema and ordinary Istanbul residents while remaining under state management. A scal measure to
be sure, this new esham modality of borrowing again enlarged the
pool of investors in the state.191 By 1800, there were more than four
thousand investors of all backgrounds in the esham.192
Behind the luxurious textiles, costly entertainments, and exquisite
manners of the courtly life captured in Levnis paintings, lay the less
familiar haunts of old regime rule. Only obliquely does the artist
betray the tensions between palace and the Porte; no mention is
made of the strategic blockage in the channels of promotion or the
collective means by which pashas secured their wealth and political
futures. Far beyond the Ok Meydan and the parade grounds, were
the shops and oces of the Armenian, Jewish, and Greek agents
who tended the accounts of viziers, commanders, captains, and
increasingly many of the provincial gentry as well.193 Completely hidden from view, were the Islamic endowments that undergirded
Ottoman public nance and the foreign letters of credit that furnished Ottoman ocials with an additional means of remitting funds
to Istanbul for the sc and their kap.
Perhaps it was not the ocial face of the state but the dizzying
intricacies of the circulatory system convergent in the Ottoman capital that explain the continued popularity of the Surnme-i Vehbi.
Although only the sultan and vizier possessed souvenirs of those marvelous days of festival in paint, the elaborate prose allegory of statesociety relationships continued to be recopied and enjoyed until the
twilight of the old order. Its reassuring allusions to redistribution of
wealth and social equity harmonized the disparate and often dissonant elements of court and society and cloaked an imperfect reality. This enduring event provided a singular optic through which

191
Aydin, Osmanl Maliyesinde Esham Uygulamas, 15458. See appendices,
table XII.
192
Sleyman Efendi, Mur"i"t-Tevarih, vol. 2A, 31. Mehmet Gen, Esham, Islam
Ansiklopedisi (Istanbul: Trkiye Diyanet Vakf, 1995), 11:37580. Norman Itzkowitz,
Mehmed Raghib Pasha: The Making of an Ottoman Grand Vizier (Ph.D. diss.,
Princeton University, 1959).
193
Ms. Canay Sahin, a Ph.D. candidate at Bilkent University, is in the process
of editing the register of one of Istanbuls nanciers whose clients included members of the gentry throughout the empire.

121

the reader might discern the logic of rule and appreciate the bases
of the empires social cohesion. By bringing the reader into this
charmed circle, Vehbi also imparted a certain knowledge of the
whole, a view from the summit denied the ordinary subject.
Each reader might nd something to suit his own tastes. The visitor who brought a copy back to Cairo might have been captivated
by the descriptions of monumental candy gardens, the performances
of agile acrobats, or the marvelous products of the capitals gifted
craftsmen. The memories of the drumbeat of the military band, the
parades of guards in formation, and the lavish banquets awaiting
the men of the state, may have inspired a commander (serasker) by
the name of Ali Pasha, to purchase a copy before leaving on assignment to Diyarbekir. Auctioned along with his personal eects, the
manuscript eventually found its way backhundreds of kilometers
from his last postingto the imperial treasury.194

194
For the location of other copies of this work, see Atl and Koc, Levni and the
Surname, 43. In 1744, Ali Pashas personal copy (TKSK MS. B 223) was conscated
by the state.

CHAPTER THREE

GOVERNMENT IN THE VERNACULAR

While the painters in the palace atelier were re-creating the candy
owers and wreaths of court pageant long past, the clerks of the
Bb- li tended another garden.
The imperial archive represents the art of governing writ large.
Through its reports, orders, certicates, requisitions, and audits, the
state ruled over many peoples and provinces. Yet where chapter 1s
map and chapter 2s festival book crack open a window on a readily discernible (if nonetheless misleading) visual order, the ledgers of
the empires eighteenth common era, or twelfth century after the
Hijra, seems to slam shut a dialogue with modernity.
Indeed, in the mirror of one of its many registerssay, a page
drawn from a master accounting of malikne revenue contracts in the
province of Diyarbekir (gs. 3 and 4)the archive seems less a
garden than an overgrown thicket: a chaotic jumble of entries inscribed
across a now-tattered and worm-eaten Venetian folio. Its caption,
the names of a pair of villages, Krd Hasan and Meslah, corresponds to no designation on the contemporary map.1 Nor does it
follow rmly in the tradition of cadastration perfected in the empires
earlier centuries; in place of neat rows describing crop types and
yields, we see knots of scribal shorthand, or siyakat, tangled references, notations, and the minutiae of dates and formulae that overow
the page.2 Rather than an exhaustive accounting of rural population
or current income from crops on a sancak-by-sancak basis,3 nearly an
1
MMD 9518:17. Only one of the two settlements bears some type of spacial reference (to the district of ermik, a town some fty kilometers northwest of presentday Diyarbekir).
2
MMD 9518. This is but one of many master registers for the networks of
provincial tax farming: for Tokat, MMD 9543, 9559; for Athens, MMD 9512; for
Mosul, MMD 9611; for Damascus, MMD 9530, 9538; for Erzurum, MMD 9517;
for Crete, MMD 9503; for Bosnia, MMD 9520; for Aleppo, MMD 9482.
3
For an exhaustive treatment of Ottoman diplomatics, see Mbahat S. Ktko[lu,
Osmanl Belgelerinin Dili (Diplomatik) (Istanbul: Kubbealt Akademisi Ktr ve San"at
Vakf, 1998). For facsimiles of the classic register, see L. Fekete, Die Siyaqat-Schrift
in der Trkischen Finanzverwaltung (Budapest: Akademiai Kiad, 1955), esp. vol. 2.

123

Fig. 3 Detail of the malikne mukataa master register. (MMD 9518:17).


The four tax-farming partnerships registered concern villages in the Diyarbekir
province, including the judicial districts of Amid, ermik and Savur. For
a translation of the entry in the upper right hand corner, see Fig. 4.

124

Village of Krd Hasan in the Judicial District of ermik


Village of Meslah el-Ma"ruf bi Suphan [
]
increase in 1708
Annual Payment

Seyyid Ahmed
share
1710

Sons, Seyyid
Salih &
Seyyid
Feyzllah
1725

Seyyid Ali
share
1710

Mehmed Emin
share
1710

Son, Seyyid
mer
1724

Ahmed A[a
1743

Seyyid Osman &


Mehmed Emin &
Yusuf [date?]

[ayan?]
Haci Ahmed
1791

ake
ake
ake
ake
ake

Seyyid Ahmed
share
1712

Elhac Ibrahim
1726

Seyyid Yusuf
& share
[date?]

Mehmed A[a in Istanbul


1760

1,202
2,285
3,485
8,513
12,000

son, Hseyin
share
[date?]
[name?]
1744

Seyyid
Abdullah
1757

Sons,
Seyyid Bekir
& Seyyid
Ahmed
1775

Hseyin & son,


Ibrahim
1780

Fig. 4 The Devolution of Shares in a Diyarbekir Tax Farm (17101791)

125

entire centurys worth of tax revenues from two villages (or likewise,
tribes and commercial revenues scattered throughout town and countryside) is subsumed in a perfunctory table: the initial amount of
3,485 ake is rounded up to 12,000 ake in 17089, after which there
is no further reassessment of value.4
Like the obscure, ill ordered, incomplete, and slovenly pages of
the tax registers that greeted Tocqueville in his foray into the ancienrgime archive, these unseemly documents might strike us as evidence of the progressive decay that brought low a great empire.5
Yet such an idealized vision of a classical age past and a naive appreciation of the bright future of transparent government only further
confound our passage through the tangled forests of the Ottoman
old regime archive.6 Enlightenment authors did advocate a new science of statecraft, a governmentality,7 they bequeathed to the
Physiocrats and Prussian statisticians. Most, like Colbert, who in 1679
dreamt of a comprehensive cadastral map that would document the
agrarian state of France in its entirety, found it impossible to realize their projects. Foreign conquest and colonialism did unfetter the
bureaucrats imagination. Without the impediment of a potent aristocracy or deference to local custom, colonial administrators, such
as William Petty, deployed political arithmetic to reduce the seventeenth-century Irish economy to numbers, just as Lord Cornwallis
would annex eighteenth-century Bengal with his surveyors.8
4
My initial assumption was that these registers were kept in the provinces by
provincial treasurers, or even local voyvodas and muhassls because their period coincides with the Nizam- Cedid (17931807) and the Tanzimat (183976). For provincial record keeping, Yavuz Cezar, Osmanl Maliyesinde Bunalm ve De[i{im Dnemi (XVIII.
Yzyldan Tanzimata Mali Tarih) (Istanbul: Alan Yaynclk, 1986), 331.
5
Alexis de Tocqueville, The Old Rgime and the French Revolution (Garden City,
N.Y.: Doubleday & Company, 1955), 16.
6
Cf. Brinkley Messick, The Calligraphic State: Textual Domination and History in a
Muslim Society (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1993).
7
See Graham Burchell and Colin Gordon, eds., The Foucault Eect: Studies in
Governmentality: With Two Lectures by and an Interview with Michel Foucault (Chicago:
University of Chicago Press, 1991).
8
Although the short leases on the Great Farm of the English customs were
phased out in the early seventeenth century, Britain continued to farm revenues in
Canada until the mid-nineteenth century and in India until the Permanentment
Settle with Bengal in 1793. See Ranajit Guha, A Rule of Property for Bengal: An Essay
on the Idea of Permanent Settlement (Durham: Duke University Press, 1996), and Anthony
Pagden, Dispossessing the Barbarian: The Language of Spanish Thomism and the
Debate over the Property Rights of the American Indians, in The Languages of
Political Theory in Early-Modern Europe, ed. A. Pagden (Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press, 1987), 7998.

126

However, it is possible to forget that in an age that considered


adherence to standard orthography optional, statesmen did not mistake the diligence of excise agents or bookkeepers for the mettle of
a nation.9 Quite the contrary; a contemporary observer, such as Sir
James Porter, who served as British ambassador to the sultan between
1746 and 1762, might nd peculiarities of chancellery style intriguing. Indeed, Sir James marveled at the singular eciency of the
Ottoman clerks techniques of compiling and retrieving data. No
tedious plugging of information into columns and categories here.
Sir James remarked upon a collocation of entries that, as in our register, pirouetted instead around date and transaction.10
Without such guidance we would surely miss the economy and
sophistication of our master register of tax farms.11 Though scant on
coordinates in space, the information condensed in this half page
furnishes a schematic: the essential details of the scal and political
history of two villages at a distance of more than a thousand kilometers from the Ottoman capital. Each ourish refers us to another
generation of contractors who pass shares by auction, cession, or
default. The page introduces us to partnerships such as those of
Seyyid Ahmed and Ali, ulema who share their holding with their
sons Salih, Feyzullah, and mer; to members of the Diyarbekir gentry; and to soldiers like Mehmet A[a, who continued to reside in
Istanbul. This is no static roster of names or mere register of quantities of goods. The Ottoman old regime recorded power as a process,
as a chain of relations tying persons, to places, and resources.
9
Article 22 of the Treaty of Paris (1763) specied the fate of French archives,
allowing for Tous les Papiers, Lettres, Documens, et Archives, qui se sont trouvs
dans les Pays, Terres, Villes, et Places qui sont restitut et ceux appartenans aux
Pas cds, seront dlivrs, ou fournis respsectivement, et de bonne Foy, dans le
mmes Tems, sil est possible, de la Prise de Possession . . . See Zenab Esmat
Rashed, The Peace of Paris, 1763 (Liverpool: University Press, 1951). Theodore M.
Porter (The Rise of Statistical Thinking, 18201900 [Princeton: Princeton University
Press, 1986], 25) attributes the peculiarities of the pre-modern archive to an epistemology xed on status rather than economics and social stratication.
10
Papers of the remotest date, if singly the year of the transaction is known,
may be found at the Porte; every command granted at that time, and every regulation then made can be immediately produced. Observations on the Religion, Law,
Government and Manners of the Turks (Dublin: Printed for P. Wilson, 1768) vol. 2, 131.
11
See Mehmet Gen, A Study on the Feasibility of Using Eighteenth-Century
Ottoman Financial Records as an Indicator of Economic Activity, in The Ottoman
Empire in the World Economy, ed. Huri Islamo[lu-Inan (Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press, 1987), 345373; and Ariel Salzmann, Measures of Empire: Tax Farmers and
the Ottoman Ancien Rgime (Ph.D. diss., Columbia University, 1995), introduction.

127

No matter how comprehensive the document, even this register


of seventy-odd pages, the archive yields no more than jagged slices
of the past. Nonetheless, with judicious supplements,12 this particular ledger may furnish an alternative point of perspective from which
to consider a form of governance that has slipped into the recesses
of the old and new regimes. It forces us to consider the state as a
work in progress and the quotidian facets of rule as an compound
that I call vernacular government. Such forms of governance took
shape in the shifting jurisdictions within and between provinces and
as a by-product of a land or, better, labor regime that was continuously remapping itself against the demands and resistance of tax
lords, peasants, peasants and herders. It also opens a window on the
city as locus of contractual relationships linking Istanbul with the
urban elites. Even as certain gures, such as great gentry, loom larger
than others, our register helps us to situate both these families and
prominent individuals within a complex system of checks and balances that anticipated the age of reforms.

Questions of Jurisdiction
As one turns the rst pages of the register, the eye searches for a
signpost, a label. The round, clear script employed for cataloging
promises a Register pertaining to the Life-leases here-indicated
[ located] in the [ jurisdiction] of the province of Diyarbekir (Defter-i
Mukatat- Malikneh-i Mezkre der Eylet-i Diyarbekir).
Yet like much else of the old regime, this register is not exactly
what it appears to be. The province, or eyalet, which we rst encountered in chapter 1, was as much an historical as a territorial notion
of space. The jurisdictional lines produced in the empires rst decades
in this region were bueted by the political, economic, and social
tempests of later centuries. While retrotting its administrative architecture, Istanbul clung to the formalities of a command structure
that bound cavalry to district captains, governor-commanders, and

12
For more on the city of Amid (todays Diyarbekir/Diyarbakr in Turkey) and
the province of Diyarbekir, see Ylmazelik, XIX. Yzyln ilk Yarsnda Diyarbakr
17901840, 2 vols. (Ph.D. diss., Frat University, 1991) (hereafter, XIX. Yzyln
ilk Yarsnda), and his monograph XIX. Yzyln ilk Yarsnda Diyarbakr, 17901840
(Ankara: TTK Basmevi, 1995) (hereafter, Diyarbakr).

128

viziers. Even as new ocials came to ll the gaps between older


forms of administration and the new, or simply to carry out mundane functions of governance, the Porte continued the convention
of issuing directives (hkm) to the vali or beylerbeyi on such issues as
security at the frontier, policing the province, the collecting of debts
and taxes, and the enforcing of land administration.
Older jurisdictional forms would continue to cast long shadows
over the archive. However, the bureaucrat who consulted this register must necessarily have been apprized of another reality on the
ground. The caption on the rst entry brings us to the point: it is
not, as one might have expected a summary of the administrative
code of a district or the income accruing to the governors estate.
Instead, an expanding column of taxes, dues, and levies is subsumed
below the heading The tax units [that form part of ] the voyvodalk
of Diyarbakir and dependencies and [values] current from the rst
of Mart 1149 (1737).13 Beneath this is the sum of the annual remittance (10,352,231 ake) and a table listing multiple adjustments and
additional revenues. Income from a Su lodge, special dues from a
battalion of soldiers ( gilman), unassigned imperial estates in Arabgir
and emi{gezik, an unassigned timar in Mardin, and, after 1776, a
share in the import tax on tobacco, magnify the jurisdictional space
and enlarge the range of contractual relationships represented within
this single tax farm.
The term voyvodalk does not only signify a large and aggregate
malikne contract with an intendant of its own or a valuable resource
that attracted some of Istanbuls most prominent rical. As a kalam
or eklm, it was also a provincial scal bureau that had absorbed a
considerable portion of the state-designated wealth of this province,
but particularly the interstitial dimension of its scal and political
structure as well as most of the life-leases awarded within this region.
Its etymology contains a microhistory of a polyglot, Eurasian regime.
Whereas eyalet traces its roots to the Arabic lexicon and Islamic precedent, the term voyvodalk derives from a Slavic noun. A voyvoda refers
to a subcommander. In the sixteenth century, it was the title of the
civil governor of the Black Sea states under Ottoman suzerainty.
Recycled through the machinery of the imperial administration from
the Balkans to northern Anatolia and Kurdistan, the title stuck to

13

MMD 9518:12.

129

those who served as intendants of tax farms or as on-site stewards of


an ocers revenues. Its transformation into an scal locution or category, the voyvodalk14 (an Ottoman hybrid formed by the addition
of a Turkish sux), introduced to its meaning sucient administrative elasticity to embrace scores of separate revenue contracts.15 The
voyvodalk of Diyarbekir, like that in Tokat or its analogues, the
muhasslk of Aleppo or the defterdarlk of Damascus, carved new administrative lines within and through the classical chain of command
and between military and civil-juridical authority.
Over the eighteenth century, the jurisdictional range of the Diyarbekir voyvodalk waxed and waned (Fig. 5). It could not but respect
the operating reality of the province, which lay in the upper Jazira
(the Tigris and Euphrates region) at the edge of the high Anatolian
plain and in the depression before the Zagros mountains. From the
provincial capital of Amid, itself 1,400 kilometers southeast of Istanbul
via Sivas and Malatya, the province in its successive incarnations
had once subordinated cities such as Harput, 160 kilometers to the
north, the mines of Keban and Ergani to the northwest, and smaller
fortied cities such as Palu and Hisnkeyf. It included a vast agricultural hinterland that stretched eastward across the fertile region
of Miyafarikin as far as the town of Siirt and westward to Siverek
on the Tigris. Its southern limits were xed by the arid land between
the provinces of Urfa, Baghdad, and Mosul.16

14
This is but one of many names for an analogous phenomenon: provincial treasuries largely made up of revenue contracts that are supervised by intendants. These
provincial treasuries are called, alternately defterdarlk (for Damascus), muhassllk (for
Aleppo), and nezaret (in Silstre and Rusuk). For the state of many of these tax
farms in Diyarbekir before this reorganization under new provincial bureaus (eklm),
see Rhoads Murphey, Regional Structure in the Ottoman Empire: A Sultanic Memorandum
of 1636 A.D. Concerning the Sources and Uses of the Tax farm Revenues of Anatolia and the
Coastal and Northern Portions of Syria (Wiesbaden: Otto Harrassowitz, 1987), 181.
15
MMD 10,143:233. Phraseology reproduces this ambiguity, referring to tax
farms within and outside the jurisdiction of the voyvodalk, that is in the judiciary
districts of Ergani, Siverek, ng{, Hani and Barzani [Biraz] . . . (der canib-
Diyarbekir harec-i voyvodalk ve dahil-i voyvodalk).
16
The number of constituent districts (sancak) in the eyalet grew from 19 in 1733,
to 27 in 1747, and nally to 30 in 1797 (Ylmazelik, Diyarbakr, 12829). D}S
360:50 (1736) adds the districts of Mihrani and e{ke. See also Mouragea DOhsson,
Tableau gnral de lEmpire othoman, divis en deux parties, dont lune comprend la lgislation
mahomtane; lautre, lhistoire de lEmpire othoman (Paris, Imp. de monsieur [Firmin Didot]
17871820) 6:300; and F. Akbal, 1831 Tarihinde Osmanl Imparatorlu[unda Idari
Taksimat ve Nufus, Belleten 15 (1951): 62122 which records the following sancak

130

Fig. 5 Shifting jurisdictions in Ottoman Asia. After (brahim Yilmazelik, XIX Yyzlln (lk
Yarsnda Diyarbekir (17901840) Ankara Trk Tarih Kurumu. 1995 appendix 4.
Courtesy of Trk Tarih Kurumu.

131

Given its proximity to the Kurdish edge, indeed the absorption


of most of the Sunni confederates in the initial conguration of the
eyalet17 and the strategic goods produced by its inhabitants, Diyarbekirs
importance to imperial defense remained undiminished in the second half of the eighteenth century. Although the region did not suer
the threat of invasion, as did Mosul, Baghdad, and Basra, it paid
dearly for the Wars of the Iranian Succession. The general insecurity of the countryside caused a hero of the Iranian campaigns such
as eteci Abdullah Pashaas well as his successors to the governorship and the oce of voyvoda in Diyarbekirto spend months on
campaigns suppressing roving bands of vagrant [ba{- bo{] levend
(mercenaries) and other bandits who preyed upon traders and peasants.18 Although spared the direct burden of the Russo-Ottoman wars
or the rebellions of Ali Bey in Egypt and the Zadaniyya in Palestine,
Diyarbekir still felt the ripple eect of crises brought by Karim Khan
Zands incursions into Iraq (and occupation of Basra in 1776) and
the uneasy succession within the pashalik of Baghdad that preceded
the restoration under Suleyman the Great (17801802). Each
conict generated fresh waves of unemployed soldiers armed with
pistols made in Erzurum or Russia.19
Soldiers were not the only actors who violently reshaped the contours of the eyalet, especially at its southern margins.20 Turn-of-thecentury eorts to resettle local tribesmen had not so much cleared

in 1831: Amid, Hani, Mazgird, Mifarkin, Harput, Sincar, Isiirt, Siverek, Ergani,
Anade (?), Hsnkeyf, emi{gezik, Nisiybin, apakur, Sa[man, ermik, Kulp, Iklis,
Penbek, and Pertek, in addition to the hkmet of Palu, Gen, Cizre, E[il, Hazzo,
Tercil, and Savur.
17
On the back and forth of branches of the Milan tribe between 1711 and 1724,
see Halao[lu, (skan Siyaseti, 52, 114. For later eorts, see the Tribal Settlement
Registers of 1146/1733 published by Cevdet Trkay: Ba{bakanlk Ar{ivi Belgeleri"ne
gre Osmanl mparatorlu[u"nda Oymak, A{iret ve Cematlar (Istanbul: Tercman, 1979).
18
Mustafa Cezar, Osmanl Tarihinde Levendler (Istanbul: Gzel Sanatlar Akademisi,
1965), 43435. For events in neighboring provinces of Mosul, see Kemp, Territoire
de lIslam; and Yasin al-'Umari, al-Durr al-Maknn f al-Ma"thir al-Mdiya min al Qurun,
3 vols., critical ed. by Sayyar Kawkab 'Ali al-Jamil (Ph.D. diss., University of St.
Andrews, 1983); Herbert L. Bodman, Political Factions in Aleppo, 17601826 (Chapel
Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1963); T. Niewenhuis, Politics and Society
in Early Modern Iraq, Studies in Social History (The Hague-Amsterdam: International
Institute of Social History, 1982).
19
Cezar, Osmanl Tarihinde Levendler, 294, 43435.
20
Xavier de Planhol, Lvolution du nomadisme en Anatolie et en Iran. tude
compare, in Viehwirtschaft und Hirtenkultur. Ethnographische Studien, ed. L. Fldes
and B. Gunda (Budapest: Akadmiai Kiad, 1969), 6993. These were the quasi-

132

the region of pastoralists as opened the door to new waves of nomadic


herdsmen from eastern Arabia. No longer strong enough to block
their path, the remaining Turkmen, Arab, and Kurdish tribes who
frequented the southern districts of Diyarbekir and the eastern fringes
of Aleppo yielded to the Arab tribes who migrated from Najd toward
the middle routes of the Euphrates. In northern Iraq, local tribes
found a way to recover an autonomy lost. Intraprovincial competition crystallized into geopolitical realignments between cities and
tribes. The Tayy tribe of Nisibin threw in its lot with the hereditary gentry-governors of Mosul, the Jalilis, and the Kurdish Milan
(in Turkish, Mill) allied with Baghdad.
Over the century, as our registers thirty-three tribal entries testify, local administration adapted the contracting system to this restive
population. Tax farming, particularly through the life-term contracts,
proved an eective instrument of harnessing branches of tribes with
mixed economies, such as the Kara Ulus, who were targeted for
new agrarian taxation.21 Alternatively, contracts reconrmed the title
and authority of a tribal shaykh. In the process, the Sublime Porte
carved out new claims against tribal incomedividing it, as happened in the case of the nine villages in Mardin Mountain, in
which 388 peasant-tribesmen were registeredunequally between the
imperial treasury (24,033 ake) and the head of the tribe (mir), whose
take (of 11,900 ake) was less than half.22 The award of contracts to
dierent shaykhs, such as Faruk, head of the Cemaleddin branch
(a{ireti ) of the Milan, whittled away at the larger Milan confederation. With it thus fragmented, the clerk needed only to transfer a
contract from one heading to another when, in 173334, the eight
branches of Milan left with Ali Pasha for resettlement in Urfa.23
Nonetheless, the large contracts awarded at the margins of the province betray the states resignation before the uidity of jurisdiction
independent governments within the original province of Diyarbekir: Hakkari, Imadiyye, Bitlis, Hisnkeyf, Cizre, Sohran, emisgezek, Mazgird, Pertek, Sa[man, Palu,
E[il, ermik, Hazzo, Sasun, Erzen, Zirkan, Gurdukan, Atak, Tercil, Mihrani, Hizan,
Hanuk, Gen, apakcur, Kulp, and Mifarikin (Van Bruinessen, Evliya elebi in
Diyarbekir, 1821). In the eighteenth century (according to Ylmazelik, Diyarbakr,
317), there were the a{iret of the Kik and the Res, as well as the cemaat of
Dgl Aluc, the Karaciya, Izolu, Karabe[an, Kirman, (Millan), and Karapnar.
21
MMD 3677:911; MMD 9518:6075. Dierent headmen, called kethuda or mir
asiret, gure in this account book.
22
MMD 9518:6575.
23
MMD 9518:71.

133

over the great arid and mountainous spaces between provinces.


Relying on either tribal elites or combined tribal-urban partnerships,
the awards of enormous malikne contracts captured valuable but otherwise elusive revenues from herds and the avriz tax in Kurdish
emi{gezek, Sa[man, and Mazgerd (yielding in 1717 a yearly payment
of 723,996 ake).24
If the state was scarcely able to provide security for cultivators in
the vicinity of Diyarbekirs capital district, Amid, where tribes were
known to raid villages for food, livestock, and even women,25 the
authorities were even less likely to defend cultivators in the lands
south of Mardin, a zone of annual tribal migration between winter
and summer pastures.26 Already in 1694 Mardin and Nisibin (128
kilometers from Amid) recorded the highest losses in the number of
tax efs: only 55 of 311 timar and zeamet holders paid their cebel
bedeliyesi (dues paid in lieu of military service). Of the remainder, 120
did not pay and 141, one-third of all units, were ocially declared
totally ruined (harabe).27 The lower districts continued to experience
24

MMD 9518:73.
DA III:50, 164; IV:7172.
26
Ylmazelik, Diyarbakr, 170. These tribes were ocially recognized in the
province of Mardin in 1747: the Mihi, Tausi, Piran-o-Zencir, Karadar, Ri{ail,
Kabal, Maski, Birnek, Cevzat, Hindl, Telermen, Karacahisar, Ihrahimiye, Bilali,
Kalemtra, }eyhhan-i Zencir, Kltl, Selah, Tekk, }i[levan, Kavus, Telfeyyaz,
Makbele, Kiki, meriyan, Milli (Milan) }arkiyan, Kalenderan, Mir Sinan, Bayrakl,
Araban, Bykhan, and Behdire.
27
Timars and Zeamets in the province of Diyarbekir
25

Amid
Harput
Ergani
Siverek
Nisibin
Mardin
Hisnkeyf
Siirt
emi{gezik
Kulb
Tercil
apakcur
ermik

1609
Total

1694
Total

1694
Paid

1694
Unpaid

1694
Ruined

176
201
124
67
6
n.d.
28
6
9
27
28
35
0

176
n.d.
128
60
21
316
38
n.d.
n.d.
78
n.d.
37
31

138
n.d.
75
47

38
10
13

43

55
13

120
25

141

37

41

37
1

30

Sources: 'Ayn-i 'Ali Efendi, Kavanin-i Al-i Osman, ed. M. Tayyib Gkbilgin (Istanbul, 1960); KK
493:130.

134

considerable dislocation of their agrarian populations during the eighteenth century. In 178384, Gksu, once a ourishing, largely Armenian agricultural district south of Diyarbekir on the Tigris, had lost
nearly three out of every ve timars. The district of Savur, also south
of the provincial capital, retained only six functioning of the twentyone timars recorded in the previous census.28 One contract auctioned
in the district of Mardin aptly expresses a pervasive reality. It is captioned: villages that are o the books and without resident cavalry ocers.29
Yet Mardins inhabitants could employ the shifting use of land to
their advantage. At 95 kilometers from Amid, the city had long
rivaled the provincial capital in textile manufacturing and, in particular, as a transit point on trade routes between Iraq and Syria.
Although wartime may have necessitated accepting the embrace of
the province anew (in 173435 and 174751, Mardin reverted to
the eyalet of Diyarbekir),30 the city remained a dependency of Baghdad.31
It was governed by a voyvoda who paid two hundred purses for his
oce and commanded both the janissary garrison and a battalion
of troops. The citys tax farms, though entered within the voyvodalk
bureau, also reected Baghdads de facto annexation of the district.
The large contract over an aggregate block of revenues (possibly former crown estates) within Mardin and Nisibin had been held by the
founders of the pashalik, Hasan Pasha (d. 1724) and a son, Ahmad
Pasha (d. 1747), and continued to be awarded as contracts to ocials
based in Baghdad.32

28

Cti 4668.
MMD 9518:75.
30
M}S 195:12. Although in 1764 the governor of Diyarbekir apparently made
the rounds of Mardin to collect his salyane (see also DA III:276); typically, however, Istanbul deferred to the local administrators. See DA III:221 addressed to the
Mardin judge and voyvoda concerning the claims of a sipahi in a canton still within
Amid sancak in 1771.
31
On the extension of the province of Baghdad to the east and north, Niewenhuis,
Politics and Society in Early Modern Iraq, 240; also Suavi Aydin, Kudret Emiro[lu,
Oktay zel, and Sha nsal, Mardin A{iret-Cemaat-Devlet (Istanbul: Tarih Vakf,
2000), 16465. For a travel account from 1766, Carsten Niebuhr, Reisebeschreibung
durch Syrien und Palstina nach Zypern und durch Kleinasien und die Trkei nach Deutschland
und Dannemark (Hamburg: Friedrich Berthes, 1837) vol. 2, 39596.
32
Niewenhuis, Politics and Society in Early Modern Iraq, 24. MMD 9518:101. The
contracts on these farms were ceded in 1751 to Suleyman Pasha; and in 1769 for
110,000 kuru{ to mr Pasha, also of Baghdad. Other contracts were administered
directly by Mardins voyvoda (see MMD 9518:103 [1731]).
29

135

Unable to prevent the transfer of power to members of Ahmad


Pashas largely Georgian household after his death, the Porte still
relied on Baghdad to protect its interests at the frontier. Nonetheless,
in matters concerning domestic commerce, especially the lifeline of
coee, spices, and cotton stus destined for Istanbul from the Gulf,
the Porte turned to the authorities of the intermediate provinces,
such as Urfa and Diyarbekir, for reinforcements.33 Unrest in the
Milan regions brought this intraimperial rivalry to a head in 1791.
The governors of Malatya and Aleppo and the voyvoda of Diyarbekir
hunted down the shaykhly elites and conscated their wealth. One
of the survivors, Timur Bey, found sanctuary in Baghdad. His brush
with the gentry-administrator of Diyarbekir in particular would add
a level of personal enmity to the geopolitical rivalry between tribal
clans and the prominent family of Amid, the }eyhzde.34
Throughout the century, rural insecurity continued to exact a
heavy toll on agricultural settlements.35 Even in the two judicial districts (kaza) immediately surrounding the provincial capital, documents indicate a decrease in the numbers of both tax efs and villages
during the rst half of the century. In 1739, Amids court clerk
recorded the names of 111 villages in Eastern Amid, of which one
in ten (eleven), he noted, were ruined for the purposes of tax
assessment.36 A series of natural disasters struck the province in midcentury. The troubles began with crop failures in dry-farmed lands
of Diyarbekir and Mosul; locusts and an unseasonably cold winter
followed. With starvation driving near-naked beggars as far as the
city of Aleppo in search of food, the region was ripe for a pandemic.37

33

DA II:243.
Aydin et al., Mardin A{iret-Cemaat-Devlet, 18283, 197.
35
Van Bruinessen, Evliya elebi in Diyarbekir, 12223. For eighteenth-century information relative to the reassignment of timar, see also DA IV:45; DA III:191. In
179596, 624 timars and zeamets paid 177,000 kuru{ (Cezar, Osmanl Tarihinde Levendler,
464).
36
D}S 360:3538. The number of avrz hanes (an accounting unit representing
a number of scal houses) dropped from 2,022 in 1701 (808,900 ake) to 2015.5
in 172324; however, income rose to 999,600 ake. (MMD 1347:2; MMD 5781:8;
MMD 10,166:231). As for the avariz in Diyarbekir in the sixteenth century, see
MMD 7637:24 for the year 1003 (159495); the rate was 2 kuru{ per household
in the city, and 3 kuru{ per household in the district (kaza); ciziye was based on
70,000 persons.
37
On the famine of August 1758, see MMD 10,200:230; for later occurrences,
see Sleyman Efendi, Mur"i"t-Tevarih, vol. 2A, 25; Charles Issawi, ed., The Fertile
Crescent, 18001914: A Documentary Economic History (Oxford: Oxford University Press,
34

136

The scars of the bubonic plague, known as the Great Dying of


1762, were still visible on timar holdings in 178384, a generation
later. In Western Amid, nearly half of the agrarian settlements were
no longer capable of supporting cavalry ocers (of a total of 98
timars, 35 were considered ruined and 17 no longer existed).38 Although
Istanbul continued to assign timars in deference to the logic of the
eyalet for another half century,39 given the sipahis increasingly marginal role in defense, there was no compelling reason, other than
rural administration, to restore the system to its former glory. Indeed,
in many respects the original timar hierarchy had become all but
vestigial. Central-state ocers whose names are recorded in our register and whose agents made payments on their behalf through the
court of Amid held contracts on the estates belonging to the treasurer and secretariat of local timars, the hass- defterdarlk- timar ve
kethdalk- defter-i vilyet-i Diyarbekir.40
Such scant and scattered indices of the health of the agricultural
economy must be handled with care. However dire conditions may
have been during these decades, population rebounded and perhaps
relocated between bouts of war and famine. Cash crops such as cotton were produced in Harput, ermik, and emi{gezik.41 In addition
to the staples of lifewheat, millet, barley, lentils, and sesame
there were luxury goods: wine from Siirt and rice and melons from

1988), 96; and Antoine Abdel Nour, Introduction lhistorie urbaine de la Syrie Ottomane
(Beirut: Publication de lUniversit Libanaise, 1982), 70.
38
Cti 4668. In Amids eastern district ({ark- Amid), the toll was somewhat less:
of 75 timar, 15 were ruined and another 17 no longer existed.
39
On the drastic decline of timar holdings in Aleppo, compare Jean-Pierre Thieck,
Dcentralisation ottomane et armation urbaine Alep la n du XVIIIme
sicle, in Mouvements communautaires et espaces urbains au Machreq, ed. Mona Zakaria
et al. (Beirut: Centre dtudes et de Recherches sur le Moyen-Orient Contemporain,
1985), 129.
40
MMD 9518:3. In 171920, it was assumed by the former inspector of the
imperial mint, Suleyman Efendi, together with Seyyid Abu Bakr Efendi, for 1,200
kuru{. Typically, there was a local partner, such as Mustafa A[a from Erzurum
in 172627 and later Huseyn A[a, who, we are told, was a member of the retinue
of (brahim, the former voyvoda of Diyarbekir, 172829. Another contract regarding
the defunct estate of the provincial treasurer (mukatat- hass- defterdarlk- hazine-i Diyarbekir
nam- di[er eske). This too was in the hands of central-state ocers (see TKSA E
10,129). They also relied on local subcontractors: in 174041 (D}S 360:35), three
Diyarbekir residents, Elhac Ali A[a, Huseyin A[a, and Halil registered, making
their payments to Istanbul partners.
41
Thus ermik, which held no timar in 1609, recorded thirty-one at the end of
the century. See n. 27 above.

137

Western Amid.42 Grain cultivation seems to have shifted eastward


toward the Silvan Plain, a region that would earn the title granary
of Kurdistan in the nineteenth century.43 In fact, whereas military
requisitions of grain targeted regions in the immediate vicinity of the
capital in the rst half of the sixteenth century, a century later, in
1741, the levy was more evenly distributed. Now, much of the grain
supply came from Hani, a small town to the northeast (in which
many of the citys gentry would purchase tax contracts), from the
well-irrigated land surrounding the city of Harput, and from Ergani
(including unku{), Palu. and Siirt. More surprising is the fact that
tribal regions that had few or no timars in the sixteenth century, such
as apakcur, Savur, Atak, and Tercil, now provided a quarter of
the total wheat requisition.44
Paradoxically, the declining number of timars and the retrenchment of the eyalet structure are also the symptoms of a new economic vitality. This was certainly true for the mining industry. The
copper, silver, and iron mines in the provinces northwestern corner
were linked by roads to the smelting factory of Amid, thirty hours,
or 73 kilometers away. To tighten their grip over production, Istanbul
bureaucrats turned over the administration of the northwestern portions of the eyalet, including Palu, ar{ancak, Harput, E[in, Arapgir,
Siverek, and unku{, to the intendant of mines at Ergani.45 Carrying

42

DA III:14 (175859); MMD 3677:11 (for rates of rice in 1697); Van Bruinessen,
Evliya elebi in Diyarbekir, 40, 16779, 193; D.B}M 5508; DA III:78 (176465); DA
II:92.
43
Charles Issawi, ed. An Economic History of Turkey (Chicago: University of Chicago
Press, 1980), 21820. Wheat was sown in the early fall and barley from November
to February, both were harvested in June and July; they were milled and stored in
August.
44
Van Bruinessen, Evliya elebi in Diyarbekir, 23. In the seventeenth century, Amid
provided about 50 percent of the levies; Harput, 11 percent; and Ergani, 10 percent. According to MMD 9891:224 in 1741, a century later, the distribution of
wheat levies was as follows: of 1 million kilos of our (39,300 kile/25.64 kilos)
requested, the capital district provided approximately 10 percent (99,996 kilos or
99.9 metric tons); Hani and ermik furnished 76,920 kilos; Harput, Ergani, and
E[il, nearly 20 percent (184,608 kilos); Hisnkeyf (205,120 kg); Siird (128,200 kg);
apakcur, Palu, Savur, Atak, Mihrani, and Tercil provided more than a quarter
of the total (284,604 kg). On the basis of the cizye of 1797 (D.B}M 6292, 81,950
kuru{), one nds that non-Muslim populations, presumably the largely Armenian villagers and town-dwellers, were particularly concentrated in the central districts of
the province (Eastern and Western Amid and in Amid itself ) and to the west and
north in the districts of Harput, Palu, and ar{nacak.
45
MMD 9518:93.

138

the rank of kapcba{, between 1740 and 1774, the intendant of mines
actually superseded the governors of Sivas and Diyarbekir in matters pertaining to production and supply in the mine.46 Within his
districts, he resettled miners and requisitioned carters. He commandeered wood for ring into coal, wax for candles to illuminate the
shafts, beasts of burden for hauling, and grain for fodder.47
Few examples illustrate more vividly the complex and overlapping
lines of jurisdictional control under the old regime, or the total inversion of prior categories of rule, than the role of the Ergani complex
with respect to the eyalet hierarchy. As a member of the aristocracy
of service with access to the Istanbul auction, the intendant of mines
might hold a share in Diyarbekirs voyvodalk, the large, composite
tax farm administered by the provinces voyvoda. By awarding shortterm tax contracts, subfarming his own, conrming guild appointments, recognizing members of the gentry, and encouraging members
of his own family and household to acquire tax farms in the districts under the command of the governor of Diyarbekir, the mine
administrator built his own sociopolitical infrastructure in the region.48
In a nal episode that turned the military and administrative hierarchy of the sixteenth century on its head, in 1794 Yusuf Ziya Pasha,
whose tenure as intendant of mines was one of the longest, absorbed
the governorship of Diyarbekir itself.49 Shunning the provincial capital, he ruled from Ergani, while consolidating his control over the
industry by acquiring shares in the valuable life-lease on the smelting factory of Amid.50

46
DA III:52 (177475). Instructions are sent to the Ergani intendant to track
down a bandit living in Amid itself.
47
Fahrettin Tzlak, Osmanl Dneminde Keban-Ergani Yresinde Madencilik (17751850)
(Ankara: TTK Basmevi, 1997), 15; see the register of the Intendant of Mines edited
by Hasan Yksel, 17761794 Tarihli Maaden Emini Defteri (Sivas: Dilek Matbaas,
1997), 1089, 121, 12628.
48
Tzlak, Osmanl Dneminde Keban-Ergani, introduction, 76; Yksel, 17761794
Tarihli Maaden Emini, 109; a former intendant of the Keban Mine, Mehmed A[a,
held a quarter share in 1723.
49
Mehmed Sreyya Bey, Sicill-i Osman; yahut Tezkere-yi Me{ahir-i Osmaniye (Istanbul:
Matbaa-i mire, 130815/189097), vol. 4, 67071. Ali Emiri, Tezkere-i }u"ar-i
Amid (Istanbul: Matbua-i Amidi, 1328/19101911) vol. 1, 141. Yusuf Ziya Pasha
began his career as a clerk in 1789. He was promoted to the position of mir-i miran
in 179394 as intendant of mines. In 1798, he was promoted to grand vizier and
then returned to Ergani as intendant of mines in 1807. The income of the intendant of mines between 1795 and 1802 was 117,776 kuru{ (Tzlak, Osmanl Dneminde
Keban-Ergani, 5863). See also n. 206 below.
50
MMD 9519:9 (1795).

139

At the Interstices of Rural Administration


The crisscrossing of jurisdictions is evident in the tug-of-war between
the intendant of mines and the governors of Diyarbekir. It was also
inherent in the very structure of smaller agrarian scal units that
made up the province. As a bureaucratic convention, an umbrella
sheltering most of the life contracts awarded within the boundaries
of the historic province, the voyvodalk adopted stray scal categories,
balanced power relationships in the countryside, and bridged town
and country. It acknowledged the lapses that had occurred in the
administration of space. Yet the contractors who lled the interstices
in the scal landscape might reside not locally but in Istanbul or
Baghdad. The revenues in question might derive from widely disparate sources, such as the eleven aggregate malikne mukataa awarded
on villages and elds in both Hani and Savur, districts located at
opposite ends of the province.51
The overwhelming majority of contracts within our voyvodalk register pertain to taxes owed by peasants and herdsmen in villages
scattered throughout the older and newer jurisdictions of the eyalet.
A determined researcher might painstakingly combine this information with data from other extant sources to reconstruct a true agrarian
survey of the province during the eighteenth century.52 Our register
does not, however, make this task easy.53 For scores of mukatat and
makt (forty-two in the register of 1799), we nd no more information
than the phrase within the jurisdiction of the sancak of Amid.54
51
Traian Stoianovich, The Segmentary State and La Grande Nation, in Geographic
Perspectives in History, ed. E. Genovese and L. Hochberg (Oxford: Oxford University
Press, 1989), 25859. DOhsson, Tableau gnral, vol. 7, 299, translates nahiye ( judiciary districts) as canton as well.
52
When I rst showed these registers to Nejat Gyn, one of the foremost
authorities on land tenure in this region, he threw up his hands in despair, commenting that the term nahiye had a very elastic meaning. For lists of villages in
the eighteenth-century district of Amid (both Eastern and Western), see Ylmazelik, Diyarbakr, 15160. Register MMD 9518 includes tax farms in dierent designations, including villages in the judicial districts (kaza) of Garb- Amid (2), }ark-
Amid (6), Amid (16), }ark-i and Garb-i Amid Mixed (6), Savur (16), Hani (30),
Hani and Savur (11), Kaza-y ermik (17), Barzani (13), Birecik (1), Atak (1), Kulp
(7), Ergani (30), and Kuh-i Mardin (2). In addition, there were 45 unidentied
makatat and one maktut as well as 33 tribes (a{iret).
53
The large imperial estates created in the original administrative division of
Syria and Kurdistan account for many of these tax farms. Barkan, Timar, 288,
estimates that 31 percent of the land in Diyarbekir itself was set aside in crown
estates.
54
For the lists of villages in the eighteenth century, see Ylmazelik, Diyarbakr,

140

Some appear on the earliest surveys of the province. The village of


Beyano[lu, for example, is found on the cadastral record of Diyarbekir
carried out in 1518.55 As tax farms and later as proprietary contracts, such villages might have slipped through the cracks of later
surveys. Others live a ghostly existence in extant documentation, like
the villages of Ali Daraklu, Hanebazar, and Dervi{ Hasan, which
gure on the judges list for 1733 but vanish thereafter.56
If many of these agricultural settlements remain specters in the
successive accounts of provincial revenues for us today, local investors
knew where they were located and whether they merited investment.57 Of course there were preferred regions: Hani and Savur, as
well as ermik to the west and the former tribal area of Barzani/Birazi,
were among the most desirable. Yet bidders were also prepared to
take a risk. Gentry from Amid, Ergani, and Harput attended the
1721 auction of the villages that made up the ruined ocaklk (agrarian revenues designated as salaries) in Harput. These villages taxes
had paid the stipends of the defenders of the fortress at Van, but
their cultivators had ed because of the oppressive practices of a
series of short-term tax farmers.58
In a changing countryside, the malikne contract addressed a perennial problem: the gaps in the land regime. Once the states agent,
presumably the voyvoda himself, identied a village as being o the
books and without an owner (harec ez defter ve bil saheb), the cen-

14460. The 46 or more villages under proprietary contract represent in the aggregate a considerable percentage of the district composed of 154 villages in 1758.
55
Both Hanebazar and Dervi{ Hasan do appear on the nineteenth-century map
prepared by Ylmazelik in his Diyarbakr, appendix. A great many may be within
two kilometers east of the provincial capital. For lists of villages from 1518, see
Ibid, 144, 149; Monla Kuuk, in Western Amid, gures in the cadastral survey of
1565.
56
We might attribute this disappearance to the very fact of their being privatized (bilcmle serbest olma[la) and hence no longer subject to bureaucratic oversight.
But this does not explain registration of the village of }ukru"llah (in Western Amid)
on the lists for 1733, 1747, and 1797, though not in 1738 or 1755; similarly,
}evketl in 1797 (also Ali Bardak, due north of Amid; Devel in Western Amid
in 1797; Akviran in Eastern Amid, appears on the list for 1747, as two villages,
upper and lower; and Nureddin in Western Amid, which appears only in
173839). Ylmazelik, Diyarbakr, 15162.
57
At present, our purpose is not to map the province, particularly given the ux
in settlement and the inconsistent use of geographical descriptions, but to sketch
out the basic political relationships that emerged from these overlapping jurisdictions and the contractualization of property and rent relations.
58
KK 3105 (1721); MMD 9518:90 (173435).

141

tral administration went into action.59 Initially repossessed (mirice


zapt),60 so to speak, some villages, such as Misr Kend, which had
been removed from the responsibility of the voyvoda of ermik, would
become the foster child of the voyvoda of Diyarbekir, under his own
designated aggregate tax farm, the voyvodalk.61 There is little explanation why others might be awarded to a malikne contractor or a
sipahi. In all cases, it was necessary to act quickly and decisively. In
the countryside, the operating principle of nulle terre sans taxe
meant that every unit of land overlooked by the scal system, absent
a revenue agent or resident lord, would soon be annexed by another
claimant, such as the zaim in the district of Eastern Amid who,
nding no sipahi in sight, merely added the surplus of the nearby
village of Timur Han Abbas to his own estate, the village of Timur
Han Eyp.62
From the distance of the Bosphorus, the land in Diyarbekirs
rural districts was an intangible without the peasants and herders
whose rents were collected by revenue agents. In an age when many
of these relationships had been reduced to short-term and lifelong
contracts rather than the older military hierarchy, establishing a chain
of scal responsibility required the mediation of a resident scal
administrator, a broker between Porte and province. In Diyarbekir
that role fell most often to the voyvoda of Amid. He still oversaw the
aggregate block of revenues, both urban and rural, for contractors
who generally resided in Istanbul.63 Over time he became responsible for most scal aairs of the province beyond the purview of the
timar system: he collected the universal taxes on households, the avarz
and bedel-i nzl, as well as the poll tax.64 Although a special ocer
59
MMD 9518:75. Regarding timars in the canton of Mardin, which originally
turned over to the voyvoda of Diyarbekir. In 1777, the miralay of Mardin, Seyyid
Abdullah, purchased the contract on these villages for 150 kuru{.
60
Cezar, Osmanl Maliyesinde Bunalm, 4142.
61
MMD 9815:77 (1781).
62
DA IV:19; DA II:97; DA I:52, 68.
63
There was not always a distinction between post and resources. During the
years 168994 (TT 831:38 (168994/11001105) the voyvodalk was held twice as
a two-year tax farm by other tax farmers by the names of }ahban A[a, Uzun Ali
A[a, and Mehmed A[a, quite probably local janissaries. Uzun Ali had a guarantor named Ahmed A[a.
64
MMD 10,168:252 (172526). The number of hane (a scal unit, or household)
in the eyalet of Diyarbekir was 2015.5 for the avarz and 2704 for the bedel-i nzl,
which yielded 20,788 kuru{ esedi. See also MMD 9518:73, a lump sum farm (maktu)
of the avarz and the bedel-i nzl for villages East and West in Diyarbekir which
are o the register.

142

from Istanbul carried out a roll call of contractors to collect the special wartime levy demanded of all malikne holders, it was the voyvoda
who handled much of the day-to-day management of the tax farms.
He must have supervised auctions, requested adjustments or new
certicates.65 He handled the retration (re, zapt, ibka) of shares or
entire contracts that had been improperly awarded or were poorly
managed.66
As violence escalated in the countryside, the voyvodas coercive abilities must have grown apace. His personal guard could not have
been inferior to that of the voyvoda of Siverek (technically subordinate to him), who, we are told in a 1742 judgment against him,
routinely sent his deputy (vekil ) and scribe (ktib) with thirty or forty
horsemen to villages to demand 5 to 10 kuru{ in special gifts ( pi{ke{),
in addition to legitimate requests for avrz, the imdad- hazariyye, and
the imdad- seferiyye.67 Indeed, in 1777 the voyvoda (smail, of whom I
will speak again, raised two thousand mercenary troops for the defense
of Iraq against the Zand armies, a number equal to that raised by
the governor of Mosul.68
Beyond the chain of payments and certicates that linked them
to the voyvoda or to high-ranking partners or benefactors in Istanbul,
contractors were fairly autonomous. By 1717, 156 individuals were
listed as holders of malikne mukatat in Diyarbekir. This was far fewer
than in the larger and wealthier district of Aleppo but still greater
than the number of contractors in Damascus. In 1717, local contractors held 179 tax farms in Diyarbekir (venal oces, villages, elds,
and tribal resources). In 1730, that number reached 205.69 In 1787,
the global value of sureties paid on malikne contracts in the region
had risen to 147,863.5 kuru{ approximately double that of 1717
(78,029.5 kuru{).70 Yet the agriculture sector, especially the small con-

65
MMD 4748:2; MMD 9518:50, by request of the voyvoda (ba arz- voyvoda);
MMD 9518:44, 50.
66
DA I:127 (174748). A tax farm on a settlement with seventeen peasants who
were growing cotton in the vicinity of Western Amid was retracted by order of the
treasurer to the Diyarbekir voyvoda Elhac Ahmad. The period of the 1730s and
1740s saw the highest rate of repossession. Of these, the Suvid a{iret (tevbi
Mehmed ve Hasan kethda), valued at 1,150 kuru{, was revoked in 1740 and again
eight years later. MMD 9518:21, 22, 28, 33, 42, 43, 50, 51, 64, 71, 73.
67
DA I:17.
68
Cezar, Osmanl Tarihinde Levendler, 45457. Each soldier was paid 36.8 kuru{.
69
Central-state investors bids outstripped those of locals four to one (MMD
4748:75, 48, 16, 76).
70
MMD 3677:23, 1216.

143

tracts scattered around the voyvodalk, remained overwhelmingly dominated by local investors. By the end of the century, 268 individuals had invested in 129 dierent village contracts in Hani, Amid,
Savur, and other villages.71
Changing relationships of administration and property were not
restricted to Diyarbekir.72 Here, however, the gentry had long exploited
private gardens along the Tigris on the outskirts of the city.73 Outgoing
orders make frequent mention of private landholdings in the form
of elds (mlk iftlik) and gardens (mlk ba[e and ba[ ), often in the
area of old tribal hkmet.74 Although the new life-contract gave the
gentry a means of entering into the agrarian economy of the provincial interior, their proprietary aspirations were contained by a cadastral map crowded with other claimants to rents and taxes. Ocials
respected the existing map of claims. Using a common locution, the
certicate awarded to a central-state ocer for a malikne mukataa in
the district of Mardin spoke of a plot of land whose boundaries
were well known and were not the benece (dirlik) or concern of
anyone else.75 Yet as a relative newcomer, the tax farmer provided
Istanbul with an unwitting surveyor to update its registers. In some
cases, that meant discovering that the resource in question was valueless: a marginal note in our register tells us of a contractor who
upon arriving at his designated area, found that there were no cultivators remaining to tax.76
From this perspective, the state ruled by default. Conicting
claims between tax agents inevitably drew central authority into the
71

MMD 9566 (1787) (excluding those in Ergani).


The need for codes and a new cadastral survey was noted in a preface to a
register on Sivas and Tokat (MMD 9481:12, 34 (16921717). Land sales in the
vicinity of the city were subject to a 10 percent surcharge.
73
Van Bruinessen, Evliya elebi in Diyarbekir, 17779.
74
A peasant iftlk ranged from 80 to 150 dnm in Diyarbekir depending on land
quality. (Halil (nalck, Osmanllarda Raiyyet Rsmu, Belleten 23 (1959): 582, n. 27).
However, the meaning of the iftlk in the following contexts is far from clear: one
reads of three iftlik bagesi belonging to a member of the ulema, Seyyid Hac
Osman; DA I:50; in 174445 a iftlik in Sa[man district; a mlk iftlik (ma"alum alhudud ) in 176768 (DA III:173); Mustafa Kasem and Isa petitioned in the same
year concerning 5 mlk iik (DA III:176); in 175556, Fatma Hatun in emisgezik
claimed a iftlik bequeathed by her father, DA II:52; Yuzo Nagata, too, notes that
a iftlik can be any tract of land (Tarihte ynlar: Karaosmano[lullar zerinde bir (nceleme
[Ankara: TTK Basmevi, 1997], 98).
75
DA I:206. A 1750 rescript given to a central-state ocer (Mehmed Silahsr)
in the district of Mardin; similarly D}S 360:57, a plot awarded because it was not the
imperial estate, zeamet or timar or vakf of anyone, [but] o the books (harez az defter).
76
MMD 9518:75.
72

144

agricultural landscape. All sorts of agents and property holders turned


to the Porte for deliberation of the relative merits of their titles or
to reconrm the terms of tenure.77 Thus the sipahi, Hseyin, who
argued that the taxes of the village of Kakulu and its state/common
eld or mezra, valued at 15,540 ake, had long been part of his ef
in Gksu and not, as the malikne contractor Abdulrahman asserted,
part of a newly contracted lot, demanded consultation of the cadastral registers and reconrmation of his claim with an imperial order
(hkm- hmayun).78 Malikne contractors frequently appealed to Istanbul,
invoking their rights to administrative immunity and freedom from
local interference in accordance with the 1695 imperial script.79 The
Istanbul administration and high court remained the ultimate arbiter
of property rights, of which tax farming was one point on a continuum of claims: it adjudicated inheritance conicts (often brought
by women, whose rights were usurped by family and stranger alike),80
determined the status of peasants deeds of usufruct (tapu), and settled questions of irrigation, cultivation rights, and personal property
within villages.81
We might detect a certain bias in judgments in favor of revenue
agents generally and timar holders in particular.82 The timar system,
indeed, still furnished the prevailing model of relationships between
tax lord and peasant. As the possessor (mutassarf ) of the contracted
rights over tax collection in a designated village, the tax farmer was
entitled to that which was due the sipahi, as described in ancient
registers (tahrir-i tik defterleri ).83 These rents included income from
nes on criminal oenses, such as the penalty for causing accidental death (resm-i crm-i cinyet), from the feudal tax on marriage (resm-i
arsne), and from varieties of cash and converted labor dues bundled together under the so-called bd-i hav (wind-of-the-air) taxes.84

77
Nonetheless, there were many cases of overlapping jurisdictional rights involving malikne, timar, vakf, and ocaklk. DA II:279; DA I:68; DA III:173.
78
DA I:134, 199, 206, 219; DA II:97.
79
MMD 9486:6.
80
See also DA II:94; DA III:141; and DA III:143, which concerns a certain
Emine Hatun petitioning Istanbul over a iftlik in a village in Pertek in 1766.
81
DA III:195; DA II:192; MMD 9486:6.
82
DA II:315. In 176061, this included a mlk iftlik and ninety-one peasants,
which the state declared a crown estate, part of the havass- hmayun and not private property (mlk).
83
Gen, Osmanl Maliyesinde Malikne Sistemi, 28488.

145

The peasant paid taxes on the produce of vegetable gardens (ba[t)


and fruit and almond trees.85 On land producing cotton, the tax lord
collected a tithe, or {r, of one-tenth the weight of the raw cotton
harvested.86 Commonly, the tithe on grains was either one-fth or
one-sixth of the harvest.87 So-called large elds (at times called iftlik) were usually taxed at the higher rate of one-fth.88
If decentralization often left peasants to the mercy of tax farmers
and landlords or to fend for themselves against marauding bandits
and rapacious revenue agents, it also allowed them to eke out minimal
advantages from momentary lapses in the states attention. Villagers
fought hard to retain certain forms of autonomy or rights of common use that landlords attempted to wrest from them. In the Aegean
region, the struggle with landlords revolved around the status of common elds (koru).89 In Diyarbekir, peasants defended time-honored
methods of paying taxes. In one petition, a malikne contractor, Molla
Musa, pleaded for state backing in his dispute with villagers. The
peasants had refused his demands for tithes, insisting that they would
continue to pay on the basis of the old lump-sum payment (maktu)
and not on the basis of the tithe. Undoubtedly, they preferred the
lump sum as a means of distributing the burden as they saw t.
Because harvests had not been assessed for some time, the lump sum
probably represented a smaller amount than tithe rate. Despite the
peasants resistance, Istanbul issued a decision favoring the tax farmer.
The tithe was xed at the rate of one in ve.90
Peasants such as the villagers of Ak Viran in the district of Eastern Amid turned to the courts too for remedies against illegal taxation and exorbitant rates demanded by malikne contractors.91 They
complained of arbitrary imposts, redundant demands for avrz and
other illegal payments (salyne) by subcontractors such as the agent
of Shaykh Mahmud, one of three shareholders in a village in the

84

DA II:23.
DA III:141.
86
DA I:127; DA III:4.
87
Compare Gksu canton (DA II:214) in 1760 with Savur (DA I:199) in 1750
and the iftlik in Ergani (DA I:134) in 1748.
88
DA II:16.
89
Nagata, Tarihte ynlar, 100.
90
DA II:26; also in Tokat (1714) MMD 3139:188.
91
DA I:244. On the maktu see also Halil (nalck, Military and Fiscal Transformation in the Ottoman Empire, 16001700, Archivum Ottomanicum 6 (1980): 334.
85

146

district of apakur,92 by heads of tribal hkmet,93 or by provincial


authorities and ocers.94 Yet justice did not come quickly for peasants. In 1754, the state nally responded to complaints made by the
villagers of E[il against two malikne holders, Tosyalio[lu and Mustafa
A[a, who had been taking duplicate taxes since 1729.95 In another
case, orders from Istanbul simply arrived too late to protect the villagers in a district of Paul. Six men met death and nine women
were raped at the hands of their aggressors.96
Given Istanbuls poor record, what prompted peasants to continue
to seek redress through the kads court in Amid, Harput, or Mardin?
Did the benevolent image of the sultan from afar disassociate him
from his immediate representative, the revenue collector, and give
villagers the illusion that imperial intercession might protect them?
Outgoing judgments suggest that peasants might nd a champion in
the courts. However, without discounting their impulse to render a
just decision, we must also remember that by restricting scal interlopers, judges and bureaucrats also safeguarded the rights of contractors and property holders.97 An injured party in Istanbul might
tip the scale of justice in the peasants direction. A avu{ at the Porte
for example, obtained a judgment against the Gksu secretary (ktib)
Elhac Hseyin, the on-site subcontractor of his 65,123 ake estate,
who had been collecting taxes in contravention of the imperial register.98 Hseyin, another Istanbul ocer, brought suit against the
kethda of Siirt, Elhac Ahmedo[lu Hseyin, whom he accused of illegally taking taxes from his aggregate mukatat, ocially valued at
10,000 kuru{ a year.99 In any event, to an Istanbul bureaucrats who
believed that every other provincial ocer was a bandit, no stretch
of the imagination was required to believe the cultivators complaints.100
Competition over peasant surplus was erce, not only because of
a surfeit of armed actors in the countryside but also because of the
92

DA II:241.
DA II:250; DA III:141; DA I:16.
94
DA III:434; DA II:218; DA I:160.
95
DA II:42.
96
DA I:160.
97
DA II:93; DA I:26.
98
DA II:21; DA I:108.
99
DA II:216.
100
DA II:23. Be{ir, also of Istanbul, accused the entire provincial administration
from the mir-i mirn, the mir alay, the mtesellim, and the voyvoda, to the alay beyi
of routine, illegal intervention in his contracted villages.
93

147

narrow margin between legal taxes and subsistence. Even in the best
of times legal taxation represented only the tip of the iceberg of
quasi-legitimate payments cultivators paid to those holding land as
contract or tax ef. The private accounts of an Istanbul courtier
from 1728 to 1737 concerning our share-croppers (bizim ekiciler)
for villages, apparently in coastal Anatolia, provide some idea of this
burden: farmers paid not only annual revenues from olive oil, barley, and wheat but also special fees such as the pi{in akesi, taken in
cash or in kind, in addition to payments of interest on previous
loans.101 Peasants were often unable to meet their annual taxes and
required loans of seed, animals, or equipment to make the next
planting. Money lending by tax farmers trapped the peasant in a
cycle of debt. It also anchored the contractors claims for generations because Ottoman judges recognized villagers debt and held
them liable for repayment of principal and interest even after the
contract lapsed or passed to another party.102
Such conditions might drive cultivators to take drastic actions. We
know the names of the inhabitants of Misr Kale village in the district of Ergani who declared a strike, refusing to pay tithes during
the famine years of 1759, 1760, and 1761. Bilalo[lu Ali, (brahimo[lu
Mustafa, }eyho[lu Kara Ali, Kurt Hseyino[lu Ali, Mecnuno[lu
Mecnun, and Osmano[lu Hasan all suered the consequences: beatings and even death.103 Others voted with their feet, eeing tax-lord
oppression and debt.104 Not a few, like the peasants of the district
of Hani who headed toward so-called asker iftlikler (perhaps some
form of ocaklk?) may have sought the promise of better soil and
lower rents.105 In response to two military ocers who complained
that the villagers from their malikne holdings under the jurisdiction

101
D.B}M 1624:6566. Compare Abdul-Karim Rafeq, Changes in the Relationship
between the Ottoman Central Administration and the Syrian Provinces in the
Sixteenth to the Eighteenth Centuries, in Studies in Eighteenth Century Islamic History,
ed. Thomas Na and Roger Owen (Carbondale: Southern Illinois University Press,
1977), 5377.
102
Compare Margaret Meriwether, Urban Notables and Rural Resources in
Aleppo, 17701830, IJTS 4 (1987): 6972; Abdel Nour, Introduction lhistorie urbaine
de la Syrie Ottomane, 39495.
103
DA III:9. A peasant who was accused of rebelliousness in Ergani was sentenced to exile. Yksel, 17761794 Tarihli Maaden Emini Defteri, 11315.
104
In the district of Savur in 1746, peasants had already deserted a makt settlement of 2,000 ake awarded as a malikne. DA I:26162.
105
DA III:283.

148

of the Diyarbekir voyvodalk had ed to so-called military estates,


Istanbul ruled pragmatically. The deputy justices of neighboring towns
and the kad of Amid were instructed to inform landlords in the
region to return all peasants who had been resident in their new
villages for less than ten years and were still not registered in the
avrz lists for that region.106 In one of the more dramatic incidents,
a 1765 order alerted authorities at the Mediterranean port of Iskenderun to be on the lookout for peasants who, having ed from Be{ir,
a janissary who held the malikne mukataa on the village of Kara
Ceylan, might attempt to seek passage to Thrace by ship.107
Peasant ight, in addition to the terrifying impact of the plagues
of 1762 and 1800, put labor at a premium during the second half
of the century.108 The need to exert new forms of social control in
order to assure a stable labor force in agriculture also helps explain
the high tolerance for local tax farmers, particularly in the West
Asian provinces. The holders of life-term contracts in Diyarbekir
made up a socially heterogeneous group that included members of
the ulema, local ocers, and town gentry or yan.109 If we follow
transactions in a sample of contracts found in our registerfourteen
tax-farm villages in the districts of Hani, Amid, ermik, Savur, and
Tercilwe see as well a tendency to retain shares within families
over several generations.110 Notable, too, in the last decades of the
eighteenth century and rst decades of the nineteenth, is the appearance of a new locution, resident in the village, which follows the
name of the last generation of contractors.111
106
DA II:222. They ed to former tribal lands, in Hani, Tercil; the state contacted the deputy judges of Mehran and Atak, as well as Eastern and Western
Amid, with descriptions of the former inhabitants of the village of Cevre named
Musa, Osman, Resul, another Osman, and the sons of the Circassian who had
left to settle in some towns and villages and asker iikler, and ordered that in
whatever region they were found they should be removed and sent back and resettled in their own villages. (See DA III:116; DA III:132; DA IV:84.)
107
DA III:129.
108
Flight was a problem throughout the Asian provinces. See Yucel zkaya,
Osmanl Imparatorlu[unda XVIII. Yuzylda G Sorunu, Ankara University DTC
Fakultesi, Tarih Arastrmalar Dergisi 14 (1983): 171203.
109
Salzmann, Measures of State, 17375. MMD 1637:730; MMD 3677:48.
In 1703, 195 individual contracts were awarded in Diyarbekir; 259 in Aleppo; and
210 in Tokat. In contrast, only 222 were awarded in all of the Balkans.
110
Villages in Diyarbekir over the period 171491 (MMD 9518:14, 15, 18, 20,
27, 38, 40, 42, 45, 50; not all of these entries had sucient data to include in this
analysis).
111
Our register does not tell who these individuals arewere they townsmen

149

In contrast to the social makeup of contractors in the Balkans,


Cyprus, and Anatolia, where janissary ocers predominated, Diyarbekirs ulema made a strong showing among the ranks of smaller
rural contractors.112 Religious ocials and dignitaries maintained a
parallel administrative network far into the countryside, serving as
village imams and deputy judges (naibs) or participating in lodges of
various tarikat in smaller towns.113 Forty-one of the 268 shareholders in villages located in Hani, Amid, and Savur carried the title of
seyyid in 178788.114
Although the ulema might have found it more dicult to summon force to defend their interests, moral authority often weighed
on their side.115 Knowledge of the intricacies of both Ottoman and
Islamic law made them better able to take their battle to the courts.
Indeed, failing to nd justice in the provincial court circuit or even
at the Porte, they often appealed their cases to the }eyh"l-(slm.116
We can appreciate the value of such legal standing in a dispute
over the legitimate title to a contract that pitted one of the citys
gentry families against the sons of the leading Sha"i dignitary. A

who had resettled in the countryside, yeoman farmers, or village heads? However,
their presence in the villages themselves during the last decades of life-term contracting coincides with the emergence of the class of village strongmen (the agha
or a[a) who gure in subsequent Kurdish agrarian history. Haim Gerber, The
Social Origins of the Modern Middle East (Boulder: Lynne Rienner, 1987), 114.
112
For the ulema in Aleppo: Mohammad Tahazde, a former nakib"l-e{rf (representative of the descendants of the Prophet), alone possessed 18.5 percent of the
total state contracts, much in the fertile district of Jabal Sima'an. The recent cataloging of provincial nance records holds must promise. See, for example, D.B}MMLK 1:13 (Hazine-i Musul) berat awarded to Dervis Seyyid Mehmet from among
the ulema for half a share in a eld (mezraa) (173031).
113
DA IV:168 concerns the appointment of an imam in a town outside Diyarbekir
in 178687.
114
MMD 9566 (178687).
115
DA II:104. Three Naqshbandi shaykhs named Mustafa, Mehmed, and Sadrullah
put a better-armed sipahi, Osman, on the defensive, forcing him to turn to the state
to ascertain whether their contract on Krk Paykar, with its twelve registered peasants and two iftliks (valued at 8,811 ake) in Ergani, overlapped with his own 11,450
ake timar at Tuna Viran.
116
A certain seyyid, Mhiddin of Palu (DA II:237), insisted on his rights concerning an iltizam, bolstered by a fetv (religious opinion) issued in his favor by the
}eyh"l-(slm. Molla Seyyid Hseyin, who held a malikne mukataa in the eastern
district of Amid, was granted permission to pass these rights to his son, along with
a fruit tree grove (DA I:17). A woman named Soya Hatun appealed to the state
for protection against the demands of a certain malikne holder who claimed her
private eld; she received an opinion that was to be put into eect by the state
authorities (DA I:237; DA II:35).

150

1786 report (takrir) sent to the treasurer in Istanbul tells of mer


Pa{azde Elhac Mehmed Ref "i Beys contract on the taxes of the
village of (drisl. He had purchased it at auction on behalf of himself and his sons Mustafa, Nurullah, (brahim, and Salih Bey. His
bid of 2,500 kuru{ also included shares in another malikne contract
in Hani, all of which came to auction after the death of its former
owner, Seyyid Mehmed Efendi Piranizde.117
Notwithstanding the award of new certicates, Piranizdes sons
successfully reclaimed their patrimony. They contended that the auction had been made improperly. The court should have informed
them, as children of the deceased contractor, of the impending resale.
Now they requested, according to the terms of the malikneor in
the words of another member of the ulema, these Islamic malikne
contracts (mezkr el-(slm olan malikneler)118rst option on the shares
and, accordingly, invalidation of the earlier sale.119 Their request was
granted. Of course it was not inconsequential that the petitioners
included none other than Seyyid Mahmud, the Shai mufti, perhaps the most inuential member of the ulema in Amid.120 He and
other members of his family enjoyed special stipends from the provincial treasury.121

Government in the Vernacular


Although our register does little to aid us in our search for coordinates and addresses, auction records and ledgers of new certicates
do provide the names and a few other pertinent details about new
contractors. Among the rst to purchase tax farms in the Diyarbekir
region was Shaykh Kasim Efendi, one of the two muftis of Amid,
who invested a sizable sum, 310 kuru{, for the lease on a village,
Monla (molla, in Diyarbekirs dialect). Mustafa and his partner, Ebu
Bekir, acquired a village contract, as did Sa"ad Shaykh Ahmed,

117

CM 28,020.
CM 14,147.
119
CM 28,020.
120
In addition to the quarter share in (drisl village
held the contracting rights to another three villages in
total investment of 753 kuru{ at the time of death. CM
121
D.B}M 6772. His share was half an Amid mud
wheat our, as was his sister Rakiyes (Raziye?) and his
118

in Eastern Amid, he also


the district of Hani for a
14,147.
(220 cubic decimeters) of
two brothers Mesuds and

151

Shaykh of the Gl{eni order, based in Mardin. Members of the gentry, the local bureaucracy, and the janissary corps appear in the register: Mehmet Emin and (brahim ibn Abdelrahman of Amid; Black
Ali, a scion of the Milan tribe; Murtaza A[a, captain of an auxillary infantry unit (sekban), and Mehmet, the clerk of the local tari
station. Some, like Ahmed and Mustafa traveled to Amid from the
town of ermik; others, like Abdullah and Suleyman, lived in the
quarter near the Ulu Mosque in the provincial capital.122
The rst auctions in Amid, in 1696 and 1697, took place under
the direction of the sales agent Abdulkader A[a, a kapcba{ dispatched from Istanbul.123 Despite rivalries over trade routes and
administrative preeminence, the provincial capitala city of some
fty thousand inhabitantsstill overshadowed the other towns of the
upper Tigris-Euphrates in size and wealth.124 Having served as the
capital of medieval Islamic dynasties, Amid retained the major cultural institutions of the region, including mosques, academies, churches,
charitable foundations, and a new library founded in 1769.125 It was
home to two muftis, a Hane, who represented the ocial Ottoman
school, and a Shai scholar who ministered to the large Kurdish
population. Christian leadership represented several denominations,
including the Armenian Orthodox; the Syrian ( Jacobite) rite; the
uniate Nestorians, or Chaldean Church; and Catholics. By the early
nineteenth century, a dwindling number of Jewish households lived
there as well.126 These workmen, merchants, traders, artisans, spinners, and manufacturers made the city one of Ottoman Asias major
manufacturers of textiles and rened copper.

Mehmeds, among thirty-six other distinguished members of the ulema and brotherhood or tarikat. In the same year (17991800), total payments in local salaries,
stipends, and subsidies from the local budget came to 5255.5 kuru{ or 630,660 ake.
122
MMD 3677:13, 1215.
123
MMD 10,143:233.
124
Van Bruinessen, Evliya elebi in Diyarbekir, 3334.
125
Ylmazelik, XIX. Yzyln ilk Yarsnda, 208.
126
The rst Carmelite mission in Basra was established by the Portuguese in
1622; a Catholic Presbyter was found in Diyarbekir by 1730. (Herman Gollancz,
ed., Chronicle of Events between the Years 1623 and 1733 Relating to the Settlement of the
Order of Carmelites in Mesopotamia [Bassura] [London: Oxford University Press, 1927],
634.) Walter J. Fischel, ed. and trans., Unknown Jews in Unknown Lands: The Travels
of Rabbi David DBeth Hillel (18241832) (New York: Ktav Publishing House, 1973),
7274. It is dicult to gauge the size of the Christian population in the eighteenth
century. After the 1819 uprising, which devasted the population, the survivors were in
roughly equal numbers Muslim and Christian. M. Fahrettin Krzo[lu, Kara-midte

152

During the eighteenth century, whenever special envoys from


Istanbul entered the city, perhaps as Elhac Sleyman A[a did in
178788, to investigate the status of malikne holdings and to collect
the special tax due for the war eort before moving on toward
Mosul,127 they must have repaired to the governors compound. It
sat protected in a citadel nested inside the citys massive basalt ramparts. The envoy might have called the citys notables and ocers
to the reception hall of the palace, where they also gathered to welcome a new governor on the rst Friday after his arrival.128 Despite
its grandeur, with rooms for the hundreds of retainers who awaited
the governors appointed from Istanbul, for much of the eighteenth
century the palace remained vacant. Turnover in appointed candidates was highest at the turn-of-the eighteenth century. Subsequently,
although appointments were made more regularly, governors frequently arrived late. In their place, governors themselves would designate a deputy (mtesellim) who frequently served out much of the
one-year term of oce.129
Even without the governor and perhaps much of the complement
of hundreds of clerks, servants, and guards who accompanied him
to his post, city government continued to function.130 The residences
of the kad, the mufti, the captain of the local gendarmerie (the janissary serdar), and the voyvoda, along with a jail, were all located inside
the citadel.131 Many of the leading gentrythe }eyhzde, Mftizde,

1819 da A"yandan }eyhzdeler"in ncl[nde Milli Deli-Behram Pa{a"ya Kar{


Ayaklanma Ve Sonucu, Kara mid Dergisi 24 (195658): 351. Ylmazelik, Diyarbakr,
1057.
127
MMD 9565:1.
128
See Hrand D. Andreasyan translation of P. G. Iniciyan (17581833)s travelogue, XVIII. Asrda (stanbul (Istanbul: Istanbul Fethi Derne[i, 1956). Ylmazelik
(Diyarbakr, 353) was able to locate a copy of Abdulgani Buldaks unpublished history of Diyarbekir, El-Cezire"nin Muhtasar Tarihi, in a private collection.
129
Diyarbekir Salnamesi, 2529. (brahim Metin Kunt, Bir Osmanl Valisinin Yllk Gelir
Gideri: Diyarbakr, 167071, No. 162 (Istanbul: Bo[azii niversitesi Yaynlar, 1981),
36. Only two (Bigal Mehmed Pasha, 16991701, and Topal Yusuf Pasha, 17023)
of nineteen candidates appointed actually served out their full tenure. There are
some exceptions: Kprlzde Abdullah Pashas wife and daughter, Zbeyde and
Leyla, were buried in Diyarbekir in the Nebi mosque in 1718. See Metin Szen,
Diyarbakr"da Trk Mimarisi (Istanbul: Ara{trma Enstits, 1971), 18990.
130
Ylmazelik, Diyarbakr, 2023. Among the residents were the divan efendisi,
voyvoda, mtesellim, ttnc a[as, kapclar kethudas, {amdan a[as, ba{ avu{ a[a, i ukadar
a[a, kaftan a[as, silahdar a[a, alemdar a[a, hazinedar a[a, miftah a[a, pe{kir a[a, ibrikdar
a[a, kahya, imam efendi, delilba{, haytaba{, ba{ ukadar a[a, ikinci kavvas, and mhrba{.
131
Compare Jean-Pierre Thieck, Dcentralisation ottomane et armation urbaine

153

Kadzde, inarzde, and Gevranl-zde132had two-story mansions


in neighboring quarters.133 The gentry formed a pool of candidates
for government oces, including that of deputy governor (mtesellim),
voyvoda, nakib"l-e{rf, and {ehir kedhdas.134 Together with the local
religious authorities and elders of the guilds, these men and organizations carried out the day-to-day functions of state: the administration of justice, collection of taxes, regulation of the economy, and
policing of the citys quarters and surrounding countryside.
Whereas rule was fragmented in the countryside and subject, as
the state entered contests over rents and landed resources as a distant party, in the city there developed a more synthetic version of
home rule. Like a dialect that consists of an imperial syntax and a
local vocabulary, vernacular government entailed a gradual transformation of the character and content of rule that diered depending on which branches of urban administration were aected.135
In some instances, vernacular government involved relinquishing
key duties and oces to local appointees. Imperial justice serves as
a case in point. Ocially, the judge (kad), leading professors (mderris), and muftis were appointed by the religious authorities of Istanbul.
The judgeship in Amid was a prestigious one. It was one of the top
forty posts in the empire.136 Occupying the rst rung up in fairly
prominent circuit of appointments, Mektbi-zde Nrullh Efendi,
who died in oce in Diyarbekir, had also held important positions
in Manisa, Baghdad, Ktahya, and Filibe.137
Despite the fact that this judgeship was a mahrec-level appointment,
Istanbul ulema grew increasingly reluctant to follow Nrullh Efendi.
The road across Anatolia was long, arduous, and dangerous for a

Alep la n du XVIIIme sicle, in Mouvements communautaires et spaces urbains au


Machreq, ed. Mona Zakaria et al. (Beirut: Centre dtudes et de Recherches sur le
Moyen-Orient Contemporain, 1985), 125.
132
Ibid. Kunt, Bir Osmanl Valisinin Yllk, 52.
133
For a plan of the city, see Mkrimin H. Ynan, Diyarbekir, (A 1: 6034.
134
For a detailed description of the both the military-administrative and judicialreligious hierarchies in the city, see Ylmazelik, Diyarbakr, 185244.
135
See Barbir, From Pasha to Efendi.
136
On these positions, see Zil, The Politics of Piety. In the seventeenth century,
a position in the medrese was at the top of the hierarchy and its teacher was paid
a 3040 ake daily salary. Van Bruinessen, Evliya elebi in Diyarbekir, 46.
137
esmi-zde Mustafa Re{id, esmi-zde Tarihi, ed. Bekir Ktko[lu (Istanbul:
Istanbul niversitesi Edebiyat Fakltesi, 1959), 46, 59, 81, 26; Ylmazelik, Diyarbakr,
225.

154

man and his family. Moreover, Amid did not lack for well-trained
scholars and lawyers who had graduated from its many ne religious
academies. Thus, Istanbul appointees began to delegate their authority and duties, albeit at the lower rank of deputy judge, naib, to local
dignitaries.138
Graduates from the Amid academies also held temporary and fulltime positions in other municipal oces, including clerkships in the
courts. Occasionally, as we saw in chapter 2, a talented and ambitious
man might make his way into the ranks of the central-state bureaucracy. Perhaps the increased opportunity for service within the province
contributed to a lack of outward mobility. The Porte certainly recognized the substantive contribution of the ulema to the order of
urban life, and it rewarded Amids scholars and the leaders of the
local Gl{eni and Naqshbandiyya brotherhoods with special stipends
and honoraria. This was a regular part of the voyvodalk budget under
the heading of du"-gyn, guardians of local morality.139 Their taxexempt status was reconrmed by the }eyh"l-(slm, who also veried
claims of membership in the e{rf, descendants of the Prophet.140
Rather than being strictly representatives of the central state, the
provincial ocers who staed the citadel and the fortresses of the
province and who acted as the urban gendarmarie functioned as a
bridge between Istanbul and Amid. Although there is no evidence
of a parallel corps of janissaries the so-called yerli recruits, as in
Damascus or Aleppo, the members of Amids corps cultivated connections in many directions. On one hand, they maintained close ties
to central authority, through the governor, who could recommend
promotions to the rank of fortress captain (kale kethdas, dizdar). Local
ocers remembered to oer the captain of the janissary corps in
Istanbul gifts (cize) to obtain new postings, such as Cairo.141 Not

138
Ylmazelik, XIX. Yzyln ilk Yarsnda, 43637, 431. Other court positions, such as ba{katp, also appear to have been lled by local appointees.
139
D.B}M 6772; 7336; 1814; MMD 19,080. Compare with Damascus: Barbir,
Ottoman Rule in Damascus, 81; Van Bruinessen, Evliya elebi in Diyarbekir, 51; Hamid
Algar, The Naqshbandi Order. A Preliminary Survey of Its History and Signicance,
Studia Islamica 44 (1976): 12352.
140
DA III:216; DA III:158; DA III:15354; DA III:55; DA I:16. This in part
explains the ambiguous role of the local ulema during this period; they actively
sought perquisites like tax farms and malikne and yet often seconded petitions by
peasants against spurious taxation. DA I:25.
141
Jane Hathaway, Years of Ocak Power: The Rise of the Qazdagli Household
and the Transformation of Ottoman Egypts Military Society, 16701750 (Egypt)

155

a few of Istanbuls kapkullar may have traced their ancestry to the


region, including Emin Mehmed A[a and his brothers (brahim,
Mustafa, and Mehmed, sons of Abdlvehab A[a, who bid successfully on the oce of the registrar (kitaplk) of Diyarbekir (1,230 kuru{);
Ahmed and Mehmed A[a who won an aggregate mukatat in the
district of Siirt (3,200 kuru{); and mer A[a, son-in-law of the head
of the mounted janissary corps (sipahi a[as), who placed a 750 kuru{
bid on another provincial tax farm.142 On the other hand, janissaries
posted to Diyarbekir became well integrated in the urban and rural
fabric. Participating in the life-lease system in town and countryside,143 they must have passed at least some of these shares and
investments, along with their connections to the military establishment, to their male ospring.144
The contracting of agrarian revenues generally and urban oces
specically was another way in which Amids government took on
a vernacular cast. Yet not all of the citys key oces were sold o.
Many ocials continued to be chosen directly by the central-state
authorities or in consultation with the urban population. This included
some of the key positions overseeing the urban market, such as the
gmrk emini, director of the local tari station; the ihtisab nzr, who
was in charge of collecting of guild taxes; the muhtar, who was responsible for public security and decorum within the city; and the {ehir
kethdas, who helped adjudicate urban and rural tax burdens and at
times aided in recruiting part-time soldiery.145
The nature of the position voyvoda of Amid, chief intendant of the
province, dees simple classication.146 Over the century, the voyvoda
(Ph.D. diss., Princeton University, 1992), 8283; and (. H. Uzunar{l, Osmanl
Devleti Te{kilatndan Kapkulu Ocaklar. Acemi Oca[ ve Yenieri Oca[ (Ankara: TTK
Basmevi, 1943), vol. 1, 32930.
142
MMD 4748:7980.
143
MMD 3677:13, 1215. MMD 9518:67, 101. Two janissaries within the inner
court, perhaps from Amid or certainly relying on their local connections, accepted
the contract on the excise tax on coee (tahmis-i kahve-i Diyarbekir) in the city in lieu
of salary as well as the secretariat of the janissaries of Diyarbekir (kitabet-i gilmann-
Amid ).
144
Ylmazelik, Diyarbakr, 23, 208. There were about three hundred soldiers
posted to the citadel. Compare with Abdul-Karim Rafeq, The Local Forces in
Syria in the Seventeenth and Eighteenth Centuries, 304. An expropriation order
for Ahmad b. (brahim, a janissary from Amid who died on campaign between
Belgrade and Nish in 1739 (D}S 315:2023).
145
Musa adrc, Tanzimatn Sralarnda Trkiye"de Ynetim (18261839),
Belleten 51 (1987): 121540.
146
In 1670, the position was held by a certain Kurd Mehmed A[a, who turned

156

absorbed many of the functions of the executive in urban administration, in addition to his tasks within the larger agrarian economy.
The position was held by both central-state and local appointees,
generally for periods of two to three years. Although the exact composition of his charges changed over the century, among his chief
responsibilities were the local tari station, the main dye house, the
wheat scales, the black stamp tax on cloth coming into the city, and
many villages and elds. Some voyvoda derived their income from a
share of the prots on the aggregate tax farm as subfarmers; others
were salaried employees of the central state. In 179798, the salary
allotted to the voyvoda was 22,500 kuru{ per year. According to the
states calculus, this equaled the prots on a quarter share of the
contract itself.147
In truth, the central state was particularly loath to delegate its
authority to the gentry in the area of regulation of the local market. The Porte directed the ocer who conducted the rst sale of
contracts in Amid to withhold the revenues from the tari station,
stamp tax, dye house, and market dues and other urban duties from
the local public auction.148 Although military ocers and Diyarbekir
gentry did obtain some prized commercial revenue contracts, Istanbuls
motive was not only to reserve such high-yielding contracts for the
privileged central state market;149 it was also to retain direct control
over the urban market itself.
Despite such concerns, contracting did aect the organization of
economic life and, by extension, touched the many workers and
tradesmen who populated the city. The primary modality of mem-

the income (voyvoda kalemiyesi ) over to the governor. At this time, the voyvoda was
responsible for collecting the avrz and the bedel-i nzl; he received fees for the
military district (sancak) and military appointments (tahvil ); the son, Yunus Bey was
appointed the revenue agent (emin) of the stamp tax on cloth (damga) as well as
supervisor of the eske (once the estate of the provincial defterdar). Kunt, Bir Osmanl
Valisinin Yllk Gelir Gideri, 42,49, 53, 70, 204, 255, 28081, 329, 159, 144; CD 2819
(1777) suggests a three-year appointment. See also Cezar, Osmanl Tarihinde Levendler,
45456; Ylmazelik, Diyarbakr, 2003.
147
D.B}M 6538 (1798) audit of the income of the voyvodalk from 1797 onward.
148
MMD 10,143:233.
149
Nonetheless, local bidders were successful in this sector. They included Kk
Ali, whose large farm on the excise tax (bac- ubur) was later rescinded; an associate of Hadarzde, Mehmed Emin the janissary Mustafa, the avu{ a[as Kara Ali;
as well as a merchant (bazirgn) and Kasim Efendi one of the two muftis of Amid.
MMD 3139:247, 369. For registers of certicates see the kalemiye register, MMD
777:21.

157

bership in the urban community was not only the mosque or the
church but also the trade association, or esnaf.150 Craftsmen, shopkeepers, and small-time traders all participated in such associations.
Although we lack a complete roll of all such professions or a full
description of their organization, a 1792 register of taxes carried out
the kad lists forty-two individual associations. They include wholesale and retail businesses such as coee sellers and cotton wholesalers ( pembeiyn), dealers in ready-made goods (oturak), and associations
that come closest to the notion of a guild, such as the manufacturers of mixed cotton and silk cloth (bezzazn). At this time, the highest dues were paid by the wealthiest tradesmen, such as the grocers
(bakkaln) and dyers (boyaciyn), and by a guild whose trade was probably the most widely practiced in the city, the weavers (hallacn).151
A traveler who visited the city in 1815 estimated that there were
some 1,500 workshops, among them 500 were devoted to cottonstamping, 300 to leather working, and 100 to ironsmithing.152
The contracting of guild dues aected both guild leaders or shaykhs
and the rank and le in unpredictable ways. To the extent that it
turned the position of head of the guild into a venal oce, it may
merely have given ocial sanction to a preexisting trend toward concentrating the position of shaykh, and therefore power within the
guilds, among certain families.153 This seems to have been the case
with the position of maktut of the cotton-uers (cullahn). It was sold
in 1715 for 100 kuru{ to two men wealthy enough to have made
the pilgrimage to Mecca, residents of the quarter named for the
Iskender Pasha Mosque, and their nephew, who lived near the Mardin
Gate. The family retained at least a 25 percent share of the contract

150
Gabriel Baer, Ottoman Guilds: A Reassessment, in Trkiye"nin Sosyal ve Ekonomik Tarihi (10711920), ed. Osman Okyar and Halil (nalck (Ankara: Meteksan/
Hacettepe University, 1980), 96; Haim Gerber, Guilds in Seventeenth-Century
Anatolia Bursa, Asian and African Studies 11 (1976): 5986. Compare this case with
Manisa; see M. a[atay Uluay, XVII inci Yzylda Manisa"da Ziraat, Ticaret ve Esnaf
Te{kilt (Istanbul: Resimli Ay Matbaas, 1942).
151
MMD 9519:81; see also D.B}M 1069:4. In 1717, the total protoindustrial
installations in nk{ yielded 10,200 kuru{ in taxes; the dye house alone was worth
1,025 kuru{. See Ylmazelik, (Diyarbakr, 60510) for another list.
152
Buckingham, Travels in Mesopotamia including a Journey from Aleppo, 80, 195, 214.
153
In an important manufacturing city such as Aleppo, the intrafamilial nature
of guild appointments in this period is very pronounced; for empirewide trends, see
Tuncer Baykara, Osmanl Ta{ra Te{kilatnda XVIII. Yzylda Grev ve Grevliler (Anadolu)
(Ankara: Vakar Genel Mdrl[ Yaynlar, 1990), 11837.

158

until 1780.154 More research is required to determine the status of


the contractors involved in the guild dues (mstahak) of the weavers
and dyers, both quite substantial, which were auctioned as malikne
in 1715 and 1725, respectively.155
In other cases, the sale of oces, particularly those aecting wholesale distribution, might have sped the transition of military ocers
into tradesmen. Three janissariesMehmed Emin A[a, Mustafa A[a,
and another ocer in the retinue of an Azizzdeheld the title to
the venal oce of head of the brokers of linen and red cotton cloth
and other stus as a malikne mukataa in 1721, for which they pledged
a surety of 200 kuru{, and committed themselves to an annual payment of 10,000 ake.
Precisely because of the high return on many of these urban contracts, they also attracted central-state investors. However, Istanbul
elites who purchased contracts on Amids guild oces needed to be
wary: they had to contend with the politics of the provincial city
and with the elders of the association who enjoyed the backing of
their fellows in the esnaf.156 Indeed, investments from Istanbul raised
new concerns about the autonomy of the esnaf.157 Although the court
might rule in favor of a high-ranking member of the Istanbul elite,
the judge could not entirely ignore their opinion without risking a
reaction from tradesmen. For example, members of the association
of weavers of kutnu, a costly fabric of mixed bers complained that
the subfarmer who administered the farm on their taxes for the
Istanbul malikne holder, Seyyid Ali, had overstepped his authority,
committing cruelty and injustice by interfering in guild aairs.
Championed by the voyvoda and the judge, the guildsmen sought a
change in sta. They were granted their wish: the oce was restored
to a local contractor.158

154

MMD 9518:68; MMD 9519:102.


MMD 9518:62, 68; MMD 9519:95, 102.
156
CM 14,097. One of Istanbuls mderris, Seyyid San"allah Efendi, petitioned in
1786, complaining that his share on the weavers association dues was being mismanaged by his local partner, Sleyman so and so, who engaged in pilfering
monies and illegally collecting duties ( fuzul ahz ve kabz). Despite holding a smaller
share (only one-fth), the local partners familiarity and proximity gave them undeniable advantages. The complaint prompted an audit by an ocer from the palace,
the silah{r Abdullah A[a, and a ruling in favor of the Istanbul partner.
157
A malikne contract conferred upon the position of head shaykh ({eyhlik ) of the
guilds was awarded in 1743.
158
CB 1375. Elhac Osman had held the oce of kethda or steward of the mar155

159

Although the state was wary of relinquishing direct control over


oces that regulated the urban market as a whole, over time select
contracts did come to auction. Among them were the venal oce
of the secretariat of the tari station (kitbet-i gmrk) and the directorship of the market and other [whole] sellers in the market. In
1777, the position of second registrar of the Diyarbekir customs
(kitbet-i sani gmrk- Diyarbekir) was sold to a local bidder, Seyyid
Hseyin Efendi, who later passed it to a son, Dervi{ Ali.159
Among urban tax farms, the tari system not only stands out as
one of the single most important sources of revenue within the large
block of tax farms administered directly by the voyvoda. It was also
a retaining wall of rights that ringed the urban economy. Lacking
city charters or ocial recognition of their corporate status, variations in tax liabilities and rights to private property separated the
town from countryside.160 Even villagers within the capital district of
Amid recognized their long-standing subordination to the city. Although
they were exempt from the higher rates of the interurban tari, the
gmrk, town ocials charged them market taxes on the sale of their
grain, animals, and garden vegetables.161 So, too, weavers and spinners who lived in the villages and towns immediately surrounding
Amid (Savur ve Gen ve ermik ve sair kasabt ve kur) were forced to
pay duties on a cheap, unnished cloth called yuban (ham yuban
bezi ), also a tax farm auctioned in the city.162
An annotated tari schedule dating to the period between 1793
and 1814 illustrates the manner in which vernacular government
rested on a fundamental compromise among central-state, regional,
and urban interests.163 Traders in bulk consumer commodities such
ket (bedestan) as a three-year tax farm or iltizam with an annual payment of 25 kuru{
until the farm was converted into a malikne contract.
159
MMD 9518:62, 77; MMD 9519:111.
160
On this point, see Baber Johansen, Amwal Zahira and Amwal Batina: Town
and Countryside as Reected in the Tax System of the Hanate School, in Studia
Arabica and Islamica Festschrift for Ihsan 'Abbas on his 60th Birthday, ed. Widad al-Qadi
(Beirut: American University of Beirut, 1981), 24763.
161
mer Lt Barkan, XV. ve XVI. inci Asrlarda Osmanl Imparatorlu[unda Zira
Ekonominin Hukuk ve Mal Esaslari (Istanbul: Istanbul niversitesi Edebiyat Fakltesi
Trkiyat Enstits Ne{riyat, 1943) vol. 1, 54952.
162
CM 12,742, makt dellllk- yuban bezi der Diyarbekir.
163
KK 5249. The document consists of two main sections: a lengthy itemized
section dating from the 1790s and an appendix dating from 180713, when }eyhzde
(brahim became the de facto ruler of the city. The annotations, which were added
by the judge, appear to have been made after (brahim Pashas death in 1814.

160

as coee, tobacco, aloe, fragrances, and sugar, and even sundry


Indian cotton textiles and twist that were destined for the Istanbul
market, paid low rates of taxation. They were spared all but a minimal transit tax, taken in kind as a percentage of weight.164 By contrast, merchants of specialty goods, which included the most famous
textiles manufactured within the empire itself and which were listed
in a lengthy itemized list within the schedule, paid particularly sti
tolls: ad valorem duties (amediyye) of 5 percent against current value.
Although burdensome for distributors and importers, such taxes
shielded urban artisans. Prot margins were narrow, and it was highquality, local raw materials and regional specialties that helped preserve the artisans share in a highly competitive domestic market.165
Because the conversion of taxes and taris into contracts served
to anticipate revenues without changing the form of the taxation
itself, contracting did little to alter the basic premises of the regions
political economy. Indeed, by reecting older scal jurisdictions, the
award of mlikane leases may have actually helped freeze long-standing
patterns of interaction between town and country, shoring up the
urban monopoly over labor-intensive and value-added specialties.
Tax farmers and the guilds shared interests in maintaining standards,
in collective bargaining for raw materials, and in establishing prices
for goods and services.166
This was particularly true for value-added techniques such as the
dyeing and stamping of cloth. One of the more prestigious and certainly wealthier esnaf, the dyers association, was particularly vigilant
about maintaining its monopoly over dyeing. It had need to be; even

164

Ibid. Indian generic cotton stus (met"i ) (and perhaps yarn) were taxed in
bulk. Kurdistani and Syrian goods warehoused in the city and taxed by animalload (donkey load, 68 para [60 para equaled one kuru{]; camel-load, 820 para; and
horse-load, 34 para), such as soap, mazu dye, henna, and possibly Mosul cloth, and
in the late eighteenth century, the copper processed in the local renery (kalhne),
which was exempt from such taxation. A. S. K. Lambton (Persian Trade Under
the Early Qajars, in Islam and Trade in Asia, ed. D. S. Richards (Oxford: Oxford
University Press, 1970), 221) estimates a camel load as 400 pounds, a mule load
at 240, and a horse load at 130.
165
For the scale of proto-industrialization, see Peter Kriedte, Peasants, Landlords
and Merchant Capitalists: Europe and the World Economy, 15001800 (Warwickshire: Berg
Publishers, 1983), 7076. On the specicity of the regional market in manufactures,
see comments by James Brant, Journey through a Part of Armenia and Asia Minor
in the Year 1835, Journal of the Royal Geographical Society 10 (1841): 383.
166
J. S. Buckingham (Travels in Mesopotamia, 84, 214), notes that stamping cotton
renders the cloth in that state nearly double the price it bears when white.

161

the hamlet of nk{ boasted an active proto-industrial base, including a tannery and a dye house large enough to warrant its own
stamp tax (damga) on cloth.167 There were dye houses in ermik,
Palu, Harput, and Hazzo as well, and important manufactories in
the neighboring cities of Mardin, Ayntab, and Urfa. So, too, centralization of value-added types of industries suited revenue contractors; in 1726, both the dyers association and the voyvoda (whose
charge included the tax farm on the dye house itself ) requested a
rescript from Istanbul to shut down the dye houses that had been
opened in the countryside by baz kur eshab (some owners of
villages).168
In privileging the citys manufactures or, alternatively, penalizing
foreign manufactures whether or not they were sold within the
city, as the tari schedule puts it, participants in the tax-farming
systems were of one accord. City artisans produced many ne textile products, including alaca as well as stus destined for mass consumption such as the imitation cotton chafarjanis, printed textiles,
tent canvas, and a specially dyed red cotton yarn.169 Even as a lively
trade in cotton cloth exported to Europe (import substitutes for Indian
fabric) spurred thread and textile production far into the countryside,170 the tari system to some degree stanched the spread of weaving beyond the city and lessened the protability of goods produced
in smaller towns within the province where costs might have been
lower. A 5 percent import tax was imposed not only on the products of Iran or on those coming from the famous workshops of
Ottoman Aleppo, Damascus, and Bursa but also on the most humble

167
MMD 9519:81; see also D.B}M 1069:4. In 1717, the total protoindustrial
installations of nk{ yielded 10,200 kuru{kuru{kuru{ in taxes yearly; the dye house
alone was worth 1,025 kuru{.
168
MMD 9916:110.
169
The kads glosses above the itemized section of KK 5249 already show considerable discrepancy between the ocial prices and current prices upon which
ad valorem taxes (of 5 percent) were based. In an 1814 report (MMD 10,262:219),
administrators noted that the gross underestimation of tax on Indian cloth resulted
in an eight to ten times underpayment (at the rate of 30 para per batman of goods).
Already in the last decade of the eighteenth century, the actual rates of internal
gmrk stations were subject to much variation, depending on local agreements and
rivalries between regimes. Also, Issawi, The Fertile Crescent, 17879.
170
Katsumi Fukasawa, Toilerie et commerce du Levant au XVIII e sicle dAlep Marseille
(Marseille: Groupe de Recherche et dtudes sur le Proche Orient Centre Regional
de Publication de Marseille, 1985).

162

cottons woven in towns like Mardin, ermik, Hazzo, Palu, and Harput, all within Diyarbekir province itself.171 When entrepreneurial
janissaries attempted to purchase cotton manufactures or perhaps to
engage in forms of putting out in the surrounding countryside,172 the
guilds had no need to rise to the occasion. Instead, the tax farmer
defended the interests of Amids weavers, objecting to the fact that
the janissaries actions allowed them to evade payment of the black
stamp tax (damga- siyah).173
The main impact of tax farming seems to have been to reinforce
the hierarchy of wealth, power, and inuence within the esnaf and the
primacy of the urban market. The privilege of holding such contracts was restricted to Muslims, a symptom of the progress of vernacular government generally. Did this privilege accentuate the
dierences between confessional groups? In economic terms, probably not. By early modern standards, Amid was a fairly integrated
city; one of every three of its townsmen lived in a confessionally
mixed neighborhood.174 Both Muslims and Christians were counted
among the largest esnaf, though they reported to dierent masters,
shaykhs and ostads, respectively.175 Both groups beneted from the
protectionism aorded by the tari system and the emphasis on
maintaining the citys monopoly on value-added, higher-skilled occupations in manufacturing. Contracts embracing aggregate resources
spread liabilities among ordinary tradesmen, whether Muslim, Christian, or Jew. For example, the farm on the taxes on the sale of beeswax and leather (mahsl- rusumt- bal- mum ve arm) actually aected
primary materials for two dierent guilds, one dominated by Muslims
(leather workers), and the other, by Christians (candle makers).176
The question, however, was not merely an economic one. In addition to reinforcing the trend toward the inheritance of oces such
as guild shaykh, which widened the political and economic gap
between rich and poor tradesmen, tax farming must have altered
the expectations of Muslim elites toward government generally. By

171
KK 5249; see also C( 432 (179798), a malikne on the damgha for cloth produced in ar{nacak and Palu.
172
CM 12,742.
173
MMD 10,246:119. In 1804, this tax, combined with the ihtisab, commanded
a bid of 32,000 kuru{.
174
Ylmazelik, Diyarbakr, 3031, 4647, 11517.
175
CZ 1364.
176
MMD 9518:62, 67.

163

becoming contractors themselves, the Muslim gentry interacted, albeit


long distance, with powerful persons in Istanbul and established themselves within local governing circles. Furthermore, although a tax
farm might involve a seemingly insignicant sum, its actual political
clout must be measured in terms of the number of people it aected.
Considering that the majority of Diyarbekirs urban population, male
and female, worked in cotton weaving, as did a large percentage of
the provinces villagers and peasants who spun thread, the small tax
farm on the weighing scales of white cotton twist (maktut- vaznlk
ri{te-i beyaz der Diyarbekir), which netted the state a mere 25 kuru{ a
year, nevertheless yielded considerable dividends, in terms of inuence
and reputation, for the family who held it for three decades from
1726 to 1757.177 How much more so for the contractors of the stamp
tax on colored silk (mahsl- damga- harir-i elvn), the tax farmer of
cloth produced in the mountain and Sa[man (damga- kh ve Sa[man),
the revenue agent who collected the taxes from the leather market
(bazaar- arm- Amid ), or the operators and tax farmer of the tannery
of the city (debba[hane-i Amid), all of whom were local Muslims? If
contracting fostered a new sense of civic partnership especially among
a middle class of Muslim tradesmen-contractors, janissary-brokers,
and hereditary guild shaykhs-revenue collectors, at best it brought
ordinary workers and non-Muslims along in a paternalistic fashion.

Checks and Balances


In reshaping our notion of center and periphery, our ledger casts
a wide net over contractors, claimants, and tax payers. In doing so,
it aids us in resituating the larger-than-life individuals who gure so
prominently in the narratives of the late eighteenth century. Certainly
the emergence of the gentry and magnatesthe derebey, or rural
lords, of Anatolia, the magnates of the Balkans; the tax farming gentry of Syria and the Aegean; and the quasi-autonomous regimes of
Cairo and Baghdad at the geopolitical fringes of the empirewas
also a product of the overarching rhythms of imperial history.178 The

177

MMD 9518:68; MMD 9519:102.


Halil (nalck (Military and Fiscal Transformation, 33132) considers them
a well-dened group. See also Albert Hourani, Ottoman Reform and the Politics
of Notables, in Beginnings of Modernization in the Middle East: The Nineteenth Century,
178

164

contracting out of rural taxes in the form of iltizam or malikne mukatat


facilitated their ascent.179 Grand Vizier Muhsinzde Mehmet Pasha
tried, from his rst term in oce in 1765 and again in 1771, to
forge a direct link between the provincial elite and the state in the
area of military recruitment, food provisions, and munitions.180
If central-state policymakers and historians failed to make ner
distinctions among the gentry, the so-called ayn ve e{rf, modern
researchers, as Engin Akarl argues,181 cannot ignore the fact that
magnates, such as the 'Azms of Damascus and the Jalilis of Mosul,
whose roots lay outside the cities in which they came to power,
served the strategic interests of the state in a dierent manner than
a home-grown urban gentry. Damascus and Mosul were frontier
posts where military might was of paramount concern. By contrast,
in a trading city like Aleppo, rival clans, the Shayhbandaris, the
Hunkrlzde, and the Tahazde, vied over the stewardship of the
main block of tax farms, the muhassllk. These great families were
part of an oligarchy of some one hundred families who held many
of the oces and tax farms in their city and province.182

ed. William R. Polk and Richard L. Chambers (Chicago: University of Chicago


Press, 1968), 4167. (smail Hakk Uzunar{l, apan O[lular, Belleten 38 (1974):
21665.
179
Gen, Osmanl Ekonomisi ve Sava{, 55. In many sectors before 1768, returns
amounted to 35 percent or even 40 percent, and though they declined after 1770
to 1822 percent, this was still a handsome prot (Gen, Osmanl Maliyesinde
Malikne Sistemi, 252). The 'Azm clan could fall back on tax farming networks
as a source of inuence within Damascus and the countryside of Syria and especially in their places of origin in Ma'arrat al-Nu'man and Hama. Abdul-Karim
Rafeq, Economic Relations between Damascus and the Dependent Countryside,
174371, in The Islamic Middle East, 7001900, ed. Abraham Udovitch (Princeton,
N.J.: Darwin Press, 1971), 65455.
180
Yuzo Nagata, Muhsin-zde Mehmed Pa{a ve ynlk Messesesi (Tokyo: Study of
Languages and Cultures of Asia and Africa Monograph Series, 1982), 5, 2831.
Nagata disputes the date of this event; dierences, however, might be attributable
to administrative forms in the Balkans and Anatolia.
181
Akarl, Provincial Power Magnates in Ottoman Bilad al-Sham and Egypt,
43. For an overview of economy of the city of Mosul, see Dina Rizk Khoury, The
Political Economy of the Province of Mosul, 17001850 (Ph.D. diss., Georgetown
University, 1991), 6877. And generally, Necdet Sakao[lu, Anadolu Derebeyi Ocaklarndan
Kse Pa{a Hanedan (Ankara: Yurt Yaynlar, 1984), 5960; and zcan Mert, XVIII.
ve XIX. Yzyllarda apano[ullar (Ankara: Kltr Bakanl[, 1980).
182
See CM 25,002 176061; MMD 9740:82. For the links between Aleppo gentry and central-state rical, see the accounts of the court banker, Musa covering the
period from 1769 to 1775 (D.B}M 4047); also Margaret L. Meriwether, The Kin
Who Count: Family and Society in Ottoman Aleppo, 17701840 (Austin: University of
Texas Press, 1999), 43.

165

The gentry government in Amid seems closer in form to Aleppos


oligarchy than the one-family rule of the Jalilis in Mosul. Yet each
city responded to the shifting patterns of provincial power during
the second half of the eighteenth century in its own fashion, infusing a distinctive type of local leadership into the amalgam of claims
and counterclaims making up vernacular government. Among the
families of the ulema and dozens of members of the great gentry,
the }eyhzde clan stands out.183 Although the clans name suggests
a link to individuals holding provincial oces from the seventeenth
century onward, convention traces their lineage to Shaykh Yusuf
Veli.184 Yet it was only in the second half of the eighteenth century,
and particularly with (smail (d. 1799), who repeatedly held the position of Diyarbekirs voyvoda, that the clan attracted the attention of
authorities in Istanbul and Baghdad.185 (smails son, (brahim (1747
1813), followed his father into provincial oce, assuming the position of voyvoda in 178788, at the rank of kapucuba{.186 (brahims
career led beyond his native city to deputy governor (178990) and
later governor of Urfa in 1797. One of a few dozen ocers to answer
the call for soldiers to ght Napoleon in Egypt,187 he returned to
take up the post of governor of his native province of Diyarbekir
for the rst time in 17991800. Local biographers remembered him
as the quintessential gentry-pashaboth a man of the state (rical-
hkmet) and native of the region (ahali buldan).188
}eyhzde father and son cut their teeth on the oce of voyvoda.189
As we have seen, the Diyarbekir voyvoda emerged as the chief scal
183
MMD 2931:122. A certain }eyhzde Ebu Bekir, who took the oce of voyvoda
in 1683 with the nancial backing of a certain Abidin (based in Istanbul?).
184
Ali Emiri, Tezkere-i }u"ar-i Amid (Istanbul: Matbua-i Amidi, 1328/19101911)
vol. 1, 22230, 239, 25354, 11517, 36869. Thanks to David Waldner, I was
able to obtain a copy of M. Fahrettin Krzo[lus Kara-mid"te 1819 da A"yandan
}eyhzdeler"in ncl[nde Milli Deli-Behram Pa{a"ya Kar{ Ayaklanma Ve Sonucu,
Kara mid Dergisi 24 (195658): 350378, which refers extensively to Abdulgani
Bulduks (18641951), El-Cezire"nin Muhtasar Tarihi, an important source that was
otherwise unavailable to me.
185
(nalck, Centralization and Decentralization, 33.
186
CZ 541; CM 25,214 (December 1813) pertains to the expropriation order of
(brahim among others.
187
Sakao[lu, Anadolu Derebeyi Ocaklarndan Kse Pa{a Hanedan, 105. The voyvoda of
E[in also volunteered according to Ylmazelik, Diyarbakr, 108.
188
CZ 541 (179091); Mehmed Sreyya Bey, Sicill-i Osman; yahut Tezkere-yi Me{ahir-i
Osmaniye (Istanbul: Matbaa-i mire, 130815/189097), 1:151; Ylmazelik, Diyarbakr,
4344, 91.
189
MMD 2931:122. The evolution from tax farmer to intendant occurs over the

166

ocer of the province and the main intendant overseeing a valuable set of revenue sources within the city. Unlike the position of
voyvoda of Ayntab or Mardin190 which was subordinate to the command of a larger administrative city, by the eighteenth century, the
voyvoda residing in Amid at times performed duties that made him
all but indistinguishable from a deputy or civil governor.191
It was this range of responsibilities over territory and government
that made the position far more than the sum of its scal parts.192
During the last quarter century, such duties included those of military recruiter and chief probate ocer, the latter responsible for conducting an inventory of the property of ocials who died in oce.
Each of these duties brought the voyvoda political preeminence in the
city and region, and he did not hesitate to use his powers against
his rivals.193 As the inventory and wide-ranging investments of one
former voyvoda, Mustafa A[a ibn Abdulveheb A[a ibn elhac Hseyin,
in 1739 demonstrate, the oce also brought its holder into contact
with the nancial, economic, and political nexus of the empire.194
In Diyarbekir, there is little doubt that the growing coercive force
and multiple institutional hats of the voyvoda increased the potential
second half of the seventeenth century. In 1683, Ebu Bekir needed a guarantor, a
certain Abidin (based in Istanbul?), to take charge of three-year iltizam. His duties
included collection of revenues totaling 19,607,908 ake, of which 2,430,180 ake
were the avrz and bedel-i nzl (100 ake/kurus) In 168994 (TT 831:38 [1689
94/11001105]), the voyvodalk (both the position and its revenues) was held twice
as a two-year tax farm by other tax farmers, {ahban A[a, Uzun Ali A[a, and
Mehmed A[a, all of whom were probably local janissaries. Uzun Ali had a guarantor named Ahmed A[a.
190
In other cases, such as eighteenth-century Ayintap, the position of voyvoda was
venal and held as a three-year iltizam. See Gzelbey, Gaziantep {erii Mahkeme Sicilleri,
1034. MMD 2931:122 (1683).
191
DA I:151. Ylmazelik, Diyarbakr, 200.
192
Van Bruinessen, Evliya elebi in Diyarbekir, 12427.
193
Ylmazelik, Diyarbakr, 238.
194
D}S 315:7380. He owed money to Vezir Mime{ Pasha, and etei Abdullal
Pasha of Kerkt; he left his wife 28,454 kuru{. For the follow-up investigations, see
D.B}M 12,532 (1741). For some of the nancial networks in Diyarbekir, see the
case of Halil, a former voyvoda at the rank of kapucuba{, who lent 7,625 kuru{ to
Mahmud, the sancakbeyi of ermik (DA I:151). Compare with MMD 9740:82
(178283) concerning the former muhassl Hunkrlizde elhac Ahmed A[a and his
son Mehmet. MMD 10,000:368 (176869) is an example of subfarming of a share
in the voyvodalk by the voyvoda. Compare Suraiya Faroqhi, Wealth and Power in
the Land of Olives: Economic and Political Activities of Muridzde Haci Mehmed
Agha, Notable of Edremit, in Landholding and Commercial Agriculture in the Middle East,
ed. a[lar Keyder and Faruk Tabak (Albany: State University of New York Press,
1991), 7796.

167

for abuse. But even a voyvoda could not operate with impunity. He
came under the scrutiny, on one side, of a variety of contractors,
venal oceholders, and provincial authorities; on the other, of the
shareholders in the super-tax farm for which he served as either an
employee or intendant. As a contractor himself, he could see his
lucrative holdings retracted and reassigned to others.195 Overall, this
division of labor between shareholders and administrators in the
peculiar type of tax farm known as the voyvodalk provided an additional rewall against a monopolization of legal, nancial, and coercive control.196 But the system of checks and balances worked only
so long as the largest shares remained in the hands of central-state
investors. It broke down, in 1784, for example, when the voyvoda
(smail A[a and a son, (brahim, obtained half the shares themselves.197
It was the inherently divergent interests in the institution of tax
farming, as Jrgen Habermas has opined, that provided an opening
for the public in local governance.198 Petitions to Istanbul and
records of subsequent investigations document the misdeeds of then
voyvoda (smail }eyhzde, who had conspired with the janissary commander (serdar) Gavuro[lu in Diyarbekir to extort money from many
of the citys residents, including its most prominent citizens.199 According to a nal resolution in 1777, their operations had apparently
195
Meriwether, Urban Notables and Rural Resources in Aleppo, 69. The former nakib"l-e{rf of Aleppo, Muhammad Tahazde, who held nearly one-fth of
all malikne lands in the surrounding districts in the last quarter of the century, provides an apt example. He was exiled and his holdings were expropriated in 1775;
reinstated a decade later, he was shorn of many of his tax farms.
196
In this way it functioned better than Aleppos muhassl: On his bankruptcy,
Ahmed Efendi Vsf, Mehsin "l-sr ve Hakik "l-Ahbr, trans. and ed. Mcteba
Ilgrel (Istanbul: Edebiyat Fakltesi Basmevi, 1978), 189. In 179899, Aleppos
muhassllk farm was placed in the esham system.
197
MMD 9896:2930. An early account of the malikne on the voyvodalk gives its
value as 764,334 kuru{ tm. In 17001701 (MMD 19,080:1), the annual payment
(mal) totaled 13,023,123 ake; in 1781, the annual remittance from the farm was
10,928,630 ake (MMD 9518:1, MMD 9519:14). The voyvoda held shares in the
voyvodalk during the following years: 1697; 17001704 (MMD 1637:152); 17056
(MMD 9896:29). Naturally, the entire family, in the case of a local notable might
benet from these political connections. In 1777, while his father served as voyvoda,
(brahim himself took hold of ve-eighths of the total shares in the highly valued
contract on the tobacco taxation (MMD 9519:22).
198
Jrgen Habermas, The Structural Transformation of the Public Sphere: An Inquiry into
a Category of Bourgeois Society (Cambridge: M.I.T. Press, 1991), 1619.
199
CD 2819 (1777). On the plague of 17991800, which took the life of (brahim
Pashas father (smail A[a (as noted by our Baghdad-based historian), see Yasin al'Umari, al-Durr al-Maknn f al-Ma"thir al-Mdiya, 487.

168

continued for quite some time before Amids enraged citizenry denounced both men for collusion and oppression of local taxpayers.200
Townsmen not only brought their prestige to the prosecution of
their case against the voyvoda but also took advantage of personal
experience and involvement in Amids system of vernacular government. As we have seen, more than a hundred of the citys residents,
including the leading members of the ulema, were contractors themselves. They understood the conditions placed on those who held
contracts. They were familiar with the apparatus in Istanbul and
had personal links to members of the religious and administrative
hierarchy. Having identied the parties and interests involved, the
townsmen pursued their greivance. They addressed a petition to the
Istanbul bureaucracy. They also sent separate letters ( ferdn ferdn)
to Abdul Rahman Efendi, Mehmed Tahir A[a, and Ahmed Efendi,
the aristocratic shareholders of the malikne in Istanbul.
Their strategy worked well enough. The malikne contractors, who
had invested a very large sum78,512.5 kuru{ to be exactas surety,
were naturally concerned about the management of their investment.
The voyvoda was already in arrears in payments.201 The contractors
joined their voices to those agitating for the dismissal of the gentryvoyvoda, (smail A[a. He was replaced by a certain Seyyid Ahmed
Bey who hailed from nearby Ergani.202
The treasury, however, in the throes of scal crises brought on
by the conclusion of the Russo-Ottoman war, including the huge
war indemnity demanded under the treaty of Kk Kaynarca of
1774, used the uproar as a pretext to take over the tax farm and
reassess its value. A revenue agent was dispatched from Istanbul.203
In what turned out to be the beginning of a more activist posture
by the state, at least once in every decade (1777, 1785, 1786, 1798,
and 1802) the central treasury intervened and replaced local agents
with salaried central-state employees. In doing so, the bureaucracy
acted as a trustee of the voyvodalk, dividing the earnings among

200

Ylmazelik, Diyarbakr, 11314.


That is not to say that the system in Diyarbekir was trouble free. See CM
29,248 (1761), addressed to Mustafa Pasha and the kad of Diyarbekir regarding
collection of 30,386.5 kuru{ arrears.
202
MMD 10,190:170.
203
Ylmazelik, Diyarbakr, 198. The voyvodalk was an emanet in 1777, 1785, 1796,
1802, 1803, and 1819.
201

169

the imperial treasury and the contractors who held the malikne.204
The tenacity of vernacular government was proven in the face of
the Nizam- Cedid, New Order, a program of military and scal
reforms initiated after 1793. One of its aims was to reintroduce state
control by the appointment of rical to provincial oces or by reshuing
local magnates within the larger region of Syria, Eastern Anatolia
and Kurdistan.205 In Diyarbekir, gentry-pashas and appointees from
the aristocracy of service alternated the oce of governor. The mobility of gentry-pashas continued to be circumscribed regionally. After
a brief tour of duty as governor of his native province,206 }eyhzde
(brahim, one of the former voyvoda (smails sons, was assigned to
other posts within West Asia, including the governorship of Jidda in
1800, before returning to Diyarbekir again in 1801. Diyarbekirs governorship was also awarded to other provincial elites, including leaders of the Kiki and Milan tribes, members of the Kseo[lu clan of
Sivas, and (brahim A[a, a retainer of Muhmamad Tahazde of
Aleppo.207 The dierences in career paths remained striking. A central-state appointee like Yusuf Ziya Pasha, who rapidly rose from
clerk to intendant of mines, to grand vizier, and to provincial governor, might dabble in both center and peripheryindeed, his sons
and associates purchased many village contracts in Diyarbekir during his tenure.208 Where Yusuf Ziya Pashas investments spanned the
empire, (brahim Pasha made his investments locally. Where Yusuf
Ziya Pasha climbed to the grand vizierate, only with the interregnum between 1807 and 1813, could (brahim Pasha aspire to rule
uncontestedly in his native province.209

204

Ibid.
To name but two: Cezar Pasha in Sidon who resisted Napoleon; the reformoriented Capano[lu of Central Anatolia who countered the Cankli of Trebizond
and Erzurum.
206
CZ 541 (1205); Sicill-i Osman, vol. 1, 151; See also Ylmazelik, Diyarbakr,
4344, 9192, 11213, 17273, 19196, 200202, 25053.
207
Meriwether, The Kin Who Count, 61.
208
Ali Emiri, Tezkere-i }u"ar-i Amid, vol. 1, 141. Mehmed Sreyya Bey, Sicill-i
Osman, vol. 4, 67071. His sons and associates held numerous tax farms in the
region, beginning with his rst tenure in oce. (For holdings of sons Mehmet Beg
and Sabit Yusuf Beg, MMD 9518:27, 28, 33, 38, 57, 78, 98, 104, and 106; and
of his retainers, 84, 85, and 91.) For his income as grand vizier, see D.B}M 7016
(18025). He also held a half share in the copper renery in Amid in 179596
(MMD 9519:9). For his earlier career see n. 49 above.
209
Mehmed Sreyya Bey, Sicill-i Osman, vol. 1, 151; Diyarbekir Salnamesi (1286/
186970), 26; CM 25, 214 (1813).
205

170

The Sublime Portes new policies toward vernacular government


failed to take local conditions into consideration. The program of
centralization found the city and province of Diyarbekir in the depths
of a severe economic crisis. Imperial demands for emergency supplies and manpower had increased during the last two decades of
the eighteenth century to pay for the wars with Russia and France.210
New impositions burdened the urban marketplace. Textile producersspinners, weavers, cloth printers, and dyerswho formed the
core of Diyarbekirs artisan class, faced increased taxation on cotton
thread, dyes, and cloth, as well as on chemicals such as alum, which
were vital to treating and dyeing textiles.211 Plague stuck the region
again in 17991800 and took the life of the former voyvoda, (smail.212
Increasingly bold attacks by the Wahhabis on southern Iraq, including the sack of the Shi"i shrines in the cities of Najaf and Kerbala,
delayed the caravans trac that transited the city and neighboring
towns.
The combination of new forms of state intervention, natural disasters and empirewide economic stresses and strains eroded the
separation of powers that had contained the impact of poor administrators.213 Suering from the rapaciousness of a deputy governor
left in place by (brahim Pasha himself, townsmen regarded the arrival
and billeting of 1,602 troops belonging to the 31st battalion (orta) of
the Nizam- Cedid army, as the nal straw. In the best of times, the
introduction of a new political group into the cityin this case, soldiers whose number equaled that of Amids gendarmerie, guards,
and janissaries combinedwould have heightened tensions. But in
1802, the towns precarious economic circumstances made the prospect
of assimilating a new social, economic, and political element into the
urban fabric unthinkable.
Vernacular government had been based on a careful balance of
force, taxation, and historic rights and forged over a century of negotiation between guildsmen, janissaries, and contractors. By violating
the century-long compact between state and society, the soldiers bullying, threats, and outright violence in the streets of Amid sparked
210

Ylmazelik, Diyarbakr, 208.


CD 2173. In May 1801, increases in the alum tax were announced in the
Asian provinces Karahisar- }ark, Aleppo, Damascus, Arabia, Van, Kars, Tokat,
Erzurum, Sivas, Diyarbekir, Rakka, Beyrut, and Iskenderiye.
212
Sleyman Efendi, Mur"i"t-Tevarih, vol. 2A, 25.
213
Ylmazelik, Diyarbakr, 11013, 24751.
211

171

the great ihtilal, or insurrection of 1802.214 That summer, townsmen


did not assault the troops. Instead, they vented their anger at a particularly egregious symbol of the states new scal program. Chanting,
Destroy them [the mengene, the presses], and They have no precedent and are illicit [muhadis dey]),215 the largely Muslim crowd surged
against the building that housed both the machine that pressed and
sized textiles and the station that levied the taxes on the exportquality cloths produced in the city.216 In three days of rioting, the
crowd leveled the presses and razed the entire Haci Osman quarter of the city, including shops, manufactories, and homes.217
Could the crowd have known that main contractor of the presses
was none other than (brahim Re{id Efendi,218 one of the architects
of the program of centralization and the controller of the New
Order sc?
The states response was swift. The ninety-eight guildsmen who
led the rebellion did not await the deputy governors reaction but
immediately ed the city. Amids Hanete mufti, Mesd Efendi, was
immediately exiled to Cyprus. Thirty-one members of the ulema
were also threatened with expulsion. (brahim Pasha, though away on
campaign, was held responsible for his deputys dereliction of duties
and his inability to control the city.219 With a new governor appointed,
the state planned to take the local gentry to task for this incident
and prevent further provincial interference in urban governance.
Intentions notwithstanding, it should not surprise us that Porte
found it dicult to reach a nal agreement without reconvening

214
CZ 1364 (30 July 1803) contains a summary of events and includes a copy
of the deposition.
215
Ibid. In his dissertation (XIX. Yzyln ilk Yarsnda, 221 [based on D}S
336:7980]), Ylmazelik notes that there was only one non-Muslim among the
ninety-eight rioters involved.
216
MMD 9518:62, 77; MMD 9519:111. The malikne contract dates to 1755. On
the mengene taxes, see MMD 9519:10; Cezar, Osmanl Maliyesinde Bunalm, 325. In
May of 1797 (CI 199; CM 14,123), and repeated on October 1804 (MMD 10,246:230):
all clothsalaca, beyazl, kutni, gazi, and atlaswere to pay at 30 ake per bolt.
217
Ylmazelik (Diyarbakr, 11314) describes this event in detail, referring not
only to the relevant court documents (D}S 536:7980) but also to the memoirs
and papers of an early-nineteenth-century administrator, (brahim b. Muhammed
(Diyarbakr Mutasarrf (brahim b. Muhammed"in Hatrat ve Mektuplar, found
in the Elaz[ Museum Archive [Ms. 137]).
218
CM 8741; C( 697. In 18001801, (brahim Re{id Efendi, held three-quarters
of the contract; one-quarter was in the hands of the voyvoda Halil A[a.
219
Ylmazelik, Diyarbakr, 238, 255.

172

vernacular government. Negotiations continued for a year. The deposition that was drawn up in August 1803 required considerable mediation. The imperial court solicited the signatures of the citys ve
leading professors (mderris), the clerks of the court, the chief baili,
and the court translator, presumably for those who spoke Kurdish
or Armenian. The notarial document named twenty-ve Muslim
shaykhs and master guildsmen along with twenty-three non-Muslim
ostad responsible for payment of a ne of 30,000 kuru{ to restore
the presses to their former state. Those damages compensated the
presses main investor, the chief treasurer, for his losses. In addition,
guildsmen promised to share a bond of 389,000 kuru{ guaranteeing
the banning of those who had ed the city.
It was a harsh punishment. Yet local society also scored a pyrrhic
victory: the 31st battalion had been withdrawn from the city in July
1803. The guilds would comanage the presses in the capacity of subfarmers.220

Final Entries
Conserving space in the half page allotted him in our register, a
clerk entered the last transaction under the tax farm on two villages
in the province of Diyarbekir in 1791. The entries grow sparser in
the register during the last decade of the eighteenth century.
The clerks in Istanbul were determined to put Diyarbekirs accounts
in order. In 1799 they opened a new set of books. An unusual attentiveness to form may be discerned in a summary of the malikne contracts under the voyvodalk that was drafted on a series of unbound
folios (Fig. 6).221 In place of the swirl of notations, dates, and fractions of shares that marked the diachronic approach to which have
referred thus far, this new register presents its documentation in a
strictly synchronic and synoptic fashion. The tax farms are entered
neatly side by side; each row repeats the same form of entry, with
the name of the type of revenue preceding the name or names of
the contractors. Its historical sweep has gone; its accounts are cur-

220
Ibid., 21920. In 1804, the esnaf split the cost with the contractor for the
repair of the building (MMD 9519:10).
221
D.B}M 14,094.

173

Fig. 6 Note the dierence in the style of a Nizm-i Cedid register. The top
entry on the last page records the maktu (lump sum tax) owed by several
villages in the kaza of Hani. The lower two entries furnish names of contractors holding various urban oces, including the kethudalk of the bedesten
of Diyarbekir, the delalba{lk of the black bazar and the delallk of the citys
beyt l-mal. In his summary, the clerk disparages local authorities.

174

rent only for a given year. Written in the well-formed nesih script,
its pages are free of shorthand, siyakat, the bane of the modern
researcher. Despite the remarkable clarity and uniformity of his
expression, the clerk concludes on a sour note. He complains that
he was forced to write the contents out in full: provincials are unable
to read siyakat, the trademark of a properly trained bureaucrat.
Feigning mutual unintelligibility, the Istanbul clerk distances himself in culture and in social status from his provincial counterparts.
He too was complicit in the denial of a system of government that
had existed with the full approval of the statesmen in Istanbul.
Without formal redrafting, provincial boundaries were redrawn
by combinations of economic and social pressures. Throughout the
Balkans, Anatolia, Syria, and Kurdistan, the treasury awarded hundreds of small contracts on villages and commercial taxes. The contractors, by default, assumed their place in provincial government;
brokers expanded their networks across the province and cultivated
links to larger, transimperial circuits of credit and nance. Although
unwilling and probably unable to assume their duties, clerks and
bureau chiefs in Istanbul used reports and marginalia to vent their
accumulated resentment toward the petty oligarchy of local gentry, ulema, and ocers who constituted the de facto vernacular government.222 In his audit of the nances of Aleppo in 1776, another
Istanbul bureaucrat commented that for many years, [the tax farm
on the muhassllk] has been assigned to persons living in the region;
the greatest part of the holders of mukatat being yan- memleket, their
relatives, and their clients (tallukt) who are chiey concerned with
their own interests and not with the aairs of the muhassllk itself . . .223
Not only are the gentry unworthy of their responsibilities and devoid
of civic virtue, it is impossible to ascertain the true state of aairs
because the records of the muhassllk in Aleppo are unreliable and
full of falsication.224
Indeed, in 1785 the treasurer ordered a full-edged investigation
of provincial accounting. He targeted provinces with mfrez (inde222
Tocqueville (The Old Rgime, 43) expresses essentially the same sentiment.
Municipal government was run by a petty oligarchy, who kept a watchful eye
on their own interests, out of the sight of the public and feeling no responsibilities
toward less privileged citizens.
223
Cited in Thieck, Dcentralisation ottomane et armation urbaine Alep
la n du XVIIIme sicle, 125.
224
Ibid.

175

pendent) treasuries, such as Crete and Damascus, or voyvodalk types


of administrations, such as Tokat and Diyarbekir.225
More than an intractable reality in the provinces or evidence of
the collapse of the imperial economy, the utterances of contemporaries should remind us of the parallax that was setting in between
the state bureaucracy and the actors in vernacular government. It
was stamped in the changing paleography of a register in the mold
of the old regime and one produced in the rst ush of the new.
Buried between formulae and routine entries was the evidence of a
growing semantic distance between the modern, unitary state and
the compromised capacities of the past. In the countryside, tax farmers lled in the gaps in the rural order as the timar system receded.
In cities such as Amid, gentry participation in local governance helped
forge an underlying consensus in the key areas of the economy, such
as manufacturing, that aected the vast majority of townsmen. Even
the malikne system, which stamped diverse societies with the terms
of a single charter, oered channels for transmuting conicts into
alliances between parties and avenues of redress for pursuing protests
through the imperial judiciary or to the Sublime Porte itself. But as
the bureaucrat, pressed to nd new resources for war, as much as
to reorder society itself,226 began to dismantle vernacular government,
what would happen to the tacit compact about the limits of state
power?

225
Cezar, Osmanl Maliyesinde Bunalm, 33133 (CM 12,343, document dated June
24, 1785). A year before the announcement of the New Order Treasury (Irade Cedid
Hazinesi ) in 1793, the director of the sc circulated a summary of an investigation
that claimed that the largest portion of the new share-system (esham) had passed
into the hands of obscure ladies and unidentiable men resident in the provinces
(see MMD 11,669:2).
226
Cezar, Osmanl Maliyesinde Bunalm, 156, 169; Stanford Shaw, Between Old and
New: The Ottoman Empire under Sultan Selim III 17891807 (Cambridge, M.A.: Harvard
University Press, 1971), 19.

CHAPTER FOUR

CONCLUSION: THE PATHS NOT TAKEN

Hardly were we masters of Algiers than we hastened to gather up


every single Turk, from the dey to the last soldier of his militia, and
transported the lot of them to the coast of Asia. In order to make the
vestiges of the enemy domination disappear, we rst took care to tear
up or burn all written documents, administrative records, and papers,
authentic or otherwise, that could have perpetuated any trace of what
had been done before us. The conquest was a new era . . .
Alexis de Tocqueville, Second Letter on Algeria, August 22, 1837.

By the time Tocqueville gathered his notes for The Old Rgime and
the French Revolution, a tidal wave of images, words, and armies had
washed away many of the semblances between the old regimes of
Europe and Asia.1 The ideological and material forces unleashed by
the French Revolution, the Empire, the Bourgeois Monarchy, the
revolutions of 1848, and nally, Louis Napoleons power seizure had
all but submerged reliable if largely descriptive and chronological
narratives of the Ottoman past written at the turn of the century.2
The bureaucratic state appeared triumphant in the West while the
government of the Ottoman Empire, once the paragon of despotic
centralism, seemed to shatter against the shoals of modernity. Blending
1
Orientalist painting played a role, to be sure. Eugene Delacroixs Collection
of Arab Taxes (1863), today in the National Gallery in Washington, D.C., might
illustrate Tocquevilles notion that the Ottomans were a government by conquest.
A horseman, with drawn sword, is ready to pounce on a hapless peasants. See also,
Henry Laurens, Les origines intellectuelles dexpdition dgypte, lorientalisme Islamisant en
France (16981798) (Istanbul: Isis, 1987); Alain Grosrichard, The Sultans Court: European
Fantasies of the East (New York: Verso, 1998); and M. S. Anderson, The Eastern
Question, 1774 1923, A Study in International Relations (Houndmills, Basingstoke,
Hampshire: Macmillan Education, 1987).
2
Mouradgea DOhsson, Tableau gnral de lEmpire othoman, divis en deux parties, dont
lune comprend la lgislation mahomtane; lautre, lhistoire de lEmpire othoman (Paris, Imp.
de monsieur [Firmin Didot] 17871820) 12 vols.; Joseph Freiherr von HammerPurstalls (17741856) monumental Geschichte des osmanischen Reiches (Histoire de lEmpire
ottoman depuis son origine jusqua nos jours), 18 vols. [Paris, Bellizard, Barthes, Dufour
& Lowell, 183543) was to be republished in 1859 in Tours by the Bibliothque
de la jeunesse chrtienne (Ad Mame).

177

the revolutionary strains of Volney with a new imperialist fervor, in


his speech on The Eastern Question the deputy from Valognes
weighed the dangers of a great-power conagration over Ottoman
lands against the new opportunities for territorial expansion oered
by Mehmet Alis occupation of Syria.3
Among many draftsmen, Alexis de Tocqueville lent his hand to
the redrawing of the modern historical map. From his youthful enthusiasm for the colonization of Ottoman Algeria to his last diplomatic
mission in Rome where he negotiated the fate of the Polish and
Hungarian refugees of 1848 with the representative of the Sublime
Porte, his political career was deeply intertwined with Frances Middle
Eastern and North African policy.4 If the monarchy saw the colonial project as a means of diverting public opinion and a way to
relieve its Malthusian burden, Tocqueville regarded colonialism as
more than a land grab. It was Frances manifest destiny. Empire
restored the great-power status of a nation defeated and secured its
naval hegemony over the central Mediterranean. A century after the
loss of its Indian Ocean and Atlantic colonies, the American experiment would again. The colon would bring civilization to the
wilderness and build a new democratic community free of the inhibitions of the Old Worlds social and economic inequality.
In his letters and reports, written after ocial tours of the European
enclave in Africa, Tocqueville expressed outrage over the heavyhandiness of the military administration. He decried the wanton destruction of Ottoman archive as a loss to ecient colonial administration.

3
His involvement in Algerian politics dates to 1828. Andr Jardin, Tocqueville: A
Biography (New York: Farrar Straus Giroux, 1988), 62, 32234. See also Alexis de
Tocqueville, Oeuvres complte: crits et discours politique, ed. Jean-Claude Lamberti (Paris,
Gallimard, 1991) 2: 288309; compare, C. F. Volney, The Ruins, or Meditation on the
Revolution of Empires: and The Law of Nations (Baltimore: Black Classics Press, 1991),
49. M. Alexandre Laya (tudes Historiques sur la vie Prive politique et Littaire de M. A.
Thirs [18301846] [Paris: Chez Furne, 1846] 2:133) the political biographer of
Thirs, Tocquevilles archpolitical rival, considered this moment a watershed in
Europes perspective on Ottoman sovereignty, commenting that no more could the
Ottoman Empire be regarded as eternal, as [an entity] that could not die, or even
that it must be saved . . . For English perspectives on Mehmet Ali Pasha, see
Khaled Fahmy, All the Pashas Men: Mehmed Ali, his Army, and the Making of Modern
Egypt (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997).
4
Jardin, Tocqueville, 66, 249250, 267, 322, 334335. For a selection of his
writings on these subjects including the epigraph on the previous page, see Alexis
de Tocqueville, Writings on Empire and Slavery, ed. Jennifer Pitts (Baltimore: Johns
Hopkins University Press, 2001).

178

As for the Algerians themselves, his attitude wavered between paternalism and ruthless expedience. At times he opposed the militarys
scorched-earth policies toward peasants and herders;5 on other occasions, he urged brute force to repress the rebellion of 'Abd al-Qadir
and to sendentarize nomadic populations.6 While abhorring the reductionist and race-based logic of his contemporaries Alfred de Gobineau
and Ernst Renan, Tocqueville remained rm in his belief that representative government was the exclusive right of a small number of
the worlds peoples.7 Thus, although he rejected calls for the ethnic
cleansing of the Arab population in its entirety, he proposed, instead,
the creation of native ghettos among the European settlements. This
liberal colonial plan pregured not only the dualism of Algerian society for the next century but settler-colonial policies elsewhere, from
the Bantustans of South Africa to contemporary Israeli settlement
policy in the West Bank and Gaza.8
Cantonnement is also an apt metaphor for Tocquevilles vision
of Europes early modern past. Like many of his Enlightenment mentors, he zealously maintained the vigil before the frontier of Western
Europe, as both a religious and civilizational crusade. However, despite his unmistakable debt to the political philosophy of Montesquieu,
his approach to the relative evils of absolutism and the global landscape of power, including colonialism, diered importantly from the
eighteenth-centurys perspective.9 Why, unlike Voltaire and Edward

5
His interest in Algerian aairs dates to 1828. Jardin, Tocqueville, 62. Andre
Jardins comments (Tocqueville, 32234) on his attachment to colonial project are
balanced but unsparing.
6
Jardin, Tocqueville, 318. In De la Dmocratie en Amrique I (1835) (Oeuvres Compltes,
ed. Jean-Claude Lamberti and James T. Schleifer [ditions Gallimard, 1992], vol.
2, 104). Tocqueville argued that Turkish populations never took part in the direction of the aairs of their society; had they not witnessed the triumph of the religion of Mohammed with the conquests of the sultans they could have accomplished
great things. Today, religion is gone; all that remains is despotism. For the some
of the key texts, see Pitts, Writings on Empire as well. Melvin Richter, (Tocqueville
on Algeria, Review of Politics [1963]: 36298) is of the opinion that Tocquevilles
colonial politics are in agrant contradiction to his theories of democracy.
7
Pitts (Writings on Empire, Introduction, xxxiii) notes that although Tocqueville
at the outset disagreed with J. S. Mill on the need for despotic government to control barbarism, he does not seemed to have opposed the 1848 provision that
demanded Algerians renounce Islam in order to gain French citizenship. See Uday
Singh Mehta, Liberalism and Empire: A Study in Nineteenth-Century British Liberal Thought
(Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1999).
8
Jardin, Tocqueville, 33435.
9
In 1848, Algerians who wanted to gain French citizenship were forced to

179

Gibbons, whose wide-angle lens on the Roman Empire placed the


Ottoman conquest of Constantinople at the birth of modernity, did
Tocqueville simply dispense with the eastern portions of the empire,
as if Asia and Africa were so much ballast to the Europes soaring
trajectory?
Absent too is the philosophes admiration of the religious tolerance within Muslim world and his appreciation of the meritocracy
of the Asian bureaucracy. As Voltaire noted, Ottoman military
democracy permitted even the humblest servant to rise to the rank
of a general or prime minister.10 Indeed, more disturbing than the
gure of the Oriental despot who still merits mention, albeit as the
butt of the denigrating satire of the Enlightenment, is the banishment of Eurasias most powerful state from the early modern landscape. It is by refusing to utter the name of the Sleyman I in
conjunction with Francis I, that Tocquevilles silence achieved a rupture with the Wests longtime rivals that the Enlightenment could
never conceive. By appropriating the origins of the modern state, he
laid one of the cornerstones of the great conceptual wall of European
social science, encircling its past, present, and future.

The Common Origins of the Modern State


Rewriting the eighteenth century was not a uniquely Western European
preoccupation. Unbeknownst to Tocqueville, his slightly younger contemporary, the Ottoman historian Ahmed Cevdet Pasha, also pressed
the old regime in his twelve-volume historical suit for the Tanzimat
reforms (183976) and the building of a unitary state.11 Where
renounce Islam. Compare, Ann Thomson, Barbary and Enlightenment: European Attitudes
toward the Magreb in the Eighteenth Century (Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1987). Sudhir Hazareesingh,
From Subject to Citizen: The Second Empire and the Emergence of Modern French Democracy
(Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1998), 232.
10
Voltaire criticized Montesquieus indiscriminate application of the term despotism to all Asian governments. (Commentaire Sur lEsprit des Lois) Oeuvres compltes de Voltaire (Paris: Chez Th. Desoer, Libraire Rue Christine, 1817) vol. 6, 968;
see also comments in Vol. 4, 79. In History of the Latin and Teutonic Nations, Francis
Is alliance with the Ottomans became an act of betrayal that Leopold von Ranke
held against the French in particular.
11
Ahmed Cevdet Pasha, Tarih-i Cevdet (Istanbul: Matbaa-y Osmaniye, 1309/1893)
vol. 2, 256. The loosening of the reins over state and government in the periphery
was a constant worry of the bureaucracy as Ya{ar Ycel, (Osmanl (mparatorlu[unda
Desantralizasyona (Adem-i Merkeziye) Dair Genel Gzlemler. Belleten 38 (1974):

180

Tocqueville sought institutional continuity in the endurance of traditional social values and vestigial social hierarchiesCevdet took a
dierent tack. Staring uninchingly at the less admirable traits of the
past century, he blamed the impasse of the late eighteenth century
on the ills of decentralization: the usurpation of state power by the
gentry and janissaries, the desperate plight of the peasantry, the greed
of tax farmers and the unreliability of gentry armies. The anarchy
of the eighteenth century and the vulnerability of disunion are tropes
that carry over into his successors. For the Turkish, Armenian, Balkan,
and Arab nationalists of the rst decade of the twentieth century, it
was the dangerous disintegration of the old regime or simply the
decay left by the Turkish yoke that served as the premise for their
programs of political and cultural renewal.
Yet neither the Ottoman bureaucrat nor sultan needed to correspond with the philosophes to discern the waning of the old regime
geopolitical order in the eastern Mediterranean.12 French retrenchment from eastern Europe and the Sublime Portes failure to win
Prussian support as a counterweight to the Habsburgs left Istanbul
isolated.13 Unimpeded, the czarina expanded into the Black Sea and
Mediterranean. Long before Campo Formio (1797) crowned Frances
arrival at the Adriatic, Russian navies had twice destroyed the Ottoman
eet. Over the course of the next half century, Russia courted discontent among the Ottomans Muslim and Christian subjects along
its outlying provinces, from Ali Bey al-Kabir (d. 1773) of Egypt,
Kara George and the Serbian rebels of 18021806, to the magnate
of Trabizon, Caniko[lu Tayyar Pasha.14 The principalities of Moldavia,

14952, 657708) points out. For his advocacy of the policies of the New Regime,
see Christoph K. Neumann, Das indirekte Argument: ein Pldoyer fr die Tanzimat vermittels der Historie. Die geschichtliche Bedeutung von Ahmed Cevdet Pa{as Ta"rih. Mnster:
Lit Verlag, 1994.
12
On the impact of Kk Kaynarca on political and military thinking see
Virginia Aksan, An Ottoman Statesman in War and Peace, Ahmed Resmi Efendi, 17001783
(Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1995); and Mariia Todorova, Imagining the Balkans (New York:
Oxford University Press, 1997).
13
Paul W. Schroeder, The Transformation of European Politics, 17631848 (Oxford:
Clarendon Press, 1994), 523; Stanford Shaw, Between Old and New: The Ottoman
Empire under Sultan Selim III 17891807 (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press,
1971), 5573; Emmanuel Le Roy Ladurie, The Ancien Regime: A History of France,
1610 1774 (Oxford and Cambridge, MA: Basil Blackwell, 1996), 447.
14
See Norma Saul, Russia and the Mediterranean, 17971807 (University of Chicago,
1970).

181

Wallachia, and Bessarabia became stepping stones for their advance


on the Bosphorus Straits.
In many respects the empires institutional predicament was not
unique. If the second partition of Poland among Prussia, Austria,
and Russia in 1792 provided an object lesson in the perils of decentralization,15 it was the cudgel welded by Frances citizen army, as
well as the threat of contagion by the new ideas of popular sovereignty that hastened the consolidation of its neighbors in Central
Europe.16 Successful adaptation of the techniques of bureaucratization and direct government did not only preserve them. These organizational tools also furthered the aims of the new imperialism. The
French troops who disembarked in Alexandria in 179899 bore one
variant of the modern state apparatus. Across the Indian Ocean, the
charter-company system of government had outlived its utility for
Britain. The nal battles of conquest against the last autonomous
governments of Mysore set the stage for a radical reorganization of
Indian agricultural taxation beginning with the new British property
code for Bengal.17
Teetering on the precipice of bankruptcy and frantically rebuilding its navy, the Sublime Porte could oer little other than sympathy to Tipu Sultans ambassador who made his way to the court
from Basra in 1786.18 In comparison to the new imperialism and
Prussias forced-march program of administrative reorganization,19

15
After the second partition of Poland, Carl von Clausewitz (On War, ed. and
trans. Michael Howard and Peter Paret [London: Everymans Library, 1993],
449450) asks: Could Poland really be considered a European state, an equal
among the European community of nations . . . No, he concludes. It was for that
reason that Europe yielded Poland like the Turks yield the Crimean Tatar state.
On Ottoman-French relations during the republican period, see Ismail Soysal, Fransiz
(htilli ve Trk-Fransiz Diplomas Mnasebetleri (17891802) (Ankara: Trk Tarih Kurumu
1999) and the special issue of RMMM 52/53 (1989) entitled, Les Arabes, Les Turcs
et la Rvolution Franaise, ed. Daniel Panzac.
16
See Brendan Simms, The Impact of Napoleon: Prussian High Politics, Foreign Policy
and the Crisis of the Executive, 17971806 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
1997).
17
See Ranajit Guha, A Rule of Property for Bengal: An Essay on the Idea of Permanent
Settlement (Durham & London: Duke University Press, 1996).
18
Ahmed Efendi Vsf, Mehsin"l-sr ve Hakik"l-Ahbr, transcr. and ed., Mcteba
Ilgrel (Istanbul: Edebiyat Fakltesi Basmevi, 1978), 367368; Abd al-Rahman
Jabarti, Napoleon in Egypt: Al-Jabartis Chronicle of the French Occupation, 1798, ed. and
trans. S. Moreh (Princeton, NJ: Marcus Wiener Publishers, 1993), 64.
19
Simms, The Impact of Napoleon, 305312.

182

the Ottoman planners contended with the sheer scale of its territories and the multiplication of potentially hostile fronts, especially with
the escalation of British and Russian expansion in Asia.20 Istanbul
had lost suzerainty over the restive Crimean khans and was forced
to concede Russian sovereignty over Georgia. While countering British,
French, and Russian overtures to the magnate-governments of Ali
Pasha in Albania and Pasvano[lu Osman Pasha in Bulgaria,21 the
new sultans advisors looked nervously across the Kurdish frontier
to Iran, where the last of the Safavids tribal oshoots, the Qajars,
had begun to install a more enduring ruling structure. With uncertainty hanging over the succession to pashalik of Baghdad as well,
a leading religious intellectual, Tartarck Abdullah Efendi tendered
a new administrative map of Iraq. He foresaw the subdivision of the
province into smaller administrative units to contain the Kurdish
tribes and to prevent concentration of powers in Baghdad. Istanbulappointed governors would take charge of provincial nance and
military recruitment, duties that had long been delegated to the local
lords and gentry.22
It is such plans for sweeping organizational change that have led
nineteenth-century the regime of scholars, like Cevdet Pasha to compare the regime Sultan Selim III (r. 17891807) with the enlightened policies of earlier sultans, including Ahmed III.23 Attentive to
military training, the sciences and engineering, the new sultan also

20
Andr Raymond, Les commerants au Caire au XVIII e sicle (Damas: Institut Franais
de Damas, 197374) vol. 1, 4350. See also Shaw, Between Old and New, and Franois
Crouzet, Wars, Blockade and Economic Change in Europe, 19721815. Journal
of Economic History 24 (1964): 56788.
21
See Katherine Elizabeth Fleming, The Muslim Bonaparte: Diplomacy and Orientalism
in Ali Pashas Greece (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1999).
22
Abdullah Efendi Tatarck, Selim-i Sni Devrinde Nizm- Devlet Hakknda
Mutla"t, Trk Tarihi Encmeni Mecmuas 8 (1333/19141915), 1819. The council, as Uriel Heyd (The Ottoman 'Ulem and Westernization in the Time of Selim
III and Mahmud II, in Studies in Islamic History and Civilization, ed. U. Heyd
[ Jerusalem: The Magnes Press, 1961] vol. 9, 83) points out frequently met in the
villa of the }eyh"l-Islam. Istanbul could not, however, prevent Davud Pashas rise
to power 1816 and enlistment of European advisors for his military. Rabbi David
DBeth Hillel, Unknown Jews in Unknown Lands: The Travels of Rabbi David DBeth Hillel
(1824 1832), ed. and trans. Walter J. Fischel (New York: Ktav Publishing House,
Inc., 1973), 83; and generally, T. Niewenhuis, Politics and Society in Early Modern Iraq
(The Hague-Amsterdam: International Institute of Social History, 1982).
23
Avigdor Levi, Military Reform and the Problem of Centralization in the
Ottoman Empire in the Eighteenth Century, Middle Eastern Studies 18 (1982): 22749.

183

shared his grandfathers love of music, poetry, and evening soires


amidst lanterns and tulips.24 However, Selims nancial policies could
scarcely be more dierent from those of his gold-scattering ancestor. The timing of reform was not surprising. Although the Swedish
subsidy of 1789 had staved o imminent nancial collapse,25 the
combined impact of a large war indemnity to Russia, the upheaval
in global nancial markets following the French Revolution, the rapid
devaluation of Ottoman currency, and nally the continental blockade, put the imperial treasury in a perpetual state of crisis.26
Indeed, if comparisons are made, the Ottoman dilemma of 1793
1807 mirrored the plight of the Bourbon Louis XVI in 178892.27
The gradual consolidation of nancial oversight and policy-making
under the grand vizier and the military reforms of Mustafa III (r.
175774) gave way to more concerted eorts. As we have seen in
the last chapter, the announcement of new infantry units in 1793
the Nizam- Cedid (cest--dire, le nouveau rglement) was a part
of a multi-faceted program that promised an overhaul of taxation,
new forms of military training and recruitment, as well as increased
central state oversight of provincial government.28 Responding to
scal emergencies domestically and upheaval in global nancial markets,29 neither sovereign foresaw the consequences of pulling the warp

24

Cevdet, Tarih, vol. 6, 143.


See Alan Fischer, Russian Annexation of the Crimea 17721783 (Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press, 1970).
26
In Egypt (Raymond, Les commerants au Caire, vol. 1, 43) the silver para lost half
of its value between 1770 and 1798; Edhem Eldem (Le commerce Franais dIstanbul
au XVIIIe sicle, Ph.D. Diss. Universit de Provence-Aix-Marseille I, 1988, 188)
notes that Istanbul witnessed an equivalent devaluation a decade later: between
1800 and 1812 the kuru{ fell from two francs to one.
27
Gabriel Ardant (Financial Policy and Economic Infrastructure of Modern
States and Nations, in The Formation of National States in Western Europe, ed. Charles
Tilly [Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1975], 2167) in many ways concurs
with Tocqueville, noting that the French Revolution manifested itself by the disintegration of the state due in large part to the illusion of reformers.
28
Mouradgea DOhsson, Tableau gnral, vol. 3, 367; As Kemal Beydilli points
out (Ignatius Mouradgea DOhsson [Muradcan Tosunyan]: Ailesi Hakknda Kaytlar,
Nizm- Cedde dire Lyihas ve Osmanl Imparatolu[lyndaki Siys Hayat in
Prof. Dr. M. C. }eheddin Tekinda[ Hatra Says (Special issue) ed. M. Cavd
Baysun, Tarih Dergisi (Istanbul niversitesi Edebiyat Fakltesi 34 (198384): 247314)
remained an Ottoman patriot.
29
On the impact of the French Revolution on nancial markets throughout
Europe: Larry Neal, The Rise of Financial Capitalism: International Capital Markets in the
Age of Reason (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990), 180214.
25

184

of scal privilege from the social fabric woven by the old regime.
The state pressured its creditors. It exacted forced loans from nonMuslim bankers and compelled them to assume direct nancial
responsibility for provincial audits and accounts.30 To raise funds for
the Irade-i Cedid treasury and pay the salaries of the new army, the
Sublime Porte redirected agricultural revenues from the resident cavalry and tapped into the life-lease market. Proceeding cautiously at
rst, the bureaucrats of the new treasury recycled revenue revenues
into general funds upon the death of the contractor or by attrition.
But there was no mistaking the ultimate aim of the New Order:
to phase out both the classical organizational infrastructure of the
empire, particularly the old-regime military orders, the timar-cavalry
and the janissaries, and to dissolve the semiprivatized revenue system that structured of vernacular government.31
Across empire, Nizam-i Cedid policies provoked mistrust, consternation, dissatisfaction and protest. The creation of new military units
and alterations to organizational charters threatened long-standing
immunities of the military corps, such as the janissaries.32 Expropriation
of life-leases over and above a general decline in the income of
shares that had once yielded returns of 35 to 40 percent per annum
as well as increased state fees, struck at the very foundation of the
corporate patrimonialism of the Istanbul elite.33 In provincial cities
30
Sultan Selim IIIs decree (Ycel zkaya III. Selim"in (mparatorluk hakknda
Baz Hatt- Hmynlar, Osmanl Tarihi Ara{trma ve Uygulama Merkezi Dergisi 1
(1990): 341) refers to the rural gentry and magnates (derebey) as usurpers who
eece the peasantry as tax-farmers . . . [and the] voyvodas and police . . . [as those
who] oppress the poor and have come to have the power of viziers and military
commanders.
31
Yavuz Cezar, Osmanl Maliyesinde Bunalm ve De[i{im Dnemi (XVIII. Yzyldan
Tanzimat "a Mali Tarih) (Istanbul: Alan, 1986), 1557; 3029. See also Joshua M.
Stein, Habsburg Financial Institutions Presented as a Model for the Ottoman
Empire in the Sefaretname of Ebu Bekir Ratib Efendi, in Habsburgisch-osmanische
Beziehungen (Colloque sous le patronage du Comit international des tudes prottomanes et ottomanes, Vienna 2630, Sept. 1983), ed. Andreas Tietze (Vienna:
Verlag des Verbandes der Wissenschaftlichen Gesellschaften sterreichs, 1985),
233242.
32
By 18041805 (KK 4499), the number of beneciaries in the tobacco tax discussed in chapter 2 fell from 1,586 (in 17745; KK 4484) to 763 individuals; more
than half (386) were wives and daughters of religious gures.
33
Mehmet Gen, Osmanl Maliyesinde Malikne Sistemi, in Trkiye Iktisat Tarihi
Semineri, ed. Osman Okyar and nal Nalbanto[lu (Ankara: Hacetepe niversites
Publishers, 1975), 246, 252. On the decline of tax-farming rents in Egypt after midcentury, Kenneth M. Cuno, The Pashas Peasants: Land, Society and Economy in Lower
Egypt, 1740 1858 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1992), 44.

185

like Diyarbekir, rising prices for raw materials and loss of markets,
and a variety of taxes, including special wartime levies, pushed artisans into outright rebellion.
While the specic conditions varied widely across Europe and Asia,
ultimately, key aspects of the old-regime impasse remained the same:
an enormous gap in capacities and powers that left the state unable
to extract the wealth necessary to pay for its military upkeep or to
subdue the many vernacular governments of the provinces.
With no history of aristocratic assemblies, Selim III could not summon the third estate to Istanbul to ratify its his program. Instead,
court and bureaucracy steered a course of contradictory policies. On
one hand, they tried to undercut local power by the abolishment of
gentry-held oces, such as the city-steward and the army-recruiter,
and by transferring important tax contracts to in-coming governors.
On the other, still undermanned militarily and administratively,
Istanbul encouraged the powerful magnates along its perimeters, such
as Cezzar Pasha who controlled the Lebanese coastline, Mehmet Ali
Pasha of Cairo, and Bayraktar Mustafa Pasha, heir to Tir{inikli (smail
in Thrace and Rusuk, to built up private armies.34 Both Suleyman
Pasha in Baghdad and Cezzar Pasha in Sidon trained modern military units.
These appeasements notwithstanding, the advocates of state consolidation found their ercest critics in the capital. A janissary coup
dtat overthrew the new regime in 1807.35 Although the Istanbul
barracks red the rst shots, many parties in the Ottoman court and
in the mosques who feared the end of scal privilege and actively
encouraged the soldiers actions.
From the provinces this turn of events seemed ominous. Many
gentry and not a few townsmen who had embraced the New Order
with reservations realized they had more to fear from a janissarycontrolled state and the reassertion of a rigid estate hierarchy. Rural
magnates and the urban gentry of Anatolia and the Balkans rallied
in Rusuk under the leadership of Bayrakdar Mustafa, one of the

34
Bruce McGowan, The Age of the Ayan, in An Economic and Social History of
the Ottoman Empire, ed. Halil (nalck with Donald Quataert, Cambridge UK: Cambridge
University Press, 1994), 666. Amnon Cohen (Palestine in the Eighteenth Century [ Jerusalem:
Magnes Press, 1973], 163) estimates that agriculture provided much of Cezzar
Pashas wealth.
35
Shaw, Between Old and New, 23.

186

leading commanders on the Russian front. Using the pretext of paying


homage to the new sultan, the janissaries candidate, Mustafa IV,
an army loyal to the former sultan entered the city. By midsummer
1808, Bayrakdar Mustafas army had put down the insurrection.
The loyalists, who failed to save the life of Selim III, replaced
Mustafa IV with his last surviving male cousin, Mahmud II (r. 1808
38). The gentry assumed ministerial positions. With the new sultan
still in his minority, the direction of the state apparatus fell fully on
the shoulders of the new grand vizier, the upper-ranking rical, and
the bureaucracy.36
That autumn, two decades after the famous appeal to convene
the Estates General brought delegates to Paris, Istanbul was itself
the scene of an extraordinary gathering of the third estate. Gentryintendants and magnates came to the capital from western Anatolia
and the eastern Balkans in the company of their militias. Although
those from more distant provinces such as Egypt and Syria were
unable to attend in person, their agents represented their interests
at court. In a reversal of roles, the Ottoman court prepared the
pavilions of the Golden Horn for the festivities to receive the gentry. The sovereign feted his guests and conferred robes of honor on
his subjects. In an unadorned speech to those assembled, the grand
vizier, Bayraktar Mustafa, appealed for unity. Stressing the common
origins of the great gentry and the men of the state, he implicitly
established the equality of the second and third estates.37 Together
with the members of the religious establishment, the captains of the
chartered military units, and the bureau chiefs of the Sublime Porte,
the gentry hammered out new principles of unity in the form of a
short agreement, the Sened-i (ttifak, the Charter of Federation.38
Contemporary historians have debated the meaning of this document and its role in the transformation of imperial governance.39
36
Ibid., 39798; Anatolii F. Miller, Mustafa Pasha Bayraktar (Bucarest: Association
International dtudes du Sud-Est europen: 1975), 29899.
37
(smail Hakk Uzunar{l, Me{hur Rumeli yanlarndan Tirsinikli (smail Ylk O[lu
Suleyman A[a ve Alemdar Mustafa Pa{a (Istanbul: Trk Tarh Kurumu Yaynlar, 1942),
14142; note the variation in texts found in Ataullah Mehmet }anizade, Tarih-i
}anizade (Istanbul: Ceride-Havadis Matbaas 1290/1873) vol. 1, 63 and Cevdet,
Tarih, vol. 9, 5.
38
Halil (nalck, Sened-I (ttifak ve Glhane Hatt- Hmyunu, Belleten 28 (1964):
60769. The text is found in }anizade, Tarih-i }anizade, vol. 1, 66 and Cevdet, Tarih,
vol. 9, 178.
39
Shaw, Between Old and New, 90; compare. Bernard Lewis, Dustr, EI2 2:

187

Some consider the agreement to be a step backwards. Certainly, a


century of decentralized administration and vernacular government
provided precedents and geared the participants expectations. Its
formulation in the terminology of contract (sened ) may harken back
to the language of the life-lease edit of 1695, which also established
a parity of scal agency between gentry and rical. Yet it would be
a mistake to reduce the Charter of Federation to a simple restoration of the status quo ante, much less equate it to a type of feudalism. The agreement between subject and sovereign reected a
sense of partnership. In exchange for mutual defense, past privileges
were elevated to permanent rights. Moreover, as Halil (nalck notes,40
the devolution of powers was explicitly conditioned on respect for
the overarching framework of imperial law. Signatories were obliged
to protect the state-mandated rights of all subjects, Muslim, Christian,
and Jew.

A Federalist Alternative?
From the perspective of world history, the experiment in federalism
in the Ottoman Empire, a brief interlude between two attempts to
implant a unitary state apparatus, has not been given the attention
it deserves. Certainly the reexive segregation of Asia from the political time line and the poverty of the modern political lexicon are
partially responsible. For Tocqueville, the failure of federalism was
a foregone conclusion. The success of the government depended on
the cultural community itself and could only be the expression of
the religious, social and economic exceptionalism of Anglo-North
America.41 Yet Tocqueville never understood that the system of decentralized administration that he had encountered in North America
was itself an interim agreement. In many ways the Ottoman civil
wars of the period between 181240 did not resemble the counterrevolution of the Vende so much as foreshadow the more violent

64047; and Kemal Karpat, The Transformation of the Ottoman State, 17891908,
IJMES 3 (1972): 25254.
40
(nalck, Sened-i (ttifak, 610.
41
Jardin, Tocqueville, 2089. Sudhir Hazareesingh, From Subject to Citizen: The Second
Empire and the Emergence of Modern French Democracy (Princeton: Princeton University
Press, 1998), 18283.

188

stage of state integration of the American Civil War of 186165.42


Whatever its shortcomings, a Philadelphian compromise might
have proven better suited to the Ottoman dilemma.43 Like all such
agreements, the Charter of Federation brought together unequal parties possessing widely divergent political and economic agendas. Its
principles of unity were narrow and the problems of enforcement,
legion. The powers allotted to the center were too limited to restrain
the most exploitative and violent provincial actors, whose oppression
of the tax-paying population continued unabated. Once again, Istanbul
relaxed its grip over provincial revenues, relinquishing malikne oces
and rural resources to the gentry; clerks who had begun to compile
audits anew, returned to registering transactions in the old-regime
style.44 Nevertheless, these deciencies might be considered the price
for the incremental bridging of the institutional chasm between state
and government across such a vast territorial polity. In retrospect,
the contradictions resulting from the bargains struck in Istanbul in
1808 must be judged in their context or in relation to a constitution crafted two decades earlier in Philadelphia, a document that in
one breath declared the equality of all men while legalizing the
enslavement of tens of thousands of inhabitants of African and native
American ancestry.
Unfortunately, what little that we know about the practice of federalism in the Ottoman Empire has all too often been gleaned from
the Mediterranean coastline, where military elites supported by foreign merchants and rival European powers exerted monopolistic con-

42

See Richard Franklin Bensel, Yankee Leviathan: The Origins of Central State Authority
in America, 18591877 (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990).
43
Miller, Mustafa Pasha Bayraktar, 318.
44
Although this did not mean that attempts to consolidate the sc stoped entirely
(Cezar, Osmanl Maliyesinde Bunalm, 243), Mehmet Gen (Osmanl Maliyesinde
Malikne Sistemi, in Trkiye (ktisat Tarihi Semineri, ed., Osman Okyar and nal
Nalbanto[lu [Ankara: Hacetepe niversites Publishers, 1975], 282) calculates that
the percentage of overall investments held by provincial life-lessors rose from a low
of 19.8% in 1801 (during the New Order) to 23.6% in 1810. Note the trends in
provincial investments in life-leases:
1787
1800
1812
Diyarbekir
147,864.5
103,332
155,375.7
Aleppo
198,271.5
178,888.75
273,120.5
Tokat
234,393.5
286,238
366,340.5
Sources: MMD 9561:109115; KK 5161:29, 77, 53, 1829, 18; MMD 9624:182,
309, 307, 218. (Figures in kuru{).

189

trol of rural production and the ow of trade. Urban politics in


Syria, Palestine and Western Kurdistan, though not free from interparty violence, were of a qualitatively dierent character. Here the
federalist opening allowed for the emergence of new forms of representation. As Elizabeth Thompson points out, the citizens of
Damascus appeared well prepared for self-governance with the arrival
of formal administrative councils, under both Egyptian rule in the
1830s, and later, Istanbuls Tanzimat (183978) programs.45
In Diyarbekir the declaration of federalism did not bring into being
parliament or male surage. But it did result in a stable, responsive,
albeit oligarchic government under the leadership of one of Amids
foremost families. Following the 1808 meeting, (brahim of the }eyhzde
clan sent a deputy to lay claim to the governorship, a position he
would hold until his death in 1814. Although he did not have an
unblemished record as a civil servant, many years in state service
within the city and in tours of duty in neighboring provinces, including a stint with the Ottoman army that routed the French from
Egypt, had seasoned (brahim as an administrator and commander.46
Politically, too he may have learned the value of appeasement, if
not consensus. A petition for clemency that (brahim forwarded to
the Sublime Porte on behalf of those accused of participation in the
18023 riots might have helped repair relations with townspeople
and earn him begrudging respect from rival clans.47 His family connections were not limited to the city. With their extensive tax farms
in the fertile farmlands around Hani, the }eyhzde had a following
among rural communities as well.48
Although lacking channels for direct representation, Amids townsmen could count on (brahims government to champion the citys
interests. The interurban trading system was arguably the most important of these concerns. Throughout his tenure, the pasha refused to
capitulate to Baghdad or Istanbul on the question of manufactured

45
Elizabeth Thompson, Ottoman Political Reform in the Provinces: The Damascus
Advisory Council in 184445, IJMES 25 (1993): 457475.
46
On the life and times of }eyhzde (brahim Pasha, CZ 541 (1789); CZ 1298
(1795); CZ 3392 (1812); CM 30,953. Ali Emiri, Tezkerei, 1:222230; Mehmed Sreyya,
Sicill-i Osman; 1:151. M. Fahrettin Krzo[lu, Kara-midte 1819 da Ayandan
}eyhzdelerin ncl[nde Milli Deli-Behram Pa{aya Kar{ Ayaklanma Ve Sonucu.
Kara mid Dergisi, 24 (195658): 356.
47
Ylmazelik, XIX. Yzyln ilk Yarsnda, 484.
48
MMD 2931:122.

190

imports. His tari agents continued to impose the full gmrk tax
(and not simply a fee, the bac) on the transit trade that passed through
the city.49 In a particularly troubled decade, when Wahhabi incursions into Najd and the resulting disruption of trac through Basra
cost Baghdad some quarter million kuru{ in customs revenues, his
militias policed the highways leading southward and guarded trac
from the depredations of Kurdish tribes.50 Personal wealth was invested
in infrastructure. (brahim dedicated one of several large family waqf
to the building of a forty-one room caravansaray complete with stables within the city walls.51
The ruling elites portfolio of assets, private and public, also suggests a certain balance in policies and a vested interest in reconciling the concerns of the citys long-distance and regional merchants
with those of its artisans and tradesmen. The pasha, his family, and
members of his advisory council, the divan, maintained their holdings in contracts on local and regional products. In addition to agricultural rents and revenues, they possessed contracts on local manufacturing taxes, such as the fees on white cotton twist.52 Since his
rst public oce as intendant in 1796, (brahim had held the lucrative malikne on the excise tax on the interregional trade in snu.53
That is not to say that (brahim opposed opening the towns market to long distance goods. A notarized appendix to the Diyarbekir
tari lists the new commodities that the governors own traders
introduced into the city. Most were European goods, including
Flemish, presumably, manufactured cotton thread.54

49
On inter-urban rivalries over tari: MMD 10,241: 230 (1798); CD 3582 (1811);
CI 990 (1815).
50
(brahim Ylmazelik, XIX. Yzyln ilk Yarsnda Diyarbakr 17901840, 2 vols.
(Ph.D. diss., Frat University, 1991), 216217; (brahim }eyhzde 178485 merited
an entry in Yasin al-'Umaris contemporary history of Iraq (al-Durr al-Maknn f
al-Ma"thir al-Mdiya min al-Qurun, critical ed., Sayyar Kawkab 'Ali al-Jaml (Ph.D.
diss. University of St. Andrews, U.K.), 443; CD 9713.
51
Ylmazelik, XIX. Yzyln ilk Yarsnda Diyarbakr, 178.
52
MMD 9519:102,80,23. One of the shareholders in 18161817 was Ishak Efendi,
mderris (scholar) and the secretary of the administrative council (divan) of the defunct
}eyhzde (brahim.
53
MMD 9519:22. MMD 9722:43. }amlu Eb Bekir (d. 179394) was an appointee
as tari keeper ( gmrk) as early as (brahim Pashas tenure as voyvoda.
54
KK 5249:18. Stamped by the judge of Amid, Seyyid Mehmed, it lists the
goods transported by his [}eyhzdes] merchants.

191

Despite these extensive regional powers, (brahim Pasha remained


a loyal public servant of the empire. Upon his death, the family surrendered the pashas accounts and wealth to the probate oce for
assessment and expropriation. His malikne contracts and household
eects were auctioned for the benet of the sc. But the bureaucrats in Istanbul did not touch other assets. The pashas considerable endowments, including the family villas and a caravan saray,
remained intact.55 Members of his family would continue to play a
signicant role in local government and enjoy the political and economic fruits of privilege through their malikne contracts and city
oces.

The Diyarbekir Commune of 1819


As this brief history of Amids interregnum history suggests, vernacular government might have provided the basis for a type of federalism within the empire. But the agreement was short lived. In fact,
the Istanbul elite may never have regarded the charter as a binding agreement and certainly did not consider it the forerunner of a
constitutional monarchy.56 After Bayraktar Mustafa Pashas death, it
did serve to temporize with the gentry until such time as bureaucrats and statesmen could mount the next phase of state centralization. Freed from other commitments with the conclusion of the war
with Russia in 1812 and buered by Western Europes preoccupation with the Napoleonic Wars, Mahmud II initiated a series of campaigns to install central authority in the Asian provinces. Fanning
out across Anatolia, by 1818, his commanders contemplated the eastern frontier. One of their major targets was the regime of Mehmed

55

CM 25,214.
On the Young Ottomans, see }erif Mardin, The Genesis of Young Ottoman Thought:
A Study in the Modernization of Turkish Political Ideas (Princeton: Princeton University
Press, 1962); and (lber Ortayl, Tanzimattan Cumhuriyete Yerel Ynetim Gelene[i (Istanbul:
Hil Yaynlar, 1985); idem, (mparatorlu[un En Uzun Yzyl (Istanbul: Hil Yaynlar,
1987). For later variations, see Yusuf Akuras Osmanl Devletinin Da[lma Devri (XVIII
ve XIX asrlarda) (Ankara: Trk Tarih Kurumu Basmevi, 1988). For more on decentralization, see Niyazi Berkes, Trkiyede Ca[da{lama (Istanbul: Do[u-Bat Yaynlar,
1978), 102. The emphasis on centralization in late Ottoman and Turkish Republican
political thought is often attributed to Durkheim. See also, Bertrand Badie and
Pierre Birnbaum, The Sociology of the State, trans. Arthur Goldhammer (Chicago: The
University of Chicago Press, 1983), 12.
56

192

Dervi{ Pasha, the lord who controlled the critical leg of the transit
route between the Iranian frontier and Diyarbekir, on one side, and
the Black Sea region on the other.57 His regime was well entrenched.
Troops from Erzurum, Mu{, ldr, Sivas, Bozuk (Yozgat), Trabzon,
and Diyarbekir were needed to carry out the nal assault on the
fortied city of Van.
The province of Diyarbekir lay south of Van. According to the
strategic map of the modern state drawn by the sultans advisors, its
capital, Amid, was next on the list of governments to be brought
back into the imperial fold. Here, however, the state was forced to
consider other tactics. Unlike Van, Diyarbekirs government was not
merely one-man rule. Undoubtedly fearing popular resistance, Istanbul
searched for a pretext for intervention. It found one in a controversial candidate for the governorship. Behram Pasha, the new governor, was a member of the Deli branch of the Kurdish Milan tribe
and a sworn enemy of the house of the }eyhzde. His appointment
seems to have been calculated to incite the urban elite. His mission,
as the historian }anzade sanitizes it, was to put in order (tertib
edp) Diyarbekirs urban aairs, ending, once and for all, gentrys
hold on the deputy governorship.
Although ocial and provincial accounts dier widely, there is no
dispute over the scale and intensity of popular resistance to Behram
Pasha. In the ocial annals the citys opposition to the new governor was no long a matter of rebellion (ihtilal ) as it had been recorded
in 1802. In 1819, the towns deance constituted outright civil war
( tna).58 Absent local testimony, there might be no means of challenging the Istanbul version of the last days of federalism in Diyarbekir.
Fortunately, one witness account is preserved in a later provincial
history.59 Its author, Hac Ragb Bey, who suf-fered exile because of
his involvement, described the denouement of the rebellion: The new
governor entered the citys basalt portals on July 18, 1819. Behram

57
Local opinions on the government of Van prior to the campaign of 1818 were
not unfavorable to the lord according to James Brant, Journey through a part of
Armenia and Asia Minor in the Year 1835, Journal of the Royal Geographical Society
10 (1841): 395.
58
}anizade, Tarih vol. 3, 54.
59
The manuscript has been lost. Krzo[lus source (Kara-midte 1819da
Ayandan }eyhzdeler, 35058, 37576) is the manuscript of Abdulghani Bulduk,
an early twentieth-century historian of the city of Diyarbekir, who cites from it
extensively.

193

Pasha summoned the urban leadership to hear his mandate. I was


sent [by the state] to destroy you, he proclaimed to Amids townsmen, to scatter your belongings [to the wind] and to burn your
houses [to the ground]. With this declaration of war, he beat a
hasty retreat to the citadel. From this heavily fortied position, troops
began an artillery assault on the city, raining death and destruction
on the villas of the gentry as well as the workshops and residences
of artisans in the adjoining quarter.
In self-defense, townsmen attacked the citadel. Merchants and
craftsmen withdrew goods from the market and stopped paying taxes.
The gentry coalesced under the leadership of a member of the
}eyhzde clan, Mehmed. They blockaded the external door of the
citadel. For a time, these actions prevented the governor from obtaining fresh supplies from the Tigris or from summoning help from the
Ergani mine. Yet word eventually reached its intendant, Nurullah
Pasha, who dispatched troops to the governors aid southward along
the main highway bisecting the province.
For three months this city of some forty to fty thousand inhabitants repelled the sultans armies at its gates. In addition to the
horsemen of the Milan Kurds and troops from Ergani, reinforcements and armaments poured into the province from the northern
Anatolian cities of Erzurum, Van, and ldr, as well as from Aleppo,
Adana, and Sivas.
A brutally long siege and the superior repower of the army nally
brought the city to its knees on October 26, 1819. The rebellion
exacted a staggering toll on the city which would be felt long into
the century. Nearly a third of the population suered casualties.
Seven to eight hundred families were sent into exile. The }eyhzde
themselves took refuge in the outskirts of Hani while many other
leading townsmen, master craftsmen, and merchants resettled in
Baghdad, Damascus, and Basra. With the communards defeated,
Behram Pashas successor could easily complete the task of extirpating local government. The new governor expropriated the taxfarms and retracted the venal oces from the rebellious gentry. After
Diyarbekir, Istanbuls campaign of consolidation would move on to
northern Syria.60

60
See Cemal Tukin, Mahmud II. Devrinde Halep Isyan: 18131819, Tarih
Vesikalar 1 (1941): 256264.

194


Of Democracy and the New Despotism

The Diyarbekir commune represented one of unnished revolutions


at the end of the old regime. Cevdet Pashas History faithfully recorded
the Charter of Federation and devoted pages to the 1819 Diyarbekir
rebellion. The Tanzimat historian betrayed no sympathy for the grievances of provincial city. Instead, his account suggests that factional
struggles, specically blood feuds between local gentry and the Kurdish
tribes, were the root cause of the violence.61
Hindsight left little room for another explanation for the surge of
resistance to state centralization. By the mid-nineteenth century, the
historians vantage point was transxed: Selim III and his successors
had begun to bring everything into order; they reconstructed a
state that the gentry and magnates had nearly torn apart.62 The
wages of decentralization in the context of a newly emerging political
order based on unitary states seemed all too clear: in the course of
the rst four decades of the nineteenth century, Greece, Algeria, and
ultimately Egypt had all but been lost to the empire. The Tanzimat
programs of 183976, premised on top-down administrative reforms,
seemed to succeed where the loose federalism of the previous century had failed. Bureaucrats and state ocials made new institutional
inroads into provincial governance; they implanted new land codes
and uniform urban administrations from Bulgaria to Iraq.63
While the trappings of culture, the imbalance of power and blinders of ideology severed the ties between adjoining regions and gave
European thinkers the illusion of a chronology all their own, Tanzimat
bureaucrats were also collaborators in the theory and praxis of the
modern state.64 Where the Ottoman elite blamed late centralization
and disunity for their vulnerability in the face of European military
power and colonial expansion, French intellectuals tied the question
of centralization to domestic struggles over the extent of popular sov-

61
Cevdet Pasha (Tarih, vol. 11, 65, 679, 83) refers to (brahims brutal repression of the Viran{ehir branch of the Milan tribe and his repeated reprisals against
the Deli Milan during his long tenure between 18078 and 1814.
62
Cevdet, Tarih, vol. 6, 221.
63
See Huri Islamo[lu, Property as a Contested Domain: A Reevaluation of the
Ottoman Land Code of 1858, in New Perspectives on Property and Land in the Middle
East, ed. Roger Owen (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2000), 363.
64
A point taken up Selim Deringil, The Well-Protected Domains: Ideology and the
Legitimation of Power in the Ottoman Empire, 18761909 (London: I. B. Tauris, 1998).

195

ereignty, particularly in the wake of the revolutions of 1789 and 1848.


In contrast to the French Legitimists, including Arthur de Gobineau
and Ernst Renan, who sought institutional decentralization and the
restoration of feudal privilege as means of restraining Frances teaming masses,65 Tocqueville believed in the dialectic evolution of democracy and institutional centralization. Increasing state centralization,
he argued, would yield stable government and economic prosperity.
If this formula had failed elsewhere, Tocqueville maintained, it was
due not to race or climate, as Gobineau claimed, but to religion
and civilization.
Christianity played a critical role in Tocquevilles political theory.
Repeatedly in The Old Rgime he reminds his readers of the need for
the counterweight of the Church against the ever-present threat of
despotism. Religious dierence also allowed him to reconcile his belief
in human equality with his advocacy of colonialism. Dispensing with
a thorough study of Islamic history and thought, a cursory reading
of the Quran was sucient to construct a world contrary to Western
civilization. For Tocqueville, Islam constituted a polity out of kilter,
an unforgiving and unyielding ideology that pitched societies between
the extremes of super-centralized authority and destructive anarchy.
In Kantian terms, Muslim society did not exemplify stasis, but
rather the absolute terror of social regression (a step backward from
paganism) and a generalized threat to civilization (deadly to
mankind). As such, Tocquevilles ideas are very much in harmony
with the segregation practiced by French colonialists in Algeria.
Membership in the republic might not demand a single national or
racial origin, but it did require a common religious aliation.66
Despite the underlying religious prejudices that sustained his political philosophy and practice, Tocqueville was well aware of the perils and pitfalls of the modern state. From his rst explorations in
North America, where he sought to elucidate key relationships between
cultures and systems of government, he scanned the world for evidence and comparative cases. He oers analyses on states from Russia
to Mexico and from Britain to the Ottoman Empire.67 Even at this
early stage of his career, Tocqueville was well aware that the unitary state had proliferated far beyond its prototype in revolutionary
65
66
67

Hazareesingh, From Subject to Citizen, 967, 13031; 17172; 191.


Jardin, Tocqueville, 203, 208, 31822.
Ibid., 248; Tocqueville, Oeuvres complte, vol. 3, pt. 1, 29253.

196

France. With it, came the dangers of despotism: the full, unmediated force of the worlds most dangerous weapon on the individual
was no longer blunted by the peculiar government-state relationship
of the old regime or the aristocratic hierarchy. At one extreme the
modern state could be a prison, like Czarist Russia. In a country of
pashas and paupers, like Mehmet Alis Egypt, the state could become
forced-labor factory.68 Although Tocqueville regarded these examples
as a travesty of modern polity and assured himself that only the
most extraordinary conditions, such as a state of total anarchy or
revolution, could bring despotism to Western Europe,69 he realized
that Europeans had reason to be wary. The future of democratic
government would rest more heavily on the individual. As in nineteenth century Britain, it could be corrupted by the passivity of its
citizenry or the excessive inuence of money.
With the 1851 coup dtat that suspended the bourgeois constitution and brought Napoleon III (r. 18521870) to power, Tocqueville
confronted the perils of the modern state close at hand. Although
he retired from active participation in the political arena, his biographer Andr Jardin notes that his voluminous correspondence between
1851 and his death in 1859 continued to run the gamut of domestic and foreign policy.70 Despite poor health, he eagerly awaited
Gobineaus letters from Iran and continued to condemn slavery as
a violation of the most basic concepts of Christianity.71
On one topic, however, Tocqueville is inexplicably silent. For a
politician who had been consumed by colonial aairs for decades,
it is remarkable that he ceased to comment on Frances colonial policy in Africa. Was he frustrated by the character of colonial rule
after the defeat of 'Abd al-Qadir in 1847 and the incorporation of
the colons as citizens after 1848? Did his inclusion of an appendix
on Canada in The Old Rgime merely express nostaglia for empire
lost or was the comment colonies bear the imprint of the metropole, in fact a pointed reminder to his countrymen that posterity
would judge the nation by its legacy of imperialism in North Africa?
Or had his political philosophy itself been altered? One might ask
whether his silence might have signaled that the neat, binary divi-

68
69
70

Jardin, Tocqueville, 6970; 375, 266. Tocqueville, Oeuvres complte, vol. 2, 30013.
Jardin, Tocqueville, 26768.
Jardin, Tocqueville, 333.

197

sion between European states and their non-Western rivals had begun
to disintegrate. Recent experience had given him reason for pause.
In contrast to the cooperation of the Ottoman representative in Rome
who readily agreed to take in the refugees from 1848, a down payment on their obligations as a future member of the Concert of
Europe, there was the utter intransigence of the Vatican. While
Istanbul embraced reforms, the Papacy rebued even the most minor
eort toward political change. And then there were the events in
France itself: in what way did the caudillismo of Latin America dier
from Bonapartism? Although the Congress of Vienna had insured
Frances territorial integrity, did not the rocky transition from the
old regime, the radical swings between revolution, monarchy, republic and empire, mirror to an uncomfortable degree, the decades of
civil war, restoration, and the quasi-constitutional sultanate of the
Ottoman Empire?
Tocqueville might have reassured himself with the thought that
barring extreme conditions, European societies could not produce a
despotism like that of Russia or the Turks. However, in the wake
of the Revolutions of 1848 and the putsch of 1851, such condence
in the internal regulating principles of Europes political society was
no longer rm.72 In his last political essay, The Old Rgime and the
French Revolution, he turned away from the present to search for the
roots of modern institutions and social relationships in the last century of the ancien rgime. By turning the clock backward, long before
the French Revolution, he may have hoped to nd in those cahiers
evidence of the enduring virtues of the nation, to cast a conceptual
anchor amid the turbulent nineteenth-century political sea.
In writing the rst of what was planned to be two volumes on
the history of the French Revolution, Tocqueville carefully demarcates the geographical limits of his inquiry. Despite furnishing ample
evidence to the contrary, he repeatedly reminds his readers of the
inevitable emergence of the modern state from the baroque cocoon
of the old regime. In rehabilitating the eighteenth-century, he admits
many of the paradoxes while creating an overarching sense of order,

71
For his correspondence with Arthur de Gobineau from Switzerland and Iran,
after 1851 see Tocqueville, Oeuvres compltes, 9: 157 .
72
Hazareesingh (From Subject to Citizen, 23132), calls this the liberalism of fear.
John Keane, Despotism and Democracy, in Civil Society and the State: New European
Perspectives, ed. idem (London: Verso, 1988), 65.

198

a vision of political progress amidst the anticipated upheaval of


revolution and the hubris of empire. In such an ideologically-motivated treatise, it should be expected, therefore, that he purge any
embarrassing connections between the Bourbons and their long-standing Muslim allies. Although he credits the Physiocrats, only grudging mention is made of the profound inuence of Asian statecraft
on Europes political imagination.73
Yet even in text that consciously eschews all of the barbed comparison between the Bourbon monarchy and Oriental despot that
was signature of the Enlightenment critique of absolutism, Tocqueville
makes but one, albeit highly evocative, reference to Islam. Oddly,
the lone reference occurs in an introductory passage in which the
author takes on one of the intellectual ghosts of his own age, Edmund
Burke, on the place of the French Revolution in modern history.
He defends the necessity of the Revolution within the larger scope
of Western political development even as he distances itself from its
radicalism and admits the exceedingly dangerous combination of
mass mobilization with the machinery of the modern state. Even as
he lays claim to his national heritage, he grasps at the rhetorical
means of separating himself from the fury its ideologies of equality
and the violence of its citizen armies. It is as if the author cannot
bear the thought that roots of the Terror and Napoleons European
empire might reside within French society or the centralized state.
Reaching for an historical analogy with which to denounce
Jacobinism, as well as to blame its ideological contagion on a world
beyond France, momentarily, Tocqueville looks across the Mediterranean.74 In a metaphor that he will repeat again in the notes to
the second volume of this study, he transforms these ideologies of

73

Tocqueville, The Old Regime, 197, 2045.


Because the Revolution seemed to be striving for the regeneration of the
human race even more than the reform of France, it lit a passion which the most
violent political revolutions had never before been able to produce. It inspired conversation and generated propaganda . . . it itself became a new kind of religion, an
incomplete religion, it is true, without God, without ritual, and without a life after
death, but one which nevertheless, like Islam ooded the earth with its soldiers,
apostles, and martyrs. The Old Rgime, 101. He repeats this metaphor. Tocqueville,
Notes on the French Revolution and Napoleon, The Old Regime and the French Revolution
(Lancien rgime et la Rvolution), ed. Franois Furet and Franoise Mlonio, trans. by
Alan S. Kahan (Chicago: University of Chicago, 1998) vol. 2, 180, 263, 446, 459.
As Furet and Melonio (ibid., 459) point out, for this metaphor as well, he is indebted
to a royalist writer, Mallet du Pan.
74

199

liberation into an alien religion. Instead of crediting Napoleon with


building the modern state or praising his advocacy of religious tolerance, he casts the First Consul as a Rights of Man thumping
missionary who wins converts with the promise of equality, a swordbearing prophet who respected neither the integrity of borders nor
the dierences between civilizations. Above all, he betrays his fear
of the unfathomable power of the modern state and a revolution
that had not yet run its course but, which had like Islam ooded
the earth with its soldiers, apostles and martyrs.

This page intentionally left blank

COLOUR PLATES

This page intentionally left blank

terminal histories and arthurian solutions

31

Plate 1. The procession of the esnaf (guilds) began with the farmer, the miller and the
bread maker. A young man reads verses from the Qur}an on camel-back. From Levnis
illustrated Surnme-i Vehbi (TKSK Ms. A 3593, fol. 72a). Courtesy of Topkap Saray
Museum.

60

chapter two

Plate 2. Sultan Ahmed III and his son-in-law, Grand Vizier `brahim Pasha view the
festivities. From Levnis illustrated Surnme-i Vehbi (TKSK Ms. A 3593, fol. 71b).
Courtesy of Topkap Saray Museum.

terminal histories and arthurian solutions

31

Plate 3. A vision of order: the eyh} l-`slam, jurists and ulema are at the top rung; they
are followed by viziers, ministers, generals, members of the divan- hmayun, and finally
the treasurers. Janissaries guard the perimeter. From Levnis illustrated Surnme-i Vehbi
(TKSK Ms. A 3593, fol. 21a). Courtesy of Topkap Saray Museum.

60

chapter two

Plate 4. A vision of disorder: the janissaries trip over themselves and one another in a
mad dash to claim their plates of rice. From Levnis illustrated Surnme-i Vehbi (TKSK
Ms. A 3593, fol. 23a). Courtesy of Topkap Saray Museum.

terminal histories and arthurian solutions

31

Plate 5. The French ambassadors seated in front of the stern faced Russian emissaries
seem to be amused by the scene of raucous firemen, clowns, and the float of the
weavers of gold cloth. From Levnis illustrated Surnme-i Vehbi (TKSK Ms. A 3593, fol.
140a). Courtesy of Topkap Saray Museum.

60

chapter two

Plate 6. The sultan has returned to the palace at the conclusion of the festivities. He
rewards his servants with a distribution of gold coins. From Levnis illustrated, Surnmei Vehbi (TKSK Ms. A 3593, fol. 175a). Courtesy of Topkap Saray Museum.

GLOSSARY
Ake
A[a
Askeri
yan
Bab- li
Bac
Berat
Beylerbeyi
Beyt"l-mal
Cebel Bedeliyesi
Cizye
iftlik
Defter
Defterdar
Divan
Du""gyn
Dar s-Sade A[as
Efendi
Esnaf
E{rf
Eyalet
Fatwa
Gedik
Gmrk
Hass
Hatt- Hmayn
Hkmet
Hkm
(lmiye
(ltizam
Kad
Kalemiye
Kanun
Kanunnme
Ktib

Small silver coin (or asper)


Military ocer or landlord
Belonging to the tax-exempt estate
Gentry, town fathers
Sublime Porte, the state apparatus
Toll, market tax
Diploma, certicate.
Provincial commander, military governor
Public weal, trust of the Muslim community
Wartime payment in lieu of military service
Poll tax
Unit of plowland, eld, or plantation.
Register, any type of bound record
Controller, imperial treasurer
Advisory council
Religious dignitaries receiving state stipends
Senior Black Eunuch
Title for high-ranking ocial or dignitary
Occupational or artisanal association
Descendants of the Prophet
Province (also vilyet)
Religious opinion issued by a mufti
Bureaucratic or military post, life tenure
Taxes on inter-urban and interstate commerce
Crown estate or benece (also, hass- hmayn)
Imperial rescript
Hereditary, semi-autonomous estate
Judgement on a petition, an order
Judiciary, the state ulema
Revenue contract
Ottoman judge
Bureaucracy, clerks
Imperial statute
Code, charter, or compilation of statutes
Secretary, clerk, or scribe

202
Kaza
Kap
Kapkulu
Kapcba{
Kuru{
Malikne Mukataa
Maktu
Miri
Muaccele
Mukataa
Mufti
Mlk
Mltezim
Msadere
Mtesellim
Nahiye
Ocaklk
Polie
Reaya
Re"is"l-Kttb
Rical- Devlet
Sancak
}eyh'l-(slam
Sipahi
Tanzimat
Timar
Ulema
Vali
Voyvoda
Voyvodalk
Waqf
Zeamet

Judicial subdistrict within a sancak


Household, retainers and sta
Salaried military corps
Palace chamberlain
Silver coin equivalent to 120 ake
Tax contract for the life of the contractor
Tax paid in a lump sum by a group
Pertaining or belonging to the state
Surety or down payment on a malikne mukataa
Fiscal unit (pl. Mukatat)
Leading Muslim religious authority
Personal or private property
Tax farmer
Expropriation of an ocial
Deputy governor
Canton, a subcomponent of a kaza
Revenue tagged for an individual or group
Letter of credit
Tax payer, the third estate
Secretary of state
Ranking ocials and ocers
Military district, also known as liva
Chief justice of the empire
Ordinary cavalry ocer/administrator
Ottoman reform programs of 183976
Tax benece of an ordinary sipahi
Muslim religious scholars, lawyers
Provincial governor-commander
Financial agent, tax-farm supervisor
Block of tax farms supervised by a voyvoda
Endowment established under Islamic law
Intermediate-sized tax ef or benece

BIBLIOGRAPHY

Unpublished Sources
Ba{bakanlk Ar{ivi (Istanbul)
(Muallim) Cevdet:
Adliye, Askeriye, Bedeliye, Dahiliye, (ktisat, Maliye, Timar, and Zaptiye.
Ahkm Defterleri:
Diyarbekir vols. I (115567/174254); II (116776/175463); II (117680/176380);
IV (11941202/178088); V (120628/17921813).
Istanbul vols. IIV; Sivas vols. IIV; Haleb vols. IV; and Erzurum vols. IV.
(selections).
Bb- Defteri Ba{muhsebe Kalemi/Diyarbekir Hazinesi.
Bb- Defteri Mevkft Kalemi.
Ba{muhsebe Kalemi.
Kmil Kepeci Defteri.
Maliyeden Mdevver Defterleri.
Milli Ktphane (Ankara)
}er"iye Sicilleri:
Mardin: Nos. 195 (11731178); 203 (11351156); 227 (11651270); 237 (11181277);
241 (11871196); 248 (11701173); 251 (11261130); 255 (11531263).
Diyarbekir: Nos. 310 (11451145); 313 (11601212); 315 (11541155); 360 (11511154);
576 (11701266).
Trkiye Diyanet Vak (slm Ara{trmalar Merkezi (Istanbul)
}er"iye Sicilleri (microlm of originals in Istanbul Mftl[):
Istanbul Kismet-i Askeriye Mahkemesi.
Sleymniye Ktphane (Istanbul)
Manuscripts:
Izmir 782. pts. 1 and 2 (n.d.).
Esad Efendi 2362. pt. 8 (menzilname, Istanbul-India, n.d.).
Hac Mahmud 5657. Kann-i Cedid der Beyn-i Tapu (1104/16921693).
Topkap Saray Mzesi Library (Istanbul)
Manuscripts:
A. 3593 Levni, Surnme-i Vehbi (Illustrated Album).
B. 223 Seyyid Vehbi, Surnme-i Vehbi (text).
H. 446. Menzilname (Istanbul-Mecca, ca. 1750).
H. 447 Map of Eurasia (1139/172627).
Published References and Studies
Abdel Nour, Antoine. Introduction lHistorie Urbaine de la Syrie Ottomane (XVIXVIII
sicles). Beirut: Publications de lUniversit Libanaise, 1982.

204

. Le Rseau Routier de la Syrie Ottomane (XVIeXVIIIe sicles). Arabica 30


(1983): 169189.
Abdullah, Thabit. A. J. Merchants, Mamluks, and Murder: The Political Economy of Trade
in Eighteenth-Century Basra. Albany: State University of New York Press, 2001.
Abou El Fadl, Khaled. Tax Farming in Islamic Law (Qibalah and Daman of
Kharaj): A Search for a Concept. Islamic Studies 31 (1992): 532.
Abou-El-Haj, Rifa"at "Ali. The Formal Closure of the Ottoman Frontier in Europe.
JOAS 89 (1969): 467475.
. The Ottoman Vezir and Pasha Households, 16831703: A Preliminary
Report. JOAS 94 (1972): 438447.
. The 1703 Rebellion and the Structure of Ottoman Politics. Istanbul: Nederlands
Historisch-Archaeologisch: Instituut te Istanbul, 1984.
. Formation of the Modern State: The Ottoman Empire Sixteenth to Eighteenth Centuries.
Albany: State University of New York Press, 1991.
Abu-Husayn, Abdul-Rahim. The (ltizam of Mansur Faraykh: A Case Study of
(ltizam in Sixteenth Century Syria. In Land Tenure and Social Transformation in the
Middle East, 249256. Edited by Tarif Khalidi. Beirut: American University in
Beirut Press, 1984.
Abu-Lughod, Janet L. Before European Hegemony: The World System A.D. 12501350.
Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1989.
Adivar, Abdulhak Adnan. Osmanl Trklerinde (lim. Istanbul: Maarif Matbaas, 1943.
Ahmed Resmi Efendi. Hamiletl-Kber. Edited by Ahmet Nezihi Turan. Istanbul:
Istanbul Kitabevi, 2000.
Akarl, Engin, D. Provincial Power Magnates in Ottoman Bilad al-Sham and Egypt,
17401840. In La vie sociale dans les provinces arabes lpoque ottomane, vol. 3: 4156.
Edited by Abdeljelil Temimi. Tunis: Publications du Centre dtudes et de Recherches Ottomanes, Morisques, de Documentation et dInformations, 1988.
Akbal F.,1831 Tarihinde Osmanl (mparatorlu[unda (dari Taksimat ve Nfus.
Belleten 15 (1951): 621622.
Akura, Yusuf. Osmanl Devletinin Da[lma Devri (XVIII ve XIX. Asrlarda). Ankara:
TTK, 1988.
Akda[, Mustafa. Celali (syanlarndan Byk Kagunluk 16031606. Tarih Ara{trmalar
Dergisi 2 (1964): 150.
Akgndz, Ahmet, et al., eds. }er"iye Sicilleri. 2 vols. Istanbul: Trk Dnyas Ara{trmalar
Vak, 1988.
Aksan, Virginia. Ottoman Sources of Information on Europe in the Eighteenth
Century. Archivum Ottomanicum 11 (1986): 516.
. Ottoman War and Warfare, 14531812. In War in the Early Modern World,
147176. Edited by Jeremy Black. London: University College London Press,
1999.
. Ottoman Political Writing, 17681808. IJMES 23 (1993): 5369.
. The One-Eyed Fighting the Blind: Mobilization, Supply and Command in
the Russo-Turkish War of 17681774. The International History Review 15 (1993):
221238.
. An Ottoman Statesman in War and Peace, Ahmed Resmi Efendi, 17001783. Leiden:
E. J. Brill, 1995.
. Locating the Ottomans among Early Modern Empires. Journal of Early
Modern History 3 (1999): 132.
Aktepe, M. Mnir. Patrona (syan (1730). Istanbul: Edebiyat Fakltesi, 1958.
. Nev{ehirli (brahim Pa{a. (A, 9:234239.
Alam, Muzaar. The Crisis of Empire in Mughal North India: Awadh and the Punjab,
17071748. Delhi: Oxford University Press, 1986.
Alam, Muzaar and Sanjay Subrahmanyam, eds. The Mughal State 15261750. New
York: Oxford University Press, 1998.

205

Ali Emiri. Tezkere-i }u"ar-y Amid. Vol. 1. Istanbul: Matbua-y Amidi, 1328/19101911.
Alorabi, Abdulrahman. The Ottoman Policy in the Hejaz in the Eighteenth Century:
A Study of Political and Admistrative Developments, 11431202 A.H./17311788
A.D. Ph.D. diss., University of Utah, 1988.
[Altnay]. Ahmet Rek. Istanbul Hayat (11001200). Istanbul: Devlet Matbaas, 1930.
. Lle Devri. Istanbul: Hilmi Kitabhanesi, 1932.
Anderson, M. S. The Eastern Question, 17741923: A Study in International Relations.
Houndmills: Macmillan Education, 1987.
Anderson, Perry. Lineages of the Absolutist State. London: Verso, 1974.
Anville, Jean Baptiste Bourguignon d. claircissements gographiques sur la carte de lInde.
Paris: De lImprimerie royale, 1753.
Arapyan, Kalost. Rusuk Ayn Mustafa Pa{ann Hayat ve Kahramanlklar. Ankara: TTK,
1943.
Ardant, Gabriel. Financial Policy and Economic Infrastructure of Modern States
and Nations. In The Formation of National States in Western Europe, 164242. Edited
by Charles Tilly. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1975.
Ardel, Ahmed, ed. Gneydo[u Anadolu"da Co[raf M{ahedeler. Trk Co[rafya
Dergisi 17 (1961): 140148.
Arkan, Zeki. Osmanl (mparatorlu[unda (hrac Yasak Mallar. In Prof. Dr. Bekir
Ktko[lu Arma[an, 279306. Edited by Mbahat S. Ktko[lu. Istanbul: Edebiyat
Fakltesi Basmevi, 1991.
Aron, Raymond. Les tapes de la pense sociologique. Montesquieu. Comte. Marx. Tocqueville.
Durkheim. Pareto. Weber. Paris: Gallimard, 1967.
Arrighi, Giovanni. The Long Twentieth Century: Money, Power and the Origins of Our Times.
London: Verso, 1984.
Artan, Tlay. From Charismatic Leadership to Collective Rule. Toplum ve Ekonomi
4 (1993): 5394.
Atan, Turhan. Trk Gmrk Tarihi. Vol. 1. Ba{langtan Osmanl Devletine Kadar. Ankara:
TTK, 1990.
Atl, Esin. Surnme-i Vehbi: An Eighteenth Century Book of Festivals. 2 vols.
Ph.D. diss., University of Michigan, 1969.
. The Story of an Eighteenth-Century Ottoman Festival. Muqarnas 10 (1993):
181211.
. and mer Koc, eds. Levni and the Surname: The Story of an Eighteenth-Century
Ottoman Festival. Seattle: University of Washington Press, 2000.
Atkin, Muriel. Russia and Iran, 17801828. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota
Press, 1980.
Avery, Peter, Gavin Hambly, and Charles Melville, eds. The Cambridge History of
Iran. Vol. 7: From Nadir Shah to the Islamic Republic. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press, 1990.
Aydin, Veli H. Osmanl Maliyesinde Esham Uygulamas, 17751840. Ph.D. diss.,
Ankara niversitesi, 1998.
Aydin, Suavi, Kudret Emiro[lu, Oktay zel, and Sha nsal. Mardin: A{iret-CemaatDevlet. Istanbul: Tarih Vak, 2000.
Ayn-i Ali Efendi. Kavnin-i l-i Osman der Hlsa-i Mezmin-i Defter-i Divn. Edited
by Tayyib Gkbilgin. Istanbul: Enderun Kitabevi, 1979.
Azimi, Vida. Un modle administratif de lancien rgime: les commis de la ferme gnrale et de
la rgie gnrale des aides. Paris: ditions du Centre National de la Rcherche
Scientique, 1987.
Azz Efendi. Kann-nme-i Sultn li" Azz Efendi. 'Aziz Efendis Book of Sultanic Laws and
Regulation: An Agenda for Reform by a Sevententh-Century Ottoman Statesman. Edited and
trans. by Rhoads Murphey. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1985.
Badie, Bertrand, and Pierre Birnbaum. The Sociology of the State. Trans. Arthur
Goldhammer. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 1983.

206

Baechler, Jean, John A. Hall, and Michael Mann, eds. Europe and the Rise of Capitalism.
New York: B. Blackwell, 1988.
Baer, Gabriel. Ottoman Guilds: A Reassessment. In Trkiye"nin Sosyal ve Ekonomik
Tarihi (10711920), 95102. Edited by Osman Okyar and Halil (nalck. Ankara:
Meteksan, 1980.
Ba[c, Serpil. Osmanl Dnyasnda Efsanevi Ynetici (mgesi Olarak Byk (skender
ve Osmanl (skendernamesi. In Humana Boskurt Gvene Arma[an, 111131. Istanbul:
Kltr Bakanl[, 1994.
., Priscilla Mary I{in, and Selmin Kangal, eds. The Sultans Portrait: Picturing the
House of Osman. Istanbul: Trkiye ({ Bankas, 2000.
Ba[{, Ali (hsan. Osmanl Ticaretinde Gayr Mslimler: Kapitlasyonlar-Beratl Tccarlar,
Avrupa ve Hayriye Tccarlar (17501839). Ankara: Turhan Kitabevi, 1983.
Bagrow, Leo. History of Cartography. 2nd edition, revised and enlarged by R. A.
Skelton. Chicago: Precedent Publishing, 1985.
Bailey, Anne, M., and Josep R. Llobera, eds. The Asiatic Mode of Production: Science
and Politics. London: Routledge & Keegan Paul, 1981.
Bakhit, Muhammad Adnan. The Ottoman Province of Damascus in the Sixteenth Century.
Beirut: Librairie du Liban, 1962.
Barbir, Karl K. From Pasha to Efendi: The Assimilation of Ottomans into Damascene
Society, 15161783. IJTS 1 (197980): 6883.
. Ottoman Rule in Damascus, 17081758. Princeton: Princeton University Press,
1980.
Barkan, mer Lt. Trk-(slm Toprak Hukuku Tatbikatnn Osmanl (mparatorlu[unda Ald[ {ekiller: Mlikne-Divn Sistemi. Trk Hukuk ve (ktisat Tarihi
Mecmuas 2 (193239): 119163.
. Malikne-Divn Sistemi. Trk Hukuk ve (ktisat Tarihi Mecmuas 2 (1939):
119184.
. }ark Ticaret Yollar Hakknda Notlar. IFM 1 (1940): 448456.
. 166970 Mali Ylna Ait bir Osmanl Btesi ve Ekleri. IFM 17 (195556):
193303, 303347.
. Research on the Ottoman Fiscal Surveys. In Studies in the Economic History
of the Middle East from the Rise of Islam to the Present Day, 163171. Edited by Michael
A. Cook. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1970.
. The Price Revolution of the Sixteenth Century: A Turning Point in the
Economic History of the Near East. IJMES 4 (1976): 328.
. Trkiye"de Toprak Meselesi. Toplu Eserler. Vol. 1. Istanbul: Gzlem, 1980.
. Caractre religieux et caractre sculier des institutions ottomanes. In
Contributions lhistoire conomique et sociale de lEmpire Ottoman, 1158. Edited by
Jean-Louis Bacqu-Grammont and Paul Dumont. Leuven: ditions Peeters, 1983.
Barsoumian, Hagop Levon. The Armenian Amira Class of Istanbul. Ph.D. diss.,
Columbia University, 1980.
Barthold, W. An Historical Geography of Iran. Trans. Svat Soucek. Princeton: Princeton
University Press, 1984.
Ba{bakanlk Osmanl Ar{ivi Rehberi. Ankara: T. C. Ba{bakanlk Devlet Ar{ivleri Genel
Mdrl[ Osmanl Ar{ivi Daire Ba{bakanl[, 1992.
Baykal, Bekir Stk. Osmanl (mparatorlu[unda XVII ve XVIII. Yzyllar boyunca
Para Dzeni ile (lgili Belgeler. Belgeler 4 (1967): 4977.
. Mustafa III. (A, 8:700708.
Baykara, Tuncer, ed. Osmanl Ta{ra Te{kilatnda XVIII. Yzylda Grev ve Grevliler
(Anadolu). Ankara: Vakar Genel Mdrl[ Yaynlar, 1990.
Bayly, C. A. Imperial Meridian: The British Empire and the World, 17801830. London:
Longman, 1989.
Baysun, Cavid M. Msadere. (A, 8:669673.
Behar, Cem, and Alan Duben. Istanbul Households: Marriage, Family and Fertility,
1880 1940. Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, 1991.

207

Beldiceanu-Steinherr, Irne. Fiscalit et formes de possession de la terre arabe dans


lAnatolie preottomane. JESHO 19 (1976): 234322.
. Malikne. EI 2, 4: 227228.
Beldiceanu-Steinherr, Irne, and Jean-Louis Bacque-Grammont. propos de quelques
causes de malaises sociaux en Anatolie centrale aux XVIe et XVIIe sicles.
Archivum Ottomanicum 7 (1982): 570.
Bensel, Richard Franklin. Yankee Leviathan: The Origins of Central State Authority in
America, 18591877. New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990.
Berkes, Niyazi, Trkiye"de Ca[da{lama. Istanbul: Do[u-Bat Yaynlar, 1978.
Berktay, Halil. Three Empires and the Societies they Governed: Iran, India and
the Ottoman Empire. The Journal of Peasant Studies 18 (1991): 242263.
Beydilli, Kemal. 1790 Osmanl-Prusya (ttifk (Meydana Geli{i, Tekinda[, Tahlili, Tatbiki).
Istanbul: Istanbul niversitesi Edebiyat Fakltesi Yaynlar, 1984.
. Ignatius Mouradgea DOhsson (Muradcan Tosunyan): Ailesi Hakknda
Kaytlar, Nizm- Cedde dire Lyihas ve Osmanl (mparatolu[undaki Siys
Hayat. Tarih Dergisi, Special issue: Prof. Dr. M. C. }eheddin Tekinda[ Hatra
Says. Edited by M. Cavd Baysun, 34 (198384): 247314.
Beysano[lu, }evket. Btn Cepheleriyle Diyarbakr. Diyarbakr: Diyarbakr Ticaret ve
Sanayi Odas, 1963.
. Diyarbakr Tarihi: Antlar ve Kitabeleri ile. 2 vols. Ankara: Neyir Matbaas,
1990.
Bin Wong, R. China Transformed: Historical Change and the Limits of the European Experience.
Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1997.
Birken, Andreas. Die Provinzen des Osmanischen Reiches. Beihefte zum Tbinger Atlas
des Vorderen Orients. Wiesbaden: Ludwig Reichert, 1976.
Blanchard, Ian. Russias Age of Silver. Precious-Metal Production and Economic Growth in
the Eighteenth Century. London: Routlege, 1989.
Blaeu, Joan. Joan Blaeu and His Grand Atlas: Introduction to the Facsimile Edition of Le
Grand Atlas. Edited by Ir. C. Koeman. Amsterdam: Theatrum Orbis Terrarum,
1970.
Bodin, Jean. Method for the Easy Comprehension of History. Trans. Beatrice Reynolds. New
York: Columbia University Press, 1945.
. Les six livres de la republique. 6 vols. Paris: Fayard, 1986.
. On Sovereignty: Four Chapters from the Six Books of the Commonwealth. Trans. Julian
H. Franklin. New York: Columbia University Press, 1992.
Bodman, Herber L. Political Factions in Aleppo, 17601826. Chapel Hill: The University
of North Carolina Press, 1963.
Bonney, R. The European Dynastic States, 14941660. New York: Oxford University
Press, 1991.
Bosher, J. F. French Finances 1770 1795: From Business to Bureaucracy. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press, 1970.
Bostan, (dris. Rusya"nn Karadeniz"de Ticaret Ba{lamas ve Osmanl (mparatorlu[u
(17001787). Belleten 59 (1995): 353389.
. Osmanl Bahriye Te{kilt XVII. Yzylda Tersne-i mire. Ankara: TTK, 1992.
Brant, James. Journey through a Part of Armenia and Asia Minor in the Year
1835. Journal of the Royal Geographical Society 6 (1836): 187223; 10 (1841): 341
433.
Braudel, Fernand. LEmpire Turc est-il une conomie-monde? In Mmorial mer
Lt Barkan, 3950. Istanbul: Bibliothque de lInstitut Franais dtudes
Anatoliennes dIstanbul, 1980.
Braun, Rudolf. Taxation, Sociopolitical Structure, and State-Building: Great Britain
and Brandenburg-Prussia. In The Formation of the National States, 243327. Edited
by Charles Tilly. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1975.
Brewer, John. The Sinews of Power: War, Money and the English State, 16881783.
London: Unwin, 1989.

208

Brotton, Jerry. Trading Territories: Mapping the Early Modern World. Ithaca: Cornell
University Press, 1998.
Bruess, Gregory L. Religion, Identity and Empire: A Greek Archbishop in the Russia of
Catherine the Great. Boulder: East European Monographs, 1997.
Bruinessen, Martin van. Agha, Shaikh and State: The Social and Political Structures of Kurdistan. London: Zed, 1992.
Buckingham, J. S. Travels in Mesopotamia including a Journey from Aleppo, Across the
Euphrates to Orfah . . . London: Henry Colburn, 1827.
Burchell Graham and Colin Gordon, eds. The Foucault Eect: Studies in Governmentality:
With Two Lectures by and an Interview with Michel Foucault. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press, 1991.
Bulgaru, M. M. Alexandrescu-Dersca. Lapprovisionnement dIstanbul par les
Principauts Roumaines au XVIIIe sicle: commerce ou requisition? RMMM
66 (1992): 7378.
Burton, Audrey J. Relations between Bukhara and Turkey. IJTS 5 (199091):
83103.
Butcher, John, and Howard Dick, eds. The Rise and Fall of Revenue Farming: Business
Elites and the Emergence of the Modern State in Southeast Asia. New York: St. Martins,
1993.
Byres, T. J., and H. Mukhia, eds. Feudalism and Non-European Societies. London: Frank
Cass, 1985.
adrc, Musa. Tanzimat Dneminde Anadolu Kentleri"nin Sosyal ve Ekonomik Yaplar.
Ankara: TTK, 1991.
. Tanzimat"n Sralarnda Trkiye"de Ynetim (18261839). Belleten 51 (1987):
12151240.
Caille, Alain and Jean Starobinski. Critique de la Raison Utilitaire: Manifeste du Mauss.
Paris: La Dcouverte, 1989.
Cassels, Lavender. The Struggle for the Ottoman Empire, 17171740. London: John
Murray, 1966.
Cevdet Pasha (Ahmed). Tarih-i Cevdet. 12 vols. Istanbul: Matbaa-y Osmaniye,
1309/1893.
Chref-ouddne. Chref-Nmeh ou Fastes de la Nation Kourde. Trans. Franois Bernard
Charmoy. St.-Ptersbourg: lAcadmie Impriale des Sciences, 1873.
esmi-zade Mustafa Re{id. esmi-zade Tarihi. Edited by Bekir Ktko[lu. Istanbul:
Istanbul Edebiyat Fakltesi, 1959.
Cezar, Mustafa. Osmanl Tarihinde Levendler. Istanbul: Gzel Sanatlar Akademisi, 1965.
. Typical Commercial Buildings of the Ottoman Classical Period and the Ottoman Construction
System. Istanbul: Trkiye ({ Bankas, 1983.
Cezar, Yavuz. Bir yann Muhallefat: Havza ve Kpr yan Kr (smail-O[lu
Hseyin (Musadere Olay ve Terekenin (ncelenmesi). Belleten 151 (1977): 4178.
. Osmanl Mali Tarihinde Esham Uygulamasnn (lk Dnemlerine (li{kin
Baz nemli ve rnek Belgeler. Toplum ve Bilim 2 (1980): 124143.
. Osmanl Maliyesinde Bunalm ve De[i{im Dnemi (XVIII. Yzyldan Tanzimat"a Mali
Tarih). Istanbul: Alan, 1986.
Chakrabarty, Dipesh. Provincializing Europe: Postcolonial Thought and Historical Dierence.
Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2000.
Chartier, Roger. The Cultural Origins of the French Revolution, Trans. Lydia G. Cohrane.
Durhan: Duke University Press, 1991.
Chaudhuri, K. N. Asia Before Europe: Economy and Civilisation of the Indian Ocean and the
Rise of Islam to 1750. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990.
Cheddadi, Abdessalam. Le systme du pouvoir en Islam daprs Ibn Khaldun.
Annales conomies, socits, civilisations 35 (1980): 534550.
Chehata, Chak. Essai dune theorie gnrale de lobligation en droit Musulman. 2 vols.
Cairo: Nury, 1936.

209

Cin, Halil. Osmanl Toprak Dzeni ve bu Dzenin Bozulmas. Ankara: Ankara Kltr
Bakanl[ Yaynlar, 1978.
izaka, Murat. A Short History of the Bursa Silk Industry (15001900). JESHO
23 (1980): 142152.
. Incorporation of the Middle East into the European World-Economy. Review
8 (1985): 353378.
. A Comparative Evolution of Business Partnerships: The Islamic World and Europe with
Specic Reference to the Ottoman Archives. Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1996.
irakman, Asl. From the Terror of the World to the Sick Man of Europe: Images of
Ottoman Empire and Society from the Sixteenth Century to the Nineteenth. New York: Peter
Lang, 2002.
Clark, John R. The Mapping of the Maliyeden Mdevver 7075. TSA Bulletin 13
(1989): 7990.
Clausewitz, Carl von. On War. Edited and trans. by Michael Howard and Peter
Paret. London: Everymans Library, 1993.
Coase, R. H. The Firm, the Market and the Law. Chicago: University of Chicago Press,
1988.
Cohen, Amnon. Palestine in the Eighteenth Century. Jerusalem: Magnes Press, 1973.
. On the Realities of the Millet System: Jerusalem in the 16th century. In
Christians and Jews in the Ottoman Empire. vol. 2, 714. Edited by Benjamin Braude
and Bernard Lewis. London: Holmes and Meier, 1982.
. Economic Life in Ottoman Jerusalem. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989.
Collins, James B. Fiscal Limits of Absolutism: Direct Taxation in Early Seventeenth-Century
France. Berkeley, CA.: University of California Press, 1988.
Comninel, George C. Rethinking the French Revolution: Marxism and the Revisionists.
London: Verso, 1987.
Constantin, }erban. La suzerainet ottomane a lgard des pays roumains dans
le contexte des rlations internationals europenes (sec. XVIXVII). Tarih Dergisi
32 (1979): 211218.
Cook, Michael A. Studies in the Economic History of the Middle East. London: Oxford
University Press, 1970.
, ed. Population Pressure in Rural Anatolia 14501600. London: Oxford University
Press, 1972.
Copland, Ian and Michael R. Godley. Revenue Farming in Comparative Perspective:
Reections on Taxation, Social Structure and Development in the Early-Modern
Period. In The Rise and Fall of Revenue Farming: Business Elites and the Emergence of
the Modern State in Southeast Asia, 4568. Edited by John Butcher and Howard
Dick. New York: St. Martins Press, 1993.
Coss, P. R. The Formation of the English Gentry. Past and Present 147 (1995): 38
64.
Crouzet, Franois. Wars, Blockade and Economic Change in Europe, 17921815.
Journal of Economic History 24 (1964): 567588.
Cuinet, Vital. La Turquie dAsie: Gographie administrative statistique dscriptive et raisonne
de chaque province delAsie-Mineure. 4 vols. Paris: Ernest Leroux, 18901894.
Cunningham, A. B. The Journal of Christophe Aubin: A Report on the Levant
Trade in 1812. Archivum Ottomanicum 8 (1983): 5132.
Cuno, Kenneth M. The Pashas Peasants: Land, Society and Economy in Lower Egypt,
1740 1858. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1992.
Cvetkova, Bistra. Recherches sur le systme daermage ((ltizam) dans lEmpire
Ottoman au cours du XVIeXVIIIe s. par rapport aux contres bulgares. Rocznik
Orientalistyezny 27 (1964): 111132.
. Les celep et leur rle dans la vie conomique des Balkans lpoque ottomane
(XVeXVIIIe s.). In Studies in the Economic History of the Middle East, 172193.
Edited by Michael A. Cook. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1970.

210

. Les institutions ottomanes en Europe. Wiesbaden: Franz Steiner Verlag, 1978.


iek, Kemal, Ercmen Kuran, Nejat Gyn, (lber Ortayl, et al., eds. The Great
Ottoman-Turkish Civilization. 4 vols. Ankara: Yeni Trkiye, 2000.
DBeth Hillel, Rabbi David. Unknown Jews in Unknown Lands: The Travels of Rabbi
David DBeth Hillel (18241832). Edited and trans. by Walter J Fischel. New York:
Ktav Publishing House, 1973.
Dainville, Franois de. Le langage des gographes: termes, signes, couleurs des cartes anciennes,
1500 1800. Paris: A. et J. Picard, 1964.
Dale, Stephen F. Indian Merchants and Eurasian Trade, 16001700. New York: Cambridge
University Press, 1994.
Danko, Robert. The Intimate Life of an Ottoman Statesman. Albany: State University
of New York Press, 1991.
Darling, Linda T. Revenue-Raising and Legitimacy: Tax Collection and Finance Administration
in the Ottoman Empire, 15601660. Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1996.
Das Gupta, Ashin. Indian Merchants and the Decline of Surat, c. 17001750. Wiesbaden:
Franz Steiner, 1979.
Davis, Natalie Zemon. The Gift in Sixteenth-Century France. Madison: University of
Wisconsin, 2000.
Davis, Ralph. Aleppo and Devonshire Square: English Traders in the Levant in the Eighteenth
Century. London: Macmillan, 1967.
. English Imports from the Middle East, 15801780. In Studies in the Economic
History of the Middle East from the Rise of Islam to the Present Day, 4568. Edited by
Michael A. Cook. London: Oxford University Press, 1970.
Davison, Roderic H. Reform in the Ottoman Empire 18561876. Princeton: Princeton
University Press, 1963.
Deringil, Selim. The Well-Protected Domains: Ideology and the Legitimation of Power in the
Ottoman Empire, 18761909. London: I. B. Tauris, 1998.
Dessert, Daniel. Argent, pouvoir et societ au Grand Sicle. Paris: Fayard, 1984.
Deyon, Pierre Ltat face au pouvoir local: un autre regard sur lhistoire de France (Paris:
Editions Locales de France, 1996
Dickson, P. G. M. Finance and Government under Maria Theresia, 17401780. 2 vols.
Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1987.
Diderot, Denis. Encyclopdie. Edited by John Lough and Jacques Proust. Paris:
Hermann, Editeurs des Sciences et des Arts, 1976.
Diyarbekir Vilyet Salnamesi. 1276/185960.
DOhsson, Mouradgea I. Tableau gnral de lEmpire othoman, divis en deux parties, dont
lune comprend la lgislation mahomtane, lautre, lhistoire de lEmpire othoman. 7 vols. Paris:
M. Firmin Didot Imp., 182024.
Doyle, William. Venality: the Sale of Oces in Eighteenth-Century France. New York:
Clarendon Press, 1996.
, ed. Old Regime France. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2001.
Darperon, L. Le Grand Dessein scret de Louis XIV, Revue de Gographie 1 (1877):
43561.
Doumani, Bishara. Rediscovering Palestine: Merchants and Peasants in Jabal Nablus,
1700 1920. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press, 1995.
Duara, Prasenjit, Culture, Power and the State: Rural North China, 19001942. Stanford,
CA: Stanford University Press, 1988.
Duka, Ferit. XVXVIII. Yzyllarda Arnavut Nfusunun Islamla{mas Sreci zerine Gzlemler. Ankara niversitesi Osmanl Tarihi Ara{trma ve Uygulama Merkezi Dergisi
2 (1991): 6372.
Dzda[, M. Ertu[rul. }eyhlislm Ebussud Efendi Fetvalar. Istanbul: Enderun Kitabevi,
1983.
Edney, Mathew. Mapping an Empire: The Geographical Construction of British India,
17631843. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1990.

211

Eisenstadt, S. N., ed. Modernization: Protest and Change. Englewood Clis, N.J.: Prentice
Hall, 1966.
. The Political Systems of Empires. New York: The Free Press, 1969.
. Political Sociology: A Reader. New York: Basic Books, 1971.
Eldem, Edhem La circulation de la lettre de change entre la France et Constantinople
au XVIIIe sicle. In LEmpire Ottoman, la Republique de Turquie et la France, 8797.
Edited by Hmit Batu and Jean-Louis Bacqu-Grammont. Istanbul-Paris: Isis, 1986.
. Le commerce franais dIstanbul au XVIIIe sicle. Thse de Doctorat.
Universit de Provence-Aix-Marseille I, 1988.
. The Trade in Precious Metals and Bills. In V. Milletleraras Trkiye Sosyal ve
(ktisat Tarihi Kongresi, 579589. Edited by Hakk Dursun Yldz, (nci Enginn and
Emine Grsoy Naskal. Ankara: TTK, 1990.
. French Trade in Istanbul in the Eighteenth Century. Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1999.
Elias, Norbert. The History of Manners. New York: Pantheon, 1978.
. The Court Society. New York: Pantheon, 1983.
Elvin, Mark. The Pattern of the Chinese Past. Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1973.
Emecen, Feridun M. Sefere Gtrlen Defterlerin Defteri. In Prof. Dr. Bekir
Ktko[luna Arma[an, 24168. Edited by Mubahat Ktko[lu. Istanbul: Edebiyat
Fakltesi Basmevi, 1991.
Encyclopedia of Islam. 2nd Edition. Eds. B. Lewis, V. L. Menage, Ch. Pellat and
J. Schacht. Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1971.
Erder, Leila T. The Measurement of Pre-Industrial Population Changes in the
Ottoman Empire from the 15th to the 17th Century. Middle Eastern Studies 11
(1975): 284301.
Erder, Leila T. and Suraiya Faroqhi. The Development of the Anatolian Urban
Network During the Sixteenth Century. JESHO 23 (1980): 265303.
Ergen, zer. Osmanl Klasik Dnemindeki E{raf ve A'yan"zerine Baz Bilgiler.
JOS 3 (1982): 105118.
Ergin, Osman Nuri. Mecelle-i Umur-u Belediye. Istanbul: Istanbul Byk{ehir Belediyesi
Kltr ({leri Daire Ba{kanl[, 1922.
Erim, Ne{e. Onsekizinci Yzylda Erzurum Gmr[. Ph.D. diss., Istanbul niversitesi, 1984.
. Trade, Traders, and the State in Eighteenth-Century Erzurum. New Perspectives
on Turkey 56 (1991): 12350.
Evans, Peter B., Dietrich Rueschemeyer, and Theda Skopcol, eds. Bringing the State
Back In. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1985.
Evliya elebi. Evliya elebi in Bitlis: The Relevant Section of the Seyahatname. Edited and
trans. by Robert Danko. Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1990.
. Evliya elebi in Diyarbekir. Edited and trans. by Martin Van Bruinessen and
Hendrik Boeschoten. Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1988.
Fahmy, Khaled. All the Pashas Men: Mehmed Ali, his Army, and the Making of Modern
Egypt. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997.
Farooqi, Naimur Rahman. Mughal-Ottoman Relations. A Study of Political and Diplomatic
Relations between Mughal India and the Ottoman Empire, 15561748. New Delhi: Idarah-i
Adabiyat-i Delhi, 1989.
Faroqhi, Suraiya. Notes on the Production of Cotton and Cotton Cloth in XVI
and XVII Century Anatolia. The Journal of European Economic History 8 (1979):
405417.
. Sixteenth-Century Periodic Markets in Various Anatolian Sancaks: (el, Hamid,
Karahisar-i Sahib, Ktahya, Aydn and Mente{e. JESHO 27 (1979): 3280.
. Textile Production and the Arab Provinces: Geographic Distribution and
Internal Trade (15601650). JOS 1 (1980): 6183.
. Camels, Wagons, and the Ottoman State in the Sixteenth and Seventeenth
Centuries. IJMES 14 (1982): 2339.

212

. Towns and Townsmen of Ottoman Anatolia. Trade, Crafts and Food Production in an
Urban Setting, 15201650. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1984.
. Civilian Society and Political Power in the Ottoman Empire: A Report on
Research in Collective Bibliography, 14801830. IJMES 17 (1985): 10917.
. Political Initiatives From the Bottom Up in the Sixteenth and SeventeenthCentury Ottoman Empire: Some Evidence for Their Existence. In Osmanistische
Studien zur Wirtschafts-und Sozialgeschichte in Memoriam Vanco Bokov, 2333. Edited
by Hans Georg Majer. Wiesbaden: Harrassowitz, 1986.
. An Ulama Grandee and his Household. JOS 9 (1989): 199208.
. Introduction: Special Issue on Ottoman Trade. New Perspectives on Turkey
56 (1991): 128.
. Traders and Customs Ocials in 1660s Iskenderun. New Perspectives on Turkey
56 (1991): 107122.
. Wealth and Power in the Land of Olives: Economic and Political Activities
of Muridzade Haci Mehmed Agha, Notable of Edremit. In Landholding and
Commercial Agriculture in the Middle East, 7796. Edited by a[lar Keyder and Faruk
Tabak. Albany: State University of New York Press, 1991.
. Introduction. The Journal of Peasant Studies (special issue) 18 (1991): 317.
. Pilgrims and Sultans: The Hajj under the Ottomans. London: I. B. Tauris, 1994.
. Approaching Ottoman History: An Introduction to the Sources. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 1999.
Fattah, Hala. The Politics of Grain Trade in Iraq, c. 18401917. New Perspectives on
Turkey 56 (1991): 151166.
Fekete, L. Die Siyqat-Schrift in der Trkischen Finanzverwaltung, Beitrag zur trkischen
Palographie. 2 vols. Budapest: Akadmiai Kiad, 1955.
Findley, Carter V. Bureaucratic Reform in the Ottoman Empire: The Sublime Porte, 17891922.
Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1980.
. Ottoman Civil Ocialdom. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1989.
Fischer, Alan. Les rapports entre lEmpire ottoman et la Crime: Laspect nancier.
CMRS 13 (1967): 368381.
. Russian Annexation of the Crimea 17721783. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press, 1970.
Ferguson, R. Brian, and Neil L. Whitehead, eds. War in the Tribal Zone: Expanding
States and Indigenous Warfare. Santa Fe: School of American Research Press, 1992.
Finkel, Caroline. The Provisioning of the Ottoman Army During the Campaigns
of 15931606. In Habsburgisch-osmanische Beziehungen (CIEPO 2630 September 1983),
107123. Edited by Andreas Tietze. Vienna: Verband der Wissenschaftlichen
Gesellschaften sterreichs, 1985.
. The Administration of Warfare: the Ottoman Military Campaigns in Hungary, 15931606.
Beihefte zur Wiener Zeitschrift fr die Kunde des Morgenlandes, no. 14. Vienna:
Verband der Wissenschaftlichen Gesellschaften sterreichs, 1988.
Fleischer, Cornell H. Royal Authority, Dynastic Cyclism and Ibn Khaldunism in
Sixteenth Century Ottoman Letters. Journal of Asian and African Studies 18 (1984):
218237.
. Bureaucrat and Intellectual in the Ottoman Empire: The Historian Mustafa 'Ali
(15411600). Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1986.
. Preliminaries to the Study of the Ottoman Bureaucracy. Journal of Turkish
Studies. Raiyyet Rsumu. Essays Presented to Halil (nalck. Edited by Bernard
Lewis et al., 10 (1986): 135142.
. The Lawgiver as Messiah: The Making of the Imperial Image in the Reign
of Sleymn. In Soliman le Manique et son temps: actes du colloque de Paris Galeries
Nationales du Grand Palais 710 Mars 1990, 159177. Edited by Gilles Veinstein.
Paris: cole des Hautes tudes en Science Sociales, 1992.
Fleming, Katherine Elizabeth. The Muslim Bonaparte: Diplomacy and Orientalism in Ali
Pashas Greece. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1999.

213

Floor, Willem, and Patrick Clawson. Safavid Irans Search for Silver and Gold.
IJMES 32 (2000): 345368.
Fodor, Pal. State and Society, Crisis and Reform in 15th17th Century Ottoman
Mirrors for Princes. Acta Orientalia Academiae Scientiarum Hungaricae 40 (1986): 217
240.
. In Quest of the Golden Apple: Imperial Ideology, Politics, and Military Administration
in the Ottoman Empire. Istanbul: Isis, 2000.
Fontana, Biancamaria. The Napoleonic Empire and the Europe of Nations. In
The Idea of Europe: From Antiquity to the European Union, 116138. Edited by Anthony
Pagden. Washington: Woodrow Wilson Center Press, 2002.
Foucault, Michel. The Archaeology of Knowledge and The Discourse on Language. New York:
Harper and Row, 1972.
Frangakis, Elena. The Balance of Trade and the Balance of Payments between
Izmir and France, 17001789. In Communications grecques prsentes au Ve Congrs
International des Etudes du Sud Est-Europen (Belgrade: 1117 Septembre 1984), 127138.
Athens: Comit National Grec, 1985.
. The Commerce of Smyrna in the Eighteenth Century, (17001820). Athens: Center
for Asia Minor Studies, 1992.
Frank, Andr Gunder. A Theoretical Introduction to 5,000 Years of World Systems
History. Review 13 (1990): 155250.
. Re-Orient: Global Economy in the Asian Age. Berkeley: University of California
Press, 1998.
Fukasawa, Katsumi. Toilerie et commerce du Levant au XVIII e sicle dAlep Marseille.
Marseille: Groupe de Recherche et dtudes sur le Proche Orient. Centre Regional
de Publication de Marseille, 1985.
Furet, Franois. Penser la Revolution franaise. Paris: Gallimard, 1978.
Garrison, Janine. Ldit de Nantes et sa rvocation: histoire dune intolerance. Paris: ditions du Seuil, 1985.
Gen, Mehmet. Osmanl Maliyesinde Malikne Sistemi. In Trkiye (ktisat Tarihi
Semineri, 231296. Edited by Osman Okyar and nal Nalbanto[lu. Ankara:
Hacetepe niversitesi/Meteksan, 1975.
. Osmanl Ekonomisi ve }ava{. Yapt 49 (1984): 5261; Tables, 8693.
. Osmanl Devletinde ( Gmrk Rejimi. In Tanzimat"tan Cumhuriyete Trkiye
Ansiklopedisi. Istanbul: (leti{im, 1985, vol. 3: 786789.
. A Study on the Feasibility of Using Eighteenth-Century Ottoman Financial
Records as an Indicator of Economic Activity. In The Ottoman Empire in the World
Economy, 345373. Edited by Huri (slamo[lu-(nan. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press, 1987.
. Osmanl (ktisad Dnya Gr{nn (lkeleri. Sosyologi Dergisi (Istanbul niversitesi Edebiyat Fakltesi, 3rd ser. 1 (1989): 176185.
. Osmanl (mparatorlu[unda Devlet ve Ekonomi. In V. Milletleraras Trkiye
Sosyal ve (ktisat Tarihi Kongresi, 1325. Edited by Hakk Dursun Yldz, (nci Enginn
and Emine Grsoy Naskal. Ankara: TTK, 1990.
. Osmanl (mparatorlu[unda Devlet ve Ekonomi. Istanbul: tken, 2000.
. Esham. (A2, 11: 375380.
Genet, Jean-Philippe, and Michel le Men, eds. Gnse de ltat moderne: prlevement et
redistribution. Paris: Editions du Centre National de la Recherche Scientique,
1987.
Genier, J. Y. La demande sous lAncien Rgime. Annales conomies, socits, civilizations 42 (1987): 497528.
Genovese, E. and L. Hochberg, eds. Geographic Perspectives in History. Oxford: Oxford
University Press, 1989.
Gerber, Haim. Guilds in Seventeenth Century Anatolian Bursa.Asian and African
Studies 11 (1976): 5986.
. The Monetary System of the Ottoman Empire. JESHO 25 (1982): 308324.

214

. Jewish Tax-Farmers in the Ottoman Empire. JTS 10 (1986): 14361.


. The Social Origins of the Modern Middle East. Boulder: Lynne Rienner, 1987.
. Economy and Society in an Ottoman City: Bursa, 1600 1700. Jerusalem: The
Hebrew University Press, 1988.
Gershenkron, Alexander. Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective. Cambridge,
MA: Harvard University Press, 1962.
Geertz, Cliord. Local Knowledge: Further Essays in Interpretive Anthropology. New York:
Basic Books, 1983, 167234.
Gibb, E. J. W. A History of Ottoman Poetry. 4 vols. London: Luzac and Company,
1967.
Gibb, Hamilton A. R. and Bowen, Harold. Islamic Society and the West: A Study of the
Impact of Western Civilization on Moslem Culture in the Near East. 1 vol. in 2 pts.
London: Oxford University Press, 1950 and 1957.
Gcek, Fatma Mge. Rise of the Bourgeoisie, Demise of Empire: Ottoman Westernization and
Social Change. New York: Oxford University Press, 1996.
Goman, Daniel. Izmir and the Levantine World, 15501650. Seattle: University of
Washington, 1990.
Goldstone, Jack A. East and West in the Seventeenth Century: Political Crises in
Stuart England, Ottoman Turkey and Ming China. Comparative Studies in Society
and History 30 (1988): 103142.
. Revolution and Rebellion in the Early Modern World. Berkeley: University of California,
1991.
Gkalp, Ziya. Krt A{iretleri hakknda (timai Tetkikler. Ankara: Komal, 1975.
Gkbilgin, Tayyp. Bbli. (A, 2:174177.
Gommans, Jos J. L. The Rise of the Indo-Afghan Empire, c. 17101780. Leiden: E. J.
Brill, 1995.
Goodrich, Thomas D. The Ottoman Turks and the New World: A Study of Tarih-i Hindi Garbi and Sixteenth-Century Ottoman Americana. Wiesbaden: Harrassowitz, 1990.
. Old Maps in the Library of the Topkap Palace in Istanbul. Imago Mundi
45 (1993): 120133.
Gyn, Nejat. Onaltnc Yzyln (lk Yarsnda Diyarbekir. Belgeler 7 (1968):
7680.
. Diyarbekir"in (lk (dari Taksimat. Tarih Dergisi 23 (1969): 2334.
. XVI. Yzylda Mardin Sanca[. Istanbul: Edebiyat Fakltesi Basmevi, 1969.
. and Wolf-Dieter Htteroth. Land an der Grenze: Osmanische Verwaltung im heutigen trkisch-syrisch-irakischen Grenzgebiet im 16. Jahrhundert. Istanbul: EREN, 1997.
Gran, Peter. Islamic Roots of Capitalism in Egypt, 17601840. Austin: University of
Texas, 1979.
Grenville, Henry. Observations sur ltat actuel de lEmpire ottoman. Edited by Andrew S.
Ehrenkreutz. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan, 1965.
Griswold, William. Political Unrest and Rebellion in Anatolia 1000 1020/15911611.
Berlin: Klaus Schwarz, 1983.
Ger, Lt. XVIXVIII Asrlarda Osmanl (mparatorlu[u"nun Ticaret Politikas.
In Trk (ktisat Tarihi Yll[, no. 1. Istanbul: Istanbul niversitesi (ktisat Fakltesi
Trk (ktisat ve (ctimaiyat Tarihi Ara{trmalar Merkezi, 1987: 155.
Gury, Alain. Le roi dpense: le don, la contrainte, et lorigine du systeme nancier
de la monarchie franaise dAncien Regime. In Les Monarchies, 25986. Edited
by Emmanuel le Roy Ladurie. Paris: Presses Universitaires de France, 1986.
Guha, Ranajit. A Rule of Property for Bengal: An Essay on the Idea of Permanent Settlement.
Durham: Duke University Press, 1996.
Gran, Tevk. The State Role in the Grain Supply of Istanbul: The Grain
Administration, 17931839. IJTS 3 (1984): 2742.
Gzelbey, Cemil Cahit and Hulus Yetkin, eds. Gaziantep }eri"i Mahkeme Sicillerinden
rnekler (Cilt 81141, Miladi 1729 1820). Gaziantep: Yeni Matbaa/Gaziantep
Kltr Derne[i Yaynlar, 1970.

215

Hagen, Gottfried. Ein osmanischer Geograph bei der Arbeit. Entstehung and
Gedankenwelt von Ktib elebis Cihnnm. Ph.D. diss., Freie Universitt
Berlin, 1996.
Halao[lu, Yusuf. XVIII. Yzylda Osmanl (mparatorlu[u"nun (skan Siyaseti ve A{iretlerin
Yerle{tirilmesi. Ankara, TTK, 1991.
Halasi-Kun, G. J. The Map of }eki-i Yeni Felemenk Maa (ngiliz" in Ebubekir
Dimi{kis Tercme-i Atlas Mayor. Archivum Ottomanicum 11 (1988): 5170.
. (brahm Mteferrika. (A, 5, pt. 2: 896900.
Hambly, Gavin. An Introduction to the Economic Organization of Early Qajar
Iran. Iran 2 (1964): 6982.
Hamilton, Alastair, and Alexander H. de Groot. Friends and Rivals in the East: Studies
in Anglo-Dutch Relations in the Levant from the Seventeenth to the Early Nineteenth Century.
Leiden: E. J. Brill, 2000.
Hammer-Purgstall, Joseph Freiherr von. Geschichte des osmanischen Reiches (Histoire de
lEmpire ottoman depuis son origine jusqua nos jours). 18 vols. Paris, Bellizard, Barthes,
Dufour & Lowell; 183543.
Harley, J. B. and David Woodward, eds. The History of Cartography: Cartography in the
Traditional Islamic and South Asian Societies. 2 vols. Chicago: The University of
Chicago Press, 1992.
Harvey, D. On the History and Present Conditions of Geography: An Historical
Materialist Manifesto. Professional Geographer 3 (1984): 111.
. The Condition of Postmodernity: An Enquiry into the Origins of Cultural Change. New
York: Basil Blackwell, 1989.
Hathaway, Jane. The Politics of Household in Ottoman Egypt: The Rise of the Qazada[l.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997.
. Years of Ocak Power: The Rise of the Qazda[li Household and the
Transformation of Ottoman Egypts Military Society, 16701750 (Egypt). Ph.D.
diss., Princeton University, 1992.
Hazareesingh, Sudhir. From Subject to Citizen: The Second Empire and the Emergence of
Modern French Democracy. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1998.
Henshall, Nicholas. The Myth of Absolutism: Change and Continuity in Early Modern European
Monarchy. London: Longman, 1992.
Heyd, Uriel. The Ottoman 'Ulem and Westernization in the Time of Selim III
and Mahmud II. In Studies in Islamic History and Civilization. Vol. 9, 6396. Edited
by Uriel Heyd. Jerusalem: The Magnes Press, 1961.
Hinz, Walther. Islamische Masse und Gewichte umgerechnet ins metrische System. Leiden:
E. J. Brill, 1970.
Hezarfen, Hseyn Efendi. Telhis"l Beyan Kavnin-i l-i Osmn. Edited by Sevim
Ilgrel. Ankara: TTK, 2000.
Hintze, Otto. The Formation of States and Constitutional Development: A Study
in History and Politics. In The Historical Essays, 15778. Edited by Felix Gilbert.
Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1975.
Hirschman, Albert O. Exit, Voice and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in Firms, Organizations,
and States. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1970.
Hodgson, Marshall G. S. The Venture of Islam: Conscience and History in a World Civilization.
3 vols. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1974.
Hoexter, Miriam. Endowments, Rulers and Community: Waqf al-Haramayn in Ottoman
Algiers. Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1998.
Homan, Philip T., Priceless Markets: The Political Economy of Credit in Paris, 16601870.
Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 2000.
and Kathryn Norberg, eds. Fiscal Crises, Liberty, and Representative Government,
1450 1789. Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1994.
, Gille Postel-Vinay, and Jean-Laurent Rosenthal, Information and Economic
History: How the Credit Market in Old Regime Paris Forces us to Rethink the
Transition to Capitalism. The American Historical Review 101 (1999): 6994.

216

Hourani, Albert. The Changing Face of the Fertile Crescent in the XVIIIth
Century. Studia Islamica 8 (1957): 89122.
. Ottoman Reform and the Politics of Notables. In Beginnings of Modernization
in the Middle East: The Nineteenth Century, 4168. Edited by William R. Polk and
Richard L. Chambers. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1968.
Howard, D. A. The Ottoman Timar System and Its Transformation, 15631656.
Ph.D. diss., University of Indiana, 1987.
. The Historical Development of the Ottoman Imperial Registry (Defter-i
Hakan): Mid-Fifteenth to Mid-Seventeenth Centuries. Archivum Ottomanicum 9
(1988): 213230.
Hulliung, Mark. Montesquieu and the Old Regime. Berkeley: University of California
Press, 1976.
Hurewitz, J. C. The Middle East and North Africa in World Politics. 2 vols. New Haven:
Yale University Press, 1975.
Wolf-Dieter Htteroth and Kamal Abdulfattah. Historical geography of Palestine, Transjordan
and Southern Syria in the late 16th Century. Erlangen: Frnkische Geographische Ges.
Palm und Enke, 1977.
Ibn Khaldn. The Muqaddimah: An Introduction to History. Trans. Franz Rosenthal,
Bollingen Series. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1969.
Ibrahim Mteferika. Usl"l-Hikem f Nizm"l-mem. Edited by Adel }en. Ankara:
Trkiye Diyanet Vak, 1995.
Igger, George G. New Directions in European Historiography. Hanover, N.H.: University
of New England, 1984.
(hsano[lu, Ekmeleddin, Ramazan }e{en, M. Serdar Bekar, Glcan Gndz, et al.,
eds. Osmanl Co[rafya Literatr. 2 vols. Istanbul: IRCICA, 2000.
(lhan, M. Mehdi. Amid (Diyarbakr). Ankara: TTK, 2000.
. Studies in the Medieval History of Diyarbekir Province: Some Notes on the
Sources and Literature. Belleten 53 (1989): 199231.
Imber, Colin. Ebu"s-Su"ud: The Islamic Legal Tradition. Stanford: Stanford University
Press, 1997.
(nalck, Halil. Osmanllarda Raiyyet Rsmu. Belleten 23 (1959): 575600.
. Bursa and the Commerce of the Levant. JESHO 3 (1960): 131114.
. Sened-i (ttifak ve Glhane Hatt- Hmyunu. Belleten 28 (1964): 605690.
. The Nature of a Traditional Society. In Political Modernization in Japan and
Turkey, 4263. Edited by R. E. Ward and D. A. Rustow. Princeton: Princeton
University Press, 1964.
. Capital Formation in the Ottoman Empire. Journal of Economic History 29
(1969): 97140.
. Suleiman the Lawgiver and Ottoman Law. Archivum Ottomanicum 1 (1969):
117124.
. The Ottoman Economic Mind and Aspects of the Ottoman Economy. In
Studies in the Economic History of the Middle East, 20718. Edited by Michael A.
Cook. London: Oxford University Press, 1970.
. The Ottoman Empire: The Classical Age, 13001600. New York: Praeger, 1973.
. The Socio-political Eects of the Diusion of Firearms on the Middle East.
In War, Technology and Society in the Middle East, 195217. Edited by V. J. Parry
and M. E. Yapp. London: Oxford University Press, 1975.
. Centralization and Decentralization in Ottoman Administration, 2752. In
Studies in Eighteenth Century Islamic History. Edited by T. Na and R. Owen.
Carbondale: University of Southern Illinois Press, 1977.
. Impact of the Annales School on Ottoman Studies and New Findings.
Review 1 (1978): 6996.
. Osmanl Pamuklu Pazar. Hindistan ve (ngiltere, Pazar Rekabetinde Emek
Maliyetinin Rol. Orta Do[u Teknik niversitesi Geli{me Dergisi (197980): 166.

217

. Military and Fiscal Transformation in the Ottoman Empire, 16001700.


Archivum Ottomanicum 6 (1980): 283337.
. Introduction to Ottoman Metrology. Turcica 15 (1983): 311348.
. Yk (hml) in Ottoman Silk Trade, Mining and Agriculture. Turcica 16
(1984): 131156.
. Islamization of Ottoman Laws on Land and Land Tax. In Festgabe an Josef
Matuz: Osmanistik, Turkologie, Diplomatik, 101118. Edited by Christa Fragner and
Klaus Schwarz. Berlin: Klaus Schwarz, 1992.
. Bennak. EI 2, 1:11601170.
. iftlik. EI 2, 2:3233.
. Ghulm. EI 2, 2:10851091.
. Harir. EI 2, 3:211218.
. Hawala. EI 2, 3:283285.
. (mtiyzt. EI 2, 3:11781189.
. Knn. EI 2, 4:558562.
. Knnnme. EI 2, 4:562566.
. Re"is-l-kttb. (A, 9:672683.
. and Cemal Kafadar, eds. Suleyman The First and His Time. Istanbul: Isis, 1993.
. ed. with Donald Quataert. An Economic and Social History of the Ottoman Empire,
1300 1914. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994.
Iniciyan P. G. XVIII. Asr"da Istanbul. Trans. and Edited by Hrand D. Andreasyan.
Istanbul: Istanbul Fethi Derne[i, 1956.
(slam Ansiklopedisi. Edited by M. Th. Houtsma et al. (slm lemi Tarih, Co[rafya,
Etnografya ve Biyografya Lugati. 14 vols. Istanbul: Maarif Matbaasi, 19401986.
(slamo[lu, Huricihan, and a[lar Keyder. Agenda for Ottoman History. Review
1 (1977): 3156.
(slamo[lu-(nan, Huri. State and Peasants in the Ottoman Empire: A Study of
Peasant Economy in North-Central Anatolia during the Sixteenth Century. In
The Ottoman Empire and the World-Economy, 101159. Edited by Huri (slamo[luInan. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1987.
. Introduction: Oriental Despotism in World-System Perspective. In The
Ottoman Empire and the World-Economy, 124. Edited by Huri (slamo[lu-Inan.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press: 1987.
. Les paysans, le march et ltat en Anatolie au XVIe sicle. Annales conomies,
socits, civilizations 43 (1988): 10251044.
. Osmanl (mparatorlu[u"nda Devlet ve Kyl. Istanbul: (leti{im, 1991.
. Peasants, Commercialization and Legitimation of State Power in SixteenthCentury Anatolia. In Landholding and Commercial Agriculture in the Middle East, 5776.
Edited by a[lar Keyder and Faruk Tabak. Albany: State University of New
York Press, 1991.
. Property as a Contested Domain: A Reevaluation of the Ottoman Land
Code of 1858. In New Perspectives on Property and Land in the Middle East, 363.
Edited by Roger Owen. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2000.
Issawi, Charles. The Economic History of the Middle East, 18001914. Chicago: University
of Chicago Press, 1966.
. The Economic History of Iran: 18001914. Chicago: The University of Chicago
Press, 1971.
. An Economic History of Turkey. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1980.
. An Economic History of the Middle East and North Africa. New York: Columbia
University Press, 1982.
, ed. The Fertile Crescent 1800 1914: A Documentary Economic History. Oxford:
Oxford University Press, 1988.
Itzkowitz, Norman. Eighteenth Century Ottoman Realities. Studia Islamica 16
(1962): 7394.

218

. Men and Ideas in the Eighteenth Century Ottoman Empire. In Studies in


Eighteenth Century Islamic History, 1526. Edited by T. Na and R. Owen. Carbondale:
University of Southern Illinois Press, 1977.
. and Max Mote, eds. Mubadele: An Ottoman Russian Exchange of Ambassadors.
Chicago: University of Chicago, 1970.
Izady, Mehrdad. The Kurds: A Concise Handbook. Washington: Crane Russak, 1992.
Jabarti, Abd al-Rahman. Napoleon in Egypt: Al-Jabartis Chronicle of the French Occupation
(1798). Trans. and edited by S. Moreh. Princeton: Marcus Wiener Publishers, 1993.
Jackson, Peter and Laurence Lockhardt, eds. The Cambridge History of Iran. Vol. 6:
The Timurid and Safavid Periods. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1986.
Jamgocyan, Onik. Les nances de lEmpire Ottoman et les nancirs de Constantinople, 17321853. Ph.D. diss., University of Paris I (Sorbonne), 1988.
Jardin, Andr. Tocqueville: A Biography. New York: Farrar Straus Giroux, 1988.
Jennings, Ronald. Loan and Credit in Early 17th Century Judicial Records. The
Shari"a Court of Anatolia and Kayseri. JESHO 16 (1973): 168216.
. Firearms, Bandits, and Gun-Control: Some Evidence on Ottoman Policy
toward Firearms in the Possession of Reaya, from Judicial Records of Kayseri,
16001627. Archivum Ottomanicum 6 (1976): 229258.
. Urban Population in Anatolia in the 16th Century: A Study of Kayseri,
Karaman, Amasya, Trabzon and Erzurum. IJMES 7 (1976): 2157.
. Kad, Court and Legal Procedure in 17th Century Ottoman Kayseri. Studia
Islamica 48 (1978): 133172.
Johansen, Baber. Amwal Zahira and Amwal Batina: Town and Countryside as
Reected in the Tax System of the Hanate School. In Studia Arabica and Islamica
Festschrift for Ihsan 'Abbas on his 60th Birthday, 247263. Edited by Widad al-Qadi.
Beirut: American University of Beirut, 1981.
. The Islamic Law on Land Tax and Rent. London: Croom Helm, 1988.
Jones, J. R. Fiscal Policies, Liberties, and Representative Government during the
Reigns of the Last Stuarts. In Fiscal Crises, Liberty, and Representative Government,
14501789, 6795. Edited by Philip T. Homan and Kathryn Norberg. Stanford:
Stanford University Press, 1994.
Joudah, Ahmad Hasan. Revolt in Palestine in the 18th Century: The Era of Shaykh Zahir
al-Umar. Princeton: The Kingston Press, 1989.
Kafadar, Jamal. Between Two Worlds. Berkeley: University of California, 1994.
Kahane, Henry, Rene Kahane, and Andreas Tietze, The Lingua Franca in the Levant:
Turkish Nautical Terms of Italian and Greek Origin. Urbana: University of Illinois Press,
1958.
Kahle, P. China as Described by Turkish Geographers from Iranian Sources.
Proceedings of the Iran Society (London) 11 (1940): 4859.
Kal"a, Ahmet, Ahmet Tabako[lu, and Salih Aynural, et al., eds. (stanbul Ahkm
Defterleri. (stanbul Finans Tarihi (17421787). Istanbul: Istanbul Ara{trmalar Merkezi,
1998.
Karal, Enver Ziya. Selim III"n Hatt- Hmayunlar. Nizam- Cedit: 17891807. Ankara:
TTK, 1988.
Karpat, Kemal. The Land Regime. Social Structure in the Ottoman Empire. In
The Beginnings of Modernization in the Middle East, 6990. Edited by William Polk
and Richard Chambers. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1969.
. The Transformation of the Ottoman State, 17891908. IJMES 3 (1972):
243281.
. The Stages of Ottoman History: A Structural Comparative Approach. In
The Ottoman State and Its Place in World History, 7998. Edited by Kemal Karpat.
Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1974.
Ktip elebi. Bozukluklarn Dzeltilmesinde Tutulacak Yollar (Dstru"l-Amel li-Islahi"l-Halel)
Edited by and trans. Ali Can. Ankara: Kltr ve Turizm Bakanl[ Yaynlar,
1982.

219

. Kitab Cihannma. Qustantiniyah: Dr al-Taba"ah al-mire, 1145 [1732].


Katrco[lu, Nurhan Fatma. The Ottoman Ayan, 15001812: A Struggle for Legitimacy. Masters thesis. University of Wisconsin-Madison, 1984.
Katrco[lu [Isvan], Nurhan Fatma. Illegal Local Trade in the Ottoman Empire
and the Guilds of Istanbul, 172526: A Suggested New Hypotheses. IJTS 5
(199091): 127.
Keane, John. Despotism and Democracy. In Civil Society and the State: New European
Perspectives. Edited by J. Keane, 3572. London: Verso, 1988.
Kellenbenz, Hermann, ed. Fisco, Religione, Stato nell"Eta Confessionale. Bologna: Societ
Editrice il Mulino, 1989.
Keller, Arthur S., Oliver J. Lisitzyn, and Frederick J. Mann. Creation of Rights of Sovereignty through Symbolic Acts, 14001800. New York: Columbia University Press, 1938.
Kemp, Percy. Territoire de lIslam: le monde vu de Moussoul au XVIII e sicle. Paris: Sindbad,
1982.
Keyder, a[lar, and Faruk Tabak, eds. Landholding and Commercial Agriculture in the
Middle East. Albany: State University of New York Press: Albany, 1991.
Khazanov, A. M. Nomads and the Outside World. Trans. Julia Crookenden. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press, 1984.
Khodarkovsky, Michael. Where Two Worlds Met: The Russian State and the Kalmyk
Nomads, 16001771. Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1992.
Khoury, Dina. The Introduction of Commercial Agriculture in the Province of
Mosul and its Eects on the Peasantry, 17501850. In Landholding and Commercial
Agriculture in the Middle East, 15572. Edited by Faruk Tabak and a[lar Keyder.
Albany: State University of New York, 1991.
. The Political Economy of the Province of Mosul, 17001850. Ph.D. diss.,
Georgetown University, 1991.
. Merchants and Trade in Early Modern Iraq. New Perspectives in Turkey. 56
(1991): 5386.
. State and Provincial Society in the Ottoman Empire: Mosul, 15401834. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press, 1997.
Knalzade Ali Efendi. Ahlk- Ali. 3 vols. Cairo: Bulak, 1248.
King, David A. World Maps for Finding the Direction and Distance of Mecca: Examples of
Innovation and Tradition in Islamic Science. Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1999.
Krzo[lu, M. Fahrettin. Kara-midte 1819da A"yandan }eyhzdelerin ncl[nde
Milli Deli-Behram Pa{a"ya Kar{ Ayaklanma ve Sonucu. Kara mid Dergisi 24
(195658): 350378.
Koi Bey. Rislesi. Trans. into modern Turkish by Zuhur Dani{man. Ankara: Kltr
ve Turizm Bakanl[ Yaynlar, n.d.
Kou, R. Ekrem. Bbli. (A, 4:1446.
Kolerkili, Ekrem. Osmanl (mparatorlu[unda Para Tarihi. Ankara: Do[u{, 1958.
Kolodziejczyk, Dariusz. The Defter-i Mufassal of Kaminie from ca. 1681: An
Example of Late Ottoman Tahrir. Reliability, Function, Principles of Publication.
JOS 13 (1993): 9198.
. Ottoman-Polish Diplomatic Relations (15th18th Century). An Annotated Edition of
Ahdnames and Other Documents. Leiden: E. J. Brill, 2000.
Kriedte, Peter. Peasants, Landlords and Merchant Capitalists: Europe and the World Economy,
1500 1800. Warwickshire: Berg Publishers, 1983.
Krger, Kersten. Public Finance and Modernisation: The Change from the Domain
State to Tax State in Hesse in the Sixteenth and Seventeenth Centuries. A Case
Study. In Wealth and Taxation in Central Europe: The History and Sociology of Public
Finance, 4962. Edited by Peter-Christian Witt. Leamington Spa: Berg, 1987.
Kunt, (brahim Metin. Ethnic-Regional (Cins) Solidarity in the Seventeenth Century
Ottoman Establishment. IJMES 5 (1974): 233239.
. Dervi{ Mehmet Pa{a. Vezir and Entrepreneur: A Study in Ottoman PoliticalEconomic Theory and Practice. Turcica 9 (1977): 197214.

220

. Bir Osmanl Valisinin Yllk Gelir Gideri: Diyarbakr, 167071. Istanbul: Bo[azii
niversitesi, 1981.
. The Sultans Servants: The Transformation of Ottoman Provincial Government, 15501650.
New York: Columbia University Press, 1983.
Kurmu{, Orhan. The 1838 Treaty of Commerce Re-Examined. In Economie et
Societ dans lEmpire Ottoman, 411417. Edited by Jean-Louis Bacqu-Grammont
and Paul Dumont. Paris: CNRS, 1983.
Kurt, (smail. Para Vakar Nazariyat ve Tatbikat. Istanbul: Ensar Ne{riyat, 1996.
Kut, Turgut, and Fatma Ture, eds. Yazmadan Basmaya: Mteferrika, Mhendishane, skdar. Istanbul: Yap Kredi, 1996.
Ktko[lu, Bekir. Vekynvis. A(, 13:271287.
Ktko[lu, Mbahat S. Osmanl-(ngiliz Iktisd Mnsebetleri (1580 1838). Vol. 1.
Ankara: Trk Kltrn Ara{trma Enstits, 1974.
. 1009/1600 Tarihli Narh Defterine Gre Istanbul"da e{itli E{ya ve Hizmet
Fiatlar. Tarih Enstits Dergisi 9 (1978): 186.
. Osmanllarda Narh Messesesi ve 1640 Tarihli Narh Defteri. Istanbul: Enderun
Kitabevi, 1983.
. Osmanl Belgelerinin Dili (Diplomatik). Istanbul: Kubbealt Akademisi Kltr ve
San"at Vak, 1998.
Kwass, Michael. A Kingdom of Taxpayers: State Formation, Privilege, and Political
Culture in Eighteenth-Century France. The Journal of Modern History 70 (1998):
295339.
Ladurie, Emmanuel Le Roy. The Ancien Regime: a History of France, 16101774. Oxford:
Blackwell, 1996.
Lambton, Ann K. S. Persian Trade Under the Early Qajars. In Islam and Trade
in Asia, 215244. Edited by D. S. Richards. Oxford: Oxford University Press,
1970.
Lane, Frederic C. Force and Enterprise in the Creation of Oceanic Commerce.
In Journal of Economic History (Supplemental issue: The Tasks of Economic History)
10 (1950): 1931.
. Economic Consequences of Organized Violence. Journal of Economic History
18 (1958): 401417.
. Venice and History: The Collected Papers of Frederic C. Lane. Edited by
a Committee of Colleagues and Former Students. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Press,
1966.
Laroui, Abdallah. The History of the Maghrib: An Interpretive Essay. Princeton: Princeton
University Press, 1977.
Laski, Harold J. Studies in the Problem of Sovereignty. New Haven: Yale University Press,
1917.
Lattimore, Owen. Inner Asian Frontiers of China. New York: Oxford University Press,
1940.
Laurens, Henry. Les origines intellectuelles de lexpedition dgypte: lorientalisme islamisant en
France (16981798). Istanbul: Isis, 1987.
Laya, M. Alexandre. tudes Historiques sur la vie prive politique et littrare de M. A. Thirs
(1830 1846). 2 vols. Paris: Chez Furne, 1846.
Leeuwen, Richard van. Notables and Clergy in Mount Lebanon: The Khazin Sheikhs and
the Maronite Church (17361840). Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1995.
Lefebvre, Henri. The Production of Space. Oxford: Blackwell, 1994.
Lemercier-Quelquejay, Chantal. Les Kalmuks de la Volga entre LEmpire russe
et lEmpire ottoman sous le regne de Pierre le Grand. CMRS 7:6373.
Levy, Avigdor. Military Reform and the Problem of Centralization in the Ottoman
Empire in the Eighteenth Century. Middle Eastern Studies 18 (1982): 227249.
Lewis, Bernard. The Emergence of Modern Turkey. 2d ed. London: Oxford University
Press, 1961.

221

. Dustr. EI 2, 2: 640647.
Livingston, John William. Ali Bey al-Kabir and the Jews. Middle Eastern Studies 7
(1971): 221228.
Longrigg, Stephen Hemsley. Four Centuries of Modern Iraq. Oxford: Oxford University
Press, 1925.
Luther, Usha M. Historical Route Network of Anatolia (Istanbul-Izmir-Konya): 1550s to
1850s. A Methodological Study. Ankara: TTK, 1989.
Luttervelt, Remmet van. De Turkse Schilderijen van J. B. Vanmour en Zijn School.
Istanbul: Nederlands Historisch-Archaeologisch Instituut in het Nabije Oosten,
1958.
Majer, H. G. Das osmanische Registerbuch der Beschwerden (}ikayet Defteri) vom Jahre
1675: sterreichische Nationalbibliothek Cod. mixt. 683. Wien: Verlag der sterreichischen Akademie der Wissenschaften, 1984.
Mandaville, Jon E. The Ottoman Province of al-Hasa in the Sixteenth and
Seventeenth Centuries. JAOS 90 (1970): 488496.
. Usurious Piety: The Cash Waqf Controversy in the Ottoman Empire.
IJMES 10 (1979): 289308.
Mann, Michael. The Sources of Social Power, Vol. 1: A History of Power from the Begining
to A.D. 1760. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1986.
. The Sources of Social Power. Vol. 2: The Rise of Classes and Nation-States, 17601914.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1993.
Mann, Susan. Local Merchants and the Chinese Bureaucracy, 17501950. Stanford, CA:
Stanford University Press, 1987.
Mantran, Robert. Istanbul dans la seconde moiti du XVII e sicle. Essai dhistoire institutionelle, conomique et sociale. Paris: Maisonneuve, 1962.
Robert Mantran et al. Histoire de lEmpire Ottoman. Paris: Fayard, 1989.
. LEmpire Ottoman du XVI e au XVIII e sicle: Administration, conomie, socit. London:
Variorum Reprints, 1984.
. Rglements scaux ottomans: La police des marchs de Stamboul au dbut
du XVIe sicle. In LEmpire Ottoman du XV e au XVIII e sicle: Administration, economie,
socit. Edited by Robert Mantran. London: Variorum Reprints, 1984.
, ed. Histoire de lEmpire Ottoman. Paris: Fayard, 1989.
Marcus, Abraham. The Middle East on the Eve of Modernity: Aleppo in the Eighteenth
Century. New York: Columbia University Press, 1989.
Mardin, }erif. The Genesis of Young Ottoman Thought. Princeton: Princeton University
Press, 1962.
. Power, Civil Society and Culture in the Ottoman Empire. Comparative Studies
in Society and History 11 (1969): 25881.
. Center-Periphery Relations: A Key to Turkish Politics? Daedulus 102 (1973):
169190.
. Trk Toplumunu (nceleme Arac Olarak Sivil Toplum. Defter 2 (1987):
716.
Marsigli, Luigi Ferdinando, comte. Stato Militare dellImpero Ottomanno, incremento e decremento del medesimo. 2 vols. In Haya: Appresso Pietro Gosse e Giovan Neaulme; In
Amsterdamo: Appresso Herm. Uytwerf, 1732.
Masson, Paul. Histoire du commerce franais dans le Levant au XVIII e sicle. Paris: Librairie
Hachette & Co., 1911.
Masters, Bruce. The Origins of Western Dominance in the Middle East: Mercantilism and
the Islamic Economy in Aleppo, 16001750. New York: New York University Press,
1988.
Mathews, George. The Royal General Farms in Eighteenth-Century France. New York:
Columbia University Press, 1958.
Mantran, Robert. Istanbul dans la seconde moiti du XVII e sicle. Essai dhistoire institutionelle, conomique et sociale. Paris: Maisonneuve, 1962.

222

Matthews, George T. The Royal General Farms in Eighteenth Century France. New York:
Columbia University Press, 1958.
Matthee, Rudolph P. The Politics of Trade in Safavid Iran: Silk for Silver, 16001730.
New York: Cambridge University Press, 1999.
Matuz, Joseph E. Constributions to the Ottoman Institution of the (ltizam. JOS
11 (1991): 237249.
McCabe, I. B. The Shahs Silk for Europes Silver: The Eurasian Trade of the Julfa Armenians
in Safavid Iran and India (15301750). Atlanta, GA: Scholars Press, 1999.
McGowan, Bruce. Economic Life in the Ottoman Europe: Taxation, Trade and the Struggle
for Land. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1981.
. The Study of Land and Agriculture in the Ottoman Provinces within the
Context of an Expanding World Economy in the 17th and 18th Centuries. IJTS
2 (1981): 5763.
. The Age of the Ayan. In An Economic and Social History of the Ottoman Empire,
637743. Edited by Halil (nalck with Donald Quataert. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 1994.
McNeill, William. Europes Steppe Frontier, 15001800. Chicago: University of Chicago
Press, 1964.
. Venice: The Hinge of Europe, 10811797. Chicago: University of Chicago Press,
1974.
. The Pursuit of Power: Technology, Armed Force, and Society since A.D. 1000. Chicago:
University of Chicago Press, 1982.
Mehmed Sreyya Bey. Sicill-i Osman yahut Tezkere-yi Me{ahir-i Osmaniye. 4 vols.
Istanbul: Matbaa-i mire, 130815 (189097).
Meriwether, Margaret, L. Urban Notables and Rural Resources in Aleppo,
17701830. IJTS 4 (1987): 5573.
. The Kin Who Count: Family and Society in Ottoman Aleppo, 17701840. Austin:
University of Texas Press, 1999.
Mert, zcan. XVIII. ve XIX. Yzyllarda apano[ullar. Ankara: Kltr Bakanl[, 1980.
Meservey, Sabra F. Feyzullah Efendi: An Ottoman Seyhlislam. Ph.D. diss.,
Princeton University, 1966.
Messick, Brinkley. The Calligraphic State: Textual Domination and History in a Muslim
Society. Berkeley: University of California Press, 1993.
Miller, Anatolii F. Mustapha Pacha Bairaktar. Bucarest: Association International
dtudes du Sud-Est Europen, 1975.
Mitchell, Timothy. Colonising Egypt. Berkeley: University of California Press, 1988.
Mo"in, Mohammad. An Intermediate Persian Dictionary. Tehran: Amir Kabir, 1996.
Montesquieu. Oeuvres compltes. Edited by Roger Caillois. 2 vols. Paris: Bibliothque
de la Pliade, 194951.
Moon, David. Peasant Migration and the Settlement of Russias Frontiers, 1509
1897. The Historical Journal 40 (1997): 859893.
Moore, Sally Falk. Law as Process: An Anthropological Approach. London: Routledge
Kegan, 1978.
Morgenthau, Hans. Politics among Nations. New York: Knopf, 1967.
Motika, Raoul and Michael Ursinus, eds. Caucasia between the Ottoman Empire and Iran,
15551914. Wiesbaden: Reichert, 2000.
Moutachieva, Vera P. Linstitution de layanlk pendant les dernieres dcennies du
XVIIIe sicle. tudes Balkaniques 23 (1965): 233247.
. Agrarian Relations in the Ottoman Empire in the 15th and 16th Centuries. New York:
Columbia University Press, 1988.
Mumcu, Ahmet. Hukuksal ve Siyasal Karar Organ Olarak Divan- Hmayun. Ankara:
Ankara niversitesi Hukuk Fakltesi Yaynlar, 1976.
. Tarih (cindeki Genel Geli{imiyle Birlikte Osmanl Devletinde R{vet: zellikle Adl R{vet.
Istanbul: (nklp Kitabevi, 1985.

223

. Osmanl Devletinde Siyaseten Katl. Ankara: Birey ve Toplum, 1985.


Murphey, Rhoads. Functioning of the Ottoman Army Under Murad IV (16231639/
10321049): Key to the Understanding of the Relationship Between Center and
Periphery. Ph.D. diss., University of Chicago, 1979.
. Tobacco Cultivation in Northern Syria and Conditions of Its Marketing and
Distribution in the Late Eighteenth Century. Turcica 14 (1985): 205226.
. Regional Structure in the Ottoman Economy: A Sultanic Memorandum of 1636 A.D.
Concerning the Sources and Uses of the Revenues of Anatolia and the Coastal and Northern
Portions of Syria. Wiesbaden, Otto Harrassowitz, 1987.
. Conditions of Trade in the Eastern Mediterranean: An Appraisal of EighteenthCentury Ottoman Documents from Aleppo. JESHO 33 (1990): 3550.
. Ottoman Warfare, 15001700. London: University of London Press, 1999.
Nader, Helen. Liberty in Absolutist Spain: The Habsburg Sale of Towns, 15161700.
Baltimore and London: The Johns Hopkins University Press, 1990.
Na, Thomas. The Ottoman Empire and the European State System. In The
Expansion of International Society, 143170. Edited by H. Bull and A. Watson. Oxford:
Clarendon Press, 1984.
. and Roger Owen. Studies in Eighteenth Century Islamic History. Carbondale and
Edwardsville: Southern Illinois University Press, 1977.
Nagata, Yuzo. Some Documents on the Big Farms (iftliks) of the Notables in Western Anatolia.
Tokyo: Institute for the Study of Languages and Cultures of Asia and Africa,
1976.
. Muhsin-zde Mehmed Pa{a ve Aynlk Messesesi. Tokyo: Institute for the Study
of Languages and Cultures of Asia and Africa, 1976.
. Materials for the Study of the Bosnian Notables. Tokyo: Institute for the Study of
Languages and Cultures of Asia and Africa, 1979.
Naima, Mustafa. Tarih-i Naima. 6 vols. Istanbul: 18631866.
Neal, Larry. The Rise of Financial Capitalism: International Capital Markets in the Age of
Reason. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990.
Niebuhr, Carsten. Reisebeschreibung durch Syrien und Palstina nach Zypern und durch
Kleinasien und die Trkei nach Deutschland und Dannemark. 2 vols. Hamburg: Friedrich
Berthes, 1837.
Nettl, J. P. The State as a Conceptual Variable. World Politics 20 (1968): 559592.
Neumann, Christoph K. Das indirekte Argument: Ein Pldoyer fr die Tanzimat vermittels
der Historie. Die geschichtliche Bedeutung von Ahmed Cevdet Pa{as Ta"rih. Mnster: Lit
Verlag, 1994.
Niewenhuis, T. Politics and Society in Early Modern Iraq. The Hague-Amsterdam: Studies
in Social History of the International Institute of Social History, 1982.
North, Douglass C. Transaction Costs in History. Journal of European Economic
History 14 (1985): 557576.
Olson, Robert W. The Esnaf and the Patrona Halil Rebellion of 1730: A Realignment
in Ottoman Politics? JESHO 17 (1974): 329340.
. The Seige of Mosul and Ottoman-Persian Relations, 1718 43. Bloomington, IN:
Indiana University Press, 1975.
. Jews, Janissaries, Esnaf and the Revolt of 1740 in Istanbul: Social Upheaval
and Political Realignment in the Ottoman Empire. JESHO 20 (1978): 185207.
. Jews in the Ottoman Empire in Light of New Documents. Jewish Social
Studies 41 (1979): 7588. .
Orhonlu, Cengiz. Osmanl Devrinde Nehir Nakliyat Hakknda Ara{trmalar: Dicle
ve Frat Nehirlerinde Nakliyat. Tarih Dergisi 12 (196263): 3955.
. Osmanl (mparatorlu[unda A{iretleri Iskan Te{ebbs 16911696. Istanbul: Edebiyat
Fakltesi, 1963.
. Osmanl (mparatorlu[unda {ehircilik ve Ula{m zerine Ara{trmalar. (zmir: Ege
niversitesi Edebiyat Fakltesi Yaynlar, 1984.

224

. Osmanl (mparatorlu[unda Derbend Te{kilat. Istanbul: Eren, 1990.


Ortayl, (lber. Tanzimattan Cumhuriyete Yerel Ynetim Gelene[i. Istanbul: Hil Yaynlar,
1985.
. (mparatorlu[un En Uzun Yzyl. Istanbul: Hil Yaynlar, 1987.
Orhonlu, Cengiz, ed. XVIII Yzylda Osmanllarda Co[rafya ve Bartnl (brahim
Hamdi"nin Atlas. Tarih Dergisi 10 (1959): 115140.
Owen, Roger. The Middle East in the Eighteenth Century. An Islamic Society
in Decline? Bulletin of the British Society for Middle Eastern Studies 3 (1976): 101117.
. The Middle East in the World Economy 18001914. London: Methuen, 1981.
zbaran, Salih. The Ottoman Turks and the Portuguese in the Persian Gulf,
15341581. Journal of Asian History 6 (1972): 4587.
zde[er, Hseyin. III. Ahmed"in Varidt ve Masrift Defteri. Trk (ktisat Tarihi
Yll[ ((stanbul niversitesi (ktisat Fakltesi Trk (ktisat ve (timiyt Tarihi
Ara{trmalar Merkezi) 1 (1987): 305352.
zdemir, Nutku. IV. Mehmet"in Edirne }enli[i (1675). Ankara: TTK, 1972.
zdemir, Rifat. XIX. Yzyln (lk Yarsnda Ankara. Fiziki, Demorak, (dari ve SosyoEkonomik Yaps, 17851840. Ankara: Kltr ve Turizm Bakanl[ Yaynlar, 1986.
zcan, Abdlkadir, ed. Anonim Osmanl Tarihi (1099 1116/16881704). Ankara:
TTK, 2000.
zkaya, Ycel. XVIIIinci Yzylda karlan Adalet-nmelere gre Trkiye"nin
( Durumu. Belleten 38 (1974): 445491.
. Osmanl (mparatorlu[unda ynlk. Ph.D. diss. Ankara: Dil Tarih-Co[rafya
Fakltesi, 1977.
. XVIII. Yzyln (lk Yarsnda Yerli Ailelerin Ayanlklar Ele Geiri{leri ve
Byk Hanedanlarn Kurulu{u. Belleten 42 (1978): 667723.
. Orta Anadolu"da Nizam- Cedidin Kurulu{u ve Kaldrl{. D.T.C.F. Atatrk
100. Do[um Ylna Arma[an Dergisi (1982): 509536.
. Osmanl (mparatorlu[unda Da[l (syanlar (17911808). Ankara: Dil ve TarihCo[rafya Fakltesi Basmevi, 1983.
. Ahmed Cevdet Pa{a Tarihinde Ar{iv Belgelerinin Kullan{ ve De[erlendiri{i.
In Ahmed Cevdet Pa{a Semineri (2728 May 1985), 14562. Istanbul: Edebiyat
Fakltesi Basmevi, 1986.
. III. Selim"in (mparatorluk hakknda Baz Hatt- Hmynlar. Osmanl Tarihi
Ara{trma ve Uygulama Merkezi Dergisi 1 (1990): 333354.
zkilin, Ahmet, Ali Co{kun, Abdullah Sivrida[, and Murat Yzba{ol[lu, eds. 998
numaral Muhsebe-i Vilyet-i Diyr-i Bekir ve 'Arab ve Z"l-Kdiriyye Defteri (937/1530).
Vol. 1. Ankara: T.C. Ba{bakanlk, Devlet Ar{ivleri Genel Mdrl[, Osmanl
Ar{ivi Daire Ba{kanl[, 1998.
ztrk, Mustafa. Osmanl Fiyat Politikas ve Fiyatlarn Tahlili. Belleten 155 (1991):
87100.
Pagden, Anthony. Lords of All the Worlds: Ideologies of Empire in Spain, Britain and France
c. 1500c. 1850. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1995.
Pamuk, }evket. Osmanl (mparatorlugunda Parann Tarihi. Istanbul: Tarih Vak Yurt
Yaynlar, 1999.
. A Monetary History of the Ottoman Empire. New York: Cambridge University
Press, 2000.
. The Recovery of the Ottoman Monetary System in the Eighteenth Century.
In The Ottoman Past and Todays Turkey, 188211. Edited by Kemal Karpat. Leiden:
E. J. Brill, 2000.
Pakaln, M. Zeki. Osmanl Tarih Deyimleri ve Terimleri Szl[. 2 vols. Istanbul: Milli
E[itim Bakanl[ Yaynlar, 1983.
Panzac, Daniel. La population de lEmpire ottoman et de ses marges du XVe au
XIXe sicle: bibliographie (194180) et bilan provisoire, Revue de lOccident Musulmane
et de la Mditerrane. 31 (1981): 11937.

225

. La peste dans lEmpire ottoman: 17001850. Leuven: Peeters, 1985.


. International and Domestic Maritime Trade in the Ottoman Empire during the 18th Century. IJMES 24 (1992): 189206.
Parry, V. J. Materials of War in the Ottoman Empire. In Studies in the Economic
History of the Middle East, 219229. Edited by Michael A. Cook. Oxford: Oxford
University Press, 1970.
and M. E. Yapp, eds. War, Technology and Society in the Middle East. London:
Oxford University Press, 1975.
Pascual, Jean-Paul. The Janissaries and the Damascus Countryside at the Beginning
of the Seventeenth Century According to the Archives of the Citys Military
Tribunal. In Land Tenure and Social Transformation in the Middle East, 35770. Edited
by Tarif Khalidi. Beirut: American University of Beirut, 1984.
Patriarca, Silvana. Numbers and Nationhood: Writing Statistics in Nineteenth-Century Italy.
New York: Cambridge University Press, 1996.
Pearson, M. N. Before Colonialism: Theories on Asian-European Relations, 15001750. New
York: Oxford University Press, 1988.
Pedani, Maria Pia. In Nome del Gran Signore: Inviati Ottomani a Venezia della Caduta di
Costantinopoli alla Guerra di Candia. Venezia: Deputazione Editrice, 1994.
Pedani-Fabris, Maria Pia. The Ottoman-Venetian Frontier (15th18th Centuries).
In The Great Ottoman-Turkish Civilization. Vol. 1, 171177. Edited by Kemal
iek, Ercmen Kuran, Nejat Gyn, (lber Ortayl et al. Ankara: Yeni Trkiye,
2000.
Perlin, Frank. Concepts of Order and Comparison, with a Diversion on Counter
Ideologies and Corporate Institutions in Late Pre-Colonial India. In Feudalism
and non-European Societies, 87165. Edited by T. J. Byres and Harbans Mukhia.
London: Frank Cass 1985.
. State Formation Reconsidered: Part Two. Modern Asian Studies 19 (1985):
41580.
. Financial Institutions and Business Practices across the Euro-Asian Interface:
Comparative and Structural Considerations, 15001900. In The European Discovery
of the World and its Economic Eects on Pre-Industrial Society, 15001900: Papers of the
Tenth International Economic History Congress, 257303. Edited by Hans Pohl. Stuttgart:
Franz Steiner, 1990.
. The Invisible City: Monetary, Administrative, and Popular Infrastructures in Asia and
Europe, 15001900. Aldershot: Variorum, 1993.
. Unbroken Landscape: Commodity, Category, Sign and Identity: Their Production as Myth
and Knowledge from 1500. Brookeld, VT: Ashgate, 1994.
Perry, John R. The Last Safavids, 172273. Iran 9 (1971): 5969.
. Forced Migration in Iran during the 17th and 18th Centuries. Iranian Studies
8 (1975): 199215.
. Karim Khan Zand: A History of Iran, 17471779. Chicago: University of Chicago
Press, 1979.
Perkins, Edwin J. American Public Finance and Financial Services, 17001785. Columbus:
Ohio State University Press.
Pierce, Leslie. The Imperial Harem: Women and Sovereignty in the Ottoman Empire. Oxford:
Oxford University Press, 1993.
Pitcher, Donald Edgar. An Historical Geography of the Ottoman Empire from the Earliest
Times to the End of the Sixteenth Century with Detailed Maps to Illustrate the Expansion of
the Empire. Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1972.
Plaisted, Bartholomew. The Desert Route to India, Being the Journals of Four Travelers by
the Great Desert Caravan Route between Aleppo and Basra, 174551. Narrative of a Journey
from Basra to Aleppo in 1750. Edited by Douglas Carruthers. London: Hakluyt
Society, 1929.
Planhol, Xavier de. Lvolution du nomadisme en Anatolie et en Iran. tude

226

compare. In Viehwirtschaft und Hirtenkultur, 6993. Ethnographische Studien. Edited


by L. Fldes and B. Gunda. Budapest: Akadmiai Kiad, 1969.
Pluchon, Pierre. Un negociant juif et deux esclaves negres a Paris: aspects du racisme au
sicle des lumieres. Port-au-Prince: Institut Franais dHaiti, 1979.
Poggi, Gianfranco. The Development of the Modern State. Stanford: Stanford University
Press, 1978.
Polanyi, Karl. The Great Transformation: The Political and Economic Origins of Our Time.
Boston: Beacon Press, 1944.
. The Economy as Instituted Process. In Trade and Market in the Early Empires,
243269. Edited by Conrad M. Arensberg and Harry W. Pearson. Glencoe, Ill.:
Free Press, 1957.
Polk, W., and R. Chambers, eds. Beginnings of Modernization in the Middle East. Chicago:
University of Chicago, 1968.
Pollington, Viscount. Notes on a Journey from Er-Rm by Diyrbekir and Birehjik to Aleppo in June 1838. Journal of the Royal Geographical Society 10 (1841):
445454.
Pomeranz, Kenneth. The Great Divergence: Europe, China, and the Making of the Modern
World Economy. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 2000.
Powell, Walter W., and Paul J. DiMaggio, eds. The New Institutionalism in Organizational
Analysis. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1991.
Power, Daniel, and Naomi Standen. Frontiers in Question: Eurasian Borderlands, 7001700.
Basingstoke: Macmillan, 1999.
Porter, James. Observations on the Religion, Law, Government and Manners of the Turks.
2 vols. Dublin: Printed for P. Wilson, 1768.
Prakash, Om. Bullion for Goods: International Trade and the Economy of Early
18th Century Bengal. The Indian Economic and Social History Review 13 (1976):
159187.
Quataert, Donald, Clothing Laws, State, and Society in the Ottoman Empire,
17201829, IJMES 29 (1997): 40325.
Rafeq, Abdul-Karim. The Province of Damascus 17231783. Beirut: Khayats, 1966.
. Economic Relations between Damascus and the Dependent Countryside,
174371. In The Islamic Middle East, 7001900, 653685. Edited by Abraham
Udovitch. Princeton: The Darwin Press, 1971.
. Changes in the Relationship between the Ottoman Central Administration
and the Syrian Provinces in the Sixteenth to the Eighteenth Centuries. In Studies
in Eighteenth Century Islamic History, 5377. Edited by Thomas Na and Roger
Owen. Carbondale: Southern Illinois University Press, 1977.
Ranke, Leopold von. The Ottoman and the Spanish Empires, in the Sixteenth and Seventeenth
Centuries. Translated by Walter K. Kelly. Philadelphia: Lea & Blanchard, 1845.
Rashed, Zenab Esmat. The Peace of Paris, 1763. Liverpool: University Press, 1951.
Ra{id, Mehmed, Tarih-i Ra{id. 6 vols. Istanbul: Matbaa-y Miri 1282/186566.
Raymond, Andr. Artisans et commerants au Caire au XVIII e sicle. 2 vols. Damascus:
Institut Franais de Damas, 1974.
. The Ottoman Conquest and the Development of the Great Arab Towns.
IJTS 1 (197980): 84101.
. The Great Arab Cities in the 16th18th Centuries: An Introduction. New York: New
York University Press, 1984.
. Le Caire des Janissaires: lapogee de la ville ottomane sous Abd al-Rahman Katkhuda.
Paris: CNRS, 1995.
Rek, Ahmet, ed. Hicr On (kinci Asrda Istanbul Hayat (11001200). Istanbul: Devlet
Matbaas, 1930.
Richards, J. F. Mughal State Finances and the Pre-Modern World Economy.
Comparative Studies in Society and History 23 (1981): 285308.

227

Ricks, T. M. Towards a Social and Economic History of 18th Century Iran.


Iranian Studies 6 (1973): 110136.
. Politics and Trade in Southern Iran and the Gulf, 17451765. Ph.D. diss.,
Indiana University, 1975.
Rhrborn, Klaus. Die Emanzipation der Finanzbrokratie im Osmanischen Reich
(Ende 16. Jahrhundert). ZDMG 122 (1972): 118139.
. Konskation und Intermedire Gewalten im Osmanischen Reich. Der Islam
55 (1978): 345350.
Root, Hilton L. The Redistributive Role of Government: Economic Regulation in
Old Regime France and England. Comparative Studies in Society and History 33
(1991): 338369.
Rothenberg, Gunter E. The Austrian Military Border in Croatia, 15221737. Urbana,
IL: University of Illinois Press, 1960.
Rudolph, Susanne Hoeber, and Lloyd I. Rudolph. Authority and Power in
Bureaucratic and Patrimonial Administration: A Revisionist Interpretation of
Weber on Bureaucracy. World Politics 31 (1979): 195227.
Rycaut, Sir Paul. The Present State of the Ottoman Empire. London: John Starkey &
Henry Brome, 1668.
George Rude, Europe in the 18th Century: Aristocracy and the Buorgeois Challenge. Cambridge,
MA: Harvard University Press, 1972.
Ruggie, J. Territoriality and Beyond: Problematizing Modernity in International
Relations. International Organization 47 (1993): 139174.
Sack, Robert D. Human Territoriality: Its Theory and History. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 1986.
Sadat, Deena. Urban Notables in the Ottoman Empire: The Ayan. Ph.D. diss.,
Rutgers University, 1969.
. Rumeli Ayanlar: The Eighteenth Century. Journal of Modern History 44
(1972): 346363.
. Ayan and A[a: The Transformation of the Bektashi Corps in the Eighteenth
Century. The Muslim World 63 (1973): 206219.
Sahillio[lu, Halil. Bir Mltezimin Zimmet Defterine gre XV. Yzyl Sonunda Osmanl
Darphane Mukataalar. Istanbul niversitesi (ktisat Fakltesi Mecmuasi 23 (1963):
145218.
. XVII. Asrn (lk Yarsnda Istanbul"da Tedavldeki Sikkelerin Raici. Belgeler
1/2 (1964): 227233.
. Drdnc Murad"in Ba[dad Seferinin Menzilnamesi. Belgeler 2 (1965): 136.
. Bir Tccar Kervan. Belgeler 2 (1969): 6569.
. }v{ Year Crises in the Ottoman Empire. In Studies in the Economic History
of the Middle East from the Rise of Islam to the Present Day, 230254. Edited by Michael
A. Cook. London: Oxford University Press, 1970.
. The Role of International Monetary and Metal Movements in Ottoman
Monetary History, 13001700. In Precious Metals in the Later Medieval and Early
Modern Worlds, 269304. Edited by J. F. Richards. Durham: Carolina Academic
Press, 1983.
. Osmanl Dneminde Irak"n (dari Taksimat. Belleten 54 (1990): 12341257.
}ahiner, Araks. The Sarrafs of Istanbul: Financiers of the Empire. Masters thesis. Bo[azii University, Institute of Social Sciences, 1995.
Said, Edward. Orientalism. New York: Vintage, 1979.
Sakao[lu, Necdet. Anadolu Derebeyi Ocaklarndan Kse Pa{a Hanedani. Ankara: Yurt
Yaynlar, 1984.
Salzmann, Ariel. An Ancien Rgime Revisited: Privatization and Political Economy
in the 18th century Ottoman Empire. Politics & Society 21 (1993): 393423.
. Toward a Comparative History of the Ottoman State, 14501850. Archv
orientln (Oriental Archive) 66 (1998), 351366.

228

}anizade, Ataullah Mehmet. Tarih-i }anizade. 4 vols. Istanbul: Ceride-i Havadis


Matbaas, 1290/1873.
Sar Mehmed Pa{a. Ottoman Statecraft: The Book of Counsel for Vezirs and Governors of
Sar Mehmed Pa{a (Nasa'ih ul-Vuzera vel-Umera). Edited by W. L. Wright. Princeton:
Princeton University Press, 1935.
Saul, Norma. Russia and the Mediterranean, 17971807. Chicago: University of Chicago,
1970.
Schilcher, Linda Schatkowski. Families in Politics: Damascene Factions and Estates of the
18th and 19th Centuries. Stuttgart: Franz Steiner, 1985.
Schmidt, Karl J. An Atlas and Survey of South Asian History. Armonk, NY: M. E.
Sharpe, 1995.
Schroeder, Paul W. The Transformation of European Politics, 17631848. Oxford:
Clarendon Press, 1994.
Scott, James C. Seeing Like a State: How Certain Schemes to Improve the Human Condition
Have Failed. New Haven: Yale University Press, 1998.
. Domination and the Arts of Resistance. New Haven: Yale University Press, 1990.
Sen, Sudipta. Empire of Free Trade: The East India Company and Making of the Colonial
Marketplace. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press, 1998.
Selnik Mustafa Efendi. Tarih-i Selnik (9711003/15631595). 2 vols. Edited by
Prof. Mehmet Ip{irli. Istanbul: Edebiyat Fakltesi Basmevi, 1989.
}em"dni-zde Fndkl Sleyman Efendi. }em"dni-zde Fndkl Sleyman Efendi Trihi
Mur"i"t-Tevrih: 3 vols. Edited by Mnir Aktepe. Istanbul: Istanbul niversitesi
Edebiyat Fakltesi Yaynlar, 19761981.
Sevgen, Nazmi. Do[u ve Gneydo[u Anadolu"da Trk Beylikleri: Osmanl Belgeleri ile. Tarihi
Trk Kltr Ara{trma Enstitts, 1982.
. Krtler. Belgeler 7 (1968): 5761.
. Krtler. Belgeler 8 (1968): 2752.
. Krtler. Belgeler 9 (1968): 7076.
Sezgin, Fuat. The Contribution of Arabic-Islamic Geographers to the Formation of the World
Map. Frankfurt: Institut fr Geschichte der Arabisch-Islamischen Wissenschaften
an der Johann Wolfgang Goethe-Universitt, 1987.
Shamir, Shimon. Belligerency in a Disintegrating Society: Factional Warfare in
Ottoman Syria on the Eve of the Period of Modernization. Abr Nahrain 12 (1972):
7584.
Shaw, Stanford. Between Old and New: The Ottoman Empire under Sultan Selim III
1789 1807. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1971.
. History of the Ottoman Empire and Modern Turkey. Vol. 1. Empire of the Gazis: The
Rise and Decline of the Ottoman Empire, 12801808. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press, 1976.
Shay, Mary Lucille, ed., The Ottoman Empire from 1720 to 1734 as Revealed in the
Dispatches of the Venetian Baili. Urbana: University of Illinois, 1944.
Shils, Edward. Centre and Periphery. In The Logic of Personal Knowledge: Essays
Presented to Michael Polanyi on His Seventieth Birthday, 11th March 1961, 11730.
Glencoe: Free Press, 1961.
. The Constitution of Society. Chicago: University of Chicago, 1982.
Shinder, Joel. Career Line Formation in the Ottoman Bureaucracy, 16481750:
A New Perspective. JESHO 16 (1973): 216237.
Silah{r Kemani Mustafa A[a. Osmanl-(ran Mnasebetleri, 17201724 ve Silah{r Kemani
Mustafa A[a"nn Revan Fetih-Namesi. Edited by Mnir Aktepe. Istanbul: Istanbul
niversitesi Edebiyat Fakltesi Yaynlar, 1970.
Silberman, Bernard S. Cages of Reason: The Rise of the Rational State in France, Japan,
the United States, and Great Britain. Chicago: University of Chicago, 1993.
Simms, Brendan. The Impact of Napoleon: Prussian High Politics, Foreign Policy and the
Crisis of the Executive, 17971806. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997.

229

Sivers, P. von. Les plaisirs du collectionneur: capitalisme scal et chefs indignes


en Algerie (18401860). Annales conomies, socits, civilizations 35 (1980): 679699.
Skinner, G. William. Cities and the Hierarchy of Local Systems. In The City in
Late Imperial China, 275351. Edited by W. Skinner. Stanford: Stanford University
Press, 1977.
Skocpol, Theda. States and Social Revolutions: A Comparative Analysis of France, Russia,
and China. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1979.
Soja, Edward W., Postmodern Geographies: The Reassertion of Space in Critical Social Theory.
London: Verso, 1989.
. Thirdspace: Journeys to Los Angeles and Other Read-and-Imagined Places. Cambridge,
Mass.: Blackwell, 1996.
Soysal, (smail. Fransz (htilli ve Trk-Fransz Diplomas Mnasebetleri (1789 1802).
Ankara: TTK, 1999.
Szen, Metin. Diyarbakrda Trk Mimarisi. Istanbul: Ara{trma Enstits, 1971.
Springborg, Patricia. The Contractual State: Reections on Orientalism and Despotism. History of Political Thought 8 (1987): 395433.
. Western Republicanism and the Oriental Prince. Austin: University of Texas Press, 1992.
Spruyt, Hendrik. The Sovereign State and its Competitors. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
University Press, 1994.
Staa, Susan. Dimensions of Womens Power in Historic Cairo. In Islamic and
Middle Eastern Societies: A Festschrift in Honor of Professor Wadie Jwaideh, 6299. Edited
by Robert W. Olson and Salman H. Ani. Brattleboro, VT: Amana, 1987.
Steensgaard, Neil. The Asian Trade Revolution of the Seventeenth Century, the East India
Companies and the Caravan Trade. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1974.
Stein, Joshua M. Habsburg Financial Institutions Presented as a Model for the
Ottoman Empire in the Sefaretname of Ebu Bekir Ratib Efendi. In Habsburgischosmanische Beziehungen (CIEPO 2630 September 1983), 233243. Edited by Andreas
Tietze. Vienna: Verband der Wissenschaftlichen Gesellschaften sterreichs, 1985.
Steingass, F. A. Comprehensive Persian-English Dictionary. London: Routledge and Kegan
Paul, 1977.
Stiglitz, Joseph E. Economics of the Public Sector. New York: W. W. Norton, 1986.
Stoianovich, Traian. Land Tenure and Related Sectors of the Balkan Economy,
16001800. Journal of European Economic History 13 (1953): 398411.
. The Segmentary State and the La Grande Nation. In Geographic Perspectives
in History, 256280. Edited by Eugene Genovese and L. Hochberg. Oxford:
Blackwell, 1989.
Stone, Lawrence. The Past and the Present. Boston: Routledge and Kegan Paul, 1981.
Stoye, John. Marsiglis Europe, 16801730: The Life and Times of Luigi Ferdinando Marsigli,
Soldier and Virtuoso. New Haven: Yale University Press, 1994.
Subrahmanyam, Sanjay. Aspects of State Formation in South India and Southeast
Asia, 15001650. The Indian Economic and Social History Review 23 (1986): 357377.
. Precious Metal Flows and Prices in Western and Southern Asia, 15001750:
Some Comparative and Conjunctural Aspects. Studies in History 7 (1991): 79105.
Subrahmanyam, Sanjay, and C. A. Bayly. Portfolio Capitalists and the Political
Economy of Early Modern India. In Merchants, Markets and the State in Early Modern
India, 242265. Edited by Sanjay Subrahmanyam. Delhi: Oxford University Press,
1990.
Sueska, Avdo. Malikana. POF 89 (195859): 11142; 36 (1986): 197230.
Sumner, B. H. Peter the Great and the Ottoman Empire. Oxford: Blackwell, 1949.
Sunar, (lkay. State and Economy in the Ottoman Empire. In The Ottoman Empire
and the World Economy, 6387. Edited by Huri (slamo[lu-(nan. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press: Cambridge, 1987.
Svoronos, Nikos G. Le commerce de Salonique au XVIII e sicle. Paris: Presses Universitaires
de France, 1956.

230

Tabak, Faruk. Local Merchants in Peripheral Areas of the Empire: The Fertile
Crescent during the Long Nineteenth Century. Review 11 (1988): 179214.
. Agrarian Fluctuations and Modes of Labor Control in the Western Arc of
the Fertile Crescent, c. 17001850. In Landholding and Commercial Agriculture in the
Middle East, 135155. Edited by F. Tabak and Ca[lar Keyder. Albany: State
University of New York, 1991.
Tabako[lu, Ahmet. Gerileme Dnemine Girerken Osmanl Maliyesi. Istanbul: Dergh
Yaynlar, 1985.
. Trk (ktisat Tarihi. Istanbul: Dergh Yaynlar, 1986.
Taeschner, Franz G. Das Anatolische Wegenetz nach Osmanischen Quellen. 2 vols. Leipzig:
Mayer & Mller, 19241926.
Tatarck, Abdullah Efendi. Selim-i Sni Devrinde Nizm- Devlet Hakknda Mutla"t. Trk Tarihi Encmeni Mecmuas 8 (1333/19141915): 1524.
Tekeli, Ilhan. On Institutionalized External Relations of Cities in the Ottoman
Empire: A Settlement Model Approach. tudes Balkaniques, 8 (1972): 4972.
Thieck, Jean-Pierre. Dcentralisation ottomane et armation urbaine Alep la
n du XVIIIme sicle. In Mouvements communautaires et espaces urbains au Machreq,
116178. Edited by Mona Zakaria et al.. Beirut: Centre dtudes et de Recherches
sur le Moyen-Orient Contemporain, 1985.
. Passion dOrient. Edited by Gilles Kepel. Paris: ditions Karthala, 1992.
Thomas, Lewis V. A Study of Naima. New York: New York University Press,
1972.
Thompson, Elizabeth. Ottoman Political Reform in the Provinces: The Damascus
Advisory Council in 184445. IJMES 25 (1993): 457475.
Thomson, Ann. Barbary and Enlightenment: European Attitudes toward the Magreb in the
Eighteenth Century. Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1987.
Tietze, Andreas, ed. Mustafa Alis Counsel for Sultans of 1581. 2 vols. Wien: Verlag
der sterreichischen Akademie der Wissenschaften, 1979.
, ed. Habsburgisch-osmanische Beziehungen: relations habsbourg-ottomanes. Wien, 26.30.
September 1983. Colloque sous le patronage du Comit International des tudes pr-Ottomanes
et Ottomanes. Vienna: Verlag des Verbandes der wissenschaftlichen Gesellschaften
sterreichs, 1985.
Tilly, Charles. Reections on the History of European State-Making. In The
Formation of the National States in Western Europe, 383. Edited by Charles Tilly.
Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1975.
. War Making and State Making as Organized Crime. In Bringing the State
Back In, 169191. Edited by Peter B. Evans, Dietrich Rueschemeyer, and Theda
Skopcol. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1985.
. The Contentious French: Four Centuries of Popular Struggle. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
University Press, 1986.
. State and Counterrevolution in France. Social Research 56 (1989): 7197.
. Coercion, Capital and European States, AD 9901990. Oxford: Blackwell, 1990.
Tzlak, Fahrettin. Osmanl Devletinde Ham Bakr ({leme Merkezleri Olarak Tokat
ve Diyarbakr. Belleten 59: (1995): 643659.
. Osmanl Dneminde Keban-Ergani Yresinde Madencilik, 17751850. Ankara: TTK,
1997.
Tocqueville, Alexis. Oeuvres compltes. 18 vols. Edited by J. P. Mayer. Paris: Gallimard,
1951.
. The Old Rgime and the French Revolution. Garden City, N.Y.: Doubleday &
Company, 1955.
. Lancien rgime et la Rvolution. Edited by J. P. Mayer. Paris: ditions Gallimard,
1967.
. The European Revolution & Correspondence with Gobineau. Westport, Conn.:
Greenwood, 1974.

231

. De la colonie en Algrie. Bruxelles: ditions Complexe, 1988.


. Lancien rgime et la Rvolution (Notes on the French Revolution and Napoleon). Edited
by Franois Furet and Franoise Mlonio and trans. Alan S. Kahan. 2 vols.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1998.
. Writings on Empire and Slavery. Edited by Jennifer Pitts. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins
University Press, 2001.
Todorova, Mariia Nikolaeva. Imagining the Balkans. New York: Oxford University
Press, 1997.
Tracy, James D., ed. The Rise of Merchant Empires: Long-Distance Trade in the Early
Modern World, 13501750. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990.
, ed. The Political Economy of Merchant Empires: State Power and World Trade,
1350 1750. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991.
Tucker, Ernest S. Religion and Politics in the Era of Ndir Shh: The View of
Six Contemporary Sources. Ph.D. diss., University of Chicago, 1992.
. The Peace Negotiation of 1736: A Conceptual Turning Point in OttomanIranian Relations. TSA Bulletin 20 (1996): 1637.
Tukin, Cemal, ed. Mahmud II. Devrinde Halep (syan: 18131819. Tarih Vesikalar
1 (1941): 256264.
Trek Ahmet, and F. etin Derin. Feyzullah Efendi"nin kend kalemnden Hal
Tercmesi. Tarih Dergisi 23 (1969): 204208; Tarih Dergisi 24 1970): 6992.
Trkay, Cevdet, ed. Ba{bakanlk Ar{ivi Belgeleri"ne gre Osmanl (mparatorlu[u"nda Oymak,
A{iret ve Cematlar. Istanbul: Tercman Messesei"ne, 1979.
Trkiye Diyanet Vak Islm Asiklopedisi. 9 vols. Istanbul: Trkiye Diyanet Vak, Islm
Ansiklopedisi Genel Mdrlg, 1988.
Turner, Bryan S. Weber and Islam: A Critical Study. London: Routledge & Kegan
Paul, 1974.
Tyan, Emile. Histoire de lorganisation judiciaire en pays dIslam. 2 vols. Paris: Librairie
du Recueil Sirey, 1938.
lker, Necmi. The Rise of Izmir, 16881740. Ph.D. diss., University of Michigan,
1974.
Uluay, M. a[atay. 18. ve 19. Yzyllarda Saruhan"da E{kiyalk ve Halk Hareketleri.
Istanbul: Berksoy Basmevi, 1955.
'Umari, Yasin al-. Al-Durr al-Maknn f al-Ma"thir al-Mdiya min al-Qurun.
Critical Edition by Sayyar Kawkab 'Ali al-Jaml. Ph.D. diss., University of St.
Andrews, 1983.
nal, Mehmet Ali. XVI. ve XVII. Yzyllarda Diyarbekir Eyaletine Tabi Sancaklarn
(dari Statleri. Ziya Gkalp Dergisi 44 (1986): 3140.
. 1056/1646 Tarihli Avrz Defterine Gre 17. Yzyl Ortalarnda Harput.
Belleten 51 (1987): 119129.
. XVI. Yzylda Harput Sanca[ (15181566). Ankara: TTK, 1989.
Unat, Faik Re{id, ed. Outline TKSK Harita No. 447 Tarih Vesikalar 1 (1941)
insert.
, ed. Ahmed III Derine Ait bir Islahat Takviri. Tarih Vesikalar 1 (1941): 107121.
, ed. Abdi Tarihi, 1730 Patrona Ihtill Hakknda Bir Eser. Ankara: TTK, 1943.
Uzunar{l, (smail Hakk. Me{hur Rumeli yanlarndan Tirsinikli (smail Ylk O[u Suleyman
A[a ve Alemdar Mustafa Pa{a. Istanbul: TTK, 1942.
. Osmanl Devleti Te{kilatndan Kapkulu Ocaklar. Acemi Oca{ ve Yenieri Oca{. Ankara:
TTK, 1943.
. Osmanl Devletinin Merkez ve Bahriye Te{kilat. Ankara: TTK, 1948.
. Nizam- Cedid Ricalinden Valide Sultan Kethdas Me{hur Yusuf A[a ve
Kethdazde Arif Efendi. Belleten 20 (1956): 485527.
. n Mustafa"nn Kz {ah Sultan"a Bor Senedi. Belleten 25 (1961): 97.
. Sultan III. Mustafa"nn Hzn Verici Bir Bor Senedi. Belleten 22 (1968):
595598.

232

. apan O[ullar. Belleten 30 (1974): 215265.


. Osmanl Tarihi. Vol. 3, pt. 1. II. Selim"in Tahta k{ndan 1699 Karlofa Andla{masna
kadar. Ankara: TTK, 1983.
. Osmanl Tarihi. Vol. 4, pts. 1 and 2. XVIII Yzyl. Ankara: TTK, 1983.
. Ayn. (A, 2: 4042.
Valensi, Lucette. Venise et la sublime porte: la naissance du despote. Paris: Hachette, 1987.
Vsif, Ahmed Efendi. Mehsin"l-sr ve Hakik"l-Ahbr. Transcribed by Dr. Mcteba
Ilgrel. Istanbul: Edebiyat Fakltesi Basmevi, 1978.
Vaughan, Dorothy M. Europe and the Turk: A Pattern of Alliances 13501700. New
York: AMS, 1954.
Vehbi Seyyit. Srnme: nc Ahmed"in O[ullarnn Snnet D[n. Edited by Re{ad
Ekrem Kou. Istanbul: igir Kitabevi, 1939.
Veinstein, Gilles. Ayan de la region dIzmir et commerce du Levant (deuxime
moiti du XVIIIe sicle). tudes Balkaniques 12 (1976): 7183.
Venturino, D. La Naissance de lAncien Rgime. In The Political Culture of the
French Revolution, 1140. Edited by Colin Lucas. Oxford: Pergamon Press, 1988.
Vilar, Pierre, A History of Gold and Money, 14501920. London: Verso, 1984.
Voltaire. Candid or Optimism. London: Penguin, 1947.
. Oeuvres compltes de Voltaire. 13 vols. Paris: Chez Th. Desoer, Libraire Rue
Christine, 18171819.
Wallerstein, Immanuel. The Modern World-System I: Capitalist Agriculture and the Origins
of the European World-Economy in the Sixteenth Century. New York: Academic Press,
1974.
. The Modern World-System II: Mercantilism and the Consolidation of the European WorldEconomy, 16001700. New York: Academic Press, 1980.
. The Modern World-System III: The Second Era of Great Expansion of the Capitalist
World Economy, 17301840s. New York: Academic Press, 1989.
. Hale Decdeli, and Re{at Kasaba. The Incorporation of the Ottoman Empire
into the World-Economy. In The Ottoman Empire in the World Economy, 8897.
Edited by Huri (slamo[lu-(nan. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1987.
Waldner, David. State Building and Late Development. Ithaca: Cornell University Press,
1999.
Wasserman, Stanley, and Katherine Faust. Social Nework Analysis: Methods and Applications.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994.
Weber, Eugen Joseph Peasants into Frenchmen: The Modernization of Rural France,
1870 1914. Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1976.
Weber, Max. Max Weber on Law in Economy and Society. Edited by Max Rheinstein.
New York: Simon and Schuster, 1967.
. Economy and Society. 2 vols. Edited by Guenther Roth and Claus Wittich.
Berkeley: University of California, 1978.
Welch, Cheryl B. De Tocqueville. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2001.
White, Hayden. Tropics of Discourse: Critical Essays in Cultural Essays. Baltimore: Johns
Hopkins, 1978.
. The Content of the Form: Narrative Discourse and Historical Representation. London
& Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press, 1987.
White, Jenny B. Islamist Mobilization in Turkey: A Study in Vernacular Politics. Seattle:
University of Washington Press, 2002.
Whittaker, C. R. Frontiers of the Roman Empire: A Social and Economic Study. Baltimore:
Johns Hopkins University Press, 1994.
Wink, Andr. Maratha Revenue Farming. Modern Asian Studies 17 (1983): 591628.
Wirth, E. Aleppo im 19. Jahrhundertein Beispiel fr Stabilitt und Dynamik
sptosmanischer Wirtschaft. In Osmanistische Studien zur Wirtschafts und Sozialgeschichte,
In memoriam Vanco Bokov 187206. Edited by Hans Georg Majer. Wiesbaden:
Harrassowitz, 1986.

233

Witt, Peter-Christian, ed. Wealth and Taxation in Central Europe: The History and Sociology
of Public Finance. Leamington Spa: Berg, 1987.
Wol, Larry. Inventing Eastern Europe: The Map of Civilization on the Mind of the Enlightenment.
Palo Alto: Stanford University Press, 1994.
Wolin, Sheldon S. Tocqueville Between Two Worlds: The Making of a Political and Theoretical
Life. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2001.
Woloch, Isser. The New Regime: Transformations of the French Civic Order, 17891820.
New York: W.W. Norton, 1994.
Woodhead, Christine. The Present Terrour of the World: Contemporary Views
of the Ottoman Empire c. 1600. History ( Journal of the Historical Association,
G.B.) 72 (1987): 2037.
Woods, A. C. A History of the Levant Company. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1935.
Yaman, Talat Mmtaz. Osmanl (mparatorlu[u Te{kilatnda Mtesellimlik Messesesine Dair. Trk Hukuk Tarihi Dergisi 1 (194142): 75105.
Yavuz, Muhsine Helimo[lu. Diyarbakr Efsaneleri zerine Ara{trma: Derleme, (nceleme. 2
vols. Ankara: M. H. Yavuz, 1989.
Yediyldz, Bahaeddin. Trk Vakf Kurucularnn Sosyal Tabakala{madaki Yeri,
17001800. JOS 3 (1982): 143164.
. Institution du vaqf au XVIII e siecle en Turquie: tude socio-historique. Ankara: Imprimerie
de la Socit dHistoire Turque, 1985.
Yldz, Hakk Dursun, (nci Enginn, and Emine Grsy Naskal, eds. V. Milletleraras
Trkiye Sosyal ve (ktisat Tarihi Kongresi: Tebli[ler. Istanbul 1989. Ankara: TTK, 1990.
Ylmaz, Nazm, Osman Yldrm, and Necla Bykkrcal. Osmanl Ar{ivinde Bulunan
Muhedenmelerden rnekler. Ankara: T. C. Ba{bakanlk Devlet Ar{ivleri Genel
Mdrl[ Osmanl Ar{ivi Daire Ba{kanl[, 2000.
Ylmazelik, (brahim. XIX. Yzyln (lk Yarsnda Diyarbakr, 17901840. Ankara: TTK,
1995.
. XIX. Yzyln ilk Yarsnda Diyarbakr, 17901840. Ph.D. diss., 2 vols. Frat
niversitesi (Elaz[), 1991.
Ynan, Mkrimin, H. Diyarbekir. (A, 1 (1945): 601605.
Yirmisekiz elebi, Mehmed Efendi"nin Fransa Sefretnmesi. Edited by Beynun Akyava.
Ankara: Trk Kltrn Ara{trma Enstits, 1993.
Ycel, Ya{ar. Osmanl (mparatorlu[unda Desantralizasyona (Adem-i Merkeziye)
Dair Genel Gzlemler. Belleten 38 (1974): 657708.
. Osmanl Devlet Dzenine Ait Metinler. Kitb Mstetb. Ankara: Ankara niversitesi
Dil ve Tarih Co[rafya Fakltesi, 1974.
Zarinebaf-Shahr, Fariba. Tabriz under Ottoman Rule, 17251730. Ph.D. diss.,
University of Chicago, 1991.
Zil, Madeline. Elite Circulation in the Ottoman Empire: Great Mollas of the
Eighteenth Century. JESHO 26 (1983): 318364.
. The Politics of Piety: The Ottoman Ulema in the Postclassical Age (1600 1800).
Minneapolis: Bibliotheca Islamica, 1988.

This page intentionally left blank

INDEX

Abou-El-Haj, Rifa"at 6 n. 8, 18, 44,


88, 104105, 194
Abdulfattah, Kamal 58 n. 81
Adana 67
Afghan 37
Ahmad Shah Durrani 72
Ahmed II 88 n. 50
Ahmed III 30, 39, 7578, 11819,
179, 182
Ahmed Cevdet Pasha 30, 180, 182, 194
Ahmed Efendi Vsf 181, n. 18
Ahmed Resmi Efendi 94, 99
Akarl, Engin 164
Aksan, Virginia 79, 94, 180 n. 12
Albania 47
Aleppo 10, 59, 61, 63, 6567, 9293,
111, 122 n. 2, 129, 132, 135, 142,
148 n. 109, 161, 164, 169, 174
Algeria 1768, 195
Ali Bey al-Kabir 49, 74, 112 n. 154,
180
Amid, city of 12, 127 n. 12, 129,
13440, 14651, 15475; sancak
of 133 n. 27, 1356, 141, 145;
(eastern) nahiye of 135, 139 n. 52;
(western) nahiye of 1367, 139 n. 52
Amsterdam 71
Alexander the Great 33
Anatolia 128, 129, 147, 149, 153,
163, 169, 174
Ancien rgime (old regime, old order)
1217
Ankara 62
Arabia 34
Archives 7; of Algeria 7, 176; of
France 126 n. 9; of Harput 171
n. 217; of Prussia 7; Ottoman
7980
Aristocracy of Service 26. See also
Rical-i devlet
Armenia 51
Armenian 27, 11113, 117 n. 180,
120, 134
Asia 33, 53, 61, 151, 176, 176, 179.
See also West Asia
Asia Minor 36. See also Anatolia
Atl, Esin 78

Auction, of tax farms 26, 889, 96,


99, 101, 103, 109, 134, 138, 140,
1501; (in provinces) 26, 134, 138,
140, 1501; of esham 119; of
personal eects. See Msadere
Ayan. See Gentry
Ayntab 53
Azarbayjan 34, 35, 38, 39, 71
Abbas III, Safavid Shah 41
Azov 40
Azam (also 'Azamzde, clan of
Damascus) 95, 107
Bab- li. See Sublime Porte
Baghdad 11, 13, 48, 50, 61, 6567,
74, 100, 111, 129, 13135, 153,
163, 165, 182, 185, 190, 193
Ba[, Serpil 33 n. 9
Bandits 131, 1456
Balkans 7, 8, 37, 47, 49, 55, 68, 71,
89, 101, 186
Barbir, Karl 18, 58 n. 82, 59 n. 87,
107 n. 135
Basra 66, 74
Battle, of e{me 74; of Plassey 72;
of Pruth 38
Bengal 61, 72, 125
Bessarabia 181
Bandar Abbas 62
Bayraktar Mustafa Pasha 1858, 191
Beyazid I 81
Black Sea 33, 35, 40, 4546, 54, 56,
62, 70, 72, 74, 75, 112, 128, 180,
192; Principalities of 45, 72. See also
Moldavia and Wallachia
Borders 4445
Bosnia 47
Britain 70
Bucak 72
Bureaucracy 29, 78, 8285, 92102
Bursa 54, 63, 161
Byzantine Empire 81
Calendar 86
Canada 197
Cartography 3134
Caspian Sea 33, 38, 39, 6162

236

Cebel Bedeliyesi 97, 114, 133


Celali 57
Centralization (state) 35, 9, 1416,
83, 133, 19195
ermik 100, 122, 136, 140, 141,
148, 151, 159, 162
eteci Abdullah Pasha 9495, 131
Cezar, Yavuz 8 n. 17, 8687
Charter of Federation. See Sened-i (ttifak
China, trade of 62. See also Manchu
Chios 109
Christian, craftsmen 162; dragoman
27; nanciers 11117
Christianity 15
Christendom 31, 37
Churches, in Diyarbekir 151
Circle of Justice 7677, 81
Circumcision, ceremonies 7576,
102, 120. See also Surnme-i Vehbi
Cizye (poll tax) 848, 141
Clement XII 41
Colbert, Jean-Baptiste 3, 79, 125
Colonialism 44, 72, 17778, 19496
Commerce 6071
Contract (concept of ) 88, 92,
96101, 187
Corporate Patrimonialism 102110
Cossacks 45
Crusade 41
Crimea 40; khanate of 46, 72, 89
Crete 94, 175
Croatia 47
Cyprus 149, 171
unku{ 137
orum 103
Damga (stamp tax) 156, 16163
Damascus, city of 48, 62, 65, 90,
161, 189, 193; province of 91, 95,
107, 122 n. 2, 129, 142, 154, 161,
164, 175
DAnville, Jean-Baptiste Bourguignon 32
Darling, Linda 82
Dar s-sade a[as. See Eunuch
Debt, personal 11117; state 8789,
11018, 128, 183; peasant 147
Decentralization 145
Defterdarlk, of Damascus 129
Delhi 61
Denmark 40
Derebey 74, 163
Deringil, Selim 194 n. 64
Diplomacy 73, 11011

Diplomats 110
Divan- Hmayun 34, 73, 79, 82,
111, 190
Diyarbekir, province of 9, 1112, 29,
50, 54, 58, 5960, 65, 66, 95, 100,
121, 12275, 185, 190; commune of
1914
DOhsson, Mouradgea 27
Du-gyan, of Diyarbekir 151; of the
empire 9091
Dye houses (boyahane) 1567, 161
Ebu Bekir al-Dimi{ki 32
Ebu Su"ud Efendi 55
Edirne 90, 101, 103, 116
Egypt 24, 34, 49, 53, 55, 74, 84, 90,
112, 154, 163, 165, 180, 186, 189,
196
Eldem, Ethem 18, n. 49
Emanet 168 n. 203
Empire, theory of 3, 1318
Enlightenment 6, 14, 16, 17880
Epidemic 148, 170
Erim, Ne{e 61
Ergani 130, 132 n. 21, 13739, 143,
145 n. 87, 147, 149 n. 115, 168
Erzurum 51, 54, 59, 61, 63, 65, 95,
100, 102, 13031, 192, 193
Esma Sultan the Elder 106
Esnaf (guilds) 77, 102, 143, 14549,
15762, 168, 173
E{rf ve yan. See gentry
Eunuch, senior black (dar s-sade
a[as) 75, 80, 84, 88, 90, 92, 95;
senior white (bab l-sade a[as) 92
Euphrates 50
Eurasia 13, 14, 21, 29, 3136, 7173,
128. See also Asia
Expropriation. See Msadere
Famine 135
Faroqhi, Suraiya 166 n. 194
Fars 51
Federalism 18788, 19192, 194. See
also Sened-i (ttifak
Feyzullah Efendi 1035
Finance, domestic 10, 11018;
interstate 118, 183
Financier (sarraf or banker) 3, 89,
11118, 184
Findley, Carter 26 n. 68
Finkle, Caroline 59 n. 84
Fisc. See Treasury
Fitna 192


Fleischer, Cornell 14 n. 33, 83
France 35, 7, 1416, 2023, 2627,
40, 47, 65, 74, 79, 83, 177, 181,
19599
Frontier 4252
Furet, Franois 16 n. 41
Georgia 35, 39, 42, 72
Gift 9293
Ghalzai Afghans 38, 61
Gelibolu 90
Gen, Mehmet 910, 18, 69
Gentry 1012, 1718, 2627, 29, 60,
74, 83, 89, 95, 100, 101, 107, 120,
132, 135, 137, 140, 14853,
15253, 156, 16369, 175
Gobineau, Alfred de 178, 195,
196
Goman, Daniel 62 n. 99
Goodrich, Thomas 32 n. 6
Government, vernacular (denition)
2526; practice of 17075,
18891
Governorship 49, 50, 93, 95, 100,
131, 138, 169, 189, 182
Guilds. See Esnaf
Gujarat 66
Gul{eni 151
Gmrk. See Tari
Habermas, Jrgen
Habsburg Empire 40
Hama 95
Hami of Amid 9495
Hamedan 34
Hanagan, Michael 24
Hane (legal school) 55, 98, 115116
Hani 129 n. 14, 137, 13940, 143,
14850
Harput 129, 131, 1367, 140, 146,
1612
Hass- Hmayun 56, 87
Hassan Pasha 50
Hickok, Michael 106 n. 129
Hierarchy 77, 92102, 107109
Haj. See Pilgrims
Hijaz 38, 48, 63, 73
Himalayas 33
Homs 95
Hourani, Albert 1718
Hungary 22
Hseyin II 38
Hdevendigar 60
Hkmet 51

237

Ibn Khaldun 76
Imam Reza 47
India 22, 32, 36; products of 62, 65.
See also South Asia
Iran 22, 47, 50, 5960, 61, 68, 7174
Iraq 1313, 134, 142, 170
Israeli policy 178
Izmir 6263, 71, 90, 100, 111
(brahim Mteferikka 33
(ltizam. See Tax Farming
(nalck, Halil 1718, 187
Jalilis (or Abdl -celilzde, clan of
Mosul) 60, 100, 132, 164, 165
Janissaries 3, 55, 57, 60 81, 83, 102
118, 180, 184, 186; in provinces
142, 151, 152, 154, 155, 158, 162,
166, 170, 171
Jews, nanciers 111112, 115; in
Diyarbekir 151
Judge (kad) 12, 27, 52, 72, 104, 117,
118, 140, 146, 147, 148, 149, 152,
153, 157, 158, 159
Kad. See Judge
Kad Sicils 9
Kafadar, Cemal 81 n. 17
Kaht 42
Kahya 80
Kalmyk 39
Kanunname 53, 82, 115
Kap 105110
Karaman 53
Karaosmano[lu clan 100
Karahsar- }ark 60
Karim Khan Zand 7274, 131, 142
Kars 60
Kerman 51
Kermanshah 34
Khuzistan 67
Krprl viziers 3
Kurdistan 5051, 56, 60, 67, 71, 74,
87, 189,
Ktahya 53
Latin America 197
Lattimore, Owen 45 n. 42
Lebanon 47
Lewis, Bernard 3 n. 3
Levni (Abdlcelil elebi) 76. See also
plates 16
Life-lease. See malikne
London 71

238

Louis XIV 3, 14
Louis XVI 4, 183
Louis Napoleon (Napoleon III) 186,
196
Luristan 34, 38
Magrib 4647
Mahmud I 105, 119
Mahmud II 186, 191
Malikne (or Life-lease) 2, 18, 2729,
8792, 95102, 11415
Malatya 51
Makran 35
Manchu (China) 34
Mann, Michael 5 n. 8
Mara{ 51
Mardin 128, 13235, 139, 141, 143,
146, 151, 157, 161, 162, 166
Marseilles 71
Marsigli, Luigi Fernando (Count)
3233
Mecca 35, 48, 72, 84, 90
Medina 35, 48, 72, 84
Mediterranean, geopolitics of 3, 6,
29, 31, 36, 40, 53, 55, 88, 177,
180, 188, 198; trade of 6163, 66,
68, 70, 118
Mehmet Ali Pasha 177
Mehmet II 8182
Mehmet IV 177, 185
Mengene (cloth presses) 171
Menzil (post system) 4851
Military, band 118; elite 108;
French 17778; insurrection of
102; Ottoman 1819, 2325, 26,
29, 3239, 5455, 60, 6769, 81,
86, 97, 10203; reform 18388
Mines (in Ergani and Keban) 137,
138, 139
Mufti, Hane in Amid 151; Sha"i
in Amid 151
Modernization, theories 5
Mohammed (Prophet) 35
Moldavia 45, 72, 181. See also Black
Sea Principalities
Monetary Policy 6871
Moore, Sally Falk 19
Morea 100
Mosul 132, 135, 143, 152, 160, 16465
Mudanya 90
Mufti (chief ), in Diyarbekir, 151.
See }eyh"l-(slam
Mughal Empire 39
Muhasslk, of Aleppo 129

Mukha 66
Mukataa (pl. mukatat) 28, 57, 87,
1267, 139, 142, 143, 146, 155,
15864, 174. See also Tax farming
Murad I 81
Murphey, Rhoads 58
Musqat 66
Mustafa II 102
Mltezim 57. See also Tax farmer
Msadere 84, 86, 9697, 191
Nadir Shah Afshar (also Tahmasp Quli
Khan) 41, 47, 60, 61, 7274
Napoleon 6, 23, 191, 198
Napoleon III 196
Naqshbandiye 149 n. 115
Nasihatname 76, 8182
New Order Army 170
New Order (Nizm- Cedid) 4,
18485, 170; New Order Treasury
((rade-i Cedid) 4
Nev{ehirli (brahim Pasha 3, 34,
7880, 89, 94, 96
Nogay Tatars 45
Nile 62
Nisibin 1324
Ocaklk 51
Oman 35, 61
Orientalism 28 n. 73
Palace (Ottoman court and dynasty)
12, 25, 28, 55, 75, 7692, 94, 95,
99, 107, 110, 111, 118120
Palestine (Filistin) 11, 40, 56, 131,
189
Palu 129, 137, 149 n. 116, 1612
Parson, Talcott 13
Partnerships, in tax farms 10608
Peasants 3, 26, 80, 12763, 175
Perlin, Frank 27 n. 71
Persian Gulf 22, 35, 51, 67, 7072
Peirce, Leslie 78 n. 5
Petition (to court) 109, 132, 150, 157,
168
Peter the Great 38, 39
Phanariote 46
Pilgrims (on Haj) 32, 6263, 84, 90
Pinto, Karen 34 n. 10
Poland 15, 22, 23, 37, 45, 46, 74,
181
Porter, James 126
Portugal 43
Property 1921, 9298, 103


Provincial Administration 818,
2330, 5460. See also Voyvoda and
Governorship
Princess 75, 8788, 104, 106, 111
Privatization 11
Ptolemy 33
Qajars 22, 38, 182
Qizilbash 28, 47
Ragb Pasha 95
Rakka (Urfa) 67
Ra{id Efendi 9697
Rebellion 96, 102, 171
Ranke, Leopold von 7
Reaya 26. See also Peasants
Red Sea 40
Renan, Ernst 178, 195
Revolution, French 6, 9, 14, 16
n. 41, 19799
Rical-i Devlet 11, 26, 76, 97, 99,
109, 18687. See also Aristocracy of
Service
Roman Empire 31
Rumeli 33
Rusuk 185
Russia 22, 3844, 45, 46, 6263, 68,
7174, 83, 110, 119, 180186, 196,
197
Safavid 22, 32, 3742, 51, 61, 68, 182
Said, Edward 28 n. 73
Salonika 62, 90
Saray. See Palace
Sarraf. See Financier
Scot, James 29 n. 76
Selim III 14, 18286
Sened-i (ttifak 18687
Sha"i (legal school) 149
Shaykh, tribal 132, 135; of guilds
or esnaf 1589. See also Ustad
Siberia 68
Silk trade 6162
Silver 6869
Srr Selim Pasha 100
Sivas 53
Siyakat 81, 122
South Africa 178
Sovereignty 13, 19, 24, 28, 4244,
47, 52, 7073, 181, 182; popular
19495
Spain 43
State, denition of early-modern 25, 83
Stiglitz, Joseph 19

239

Sub-contracting (or sub-farming) 136,


138, 145, 146, 156, 158, 166, 172
Sublime Porte 12, 18, 29, 7892
Su Orders 90, 91, 149, 151
Sleyman I 14
Sumptuary Codes 92
Surat 72
Surnme-i Vehbi 75, 120
Sweden 40
Syria 134, 139, 169, 174
}ahiner, Araks 109 n. 142
}anizde, Ataullah Mehmet 192
}emdni-zde Fndkl Sleyman Efendi
114
}ehrizor 60
}eyhzde Ibrahim 165, 167, 189193
}eyhzde Ismail 165170
}eyh"l-(slam 91, 99, 10405, 11516
Tabriz 71, 78
Tahmasp II 41
Tari ( gmrk) 3, 38, 6465, 90, 109,
111, 114, 151, 155, 156, 159162, 190
Tanzimat 179, 189, 194
Tapu 144
Tatarck Abdullah Efendi 182
Taxation, avarz and bedel-i nzl 84;
cizye 85; coee 85; history of 52,
60, 8192; tobacco 85, 1457. See
also tari and damga
Tax Farming 1011, 15, 2021, 56,
106115; comparative 17 n. 44.
See also Iltizam and Malikne
Territorial scale 2223
Thieck, Jean-Pierre 10, 18
Thompson, Elizabeth 109
Tibet 34
Tiis 41
Tigris 50
Tilly, Charles 5 n. 6, 15 n. 37, 17
n. 44, 21 n. 56, 104 n. 122
Timar 28, 5457, 71, 84, 87, 128,
13337, 143, 144, 175, 175, 184
Timur Bey (Milan Kurds) 135
Tipu Sultan 181
Tocqueville, Alexis de 130, 17680,
187, 19598
Tokat 29 n. 75
Trabzon 65, 192
Trade 6267
Treasury (hazine) 4, 57, 61, 69, 73,
7991, 8486, 114, 121, 183.
See also New Order Treasury

240

Treasurer (defterdar efendi) 7782


Tribes, (Central Asian) a[atay 35;
Kalmyk 39; (Ottoman) 'Anaza 67;
Ka"b 67; Khaza"il 67; Kiki 000;
Kurdish 5152; Milan 125,
1313, 139 n. 52, 169; Munaq
67; Trkmen 35, 132; Tayy 132
Transylvania 45
Treaty, of Belgrade 40, 48, 62; of
Karlowitz 38, 44, 47; of Kk
Kaynarca 47, 72; of Kurdan 73;
of Nantes 47; of Paris 73; of
Tordesilla 43; of Utrecht 37, 73;
of Vienna 197; of Westphalia 44,
73; of Zuhab 28
Turan (zemin) 34
Tripoli (Syria) 95
Tucker, Ernest 73
Ulema 26, 28, 29, 56, 77, 9092,
98, 103, 104, 105, 107, 116, 117,
119, 153, 154, 163, 168, 171, 174;
as tax farmers 143, 14950
Ukraine 45
United States 177, 187, 188, 195
Urfa (Rakka) 100
Uzbek 35, 39
Vehbi Hseyin Efendi 75, 81, 120
Vassals (Ottoman) 45. See also Black
Sea and Crimea

Vatican 6, 41, 42 n. 30, 177,


197
Vienna 38
Voltaire 14, 178, 179
Voyvoda, of Diyarbekir 125, 128,
135, 138, 1413, 16570; of
ermik 141; of Mardin 134; of
Tokat 175
Voyvodalk, of Diyarbekir 91, 128,
135, 13841, 143, 148, 154,
16768, 172, 175
Wallachia 45, 72, 181
Waldner, David 5 n. 6
Waqf 28, 8990, 116, 190,
War, of the Holy League 87; of the
Iranian Sucession 22, 37, 47, 59,
74, 192; Seven Years 74
West Asia 3, 22, 37, 39, 30,
3840, 49, 50, 53, 59, 61, 71,
87
White, Jenny 26 n. 66
Yemen 19, 49
Yerevan (Revan) 51
Ylmazelik, (brahim 12
Yusuf Ziya Pasha 138, 169
Zagros Mountains 129
Zarinebaf-Shahr, Fariba 38 n. 17
Zil, Madeline 99 n. 99

You might also like