A Critique of The Recession of 1920
A Critique of The Recession of 1920
A Critique of The Recession of 1920
1920-21
Today the United States finds itself in one of the longest and deepest recessions in
its history. Many have blamed deregulation, greed and a naive ideological adherence to
free market capitalism for our current woes. As such, the US has embarked on a course
of policies largely Keynesian in nature, including deficit spending, public works projects
and a variety of policies revolving generally around increasing demand and lessening the
blows of the deleveraging private sector. In many ways, this era has paralleled that of the
Depression, with President Obama playing FDR and George W. Bush playing Hoover.
Popular refrains in contemporary America include “We are all Keynesians now,”
and “There are no libertarians in financial crises.” With Keynesian nostrums en vogue,
the liberal economic schools appear to have grown obsolete. And on some levels this is
understandable, given that the Keynesian prescriptions for our maladies seem to reflect
common sense. If people are out of work, let the government gainfully employ them. If
the private sector is overlevered, counteract their delevering by levering up the public
sector. If banks are failing to generate credit, print money and force it into their coffers,
so that they lend and the economy can once again grow.
However, as Frédéric Bastiat, the sage 19th century French theorist, political
economist and assemblyman noted in his work That Which Is Seen, and That Which is
Not Seen, the prudent economist looks at the consequences of actions both intended and
unintended. This is analogized in the so-called “broken window fallacy,” in which a boy
throws a rock through a shopkeeper’s window. One observer argues that this is a
blessing because the glazier will now have work in installing a new window, stimulating
the economy. However, what he misses is the fact that had the window not been broken,
2
the shopkeeper would have perhaps used the money now being paid to the glazier to buy
a new set of shoes, employing the shoesmith, or a book, increasing his knowledge
(Bastiat, 1-4). There are other considerations as well. What if the boy is employed by
the glazier to break windows? Then this act would be regarded as theft, not stimulus.
Finally, if it is economically beneficial to break one window, why not break all windows
everywhere? Extending the analogy, classical liberals argue that government represents
the boy throwing the rock through the window, causing unintended, damaging
consequences in its economic intervention, and distributing wealth from one class to
another, never creating it. It is under Bastiat’s essential insights that we will proceed.
Herein I will first develop the theoretical underpinnings to our study, in giving an
elementary summation of what a free market entails, introducing to it a central bank and
then giving a brief overview of the results of central banking under the Austrian theory of
the business cycle. Next, I will analyze within this framework the Recession of 1920-21,
the conditions it created and the policy prescriptions applied to it for economic
correction. Upon explaining how we exited from the deep recession, I will enumerate the
insights from a political economy perspective that this historical episode provides us.
Finally, I would be remiss in not briefly divulging why I chose to study the
Recession of 1920-21. This was a particularly brutal recession not unlike the one we are
which made me as a contrarian naturally curious. This was in fact the last recession in
which US representatives administered what I would come to discover were their age-old
3
self-correct. I contend that these antidotes were as proper in the early 1920s as they are
today.
Before intervening in the paradigm of free market capitalism with the introduction
of a central bank, we must ask what the characteristics of a free economy entail.
According to Adam Smith, capitalism has as its root the defining feature that it is based
on self-interest. After all, it “is not from the benevolence of the butcher, the brewer, or
the baker that we expect our dinner” (“The Wealth of Nations by Adam Smith: Chapter
network of free and voluntary exchanges in which producers work, produce, and
exchange their products for the products of others through prices voluntarily arrived at”
definition that encompasses both the economic and political aspects of a capitalist
system:
the good life as they subjectively define it. People work, and exchange the fruits of their
labor for goods, services or more abstract wants in mutually beneficial trade. The liberty
4
to do so is protected by a government that ideally serves as a referee, preventing us
against aggression such as fraud, theft and the like by others and by government itself,
The US today is of course far removed from this type of system. Even back in the
go-go 1920s, the country had started to shed the yoke of laissez-faire due to the
introduction of the Federal Reserve, imposition of the income tax, and the creation of
our study is the creation of the Federal Reserve in 1913, as it is essential to the business
cycle. Throughout US history, there had been a variety of central banks, all of which had
failed due to artificially expanding the supply of money and credit on top of gold, or
through setting the gold-silver ratio improperly (Rothbard 2005, 45-179). The Federal
Reserve however was by far the most powerful, and in this author’s view, dangerous
institution shrouded in mystery. I would like to demystify this however for our
undertaking. The Fed is a lender of last resort that effectively cartelizes the major US
banking houses. It is the banker’s bank. Its board members are granted a monopoly over
the money supply of the American people, as they set the interest rate through open
market operations. In this way, the Fed is anathema to the free market, as it represents a
government monopoly over the commodity of money (though the bank is nominally
quasi-private), in its sole right to coin and regulate its value. Today, unconstrained by a
gold standard, the Fed has the power to create paper money out of thin air as it sees fit.
5
In earlier centuries in Europe, money had been privately coined. However, as
government’s grew, central banking supplanted the private money system, nominally
with the intention of ensuring a more “elastic” monetary system theoretically to prevent
downturns such as those of the Panic of 1907 (Rothbard 2005, 40). The fundamental
point as we will see is that though in 1920, government played a much smaller role in the
economy than it would during the Depression and in modern-day America, the Federal
business cycle. Murray Rothbard lays out the perpetual peril that has inflicted man
The Austrian Theory of the Business Cycle explains how businessmen invariably come to
make the cluster of error characteristic of the boom-and-bust cycle. To expound upon
this theory, we will examine the free capital market, and then the effects of introducing a
central bank, the Austrians’ main culprit in causing the chronic economic ups and downs.
6
In a free market, individuals earn money and choose to consume some of it and
invest the rest of it, according to their so-called “time preference.” During certain times
in life, individuals will want to consume much while saving little, while at other times
they will choose to forego current consumption and save so that they can consume more
later. Saved or invested money represents the capital stock that can be loaned out to
upon the supply of and demand for funds will dictate the interest rate of the economy
(Garrison, 64).
The interest rate is a price just like any other that serves as a signal to businesses
and consumers. Lower interest rates will indicate that the capital available for investment
in projects is large; people are willing to forego consumption now to reap greater benefits
down the road, leading businesses to undertake longer-term projects. Higher interest
rates will indicate that the capital available for investment is small; people are willing to
forego future goods to consume the fruits of their labor now, leading businesses to
undertake shorter-term projects (“The Forgotten Depression of 1920”). The interest rate
7
(“An Austrian Theory of the Business Cycle”)
The horizontal base of the triangle represents the element of time in economic
development, required for things such as R&D, commodity extraction, etc. The vertical
legs represent the value of the different inputs created in the steps towards producing the
final output, with the last leg representing the value of the completed good. The slope of
the triangle represents the interest rate. The length and height of the triangle will change
in response to changing time preferences amongst consumers, altering the interest rate
The structure of production coordinates the time preferences of all people across
the economy. In this way, the demands of the consumers direct the supply of producers,
Roger Garrison notes, “the natural rate guides the economy along a sustainable growth
path. That is, governed by the natural rate, unconsumed current output (real saving) is
used for augmenting the economy’s productive capacity in ways that are consistent with
and busts. Surely certain assets might boom in price whilst others might bust based upon
the desires of consumers, but the sole effect would be the changing values of goods
relative to each other; the rise in the prices of some assets would lead to an offsetting fall
in the prices of others. In addition, in this theoretical economy, there would still be
8
business failure. After all, man is fallible, and competition will always yield winners and
losers. But capital markets governed by natural interest rates would ensure that most if
not all businesses in a particular sector or in the economy as a whole would not
artificially boom and bust together. Entrepreneurs would avoid the cluster of error
because the price signal of the interest rate dictated solely by the market would lead them
However, when the Federal Reserve is empowered to control the money supply,
the capital base that had been governed by the market is thrown into disequilibrium.
Below we show an economy in which the market for loanable funds is in equilibrium –
i.e. where the supply of and demand for capital, and thus the interest rate is freely set by
9
The intersection of supply and demand meets the optimal point on the production
consumers. A Federal Reserve that can set the interest rate however will invariably be
unable to choose this market rate of interest, thus throwing an economy off of the PPF.
No individual or group of economists can centrally plan an interest rate, just as no central
planner can set the price properly for any good. It is a problem of economic calculation,
dynamically change, whose effect can only be borne out through infinite transactions by
market participants. Central planners are also not subject to the market, where their
caveat is that that central planners do compete against other central planners in foreign
exchange markets, though the US today holds the upper hand by default as manager of
the world’s reserve currency. One might ask in general why we want governments
dictating the value of our money in the first place, and though this is for another paper,
certainly our study will fan the flames of this question. In any event, central planners will
generally choose to set an interest rate low to induce businesses to increase their
investments in projects and thus spur economic growth. Below we see what happens
10
(“Capital-Based Macroeconomics,” 42)
The effect of the pumping of money and credit into the capital markets is
economic disequilibrium. On the one hand, low interest rates signal to businesses that
they should invest in long-term projects. On the other, low interest rates incentivize
people to borrow and spend more. As one can see, the effect is that this new artificially
low interest rate pushes the economy off of the PPF. The mismatch between the
consumers increasing their spending and businesses increasing their investment due to
the artificial infusion of credit ultimately leads to a bust. Businesses will commence
projects they would not have undertaken were the interest rate to accurately reflect
consumer demands, and consumers will purchase more than they would have were the
interest rate to accurately reflect their desired trade-off between consumption and
investment. Put succinctly, the “intertemporal mismatch between earning and spending
patterns eventually turns boom into bust” (“The Austrian Theory of the Business Cycle”).
And again, this is because there is an artificial increase in the pool of capital; the lesson is
11
that the only way to truly stimulate investment is to build the pool of capital through a
real increase in saving. It is also worthy of note that the system of fractional reserve
banking whereby deposits nominally supposed to be warehoused by banks are lent out to
other institutions and pyramided upon facilitates the process of creating additional money
This overall process is well analogized in Ludwig von Mises’s magnum opus,
masterbuilder of a house who runs out of bricks before the house can be completed.
Since he assumes there will be more loanable funds and free resources than there actually
are to complete a bigger house than he would have constructed had the interest rate
unsustainable project, making society poorer. To heal these wounds, when all the
masterbuilders err because of government creation of money and credit, society must
endure a recession to properly adjust the interest rate structure and reallocate the
discussion on the recession of 1920-21, we will see the above scenario played out, with
The US economy found itself at the edge of the abyss in 1920. As economist
Benjamin Anderson put it, the situation “was shot through with abnormalities, stresses
and strains. The movement was in almost every case away from equilibrium” (Anderson,
economic disruptions created by World War I. In war, we see a heavy emphasis placed
12
upon natural resources and labor, necessary allocation of money to heavy industrial
sectors and major government intervention in an economy in order to finance and direct
Before looking at the other causes of the economic struggle that the US would
find itself in between 1920 and 1921, we should note that war is another example of the
productive. Many attribute our exit from the Great Depression itself to war. Yet war is a
time in which the government, like the boy, effectively throws rocks through many
windows, except the rocks represent the use of far more valuable commodities. In war,
productive at the aggregate level, but rather shifts resources from some industries towards
others, such as heavy industry and technology. It does so on the basis of governmental
planning, with the economy ceasing to function on the basis of consumer demand and
free enterprise. War is beneficial to the extent that it employs people, and it may
living following the war (Murphy, 145-64). This criticism is not to condemn all war, as I
certainly believe there are situations in which war is merited, regardless of economic
wrongheaded and dangerous fallacy. Otherwise, why not destroy the infrastructure of our
own country so we can employ everyone to rebuild it? The effects of war are the same as
the effects of central banking – due to government intervention, the economy is thrown
out of balance, with unsustainable artificial booms in certain industries that will bust in
economic adjustment.
13
Distortive as the war effort was for the economy, many have argued that it was
the Fed that caused the painful boom-and-bust cycle that led to the Recession of 1920-21.
Paraphrasing the words of former National City Bank President Frank Vanderlip, a
“the Federal Reserve system opened the door to the inflation of the
country’s credit and asserted that the “brake” against inflation provided for
in the act had not been used because of political considerations…the
Treasury…kept rates low and opened up the door to great expansion. The
treasury…took a circumscribed view of the financial situation…for the
purpose of enabling the Government to borrow at an advantage…[and]
failed to understand the consequences of such a policy…Because of
inflation…prices since 1914 have shown an advance of 234 per cent, with
the result that the Dollar will purchase but 43 cents worth of its value in
1914…In the war period the currency had increased 68 per cent…while
the deposits in commercial banks increased 103 per cent, but there was no
substantial increase in production (“Vanderlip Attacks Federal Reserve”).
Princeton economist E.W. Kemmerer calculated that from 1913 to 1919, money in
circulation increased 71 percent while the physical volume of business increased by 9.6
percent (9-14). Indeed, it is no wonder that Woodrow Wilson under whom the Federal
Kemmerer attributes this inflation in the money supply to both the large inflow of
gold from Europe during the war in exchange for materials we shipped overseas, and the
14
fact that the Federal Reserve withdrew gold certificates and coin from circulation,
substituting for it Federal Reserve notes backed by a gold reserve of only 40 percent. On
the former point, four major factors triggered the gold expansion: bankers seeking profits,
bankers wanting to patriotically support the nation, and Government desiring to finance
itself with minimal disturbance to business and at a low rate of interest (Kemmer, 14-18).
On the latter, while in 1913, Federal Reserve notes in circulation were non-existent, by
1919 its notes numbered $2.8 billion, roughly $1.5 billion of which was uncovered by
gold. Legal reserve requirements for banks were significantly reduced, with national
banks in reserve cities required to hold 25% worth of their deposits in reserve, while so-
called country backs only had to keep 15% on reserve, 3/5th of which had to be held by
national banks. Time deposits were subject to even lower reserve rates. Overall, these
policies pushed interest rates artificially low. Kemmerer gleans a fundamental insight
from our situation directly in line with the Austrian theory we spoke to earlier:
We bought our low interest rates on government paper at the price of very
high prices for commodities. We kept interest rates down by a policy that
kept pushing the price level up. The fundamental economic law which
makes the interest rate the resultant of the interaction of the forces of
demand and supply in the capital market was forcing up the real interest
rate under the influences of a world wide destruction of capital and an
unprecedented demand. “Present goods were at a large and ever-
increasing premium over future goods.” The fundamental economic law
determining the real interest rate could not be annulled by the policy of
the federal reserve board of artificially depressing the market rate of
discount through inflating the country’s supply of bank notes and deposit
currency. When the discount rate was artificially pushed down prices
bulged up (24-5).
It is to this that we can attribute the great increases in prices of all goods that we will
speak to shortly, as Kemmerer notes that without the monetary inflation, while
commodity prices would have risen due to increased demand, this would have been offset
15
by falling prices in other goods (33). With a constant monetary stock, again all that
would change would be the proportions of the values of goods relative to each other
Indeed in the years preceding the recession, interest rates had been kept artificially
principal cause in the price inflation. As Hollander states, “additional credit was created
in the course of Government expenditure, found its way into individual accounts and
tended to swell the amount of deposit currency over and above the amount of currency”
(Hollander, 62).
inflation of the supply of money and credit. Anderson considers the fundamental
problem of inflated prices (which I will describe shortly) in the US economy to shortages
in a variety of resources due to a too-great trade balance that had been run up for five and
a half years prior to 1920. Anderson argues that the impetus behind this problem was
that the one-sided export trade was “financed by the government…[and] going on the
basis of unfunded credits” (1979, 71). In addition, following the war, trends in our gold
supply reversed: “despite our tremendous export balance of trade we were losing gold
heavily...We had an export balance with Europe only, and we could not draw on Europe
for payments to the non-European world to pay for our import surplus from them” (1979,
74). Nevertheless, Anderson notes that “the handling of the Federal Reserve rediscount
rate permitted the expansion to move faster and go further than would otherwise have
16
been the case,” as during 1919 the rate was held at 4 percent while money market interest
rates steadily increased (1979, 71). Ultimately, the major outgrowth of these problems of
finance was a 25.4 percent increase in loans and investments of Federal Reserve member
Anderson attributes other problems directly to the war. He recounts that war led to
trade. Anderson also notes that given wartime suspension of antitrust law accompanied
by price-fixing, rationing and allocation, many prices remained fixed following the
armistice (Anderson 1979, 62). He further argues that the five million men who
withdrew from the Army and Navy after the armistice were poorly absorbed into the
economy, as reflected in decreased production between 1918 and 1919 (Anderson 1921,
3-37). Thus, Anderson sums the situation leading to shortages of goods and higher prices
as follows: “The net result of diminished production, increased exports over imports, and
markedly greater at the present moment than they were at the time of the armistice”
(Anderson 1949, 64). We might note that people may have spent extravagantly given
that interest rates were artificially low. As Anderson argues, “it was not until the end of
1919 that artificially low rediscount rates were discontinued.” These rates at the least
businessmen to borrow money which they otherwise would not have borrowed for the
17
Persons noted that: “High taxes were a factor contributing to insolvency when prices
turned downward. The rates of surtax levied upon large incomes have been so heavy as
bonds” (18-19).
Though as we have noted, government increased the supply of money and credit,
liquidation of bank credit amongst businesses, borrowing rates eased and between 1919
and 1920 there was one last temporary post-war boom (Anderson 1949, 61). Anderson
notes:
From many causes, then, costs of production rose with startling rapidity
during the second half of 1919 and the first half of 1920: (a) labor costs
rose; (b) Interest Rates and Money Rates rose; (c) rentals rose; (d) Raw
materials rose; (e) Railroad congestion made for a vicious increase in
costs, even though railroad rates did not rise; (f) Coal rose; and (g)
Declining managerial efficiency led to rapidly rising costs. As costs rose,
businesses which were unable to advance their prices faced declining and
vanishing profits, and this was true even of businesses whose prices were
rising but whose prices were rising less rapidly than their costs. With the
decline in profits in a sufficiently large number of important businesses, a
boom must come to an end. Credits are based on earnings power. As
earning power diminishes creditors get nervous and begin to press for
collection, liquidation is forced, and reaction and crisis come” (1921, 11).
Anderson notes in the Chase Economic Bulletin that “It was very difficult for men to fail
in a period of rapidly rising prices, and a good many inefficient business men who would
normally have been weeded out by the severe process of competition, was able to
It is clear that government intervention in our economy threw the system out of
equilibrium. Land, labor and capital were diverted to fight the war, government
intervened to artificially keep its borrowing costs low to finance the war and imposed
18
regulations and levied taxes to coordinate and fund war efforts, and perhaps most
credit before, during and after wartime. It is tough to attribute the recession primarily to
one factor, but clearly the recession occurred when the illusory boom and concomitant
inflation in prices stopped and reversed. War is a major factor in this equation, but the
massive increase in money and credit over time at the very least amplified the boom-bust
cycle.
The results of the misaligned economy, distorted for years by poor monetary
policy and war were staggering. By late 1919, the CPI was running at 20 percent. The
unemployment rate between 1920 and 1921 grew over 100 percent, from 5.2 to 11.7
percent. Between 1920 and 1921, production fell by a staggering 21 percent. From their
peak in June 1920, prices fell by 15.8 percent, a 50 percent greater deflation in prices
than during any 12-month period during the Great Depression. Commodity prices were
especially hard hit, collapsing by over 100 percent in a single year, and putting many a
farmer out of business (Anderson 1949, 87-8). Wholesale prices fell from a level of 248
to 141 by measure of the BLS index. “Credit policy came to be centered on the question
primarily with profits and came to be concerned primarily with solvency (Anderson
19
(“The Crisis of 1920 in the United States: A Quantitative Survey”)
Deep as the downturn of 1920-21 was, and imbalanced and distorted as the
economy may have been as a result of the factors mentioned heretofore, today we hear
nary a mention of this recession. Given the rapidity of the collapse in prices and increase
in unemployment, this is hard to fathom. Part of the reason undoubtedly is the fact that
the recession passed quite quickly, as by 1922 the US returned to a path of staggering
prosperity. The natural question that we have to ask ourselves as we sit in the US today
tremendous collapse in housing prices amongst those of other assets is, how did we
20
Economists during the recession seem to be rather consistent in their appraisal of
what was needed fix the American economy. A.C. Miller, a member of the Federal
“There can be little question of what form the correction should take.
Where there has been inflation there must follow deflation, as a
necessary condition to the restoration of economic health. Contraction of
bank deposits and currency, through the liquidation of war loan accounts,
is clearly indicated as the next and necessary step in the process of
bringing the credit currency and price situation back to normal. Those who
in our liberty loan campaigns were persuaded to borrow and buy must now
be made to save and pay. “Save and pay up” should henceforth be our
slogan. The problem of correcting a state of banking inflation is mainly a
problem in saving. We must either put more goods behind the outstanding
volume of credit and currency-that means production-or we must reduce
the volume of credit and currency to suitable proportions-that means
saving (Miller, 318).
Chase National Bank economist Benjamin Anderson concurred, arguing that the
industries and the readjustment of the price system (Anderson 1921, 28).
specifically for those such as debtors, claimed that deflation would be a favorable policy
because “our present gold base is altogether inadequate safely to support the present
paper money and deposit currency circulation,” and “that inflation’s work has not yet
been completed and…therefore some of the otherwise evil results of our inflation
further argued generally that the Federal Reserve rate should be set above the market rate
following Bagehot’s dictum that a central bank should lend freely but at a punitive rate of
interest against sound collateral in a time of panic (Anderson 72, Bagehot, 56-7). Jacob
21
Hollander, professor of Political Economy at Johns Hopkins University acknowledged
that though economically efficacious, deflation would prove politically perilous, noting:
These words are probably even truer today, as certainly Paul Volcker can attest.
Most important however were the words and actions of the President who
inherited the post-war recession, Warren Harding. Harding, though not considered the
most eloquent President in the annals of American political rhetoric outlined his policy
Gross expansion of currency and credit have depreciated the dollar just as
expansion and inflation have discredited the coins of the world. We
inflate it in haste, we must deflate in deliberation. We debase the dollar in
reckless finance, we must restore in honesty. Deflation on the one hand
and restoration of the 100 cent dollar on the other ought to have begun the
day after the armistice, but plans were lacking or courage failed…We will
attempt intelligent and courageous deflation, and strike at government
borrowing which enlarges the evil, and we will attack high cost of
government with every energy and facility which attend republican
capacity. We promise that relief which will attend the halting of waste
and extravagance and the renewal of the practice of public economy not
alone because it will relieve tax burdens but because it will be an example
to stimulate thrift and economy in private life…There hasn’t been a
recovery from the waste and abnormalities of war since the story of
mankind was first written except through work and saving, through
industry and denial, while needless spending and heedless extravagance
have marked every decay in the history of nations…(“Speech accepting
the Republican nomination”).
22
and courage. Our people must give and take. Prices must reflect the
receding fever of war activities. Perhaps we never shall know the old
levels of wages again, because war invariably readjusts compensations,
and the necessaries of life will show their inseparable relationship, but we
must strive for normalcy to reach stability. All the penalties will not be
light, nor evenly distributed. There is no way of making them so. There is
no instant step from disorder to order. We must face a condition of grim
reality, charge off our losses and start afresh. It is the oldest lesson of
civilization (“Inaugural Address”).
It is simply unfathomable that a politician today would have the intestinal fortitude to
utter words as stark yet truthful as those uttered by Warren Harding in 1920. Even more
shocking, Harding was a politician whose candor was met with concordant action.
Harding understood that in order for the economy to properly adjust to prewar
conditions, prices needed to fall from their inflated levels, and rebalance in accord with
demand as dictated by the consumer. Thus, as economist Robert Murphy notes in his
…the (New York) Fed hiked its discount rate from 4.75 percent up to 6
percent in one fell swoop in January 1920. The Fed then hiked again to a
record-high 7 percent in June 1920. Despite the fairly severe depression—
recall that unemployment averaged 11.7 percent in 1921—the Fed held
steady to its record-high rate for almost a full year, not cutting until May
1921, after the depression was basically over (78-9).
Raising interest rates naturally had the effect of forcing companies that had survived due
to artificially cheap credit to become insolvent and enter bankruptcy, where businessmen
would discern the value of the assets of the failed enterprise, purchase them and put them
to more profitable lines of use. This economic restructuring is essential for economic
progress. As Don Boudreaux argues regarding our modern-day auto companies, “The
bigger the unprofitable firm, the more vital it is that it be allowed to fail” (“Bankruptcy
23
Second, as Harding understood that cutting down the size of government would
put more money back in the hands of businesses and households, as illustrated below, he
slashed the Federal budget, retreating significantly from the persistently high spending
levels of wartime:
This reflected Harding’s belief that the government’s role in the private economy should
be diminished in order for the nation’s economy to return to growth and prosperity.
Harding was fiscally conservative in both the short and long-term, as reflected in the
figures below:
Though Harding significantly slashed the budget, tax receipts outweighed expenditures
during and after the recession, allowing him to pay down a fairly significant part of the
national debt given the limited timeframe. During his presidency, Harding would also
reduce income tax rates across the board, with the highest tax rate falling from 73% in
1921 to 25% by 1925 under the care of Treasury Secretary Andrew Mellon (Murphy, 22).
24
to business was to reduce as much as possible the amount of government
expenditure, which had risen to great heights during the war; to reduce
taxes—but not much; and to reduce public debt.
Nor did the government increase public employment with a view to taking
up idle labor. There was a reduction in the army and navy in the course of
these years, and there was a steady decline in the number of civilian
employees of the federal government. This policy on the part of the
government generated, of course, a great confidence in the credit of the
government, and the strength of the gold dollar was taken for granted.
The credit of the government and confidence in the currency are basic
foundations for general business confidence. The relief to business
through reduced taxes was extremely helpful (1949, 92-3).
Overall, Anderson feels that the best example of the efficacy of Harding’s policies
is shown by way of comparison between the US and Japan during the 1920s. He notes:
The great banks, the concentrated industries, and the government got
together, destroyed the freedom of the markets, arrested the decline of
commodity markets, and held the Japanese price level high above the
receding level of the last 7 years. During these years, Japan endured
chronic industrial stagnation and at the end in 1927, she had a banking
crisis of such severity that many great branch bank systems went down, as
well as many industries. It was a stupid policy. In the effort to avert
losses on inventory representing one year’s production, Japan lost 7 years.
The US was different, we took our losses, we readjusted our financial
structure, we endured our depression and in August 1921 we started up
again. The rally in business production and employment that started in
August 1921 was soundly based on a drastic cleaning up of credit
weakness, a drastic reduction in the costs of production, and on the free
play of private enterprise. It was not based on governmental policy
designed to make business good (1949, 88).
Harding understood that only in allowing the economy to properly restructure could
prices of goods and wages for labor return to equilibrium. For the inflation in money and
thus prices, and the boom in illusory industry, the economy needed to correct itself with
the equal and opposite reaction of deflation in money and thus prices, and the bust in
illusory industry. The policies that contributed to falling prices and the liquidation of
25
earlier, but this temporary pain was deemed a necessary evil that would quickly return
In closing this chapter, I’d like to note that there is great irony in Anderson’s
analysis when one considers Japan’s lost decade, and the fact that the US today is
following many of the same policies the Japanese took both in the early 20th century and
over the last two decades (“The Cause of Japan’s Boom and the Reasons for Its
Prolonged Bust”). More important is our recognition of the contrast in policy between
Harding and every President since. Harding argued that in times of distress, the size of
government must be cut back just as the household cuts back, saving must be encouraged
and so interest rates must be tightened, and the resultant necessary but painful liquidation
of enterprises and fall in prices must occur so as to foster a new period of economic
growth, or as Harding would put it, “a return to normalcy.” Of course given the
dominant Keynesian philosophy in dealing with downturns today, for a politician to take
Throughout history while the world has evolved, man at root has remained the
same. One of our greatest failures as humans is our inability to learn from the past. In
the case of economic history, I attribute our lack of proper understanding to at best
miseducation, and at worst ignorance, the results of which are particularly harmful. The
acted in a way completely contrary to that of any financial crisis since. The results were
that we sustained a harsh but quick restructuring of our economy, and came out the other
side poised for a period of tremendous economic growth and prosperity. Yet who has
26
ever learned of this lesson in a textbook? Where are the mainstream economists and
pain? Are the rules of recession different now than they were throughout the history of
mankind?
Taken in a vacuum, one might be able to say that the Recession of 1920-21 is but
one mere example of a policy by happenstance working. However, if we look back at the
American experience in all previous recessions, every crisis was met with the same
artificial expansion of money and credit, albeit mitigated by a gold standard, the country
experienced astounding industrial growth and gently falling prices along with a
strengthening dollar, rewarding the American people with an increased living standard
and ascendant position in the world (Rothbard 2000, 5-179). The specifics of downturns
may differ – the 1920-21 crisis was not a subprime one, nor were their trillions of dollars
in derivatives being traded around the world, nor was there a Fannie Mae or Freddie Mac
or any of the thousands of other regulations, bureaucracies, interest groups and other
political influences as in contemporary America, nor was the US a net debtor nation. But
there clearly was great government intervention given the massive imbalances created by
our monetary policy and war. But we survived, adjusted and flourished. Dare I say if we
had continued to follow the policies of letting markets adjust, encouraging the
problems caused by government intervention in the first place, eliminating the moral
hazard that characterizes markets today, we might be all the stronger for it.
27
Moreover, in the early 20th century there was a commitment to certain principles
that the US, along with all great powers historically have lost. Saving and thrift are to be
favored to consumption and profligacy. A prosperous nation must produce more than it
consumes. Wealth emanates from the producers, entrepreneurs and the people, under the
invisible hand of the market, not from enlightened central planners. In times of economic
struggle, governments just as people must tighten their belts. Most important is the
notion that the proper role of government is to protect the life, liberty and property of the
people. We have forgotten these very principles that built our nation to its (fast-
crumbling) hegemonic position. It seems to me that this is the price of success. With
wealth and splendor we forget the toil and sacrifice that was needed to achieve them.
With the growth of the welfare state and the intrusion of government into all sorts
of spheres that in my view our Founders could have never imagined, we have squandered
the fruits of the labors of our forefathers. Adding to our struggles are the policies during
our current depression of continued regulations, bailouts and spending programs intended
to stop our economy from readjusting. I am not without compassion for those hurt by
downturns. It is the moral duty of each of us to judge if and how we should help out our
current depression policies is both immoral and economically harmful. Its costs far
outweigh its benefits over the long run. These policies will merely indebt our children
and our children’s children, prolong the downturn and further endanger our position as
the leading world power. Governmental action will not solve crises but perpetuate new
ones down the road that will only lead to more intervention and a greater tie of the state
to society.
28
There is however a beneficial role that our leaders can play in helping our country
back on its feet. Murray Rothbard in his America’s Great Depression puts it better than I
could:
I fear that it will take a great many hardships before this lesson is learned. Fortunately,
history tells us that out of crisis comes great opportunity. With this downturn has come
the opportunity for lovers of liberty to educate people on historical episodes such as the
Recession of 1920-21 that bring out fundamentally important insights. Armed with
historical understanding, an actively engaged public will be able to effectuate the change
dangerous to usurpers of liberty, and it is only a knowledgeable populace that can restore
the Republic to its rightful place as the last, best hope of man on Earth.
29
Works Cited
Anderson, Benjamin M. Economics and the Public Welfare: A Financial and Economic
History of the United States, 1914-1946. Indianapolis: LibertyPress, originally
1949.
Anderson, Benjamin M. “The Return to Normal.” Chase Economic Bulletin, Vol. 1, No.
3: 3-37. 28 February, 1921. Google Books. 1 December, 2009.
<http://books.google.com/books?id=iEfPAAAAMAAJ&lpg=PA1&ots=ywLjALb
Swk&dq=anderson%20chase%20economic%20bulletin&pg=RA1-
PA43#v=onepage&q=anderson%20chase%20economic%20bulletin&f=false>.
Bagehot, Walter. Lombard Street: A Description of the Money Market. New York:
Scribner, Armstrong & Co, 1877. Google Books. 10 December, 2009.
<http://books.google.com/books?id=EA8xAAAAMAAJ&dq=lombard%20street
%20a%20description%20of%20the%20money%20market&pg=PR3#v=onepage
&q=&f=false>.
Bastiat, Frédéric. The Bastiat Collection - Volume 1. Auburn: Ludwig von Mises
Institute, 2007.
Boudreaux, Don. “Bankruptcy Doesn’t Equal Death.” Wall Street Journal Online:
Opinion, 11 December, 2008. <
http://online.wsj.com/article/SB122895755096596653.html>.
Garrison, R.W. “Natural and Neutral Rates of Interest.” Quarterly Journal of Austrian
Economics, Winter 2006. <http://www.auburn.edu/~garriro/ppsus.htm>.
30
Harding, Warren G. “Inaugural Address.” 4 March, 1921. <
http://www.bartleby.com/124/pres46.html>.
Hollander, Jacob. “Fiat Credit and High Prices.” New York Times Online Archives. 29
October, 1919.
<http://query.nytimes.com/gst/abstract.html?res=9B03E3DC1138EE32A2575AC
2A9669D946896D6CF>.
Kemmerer, E.W. High Prices and Deflation. Princeton: Princeton University Press,
1920. Google Books. 10 December, 2009.
<http://books.google.com/books?id=at9AAAAAIAAJ&ots=tMVtIgulI3&dq=kem
mer%20high%20prices%20and%20deflation&pg=PP7#v=onepage&q=&f=false>
.
Miller, A.C. “After-War Readjustment: Rectifying the Price Situation.” The Annals of
the American Academy of Political and Social Science, Vol. 82: 306-322.
JSTOR. 1 December, 2009. <
http://www.jstor.org/page/termsConfirm.jsp?redirectUri=/stable/pdfplus/1014318.
pdf>.
Murphy, Robert. The Politically Incorrect Guide to the Great Depression and the New
Deal. Washington, D.C.: Regnery Publishing, 2009.
Paul, Ron. “End the Fed.” Excerpted from Chapter 2 of End the Fed (Grand Central
Publishing, 2009). Ludwig von Mises Institute. <http://mises.org/daily/3687>.
Persons, Warren M. “The Crisis of 1920 in the United States: A Quantitative Survey.”
The American Economic Review: Vol, XII, No. 1 Supplement: 5-19. March, 1922.
JSTOR. 1 December, 2009.
<http://www.jstor.org/page/termsConfirm.jsp?redirectUri=/stable/pdfplus/180539
8.pdf>.
Reisman, George. “The Myth that Laissez-Faire is Responsible for Our Financial
Crisis.” George Reisman's Blog on Economics, Politics, Society, and Culture. 21
October, 2008. <http://georgereisman.com/blog/2008_10_01_archive.html>.
31
Rothbard, Murray N. America’s Great Depression. Auburn: Ludwig von Mises Institute,
2000. Google Books. 1 December, 2009.
<http://books.google.com/books?id=RHINtHpq8p0C&lpg=PP1&dq=america's%2
0great%20depression%20rothbard&pg=PP1#v=onepage&q=&f=false>.
Rothbard, Murray N. A History of Money and Banking in the United States: The
Colonial Era to World War II. Auburn: Ludwig von Mises Institute, 2005.
“Vanderlip Attacks Federal Reserve.” New York Times Online Archives. 22 February,
1920: Editorial Page E1.
<http://query.nytimes.com/gst/abstract.html?res=9D04E2DC103BEE32A25751C
2A9649C946195D6CF>.
Weingarten, Benjamin. “The Cause of Japan’s Boom and the Reasons for Its Prolonged
Bust.” Mises Institute Working Papers. 28 December, 2009. <
http://mises.org/journals/scholar/weingarten.pdf>.
Wilson, Woodrow. The New Freedom. New York: Doubleday, Page & Company, 1918.
Google Books. 1 December, 2009.
<http://books.google.com/books?id=MW8SAAAAIAAJ&dq=wilson%20the%20
new%20freedom&pg=PP7#v=onepage&q=&f=false>.
Woods, Thomas E. “The Forgotten Depression of 1920.” Ludwig von Mises Institute
Online. Reproduced 27 November, 2009. < http://mises.org/daily/3788>.
32