Economic Modelling: António Afonso, Ana So Fia Nunes
Economic Modelling: António Afonso, Ana So Fia Nunes
Economic Modelling: António Afonso, Ana So Fia Nunes
Economic Modelling
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/ecmod
a r t i c l e
i n f o
Article history:
Accepted 11 March 2014
Available online 26 April 2014
JEL classication:
C23
E44
H68
Keywords:
Macro forecasts
Fiscal forecasts
Sovereign yields
a b s t r a c t
We assess whether the corrections made to the EC macro and scal forecasts (GDP growth rate, ination, budget
balance, debt ratio, current account) have an impact in sovereign yields. We perform a panel analysis of 15 EU
countries (Austria, Belgium, Germany, Denmark, Spain, Finland, France, United Kingdom, Greece, Ireland, Italy,
Luxembourg, Netherlands, Portugal and Sweden), for the period from 1999:1 until 2012:1, and we also analyse
each country individually, on the basis of a SUR estimation. We nd that corrections in the EC's forecasts impinge
on 10-year sovereign bond yields, particularly corrections in scal variables, being more pronounced in countries
with less favourable economic conditions. The penalization for the yields is higher in corrections for the current
and next years than for previous years.
2014 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
1. Introduction
Since 1998 the European Commission (EC) releases in a regular basis
twice a year, in the spring and in autumn, short-term economic forecasts for the member states of the Economic and Monetary Union
(EMU), candidate countries and other important economies, as the
United States, Japan and the United Kingdom.
Since the forecasts are publicly available, investors may use this
information to decide their investment portfolio, notably their investment in the sovereign bonds. Therefore, the release of these forecasts should, theoretically, have an impact on sovereign spreads.
Indeed, we may argue that rational investors use all the available information; thus, a release of new information will cause a rearrangement in their investment portfolio. However, it is not obvious that
this happens in reality.
Hence, we are interested in assessing what is the impact of releasing economic forecasts on the sovereign yields. If, as expected, the
impact on sovereign yields is signicant, the institutions which
The authors are grateful to an anonymous referee, to Patrcia Martins and to participants
at the UECE Conference on Economic and Financial Adjustments in Europe, Technical
University of Lisbon, 28 June 2013 for very useful comments. The opinions expressed herein
are those of the authors and do reect those of the ECB or the Eurosystem.
Corresponding author.
E-mail addresses: [email protected] (A. Afonso), [email protected]
(A.S. Nunes).
1
UECE is supported by Fundaco para a Cincia e a Tecnologia (Portuguese Foundation
for Science and Technology) through the project PEst-OE/EGE/UI0436/2011.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2014.03.012
0264-9993/ 2014 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
release these forecasts (EC, Organization for Economic and Cooperation Development (OECD), European Central Bank (ECB), and
others) and in particular the governments, want to be aware of the
consequences of forecast accuracy. That is particularly relevant
regarding forecasts for current and next years (the ones with most
obvious possible inuence), but also for past years, as there are
often corrections to past data.
Moreover, there is also an interest for private agents to know the impact of macro and scal forecasts, especially traders, as every anticipation of future movements in bond's prices may bring prot. Therefore,
knowing if and how the bond market reacts to the release of these forecasts is paramount.
The present research will try to provide an answer for this problem,
and it is a contribution to the literature since these linkages have not
been much explored, at least to our knowledge, after reading the
existing related literature. In fact, there are only a few studies for the
USA,2 and some were made 15 or more years ago.3 On the contrary,
there are numerous studies on sovereign spreads' determinants, on
forecasts' accuracy, and on the causes of forecast errors (notably,
Jonung and Martin, 2006; Martins and Mora, 2007; Merola and Prez,
2012; Moulin and Wierts, 2006).
2
3
320
321
1) they seem to be unbiased and efcient, either for the EU and for the
non-EU countries (Melander et al., 2007);
2) however, they appear to be correlated with the electoral cycles,
though less than those from the government, and do not include
all the available information, though they consider more information than governments (Merola and Prez, 2012).
Thus, according to the available empirical evidence, it appears
that independent agencies' forecasts are more reliable than governments', which might notably be linked to the fact that governments
have sometimes to accommodate the political cycle. Melander et al.
(2007) show that the forecasts for GDP, ination, current account
balance and public budgets are the most accurate ones, though not
totally correct. Indeed, the authors report that real growth and budget balance forecasts do not show persistent errors (the study covers
the 19701995 period).
In our analysis we will consider EC's forecasts, as they are part of the
basis of budgetary surveillance in the context of the application of the
Excessive Decits Procedure, and are considered more reliable than the
government's, being a major reference for investors, economists and
managers.
322
Table 1
Estimation results for 10-year yields: forecasts for year t.
IV
Ci,t
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
(8)
Yes
3.526***
(0.159)
Yes
3.494***
(0.166)
Yes
3.555***
(0.169)
Yes
3.662***
(0.177)
Yes
3.523***
(0.254)
0.398*
(0.210)
Yes
3.460***
(0.262)
0.409*
(0.222)
0.027
(0.037)
Yes
3.580***
(0.267)
0.442*
(0.228)
No
3.639***
(0.174)
BALi,t
CAi,t
DEBTi,t
INFi,t
REERi,t
YRi,t
Ii,t
VIXi,t
FRIi,t
R-square
N
Obs
Endogeneity
Hausman
0.135**
(0.062)
0.299
(0.206)
0.017
(0.027)
0.114
(0.088)
0.298***
(0.038)
0.003
(0.006)
0.020
(0.140)
0.357
15
303
0.396
0.005
0.132**
(0.066)
0.020
(0.028)
0.178
(0.112)
0.328***
(0.039)
0.002
(0.005)
0.084
(0.142)
0.329
15
303
0.493
0.003
0.019
(0.020)
0.077
(0.077)
0.150*
(0.078)
0.243
(0.189)
0.013
(0.026)
0.364
(0.246)
0.166
(0.207)
0.342***
(0.040)
0.011
(0.008)
0.189***
(0.054)
0.185
15
314
0.099
0.600
0.152*
(0.090)
0.314***
(0.039)
0.001
(0.007)
0.172***
(0.054)
0.097
15
349
0.204
0.539
0.194*
(0.108)
0.337***
(0.045)
0.001
(0.006)
0.164
(0.103)
0.057
15
349
0.802
0.763
0.031
(0.034)
0.157
(0.119)
0.352***
(0.049)
0.004
(0.006)
0.105
(0.099)
0.048
15
302
0.879
0.191
0.131
(0.099)
0.310***
(0.046)
0.001
(0.007)
0.129
(0.095)
0.077
15
349
0.794
0.825
0.111
(0.141)
0.041*
(0.022)
0.223***
(0.058)
0.007*
(0.003)
0.053
(0.112)
0.315
15
302
0.070
Note: the asterisks *, ** and *** represent signicance at 10, 5 and 1% level, respectively. The values present between parentheses are the standard error. IV indicates if instrumental
variables were used in the regression, N is the number of countries included in the sample, Obs is the number of observations, Endogeneity is the p-value obtained by performing the
WuHausman endogeneity test for YR, and Hausman is the p-value for the Hausman's random effect test.
to budget balance. The constant term, short-term interest rate and VIX
remain signicant, and VIX starts to appear as well.
Finally, in the case of forecasts for year t 2, none of the scal variables is signicant. We nd once more that the constant term, shortterm interest rate and FRI are signicant, as in all the tables above.
Moreover, in this case VIX is also signicant in all regressions, probably
because investors do not pay attention to corrections in forecasts of so
far back; thus, VIX gains signicance.
Table 2
Estimation results for 10-year yields: forecasts for year t + 1.
IV
Ci,t
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
(8)
Yes
3.581***
(0.207)
Yes
3.664***
(0.224)
Yes
3.633***
(0.203)
Yes
3.681***
(0.202)
Yes
3.881***
(0.378)
0.456*
(0.259)
Yes
3.843***
(0.405)
0.334*
(0.198)
0.061
(0.038)
Yes
3.795***
(0.314)
0.373*
(0.209)
No
3.629***
(0.166)
BALi,t + 1
CAi,t + 1
DEBTi,t + 1
INFi,t + 1
REERi,t
YRi,t + 1
Ii,t
VIXi,t
FRIi,t
R-square
N
T
Endogeneity
Hausman
0.099*
(0.053)
0.200
(0.164)
0.036
(0.029)
0.048
(0.101)
0.335***
(0.048)
0.011
(0.009)
0.006
(0.192)
0.302
15
303
0.945
0.001
0.085*
(0.052)
0.038
(0.031)
0.020
(0.106)
0.342***
(0.048)
0.011
(0.010)
0.173**
(0.069)
0.197
15
303
0.924
0.103
0.094*
(0.050)
0.190
(0.140)
0.098
(0.092)
0.323***
(0.047)
0.004
(0.008)
0.157
(0.171)
0.234
15
349
0.728
0.089
0.028
(0.018)
0.085*
(0.051)
0.056**
(0.027)
0.207
(0.170)
0.004
(0.097)
0.334***
(0.046)
0.010
(0.010)
0.177***
(0.051)
0.215
15
314
0.295
0.231
0.185
(0.178)
0.328***
(0.051)
0.013
(0.014)
0.225**
(0.089)
0.412
15
349
0.466
0.101
0.047
(0.037)
0.017
(0.179)
0.310***
(0.050)
0.016
(0.013)
0.150
(0.120)
0.186
15
302
0.628
0.169
0.106
(0.168)
0.293***
(0.054)
0.008
(0.010)
0.130
(0.206)
0.131
15
349
0.697
0.028
0.024
(0.063)
0.039*
(0.021)
0.244***
(0.043)
0.006*
(0.003)
0.076
(0.106)
0.319
15
302
0.000
Note: the asterisks *, ** and *** represent signicance at 10, 5 and 1% level, respectively. The values present between parentheses are the standard error. IV indicates if instrumental
variables were used in the regression, N is the number of countries included in the sample, Obs is the number of observations, Endogeneity is the p-value obtained by performing the
WuHausman endogeneity test for YR, and Hausman is the p-value for the Hausman's random effect test.
323
Table 3
Individual results of estimations of forecasts for year t, regression (2).
AT
BE
DE
DK
ES
FI
FR
GB
GR
IE
IT
NL
PT
SE
Ci,t
DEBTi,t
INFi,t
REERi,t
YRi,t
Ii,t
VIXi,t
R-square
Obs
3.120***
(0.198)
3.312***
(0.208)
2.801***
(0.273)
3.568***
(0.352)
4.013***
(0.298)
2.852***
(0.189)
3.143***
(0.199)
3.287***
(0.242)
9.080***
(1.895)
5.799***
(0.658)
3.995***
(0.277)
2.970***
(0.256)
5.823***
(0.798)
2.671***
(0.210)
0.008
(0.015)
0.047***
(0.016)
0.018
(0.017)
0.036***
(0.013)
0.018
(0.047)
0.119***
(0.016)
0.038*
(0.020)
0.056**
(0.027)
0.256***
(0.041)
0.080***
(0.020)
0.016
(0.032)
0.008
(0.015)
0.035
(0.048)
0.039
(0.034)
0.127*
(0.067)
0.006
(0.046)
0.038
(0.074)
0.343
(0.323)
0.230**
(0.110)
0.052
(0.068)
0.030
(0.064)
0.039
(0.086)
0.436
(0.420)
0.571***
(0.209)
0.208
(0.127)
0.041
(0.059)
0.959***
(0.256)
0.156
(0.136)
0.043
(0.031)
0.080***
(0.023)
0.014
(0.011)
0.102
(0.105)
0.102**
(0.040)
0.052**
(0.025)
0.008
(0.019)
0.066***
(0.012)
0.322
(0.212)
0.069
(0.055)
0.066**
(0.033)
0.013
(0.024)
0.277***
(0.076)
0.013
(0.024)
0.095
(0.058)
0.141**
(0.057)
0.032
(0.040)
0.146
(0.220)
0.194
(0.141)
0.010
(0.035)
0.128*
(0.070)
0.073
(0.097)
1.082**
(0.431)
0.027
(0.111)
0.089
(0.105)
0.004
(0.045)
0.063
(0.225)
0.350***
(0.095)
0.415***
(0.044)
0.302***
(0.049)
0.550***
(0.064)
0.313**
(0.147)
0.117
(0.078)
0.520***
(0.046)
0.413***
(0.046)
0.355***
(0.034)
1.431***
(0.519)
0.526***
(0.178)
0.085
(0.072)
0.474***
(0.059)
0.711***
(0.207)
0.632***
(0.062)
0.000
(0.007)
0.012
(0.007)
0.013
(0.010)
0.003
(0.031)
0.005
(0.011)
0.005
(0.007)
0.001
(0.007)
0.005
(0.009)
0.041
(0.066)
0.022
(0.024)
0.017*
(0.010)
0.004
(0.009)
0.052*
(0.028)
0.000
(0.007)
0.700
24
0.599
25
0.678
25
0.771
13
0.283
25
0.817
25
0.686
25
0.763
25
0.612
25
0.474
25
0.247
25
0.643
25
0.492
25
0.838
20
Note: the asterisks *, ** and *** represent signicance at 10, 5 and 1% level, respectively. The values present between parentheses are the standard error. Obs is the number of observations.
324
Table 4
Individual results of estimations of forecasts for year t + 1, regression (2).
AT
BE
DE
DK
ES
FI
FR
GB
GR
IE
IT
NL
PT
SE
Ci,t
DEBTi,t + 1
INFi,t + 1
REERi,t
YRi,t + 1
Ii,t
VIXi,t
R-square
Obs
2.971***
(0.207)
3.318***
(0.211)
2.269***
(0.276)
2.658***
(0.265)
4.037***
(0.336)
2.669***
(0.203)
3.029***
(0.185)
3.030***
(0.288)
9.761***
(1.983)
5.162***
(0.707)
3.790***
(0.269)
2.874***
(0.253)
5.044***
(0.811)
2.792***
(0.239)
0.011
(0.012)
0.019
(0.012)
0.024*
(0.013)
0.091**
(0.037)
0.011
(0.021)
0.073***
(0.014)
0.043***
(0.011)
0.024
(0.016)
0.119***
(0.041)
0.098***
(0.027)
0.022
(0.020)
0.016
(0.010)
0.162***
(0.042)
0.055**
(0.027)
0.331***
(0.118)
0.008
(0.088)
0.238**
(0.100)
1.442***
(0.440)
0.222
(0.156)
0.220*
(0.124)
0.260
(0.109)
0.152
(0.147)
0.269
(0.949)
1.562***
(0.474)
1.235***
(0.250)
0.005
(0.015)
2.318***
(0.532)
0.249
(0.173)
0.037
(0.036)
0.056***
(0.020)
0.029**
(0.013)
0.150**
(0.064)
0.095**
(0.037)
0.024
(0.023)
0.037*
(0.019)
0.073***
(0.015)
0.630***
(0.214)
0.020
(0.061)
0.053*
(0.030)
0.006
(0.020)
0.311***
(0.085)
0.005
(0.028)
0.174*
(0.093)
0.103
(0.084)
0.155*
(0.091)
1.600***
(0.467)
0.200
(0.130)
0.299***
(0.089)
0.207***
(0.069)
0.209*
(0.117)
1.037**
(0.499)
0.197
(0.168)
0.191
(0.130)
0.169***
(0.062)
0.671**
(0.323)
0.298**
(0.141)
0.444***
(0.047)
0.309***
(0.051)
0.574***
(0.066)
0.519***
(0.123)
0.054
(0.088)
0.527***
(0.046)
0.436***
(0.044)
0.381***
(0.038)
1.692***
(0.554)
0.748***
(0.211)
0.066
(0.068)
0.499***
(0.059)
0.466**
(0.206)
0.694***
(0.071)
0.006
(0.008)
0.010
(0.008)
0.008
(0.010)
0.025
(0.022)
0.011
(0.013)
0.004
(0.007)
0.000
(0.007)
0.004
(0.010)
0.036
(0.071)
0.032
(0.026)
0.024**
(0.010)
0.000
(0.009)
0.049
(0.029)
0.020**
(0.008)
0.686
24
0.584
25
0.702
25
0.847
13
0.192
25
0.810
25
0.741
25
0.781
25
0.535
25
0.453
25
0.385
25
0.658
25
0.518
25
0.810
20
Note: the asterisks *, ** and *** represent signicance at 10, 5 and 1% level, respectively. The values present between parentheses are the standard error. Obs is the number of observations.
T
YRi;s
T
YRi;s
The results of forecasts for years t 1 and t 2 are also available from the authors.
325
Table 5
Individual results of estimations of forecasts for year t, for regression (3).
AT
BE
DE
DK
ES
FI
FR
GB
GR
IE
IT
NL
PT
SE
Ci,t
BALi,t
CAi,t
REERi,t
YRi,t
Ii,t
VIXi,t
R-square
Obs
3.108***
(0.202)
3.452***
(0.206)
2.840***
(0.262)
3.282***
(0.310)
4.026***
(0.283)
2.858***
(0.215)
3.214***
(0.181)
3.372***
(0.217)
8.554***
(2.051)
5.595***
(0.742)
4.048***
(0.264)
3.003***
(0.244)
5.779***
(0.939)
2.707***
(0.190)
0.114
(0.076)
0.036
(0.045)
0.171*
(0.091)
0.260
(0.163)
0.213***
(0.055)
0.177**
(0.069)
0.168***
(0.050)
0.145***
(0.054)
0.219
(0.188)
0.095***
(0.022)
0.301**
(0.131)
0.049
(0.060)
0.116
(0.219)
0.149
(0.097)
0.032
(0.035)
0.002
(0.021)
0.054
(0.048)
0.150
(0.116)
0.013
(0.016)
0.046
(0.035)
0.041
(0.031)
0.033
(0.056)
0.456**
(0.222)
0.105
(0.140)
0.187***
(0.069)
0.039
(0.028)
0.167
(0.119)
0.097
(0.066)
0.032
(0.040)
0.077***
(0.025)
0.027
(0.019)
0.114*
(0.079)
0.117***
(0.031)
0.081***
(0.028)
0.057***
(0.019)
0.041***
(0.010)
0.851***
(0.192)
0.079
(0.053)
0.050
(0.036)
0.008
(0.038)
0.321***
(0.091)
0.021
(0.021)
0.034
(0.060)
0.068
(0.047)
0.090
(0.077)
0.006
(0.258)
0.357***
(0.086)
0.020
(0.056)
0.059
(0.053)
0.215**
(0.101)
0.623
(0.500)
0.139*
(0.076)
0.169*
(0.099)
0.033
(0.070)
0.175
(0.245)
0.279***
(0.082)
0.390***
(0.044)
0.290***
(0.049)
0.506***
(0.062)
0.305**
(0.134)
0.071
(0.073)
0.526***
(0.052)
0.392***
(0.042)
0.324***
(0.028)
1.576***
(0.561)
0.440**
(0.194)
0.091
(0.069)
0.469***
(0.057)
0.575**
(0.239)
0.677***
(0.057)
0.002
(0.007)
0.006
(0.007)
0.011
(0.009)
0.020
(0.026)
0.013
(0.010)
0.003
(0.008)
0.005
(0.007)
0.004
(0.008)
0.065
(0.075)
0.027
(0.027)
0.018*
(0.009)
0.007
(0.009)
0.051
(0.033)
0.006
(0.006)
0.707
24
0.574
25
0.703
25
0.759
13
0.336
25
0.746
25
0.729
25
0.783
25
0.529
25
0.350
25
0.319
25
0.672
25
0.387
25
0.861
20
Note: the asterisks *, ** and *** represent signicance at 10, 5 and 1% level, respectively. The values present between parentheses are the standard error. Obs is the number of observations.
countries with lower credibility tend to have yields that are more reactive to forecasts' corrections.
After making the individual analysis, it is visible that the real
effective exchange rate and real GDP growth rate corrections are not
so important in the panel results because they have opposite effects in
some countries.
Table 6
Individual results of estimations of forecasts, year t + 1, regression (3).
AT
BE
DE
DK
ES
FI
FR
GB
GR
IE
IT
NL
PT
SE
Ci,t
BALi,t + 1
CAi,t + 1
REERi,t
YRi,t + 1
Ii,t
VIXi,t
R-square
Obs
2.874***
(0.197)
3.385***
(0.210)
2.694***
(0.265)
3.079***
(0.337)
3.975***
(0.318)
2.756***
(0.220)
3.148***
(0.180)
3.039***
(0.249)
9.165***
(1.980)
5.315***
(0.819)
4.028***
(0.300)
2.942***
(0.239)
5.670***
(0.899)
2.799***
(0.224)
0.138***
(0.049)
0.032
(0.031)
0.063
(0.043)
0.266
(0.220)
0.118***
(0.038)
0.180***
(0.040)
0.078***
(0.029)
0.049
(0.042)
0.024
(0.226)
0.202*
(0.115)
0.033
(0.052)
0.051
(0.034)
0.178
(0.205)
0.242*
(0.135)
0.059*
(0.030)
0.014
(0.018)
0.094**
(0.040)
0.109
(0.113)
0.005
(0.014)
0.023
(0.030)
0.030
(0.027)
0.050
(0.061)
0.791***
(0.206)
0.062
(0.143)
0.064
(0.043)
0.036
(0.028)
0.090
(0.136)
0.060
(0.073)
0.025
(0.039)
0.061***
(0.017)
0.024
(0.020)
0.148*
(0.082)
0.074**
(0.034)
0.074***
(0.025)
0.050***
(0.017)
0.051***
(0.012)
1.134***
(0.219)
0.061
(0.064)
0.051**
(0.025)
0.011
(0.029)
0.155
(0.097)
0.016
(0.026)
0.237**
(0.100)
0.047
(0.062)
0.108
(0.101)
0.527
(0.537)
0.242**
(0.100)
0.224**
(0.089)
0.121*
(0.065)
0.175*
(0.101)
0.297
(0.437)
0.071
(0.138)
0.107
(0.102)
0.130*
(0.072)
0.588**
(0.258)
0.423**
(0.213)
0.411***
(0.044)
0.308***
(0.051)
0.537***
(0.064)
0.325**
(0.148)
0.083
(0.080)
0.515***
(0.050)
0.398***
(0.042)
0.370***
(0.032)
2.132***
(0.551)
0.466**
(0.205)
0.085
(0.075)
0.473***
(0.054)
0.495**
(0.226)
0.690***
(0.065)
0.011
(0.007)
0.006
(0.007)
0.009
(0.009)
0.024
(0.031)
0.012
(0.012)
0.001
(0.008)
0.002
(0.007)
0.003
(0.009)
0.110
(0.073)
0.047
(0.030)
0.018*
(0.011)
0.003
(0.009)
0.026
(0.033)
0.018**
(0.008)
0.750
24
0.587
25
0.705
25
0.696
13
0.233
25
0.753
25
0.735
25
0.778
25
0.549
25
0.276
25
0.202
25
0.683
25
0.404
25
0.816
20
Note: the asterisks *, ** and *** represent signicance at 10, 5 and 1% level, respectively. The values present between parentheses are the standard error. Obs is the number of observations.
326
5. Conclusion
References
In our study we have assessed the relevance of macro and scal forecast vintages for the explanation of sovereign yield developments in a
panel of 15 EU countries. Our analysis covers the period from 1999:1
till 2012:1.
We show that we can draw an important conclusion: corrections in
the EC's forecasts do impinge on the 10-year sovereign bond yield
spreads, particularly the corrections in scal variables (public debt and
budget balance), but this impact is different across countries, being
more pronounced in countries with less favourable economic conditions.
It seems that whether or not macro and scal forecasts are consistently seen as credible by the markets plays a relevant work. On the
one hand, the credibility that investors give to EC's forecasts is relevant,
and on the other hand the credibility that they give to the country and,
consequently, to governments' forecasts is also paramount.
As we have seen, higher credibility means yields will react less to
changes in forecasts. Hence, in spite of the incentive that governments
have to report less accurate forecasts, as the penalization is higher in
corrections for the current and next years than for previous years, if it
lowers its credibility, it may be worse than revealing the right way the
true results.
A relevant policy implication is that if more accurate values are only
known afterwards, the market penalization for worst budget balances
will be lower than if budget balances' data was corrected ex-ante. This
implies the need for a better perception of the forecast errors by market
participants, which could imply additional scepticism regarding the initial vintage forecasts, and already an increase in the yields at the time of
probably too optimistic 1st year vintage forecasts.
We also saw evidences that the sovereign debt crisis altered the variables to which investors pay attention. After including 2011 and 2012
forecasts, the budget balance lost statistical signicance, public debt became a more relevant determinant, and the real effective exchange rate
started to be signicant as well. Also, the constant term increased, indicating that investors demanded a higher risk premium, due to higher
risk and uncertainty in the bond market.
However, it is important to notice that there are some limitations in
our analysis. In fact, the number of observations is not very large, which
may bias our results, especially when we perform the SUR analysis. In
addition, the period under analysis is very typical, since half of the
years considered encompass the subprime and subsequent sovereign
crisis. As follow up work it would be useful to separate the data during
the sovereign crisis, in order to understand its consequences on investors' reactions. However, that is not possible, due to the yet low number
of forecasts made after the beginning of the crisis, but it stays as a
possible future research development.
Afonso, A., 2010. Long-term government bond yields and economic forecasts: evidence
for the EU. Appl. Econ. Lett. 17 (15), 14371441.
Afonso, A., Gomes, P., 2010. Do scal imbalances deteriorate sovereign debt rating? Revue
conomique 62 (6), 11231134.
Afonso, A., Rault, C., 2010. Long-run determinants of sovereign yields. CESifo Working
Paper 3155.
Afonso, A., Arghyrou, M., Kontonikas, A., 2012. The determinants of sovereign bond yield
spreads in the EMU. Department of Economics, ISEG-UTL, Working Paper 36/2012/
DE/UECE.
Akitoby, B., Stratmann, T., 2006. Fiscal policy and nancial markets. IMF Working Paper
16.
Alexopoulou, I., Bunda, I., Ferrando, A., 2009. Determinants of government bond spreads
in new EU countries. ECB Working Paper 1093.
Amira, K., 2004. Determinants of sovereign Eurobonds yield spreads. J. Bus. Finan. Acc. 31
(56), 795821.
Baldacci, E., Kumar, M., 2010. Fiscal decits, public debt and sovereign debt yields. IMF
Working Paper 184.
Bernoth, K., Wolff, G., 2008. Fool the markets? Creative accounting, scal transparency
and sovereign risk premia. Scott. J. Polit. Econ. 55 (4), 465487.
Canzoneri, M., Cumby, R., Diba, B., 2003. Should the European Central Bank and the Federal Reserve be concerned about scal policy? Proceedings, 333-389, Federal Reserve
Bank of Kansas City.
Castro, F., Prez, J., Vives, M., 2011. Fiscal data revisions in Europe. Banco de Espaa,
Documentos de Trabajo N 1106.
Dell'Erba, S., Sola, S., 2011. Fiscal policy, interest rates and risk premia in open economy.
The Graduate Institute of International and Development Studies.
EC, 2011. Public nances in EMU2011. European Commission.
Faini, R., 2006. Fiscal policy and interest rates in Europe. Econ. Policy 21 (47), 443489.
Frankel, J., 2011. Over-optimism in forecasts by ofcial budget agencies and its implications. Oxf. Rev. Econ. Policy 27 (4), 536562.
Gruber, J., Kamin, S., 2010. Fiscal positions and government bond yields in OECD countries. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, International Finance Discussion Papers.
Hischer, J., Nosbusch, Y., 2010. Determinants of sovereign risk: macroeconomic fundamentals and the pricing of sovereign debt. Eur. Finan. Rev. 14, 235262.
Jonung, L., Martin, L., 2006. Improving scal policy in the EU: the case for independent
forecasts. Econ. Policy 21 (47), 491534.
Laubach, T., 2009. New evidence on the interest rate effects of budget decits and debt. J.
Eur. Econ. Assoc. 7 (4), 128.
Martins, J., Mora, L., 2007. How reliable are the statistics for the Stability and Growth Pact?
Banco de Espaa, Notas Estadsticas N. 4.
Melander, A., Sismanidis, G., Grenouilleau, D., 2007. The track record of the Commission's
forecastsan update. Directorate General for Economic and Financial Affairs,
European Commission.
Merola, R., Prez, J., 2012. Fiscal forecast errors: governments vs independent agencies.
Banco de Espaa Working Paper 1233.
Moulin, L., Wierts, P., 2006. How credible are multiannual budgetary plans in the EU?
Banca di Italia.
Porter-Hudak, S., Quigley, M., 1994. A new approach in analyzing the effect of decit announcements of interest rates. J. Money, Credit, Bank. 26 (4), 894902.
von Hagen, J., Wolff, G., 2006. What do decits tell us about debt? Empirical evidence on
creative accounting with scal rules in the EU. J. Bank. Financ. 30 (12), 32593279.