Allen F. y D. Gale. Comparative Financial Systems
Allen F. y D. Gale. Comparative Financial Systems
Allen F. y D. Gale. Comparative Financial Systems
Franklin Allen
Wharton School
University of Pennsylvania
Philadelphia, PA 19104
[email protected]
Douglas Gale
Economics Department
New York University
New York, NY 10003
[email protected]
April 2001
The purpose of a financial system is to channel funds from agents with surpluses to agents with deficits. In the traditional literature there have been
two approaches to analyzing this process. The first is to consider how agents
interact through financial markets. The second looks at the operation of
financial intermediaries such as banks and insurance companies. Fifty years
ago, the financial system could be neatly bifurcated in this way. Rich households and large firms used the equity and bond markets, while less wealthy
households and medium and small firms used banks, insurance companies
and other financial institutions. Table 1, for example, shows the ownership
of corporate equities in 1950. Households owned over 90 percent. By 2000 it
can be seen that the situation had changed dramatically. By then households
held less than 40 percent, nonbank intermediaries, primarily pension funds
and mutual funds, held over 40 percent. This change illustrates why it is no
longer possible to consider the role of financial markets and financial institutions separately. Rather than intermediating directly between households and
firms, financial institutions have increasingly come to intermediate between
households and markets, on the one hand, and between firms and markets,
on the other. This makes it necessary to consider the financial system as an
irreducible whole.
The notion that a financial system transfers resources between households
and firms is, of course, a simplification. Governments usually play a significant role in the financial system. They are major borrowers, particularly
during times of war, recession, or when large infrastructure projects are being undertaken. They sometimes also save significant amounts of funds. For
example, when countries such as Norway and many Middle Eastern States
have access to large amounts of natural resources (oil), the government may
acquire large trust funds on behalf of the population.
In addition to their roles as borrowers or savers, governments usually play
a number of other important roles. Central banks typically issue fiat money
and are extensively involved in the payments system. Financial systems with
unregulated markets and intermediaries, such as the US in the late nineteenth
century, often experience financial crises (Gorton (1988) and Calomiris and
Gorton (1991)). The desire to eliminate these crises led many governments
to intervene in a significant way in the financial system. Central banks or
some other regulatory authority are charged with regulating the banking
system and other intermediaries, such as insurance companies. So in most
1
that the lender will not carry out the threat in practice, the incentive eect
disappears. Although the lenders behavior is now ex post optimal, both
parties may be worse o ex ante.
The time inconsistency of commitments that are optimal ex ante and suboptimal ex post is typical in contracting problems. The contract commits
one to certain courses of action in order to influence the behavior of the other
party. Then once that partys behavior has been determined, the benefit of
the commitment disappears and there is now an incentive to depart from it.
Whatever agreements have been entered into are subject to revision because
both parties can typically be made better o by renegotiating the original
agreement. The possibility of renegotiation puts additional restrictions on
the kind of contract or agreement that is feasible (we are referring here to
the contract or agreement as executed, rather than the contract as originally
written or conceived) and, to that extent, tends to reduce the welfare of both
parties ex ante. Anything that gives the parties a greater power to commit
themselves to the terms of the contract will, conversely, be welfare-enhancing.
Dewatripont and Maskin (1995) (included as a chapter in this section)
have suggested that financial markets have an advantage over financial intermediaries in maintaining commitments to refuse further funding. If the firm
obtains its funding from the bond market, then, in the event that it needs
additional investment, it will have to go back to the bond market. Because
the bonds are widely held, however, the firm will find it dicult to renegotiate with the bond holders. Apart from the transaction costs involved in
negotiating with a large number of bond holders, there is a free-rider problem. Each bond holder would like to maintain his original claim over the
returns to the project, while allowing the others to renegotiate their claims
in order to finance the additional investment. The free-rider problem, which
is often thought of as the curse of cooperative enterprises, turns out to be a
virtue in disguise when it comes to maintaining commitments.
From a theoretical point of view, there are many ways of maintaining
a commitment. Financial institutions may develop a valuable reputation
for maintaining commitments. In any one case, it is worth incurring the
small cost of a sub-optimal action in order to maintain the value of the
reputation. Incomplete information about the borrowers type may lead to a
similar outcome. If default causes the institution to change its beliefs about
the defaulters type, then it may be optimal to refuse to deal with a firm
after it has defaulted. Institutional strategies such as delegating decisions to
agents who are given no discretion to renegotiate may also be an eective
6
commitment device.
Several authors (Huberman and Kahn (1988), Hart and Moore (1988),
Gale (1991) and Allen and Gale (2000a, Chapter 10)) have argued that, under
certain circumstances, renegotiation is welfare-improving. In that case, the
Dewatripont-Maskin argument is turned on its head. Intermediaries that
establish long-term relationships with clients may have an advantage over
financial markets precisely because it is easier for them to renegotiate contracts.
The crucial assumption is that contracts are incomplete. Because of
the high transaction costs of writing complete contracts, some potentially
Pareto-improving contingencies are left out of contracts and securities. This
incompleteness of contracts may make renegotiation desirable. The missing
contingencies can be replaced by contract adjustments that are negotiated by
the parties ex post, after they observe the realization of variables on which
the contingencies would have been based. The incomplete contract determines the status quo for the ex post bargaining game (i.e., renegotiation)
that determines the final outcome.
An important question in this whole area is How important are these
relationships empirically? Here there does not seem to be a lot of evidence.
As far as the importance of renegotiation in the sense of Dewatripont and
Maskin (1995), the work of Asquith, Gertner and Scharfstein (1994) suggests
that little renegotiation occurs in the case of financially distressed firms.
Conventional wisdom holds that banks are so well secured that they can and
do pull the plug as soon as a borrower becomes distressed, leaving the
unsecured creditors and other claimants holding the bag.
Petersen and Rajan (1994) suggest that firms that have a longer relationship with a bank do have greater access to credit, controlling for a number
of features of the borrowers history. It is not clear from their work exactly
what lies behind the value of the relationship. For example, the increased
access to credit could be an incentive device or it could be the result of
greater information or the relationship itself could make the borrower more
credit worthy. Berger and Udell (1992) find that banks smooth loan rates
in response to interest rate shocks. Petersen and Rajan (1995) and Berlin
and Mester (1997) find that smoothing occurs as a firms credit risk changes.
Berlin and Mester (1998) find that loan rate smoothing is associated with
lower bank profits. They argue that this suggests the smoothing does not
arise as part of an optimal relationship.
This section has pointed to a number of issues for future research.
7
The relationship between the growth rate of an economy and its financial
structure is a long-debated issue. On the one hand, Bagehot (1873) and Hicks
(1969) argue that the UKs financial system played an important role in the
Industrial Revolution. On the other hand, Robinson (1952) suggests that
the causation goes the other way and that the financial system developed
as a result of economic growth. In his survey of development economics,
Stern (1989) does not even mention finance (not even under omitted topics).
Levine (1997) provides an excellent overview of the literature on economic
growth and financial development.
In a pioneering study using cross-country data, Goldsmith (1969) found a
relationship between growth and financial development. However, his study
was based on limited data and did not control in a satisfactory way for other
factors aecting growth. In a series of studies King and Levine (1993a, b,
c) consider data for 80 countries over the period 1960-1989 and carefully
control for other factors aecting growth. They find a strong relationship
between growth and financial development and also find evidence that the
level of financial development is a good predictor of future economic growth.
In an innovative study Rajan and Zingales (1998) use data from the US to
find which industries rely on external finance and investigate whether these
industries grow faster in countries with better developed financial systems.
They find a positive correlation between growth rates and financial development, suggesting that finance is important for growth. Demirguc-Kunt and
8
Maksimovic (1996) consider firm-level data from 30 countries and argue that
access to stock markets leads to faster growth. In an influential contribution,
McKinnon (1973) did case studies of Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Germany, Korea, Indonesia and Taiwan in the period after the Second World War. His
conclusion from these cases is that better financial systems support faster
economic growth. Taken together these studies provide considerable support
for a relationship between finance and growth.
A large number of theoretical studies consider the growth-finance relationship. Hicks (1969) and Bencivenga, Smith and Starr (1995) argue that the
liquidity provided by capital markets was key in allowing growth in the UK
Industrial Revolution. Many of the products produced early in the Industrial
Revolution had been invented some time before but lack of long-term finance
delayed their manufacture. Liquid capital markets allowed the projects to be
financed by savers with short time horizons and/or uncertain liquidity needs.
Similarly, Bencivenga and Smith (1991) argue that intermediaries may be
able to enhance liquidity, while at the same time funding long-lived projects.
Greenwood and Jovanovic (1990) point out that intermediaries that can effectively process information about entrepreneurs and projects can induce a
higher rate of growth. King and Levine (1993c) suggest that intermediaries
can also do a better job of choosing innovations. Another avenue for increasing growth is the higher expected returns that can be achieved if risk is
reduced through diversification (Saint-Paul (1982)). Boyd and Smith (1996,
1998) suggest that banks are important at low levels of development while
markets become more important as income rises. Rajan and Zingales (1999)
suggest that banks are less dependent than markets on legal system. Hence,
banks can do better when the legal system is weak and markets do better
when the legal system is more developed.
Another important element of the debate concerns the relative contributions of banks and financial markets in spurring growth. This debate was
originally conducted in the context of German and UK growth in the late
nineteenth and early twentieth centuries. Gerschenkron (1962) argues that
the bank-based system in Germany allowed a closer relationship between
bankers providing the finance and industrial firms than was possible in the
market-based system in the UK. Goldsmith (1969) pointed out that although
manufacturing industry grew much faster in Germany than the UK in the
late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries the overall growth rates were
fairly similar. More recently Levine (2000) uses a broad data base covering 48 countries over the period 1980-1995. He finds that the distinction
9
have to be revealed. In equilibrium, firms with high quality proprietary information use bilateral financing. Product market competitors deduce this
relationship and take appropriate actions to oset it.
Allen and Gale (1999, 2000a, Chapter 13) ask whether financial markets
or banks are better at providing finance for projects where there is diversity
of opinion, for example, in the development of new technologies. Diversity
of opinion arises from dierences in prior beliefs, rather than dierences in
information. The advantage of financial markets is that they allow people
with similar views to join together to finance projects. This will be optimal
provided the costs necessary for each investor to form an opinion before
investment decisions are made are suciently low. Finance can be provided
by the market even when there is great diversity of opinion among investors.
Intermediated finance involves delegating the financing decision to a manager
who expends the cost necessary to form an opinion. There is an agency
problem in that the manager may not have the same prior as the investor.
This type of delegation turns out to be optimal when the costs of forming
an opinion are high and there is likely to be considerable agreement in any
case. The analysis suggests that market-based systems will lead to more
innovation than bank-based systems.
There are a number of important open questions about the relationship
between growth and financial structure.
There appears to be a wide range of empirical evidence that growth and
financial structure are positively correlated. There is little agreement as
to the direction of causation and the channels by which each influences
the other.
The empirical evidence on the eectiveness of bank-based and marketbased systems is mixed.
In both cases, we are a long way from being able to make welfare-based
recommendations.
Risk sharing
How can one explain these dierences in the amount of risk households
are apparently exposed to in dierent financial systems? Standard financial
theory suggests that the main purpose of financial markets is to improve
risk sharing. Financial markets in the US and UK are more developed by
most measures than in Japan and France and much more developed than in
Germany. How can it be that households are exposed to more risk in the US
and UK than in Japan, France and Germany?
Allen and Gale (1997; 2000a, Chapter 6) (included as a chapter in this
section) have provided a resolution to this paradox. They point out that
traditional financial theory has little to say about hedging non-diversifiable
risks. It assumes that the set of assets is given and theory focuses on the
ecient sharing of these risks through exchange. For example, the standard
diversification argument requires individuals to exchange assets so that each
investor holds a relatively small amount of any one risk. Risks will also
be traded so that more risk-averse people bear less risk than people who
are less risk-averse. This kind of risk sharing is termed cross-sectional risk
sharing, because it is achieved through exchanges of risk among individuals at
a given point in time. However, importantly, these strategies do not eliminate
macroeconomic shocks that aect all assets in a similar way.
Departing from the traditional approach, Allen and Gale focus on the
intertemporal smoothing of risks that cannot be diversified at a given point
in time. They argue that such risks can be averaged over time in a way
that reduces their impact on individual welfare. One hedging strategy for
non-diversifiable risks is intergenerational risk sharing. This spreads the risks
associated with a given stock of assets across generations with heterogeneous
experiences. Another strategy involves asset accumulation in order to reduce
fluctuations in consumption over time. Both are examples of the intertemporal smoothing of asset returns.
Allen and Gale show that the opportunities for engaging in intertemporal smoothing are very dierent in market-based and bank-based financial
systems. They demonstrate that incomplete financial markets, on the one
hand, may not allow eective intertemporal smoothing. Long-lived financial
institutions, such as banks, on the other hand, can achieve intertemporal
smoothing, as long they as are not subject to substantial competition from
financial markets. In fact, competition from financial markets can lead to
disintermediation and the unraveling of intertemporal smoothing provided
by long-lived institutions. In good times, individuals would rather opt out
of the banking system and invest in the market, thus avoiding the accumu13
lation of reserves from which they may not benefit. Therefore, in the long
run, intertemporal smoothing by banks is not viable in the presence of direct
competition from markets.
This theory provides a framework for thinking about the role of risk
management in dierent financial systems. In bank-based systems, such as
those in Japan, France and Germany, risk management could be achieved
through intertemporal smoothing, in which financial intermediaries eliminate
risk by accumulating low risk, liquid assets. Cross sectional risk sharing
through markets is less important, and the importance of other forms of risk
management is reduced correspondingly.
In market-based financial systems, on the other hand, intertemporal smoothing by intermediaries is ruled out by competition from financial markets.
Here, cross-sectional risk sharing becomes correspondingly more important.
As a result, individuals and institutions acting on their behalf need to trade
and manage risk in a very dierent way. They need to ensure that those who
are most tolerant of risk end up bearing most of the risk. The Allen-Gale
theory thus predicts that as financial systems become more market-oriented,
risk management through the use of derivatives and other similar techniques
will become more important. The theory is thus consistent with the fact that
these particular forms of risk management are much more important in the
US and UK than they are in less market-oriented economies such as Japan,
France and Germany.
The Allen-Gale theory points to clear oportunities for improving welfare through intertemporal risk sharing when markets are incomplete, but it
leaves open the question of whether financial institutions will have the right
incentives to oer this kind of risk sharing. In fact, there is as yet no adequate
theory of long-lived financial institutions. In some cases, we can obviate this
gap in the theory by assuming that competitive institutions maximize the
welfare of their depositors. However, when depositors are heterogeneous as,
for example, in an overlapping generations economy, this device breaks down.
One of the important questions posed by the behavior of financial institutions in dierent countries is, what is the objective function of a financial
institution? At the moment, we do not know.
The risks associated with holding stocks, bonds and other financial assets
are only some of the risks that individuals face. There are many other risks,
such as the risk of unemployment, illness, changes in the value of ones home,
and changes in the value of ones human capital, to name a few. Despite
the enormous pace of financial innovation in the 1980s and 1990s, there are
14
very few ways in which these risks can be shared. Shiller (1993) has argued
that there is scope for creating securities for hedging risks such as changes
in the value of real estate, or changes in the level of national, regional, or
occupational incomes. However, in many cases there are good reasons why
such markets do not exist. These include moral hazard, adverse selection
and transaction costs. In many cases, these market failures have led to
government intervention. For example, governments in most countries are
heavily involved in the provision of unemployment insurance, health care,
disability insurance and so forth. Thus, the public sector plays an important
role in the sharing of risks. The tax system itself can also be thought of as
a risk sharing vehicle. The fact that gains can be set against losses and so
forth also helps to share risks.
Perhaps one of the most important areas in which the government intervenes to share risks is the public provision of pensions. Because of problems
of adverse selection and moral hazard, the market for annuities is inecient.
This market failure provides a rationale for government provision of pensions.
Other reasons include the fact that agents cannot trade before they are born
and hence cannot insure against accidents of birth. This market failure
and the resulting overlapping generations structure means that a Pareto improvement can be achieved with a pay as you go public pension system.
In addition to the public provision of pensions, many countries provide tax
advantages for private pensions.
In practice, the extent to which countries provide public pensions diers
substantially (see Davis (1992, 1996) for an account and Miles (1996) for
asset holdings or Allen and Gale (2000a, Chapter 3) for a summary of both).
For example, in the UK public pensions are rather meagre. The basic component is small. There is also an earnings-related component to supplement
the basic rate. However, it is possible to contract out of this earnings-related
part and replace it with a private pension scheme. As a result of the limited public pension scheme, private pensions are popular in the UK. The
contributions and asset returns are untaxed and only the benefits are taxed.
Coverage is high with 50 percent of the work force participating in company
schemes. The proportion of assets ultimately owned by the household sector
and held by public and private pension funds is 24%. Over 75% of these
assets are equities. Clearly, the importance of private pensions in the UK
has contributed to the growth of the stock market there.
In Germany the structure of pensions is quite dierent. The social security system provides pensions to all workers. These state pensions are linked
15
Information provision
that the banks are able to acquire considerable amounts of information about
the firms they lend to, more than is released to the market. This can be used
to allocate resources more eciently.
Corresponding to these two perspectives are two traditional approaches
to the role of information in financial systems. The first comes from the
general equilibrium and rational expectations literatures on the role of prices
in resource allocation. The second comes from the intermediation literature
and is concerned with the role of banks as delegated monitors. We consider
each in turn. Based on the first approach, it is sometimes argued that since
market-based financial systems have many more prices that are publicly observed they allocate resources better than bank-based systems. Similarly
based on the second approach it is sometimes argued that bank-based systems do better. As will be seen these simplistic arguments ignore many
important factors.
Prices and information
The standard neoclassical view of prices, which originated with Adam
Smiths invisible hand, is that they are indicators of scarcity and value.
The modern version of this theory is captured in the Arrow-Debreu-Mackenzie
(ADM) model and the fundamental theorems of welfare economics. If markets are complete and certain other restrictions are satisfied, markets allow
a Pareto ecient allocation of resources.
The neoclassical theory of resource allocation, which culminated in the
ADM theory, was initially developed under the assumption of certainty. Under these conditions, decision-making is relatively simple. How firms should
make investment decisions to maximize their value is the subject of capital budgeting. Over the years, it has become a mainstay of the curriculum
in most business schools. It has been expounded in numerous textbooks.
Current examples in wide use are Brealey and Myers (2000) and Ross, Westerfield and Jae (2001). According to the methodology outlined in these
books, managers first need to derive the stream of cash flows that will accrue
to shareholders over time, including the initial cost of the investment. This
is done using various types of information. Projections based on accounting
data generated within the firm usually play an important part. Once the
cash flows have been calculated, they are discounted at the opportunity cost
of capital for each period. NPV is obviously maximized by accepting positive
NPV projects and rejecting negative NPV projects. There are a number of
other capital budgeting methods such as internal rate of return (IRR) and
profitability index (PI) which are widely used and are equivalent to NPV if
18
of expected cash flows and the present value is calculated using a discount
rate from an asset pricing model estimated from historical price data. The
model that is typically used is the capital asset pricing model (CAPM). In
order to calculate the discount rate using the CAPM, it is necessary to have
historical data from the stock market on the covariance of returns for the
firms stock with the market portfolio (a value weighted portfolio consisting
of all the stocks in the market). It is possible to show that if firms adopt
this method, there will be an ecient allocation of resources in a stockmarket economy provided some firms are listed in every industry (see, e.g.,
Allen and Gale (2000a, Chapter 7)). Thus, a stock market provides the
information that is necessary for ecient decentralization. Stock market
prices provide information in the sense that they allow the asset pricing
model to be estimated. They are no longer redundant.
Even though the CAPM is based on very special assumptions and has limited empirical support, this result revives the argument that market-based
financial systems are superior to bank-based systems because of the availability of stock-price information. If the financial system is bank-based, it
would appear that this kind of decentralization is not possible. However,
Allen and Gale (2000a, Chapter 7) suggest that if the institutional structure
is similar to the US in the nineteenth century or some European economies
in the twentieth century, decentralization will still be possible in an intermediated economy. Suppose finance is provided by intermediaries such as banks
and insurance companies. There is a stock exchange, but only the intermediaries are listed. They make loans to firms and have equity investments in
them. Since the intermediaries are listed and hold equity in all the firms in
the economy, a portfolio consisting of the intermediaries is like the market
portfolio in a full stock market economy. Provided firms can use accounting
data to calculate the returns on a firm they will then be able to calculate the
covariance with the market and hence be able to use the CAPM to find a
discount rate. In this case, bank-based systems will not be at a disadvantage
compared to market-based systems in terms of the information available to
allocate resources.
In the frameworks discussed so far, information is public. An important
issue in the literature has been the process by which private information
becomes reflected in prices; in other words, their role as aggregators of information. One of the questions that received considerable attention in the
1960s and 1970s is the extent to which stock markets are informationally
ecient and reflect all the available information. The notion implicit in much
20
of this research is that if stock prices are informationally ecient, they would
provide a good mechanism for allocating investment resources. This view is
well exposited by Fama (1976, p.133) who wrote:
An ecient capital market is an important component of a
capitalist system. In such a system, the ideal is a market where
prices are accurate signals for capital allocation. That is, when
firms issue securities to finance their activities they can expect to
get fair prices, and when investors choose among the securities
that represent ownership of firms activities, they can do so under
the assumption they are paying fair prices. In short, if the capital market is to function smoothly in allocating resources, prices
of securities must be good indicators of value.
Extensive evidence was provided during the 1960s and 1970s that markets are ecient in the sense that investors pay fair prices and it is not
possible to make excess returns above the reward for bearing risk using information that is publicly available. This is termed semi-strong form eciency.
There was some evidence that even using apparently private information, it
is not possible to make excess returns. This is termed strong-form eciency.
More recently studies have been less supportive. For surveys of the empirical literature on ecient markets see Fama (1970; 1991) and Hawawini and
Keim (1995).
Grossman (1976) developed a theoretical model based on rational expectations to show how private signals obtained by investors could become
incorporated in prices, so that apparently private information became public.
If an investor has favorable information, she will buy the security and bid up
its price while if she has unfavorable information she will sell and bid down
the price. Grossman was able to show that, under certain conditions, prices
aggregate all the economically relevant private information. This result provides a theoretical underpinning for the notion of prices as aggregators of
information and led to a large literature on information revelation, including Grossman and Stiglitz (1976; 1980), Hellwig (1980) and Diamond and
Verrecchia (1981). For surveys see Grossman (1981) and Admati (1989).
An important point, which is often disregarded in discussions of financial
systems, is that informational eciency and welfare (Pareto) eciency are
dierent things (see, e.g., Dow and Gorton (1997) and Allen and Gale (2000a,
Chapter 7)). In special cases, full revelation of information through market
21
prices or in some other way can lead to the first best, as the above quote
from Fama suggests. In other words, informational eciency is equivalent to
Pareto-eciency. However, this need not be true in general. For example, in
order to reveal information, prices have to fluctuate with changes in underlying information; but price fluctuations themselves are costly to the extent
that they impose risk of uninsured changes in wealth on investors. There
is therefore a trade-o between allocative eciency and risk sharing. This
is similar to the point made by Hirshleifer (1971) that the public release of
information can destroy valuable risk sharing opportunities.
There is a large literature on the welfare analysis of rational expectations
models. Allen (1983) and Laont (1985) showed that more information could
make people worse o because the added price volatility increases consumption variability. Jacklin and Bhattacharya (1988) showed that bank deposits
can be more desirable than equity mutual funds for similar reasons. Much
of this literature is concerned with the desirability of allowing insider trading. One view is that insider trading involves the informed benefiting at the
expense of the uninformed. Another view is that insider trading is desirable
because it leads to prices being more informative, which improves the allocation of investment. For a variety of positions on and analyses of insider
trading see Glosten (1989), Manove (1989), Ausubel (1990), Fishman and
Hagerty (1992), Leland (1992), Bernhardt, Hollifield and Hughson (1995)
and Bhattacharya and Nicodano (1995).
Another set of papers analyzes what happens when one group of traders
is simply better informed than another, either because they have paid to
acquire information or because they are endowed with superior information.
Bernardo and Judd (1997) analyze a version of the Grossman and Stiglitz
(1980) model with pure exchange using numerical techniques and show that
everybody would be better o without information. Dow and Rahi (1997)
analyze a parametric model with investment in productive assets by firms.
They are able to derive closed-form solutions for all agents utilities and
this allows a nice characterization of the trade-o between risk sharing and
investment.
A third strand of the literature takes a security-design approach to analyze the relationship between incomplete markets and information revelation.
This literature has identified three eects of security design on welfare when
agents are asymmetrically informed: spanning, adverse selection and insurance destruction (i.e., the Hirshleifer eect). In general, welfare improves
with spanning and is reduced with adverse selection and insurance destruc22
tion. Taking the number of assets as given, Rahi (1995) finds that it is
constrained Pareto-ecient to issue information-free securities as a way to
minimize the adverse selection problem. Marin and Rahi (1999) generalize
the analysis of the previous paper and show that under certain conditions
its main conclusion is reversed. In particular, they identify conditions on
the primitives of the economy for which it is Pareto-ecient to issue speculative securities. These are securities whose payo explicitly depends on
private information sunspots (i.e. a random shock unrelated to endowments
and preferences about which some agents have private information). Finally,
Marin and Rahi (2000) consider the eect of endogenizing the number of
assets in this type of model and build a theory of (endogenous) market incompleteness. They find that, under certain conditions, the introduction of a
new security makes all agents worse o because it provides new information
that destroys insurance opportunities. In the last two papers, the incorporation of asymmetric information, sunspots, and the reduction of the number of
tradable securities inject noise into the price system so that less information
is revealed and, consequently, fewer insurance opportunities are destroyed.
A number of papers consider the feedback role of stock prices in providing
incentives when there is an agency problem between shareholders and managers. Diamond and Verrecchia (1982) and Holmstrom and Tirole (1993)
consider how compensation contracts can be conditioned on stock prices to
give incentives to make an eort. Dow and Gorton (1997) consider how good
investment incentives can be provided to managers when stock prices contain
information managers do not have.
The trade-o between allocative eciency and risk sharing has important
implications for the structure of financial systems. Although there may be
allocational advantages, the mere existence of more price data from stock
markets in the US may not be a decisive point in favor of a market-oriented
system. In financial systems like Germanys, few companies are publicly
quoted and little information is revealed by the companies that are. This lack
of information, which may be bad from the point of view of ecient decisionmaking, may be a good thing from the point of view of risk sharing. There is
no theoretical presumption that more information leads to a better outcome,
even if that information is useful for productive eciency. This suggests
that countries such as Germany and France, where accounting information
about companies is not freely available and few analysts follow companies,
are not necessarily at a disadvantage compared to countries such as the US
and UK, where the reverse is true. Allocative eciency is oset by the fact
23
Corporate governance
In most countries, including the US, the UK, Japan, and France, managers
of corporations are ultimately responsible to the shareholders. However, the
details of corporation law dier across countries. The common origins of company law in the US and UK have led to a similar structure. In both countries,
managers have a fiduciary duty, that is, they have a strong legal requirement
to act in the interests of shareholders. The ocial channel through which
shareholders influence company aairs is the board of directors, elected by
the shareholders, typically on the basis of one share, one vote. The board of
directors is a mixture of outside and inside directors, the latter being the top
25
than in Japan, Germany and France. The main restriction on the holding of
shares by nonfinancial corporations in other firms is the requirement that this
not restrict competition in any way. The USs 14% ownership of shares by
nonfinancial corporations is much lower than in Japan, Germany and France,
but is comparable to the UKs.
It can be seen from Table 6 that the UK has far fewer formal regulations
than the US does. Banks can hold equity if they wish and need only obtain
permission from the Bank of England to purchase large blocks of equity. Insurance companies are only limited by the (self-imposed) need to diversify.
With regard to holdings of nonfinancial corporations, the only limitation is
that firms must not mutually hold each others shares to prevent a transfer of
control. The relative lack of regulation creates dierent ownership patterns.
Compared to the US, financial institutions hold more and individuals less.
Compared to Japan, Germany and France, the holding of shares by nonfinancial corporations is much less and the holdings of pension funds much
greater.
As Tables 2 and 3 indicate, Japan, Germany and France are all somewhat similar in terms of the regulatory restrictions on holding shares and
the patterns of ownership. In all three countries banks can hold the equity
of companies. There are regulations on the proportions of the equity of firms
that banks can hold in Japan. In Germany and France there are restrictions on holdings of equity relative to bank capital. As mentioned above,
holding companies were traditionally not permitted in Japan. In Germany
and France there are limitations on the percentages of firms that can be
owned. Complex interactions of holding companies occur in both Germany
and France. Van Hulle (1998) contains an account of European holding
groups. In Japan the interactions in terms of crossholdings are relatively
simple.
In their seminal book, Berle and Means (1932) argued that, in practice,
managers pursued their own interests rather than the interests of shareholders. The contractual aspect of the firm together with the problem highlighted
by Berle and Means led to the development of the agency approach to corporate governance by, among others, Coase (1937), Jensen and Meckling
(1976), Fama and Jensen (1983a,b) and Hart (1995). Excellent surveys are
contained in Shleifer and Vishny (1997) and Becht, Bolton and Roell (2001).
Vives (2000) contains a number of recent papers that provide good coverage
of the literature. The main focus of the agency approach is the question:
29
price and this reflects information gathered by analysts. Stock prices are not
the only contingency that can be used to motivate managers. Accounting
based performance measures are also frequently used. Managers who perform extremely well may be bid away at higher compensation levels to other
companies. The managerial labor market thus also plays an important part
in providing incentives to managers. There has been some debate about
the optimal sensitivity of executive compensation to stock price in practice.
Jensen and Murphy (1990) confirm previous findings of a positive relationship between executive pay and performance in the US and estimate CEO
compensation varies by about $3 for every $1,000 change in firm value. They
suggest that this figure is much too small. Haubrich (1994) has calibrated
an appropriately designed principal agent model which takes into account
risk aversion and argues that a small sensitivity is optimal for reasonable
parameter values. For other countries, the number of empirical studies is
small. Kaplan (1994a,b) considers the sensitivity of pay and dismissal to
performance in Germany and Japan. He finds that they are similar to the
US in this respect.
The market for corporate control
Manne (1965) has argued that an active market for corporate control is essential for the ecient operation of capitalist economies. It allows able management teams to gain control of large amounts of resources in a small amount
of time. Inecient managers are removed and replaced with people who are
better able to do the job. The existence of a market for corporate control also
provides one means of disciplining managers. If a firm is pursuing policies
which do not maximize shareholders wealth it can be taken over and the
managers replaced.
The market for corporate control can operate through proxy contests,
friendly mergers and hostile takeovers. Recent theoretical analyses of proxy
fights, which throw some light on why they do not work well, are contained
in Bhattacharya (1997), Yilmaz (1997) and Maug (1998).
Friendly mergers occur when both firms agree that combining them would
be value creating. Friendly mergers and takeovers occur in all countries
and account for most of the transaction volume that occurs. Prowse (1995)
reports that in the US friendly transactions constituted 82.2% of transactions,
in the UK 62.9% and in the rest of Europe 90.4%.
The third way in which the market for corporate control can operate is
through hostile takeovers. This mechanism is potentially very important in
ensuring an ecient allocation of resources in the way Manne (1965) sug31
gested. However, Grossman and Hart (1980) have pointed to a problem with
the operation of this mechanism of corporate governance. Existing shareholders will have a strong incentive to free ride on raiders who plan to increase
the value of the firm. On the one hand, if the price oered by the raider is
below the price that the new policies will justify and the shareholder believes
the oer will succeed, then there is no point in tendering. However, in that
case the oer will not succeed. On the other hand, if the raider oers a
price above the current value and the shareholder believes that the oer will
not succeed, then it will be worth tendering his shares. But then the oer
will succeed. In both cases, the shareholders beliefs are inconsistent with
equilibrium. The only equilibrium is one in which the raiders oer price is
equal to the price the new policies will justify. In that case, the raiders profit
will be zero, before allowing for any costs incurred in undertaking the bid.
If these costs are included, the profit will be negative and there will be no
incentive to attempt a takeover.
A number of solutions to the free-rider problem have been suggested.
Grossman and Harts (1980) solution is that corporate charters should be
structured so that raiders can dilute minority shareholders interests after
the takeover occurs. This means the raider can oer a price below the posttakeover value of the firm to him and the bid still succeeds. Existing shareholders will know that if they retain their shares the raider will dilute their
interest. Shleifer and Vishny (1986) pointed out that if the raider can acquire a block of stock before attempting a takeover at the low pre-takeover
price there will be a profit on this block even if all the remaining shares are
purchased at the full price justified by the raiders plans. Burkart (1995)
shows that it is privately optimal for a large shareholder to overbid and this
can lead to possible losses and ineciencies.
In addition to the Grossman and Hart free rider-problem there are a
number of other problems with the operation of the market for corporate
control. One is that once a takeover bid is announced other raiders will
realize it is an attractive target and will bid. This will mean it is not possible
for the initial firm to recoup any fixed costs from identifying the target in the
first place. The third problem in the operation of the market for corporate
control is the possibility of management entrenchment. Managers may be
incompetent and want to prevent a takeover to preserve their jobs.
Despite all these problems, hostile takeovers do occur fairly frequently
in the US and UK. Prowse (1995) points out that in the US almost 10% of
companies that belonged to the Fortune 500 in 1980 have since been acquired
32
in a transaction that was hostile or started o as hostile. For the UK, Franks
and Mayer (1992) report that there were 35 successful hostile bids made over
two years in the mid-1980s. This is much higher than in Germany, France
or Japan. In Germany, Franks and Mayer (1998) report that there have
only been three hostile takeovers between 1945 and 1994 and analyze them.
Franks and Mayer (1997) document a substantial market in share stakes but
their analysis suggests such sales do not perform a disciplinary function. In
Japan Kester (1991) argues that there have been no hostile takeovers among
large firms in that period. In France hostile takeovers were also rare until
recently.
Why do these dierences in the number of hostile takeovers between the
US and UK and other countries exist? A standard explanation for the difference in the occurrence of takeovers across countries is the prevalence of
cross shareholdings in Japan and the structure of holding companies and
cross shareholdings in Germany and France that make it dicult to acquire
the necessary number of shares.
Another important issue is the extent to which the market for corporate
control leads to an improvement in eciency in the way Mannes (1965)
argument suggests it should. There have been numerous empirical studies
of takeovers in an attempt to understand whether they create value. Jensen
(1993) estimates the total increase in the stock market value of target firms in
the US from 1976-90 as $750 billion. In contrast, it seems that the increase in
value for bidding firms was zero and possibly even negative. Overall, the stock
market data suggests that total value (i.e., the sum of the targets values and
bidding firms values) did increase significantly. There is an issue of whether
this was caused by the mergers and takeovers or was simply a reflection of a
previous undervaluation in the stock market. Another possibility, suggested
by Shleifer and Summers (1988), is that gains from takeovers may be the
result of violating implicit contracts with workers and other suppliers.
A number of studies have attempted to use accounting data to identify
the reason why the value of the targets increased. For example, Ravenscraft
and Scherer (1987) and Herman and Lowenstein (1988) have found little
evidence that operating performance improves after takeovers. Franks and
Mayer (1996) found for a sample of UK firms that hostile takeover targets did
not underperform before acquisition, but were subject to the redeployment
of assets afterwards. There are some studies, such as Kaplan (1989), Bhagat,
Shleifer and Vishny (1990), Kaplan and Weisbach (1991) and Healy, Palepu
and Ruback (1992; 1997), that do find changes and improvements in opera33
tions that can at least partially explain takeover premia, so the evidence is
mixed.
Concentrated holdings and monitoring by financial institutions
Stiglitz (1985) has argued that one of the most important ways that value
maximization by firms can be ensured is through concentrated ownership of
the firms shares. Shleifer and Vishny (1986), Huddart (1993) and Admati,
Pfleiderer and Zechner (1994) all model equity financed firms which have
one large shareholder and a fringe of smaller ones. In all these models, more
wealth commitment by owners increases monitoring and firm performance.
Shleifer and Vishny find that firm value increases with the large shareholders
holding but this neednt be true. In Huddart (1993) and Admati, Pfleiderer
and Zechner (1994) the reverse can occur because the large shareholder is
risk averse.
A number of recent theoretical analyses have re-considered important aspects of concentrated ownership. Burkart, Gromb and Panunzi (1997) consider the costs and benefits of monitoring by large shareholders. They show
that such monitoring may restrict the misuse of resources ex post, but may
also blunt ex ante managerial initiative. There is a trade-o between control
and initiative. Bolton and von Thadden (1998a,b) develop a framework to
analyze the trade-o between liquidity and control. Large blocks result in
incentives to monitor but also lead to a lack of liquidity. Pagano and Roell
(1998) consider the trade-o between public and private ownership and monitoring. With private ownership there is monitoring because of shareholder
concentration but no liquidity. Going public is costly and public ownership
results in less monitoring but greater liquidity.
The importance of equity ownership by financial institutions in Japan and
Germany, shown in Table 7, and the lack of a market for corporate control
in these countries have led to the suggestion that the agency problem in
these countries is solved by financial institutions acting as outside monitors
for large corporations. In Japan, this system of monitoring is known as
the main bank system. The characteristics of this system are the long-term
relationship between a bank and its client firm, the holding of both debt
and equity by the bank, and the active intervention of the bank should its
client become financially distressed. It has been widely argued that this
main bank relationship ensures the bank acts as delegated monitor and helps
to overcome the agency problem between managers and the firm. Hoshi,
Kashyap and Scharfstein (1990a, 1990b, 1993) provide evidence that the
main bank system helps firms by easing liquidity constraints and reduces
34
agency costs. They also document that firms reduced their bank ties in the
1980s as access to the bond market became easier. In contrast to Hoshi,
Kashyap and Scharfstein, Hayashi (1997) finds no evidence that main bank
ties ease liquidity constraints. He suggests their results are probably due
to the poor quality of their capital stock estimate. Kang and Shivdasani
(1997) find that companies restructure to a greater extent in response to
adverse circumstances the greater the ownership of the main bank. Aoki and
Patrick (1994) contains a number of studies suggesting that until recently the
eectiveness of the main bank system has been high. A dissenting view is
contained in a paper by Ramseyer (1994) who suggests that the traditional
emphasis in the literature on the importance of this system in achieving
eective corporate governance is too strong. He argues that, if the system
really worked in the way described, explicit contracts should be used much
more than they are in practice. Overall, the main bank system appears
important in times of financial distress, but less important when a firm is
doing well.
In Germany, the data on concentration of ownership probably understate
the significance of the banks eective position. The reason is that many
bank customers keep their shares on deposit at banks and allow banks to
exercise proxies on their behalf. As a result banks control a higher proportion
of voting equity and have more representation on boards of large industrial
enterprises than their direct holdings suggest. A 1978 Monopoly Commission
study found that, of the top 100 corporations, banks controlled the votes of
nearly 40% of the equity and were represented on two thirds of the boards.
German banks thus tend to have very close ties with industry and form longrun relationships with firms. This is the hausbank system. A number of
studies have provided evidence on the eectiveness of the outside monitoring
of German banks. Elston (1993) finds firms with strong ties to a bank are
not as likely to be liquidity-constrained as firms with weaker ties. Cable
(1985) and Gorton and Schmid (2000) find evidence that firms with a higher
proportion of equity controlled by banks have better performance. This
evidence is consistent with the hypothesis that bank involvement helps the
performance of firms, but it is also consistent with the hypothesis that banks
are good at picking winners.
A number of issues concerning the eectiveness of banks as outside monitors arise in the case of Japan and Germany. The first is that banks are
themselves subject to the same agency problems as firms. Charkham (1994;
p.36) points out that, in eect, the big three banks essentially control them35
have an incentive to take risks and may even accept projects that destroy
value if significant amounts of debt are used. Myers (1977) pointed to the
debt overhang problem where firms may forego good projects if they have
significant debt outstanding. The reason is that for a firm facing financial
distress a large part of the returns to a good project go to bondholders.
Perhaps the most important weakness of the argument that debt is important for ensuring managerial discipline in corporations is the fact that
retained earnings are the most important source of finance for corporations,
as Table 6 indicates. In most countries, debt is much less important than
retained earnings. Typically, large corporations can service their debt without diculty, i.e., without constraining their operations or investment plans.
Taggart (1985) has found that during the post-war period, long-term debt
constituted about 35 percent of the market value of large US corporations,
with most of the remainder being made up of equity. Although such firms
have issued relatively little new equity, the significant level of internal finance
through retained earnings has ensured outside equity is (indirectly) the most
important financing instrument.
Product market competition
It has been argued (see, e.g., Alchian (1950) and Stigler (1958)) that competition in product markets is a very powerful force for solving the agency
problem between owners and managers. If the managers of a firm waste or
consume large amounts of resources, the firm will be unable to compete and
will go bankrupt. There is little doubt that competition, particularly internationally, is a powerful force in ensuring eective corporate governance.
Competition between dierent organizational forms may be helpful in
limiting eciency losses. If a family owned business has the sole objective
of maximizing share value, it may force all the corporations in that industry to do the same thing. Hart (1983) develops a model based on this idea.
Unobservable eort leads to managerial slack. Using the assumption that
managers are infinitely risk averse at a particular level of income, Hart is
able to show that aggregate output is lower and price is higher than in the
first best, where every action is contractible. Scharfstein (1988) shows that if
the managers marginal utility of income is strictly positive, increased competition can increase rather than reduce managerial slack. Schmidt (1997)
addresses a related question in a model without hidden information. He
observes that increased competition may threaten the survival of a firm by
forcing it into bankruptcy and asks what eect this may have on managerial
slack. As in Scharfstein (1988), he demonstrates that increased competition
37
38
and are moving in that direction in countries such as Germany. Rajan and
Zingales argue that understanding this reversal requires an analysis of political factors, including the openness of the country to outside influences and
the centralization of the political system.
Another important legal aspect of comparative financial systems is the
form of the bankruptcy code. The literature compares the bankruptcy codes
in use in dierent countries and suggests reforms of these codes. One broad
category of procedures comprises cash auctions, like the US Chapter 7 procedure. Another comprises structured auctions, like the US Chapter 11. Rajan
and Zingales (1995) report that all the countries in their sample have cash
auctions, while those with developed financial markets like Canada and the
US have structured auctions. Stromberg (2000) finds that, in practice, cash
auctions in Sweden work very like reorganization procedures.
In practice there is considerable evidence of deviations from absolute
priority in bankruptcy (see Eberhart, Moore, and Roenfeldt (1990), Weiss
(1990), Franks and Torous (1994) and Betker (1995)). Brown (1989), Bergman
and Callen (1991), Gertner and Scharfstein (1991) provide arguments for deviations from absolute priority. Berkovitch, Israel and Zender (1998) and
Berkovitch and Israel (1999) have argued that deviations from absolute priority can lead to ecient ex ante decisions.
Bebchuk (1988), Aghion, Hart and Moore (1992) and Shleifer and Vishny
(1992) have argued that ineciencies are likely to arise from transaction
costs and illiquidity in cash auctions. Pulvino (1998, 1999) provides some
evidence that market liquidity leads to low value users ending up in control.
Bebchuk (1988) suggested an ingenious scheme of options to overcome the
liquidity problems and dierent valuations by security holders. Aghion, Hart
and Moore (1992) suggest a development of this type of plan that allows
managers to remain in control when they are the highest valued claimants in
the view of the residual claimants.
The intersection of law, finance, and politics contains many interesting
topics for further research.
Historically, financial activity has often taken place without an eective
legal system or with a legal system that did not play an important role
(see, e.g. Greif (2000)). Understanding the operation of such systems
is an important complement to understanding the role of the law.
Even in countries with sophisticated legal systems, reputations and implicit contracts play an important role. Gaining a fuller understanding
41
Financial crises
In addition to the legal system and political factors Allen and Gale (2000a)
have argued that financial crises have had a significant impact on the historical development of financial systems. Prior to the twentieth century
banking crises, currency crises and stock market crashes occurred frequently
in Europe and the US. These crises were generally regarded as a bad thing.
Over time one of the most important roles of central banks came to be to
eliminate panics and ensure financial stability. The Bank of England played
an especially important role in the development of eective stabilization policies in the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries. By the end of the nineteenth
century, banking panics had been eliminated in Europe. The last true panic
in England was the Overend, Gurney & Company Crisis of 1866.
The US took a dierent tack. Alexander Hamilton had been impressed
by the example of the Bank of England and this led to the setting up of
the First Bank of the United States and subsequently the Second Bank of
the United States. However, after Andrew Jackson vetoed the renewal of
the Second Banks charter, the US ceased to have any form of central bank
in 1836. It also had many crises during the nineteenth and early twentieth
centuries. During the crisis of 1907 a French banker commented that the US
was a great financial nuisance. The comment reflects the fact that crises
had to a large extent been eliminated in Europe and it seemed as though the
US was suering gratuitous crises that could have been prevented by setting
up a central bank.
The Federal Reserve System was eventually established in 1914. In the
beginning it had a decentralized structure, which meant that even this development was not very eective in eliminating crises. In fact, major banking
panics continued to occur until the reforms enacted after the crisis of 1933. At
42
that point, the Federal Reserve was given broader powers and this together
with the introduction of deposit insurance finally led to the elimination of
periodic banking crises. Bordo (2000) contains an overview of the historical
literature on crises.
The tight regulations that were imposed on banks in the US and other
countries in response to the experience of the Great Depression meant that
for the period between 1945 and the early 1970s there were no banking crises.
The structure of the Bretton Woods fixed exchange rate system meant that
there were currency crises when a countrys macroeconomic policies were
inconsistent with its exchange rate. Following the collapse of the Bretton
Woods agreement in the early 1970s and the deregulation that followed in
many countries financial crises reemerged. Lindgren, Garcia, and Saal (1996)
find that about three quarters of the IMFs member countries suered some
form of banking crisis between 1980 and 1996. In many of these crises, panics
in the traditional sense were avoided either by central bank intervention or
by explicit or implicit government guarantees. In an important study Kaminsky and Reinhart (1999) found that the advent of financial liberalization in
many economies in the 1980s has led to twin banking and currency crises.
Historical evidence provided by Bordo and Eichengreen (2000) suggests that
twin crises both in recent decades and prior to the First World War have been
fairly similar in a number of respects. In particular in both periods crises
were particularly disruptive in terms of the depth of ensuing recessions. The
recent experience with crises has meant that the susceptibility of dierent
types of financial systems to crises has become one of the most important
areas of comparative financial systems.
Although many crises have occurred in emerging economies many have
also occurred in developed countries. Recent deregulation has often been associated with monetary expansion and lending booms and apparent bubbles
in real estate and stocks. The subsequent bursting of these bubbles has led
to financial crises. The idea that the amount of money and credit available
is an important factor in the determination of asset prices is not new. In
his description of historic bubbles Kindleberger (1978; p. 54) emphasizes the
role of this factor: Speculative manias gather speed through expansion of
money and credit or perhaps, in some cases, get started because of an initial
expansion of money and credit.
Perhaps the best known recent example of this type of phenomenon is
the dramatic rise in real estate and stock prices that occurred in Japan in
the late 1980s and their subsequent collapse in 1990. Financial liberalization
43
throughout the 1980s and the desire to support the United States dollar in
the latter part of the decade led to an expansion in credit. During most of
the 1980s asset prices rose steadily, eventually reaching very high levels. For
example, the Nikkei 225 index was around 10,000 in 1985. On December 19,
1989 it reached a peak of 38,916. A new Governor of the Bank of Japan,
less concerned with supporting the US dollar and more concerned with fighting inflation, tightened monetary policy and this led to a sharp increase in
interest rates in early 1990 (see Frankel (1993) and Tschoegl (1993)). The
bubble burst. The Nikkei 225 fell sharply during the first part of the year
and by October 1, 1990 it had sunk to 20,222. Real estate prices followed a
similar pattern. The next few years were marked by defaults and retrenchment in the financial system. The real economy was adversely aected by
the aftermath of the bubble and growth rates during the 1990s have mostly
been slightly positive or negative, in contrast to most of the post war period
when they were much higher.
Similar events occurred in Norway, Finland and Sweden in the 1980s
(see Heiskanen (1993) and Drees and Pazarbasioglu (1995)). In Norway the
ratio of bank loans to nominal GDP went from 40 percent in 1984 to 68
percent in 1988. Asset prices soared while investment and consumption also
increased significantly. The collapse in oil prices helped burst the bubble and
caused the most severe banking crisis and recession since the war. In Finland
an expansionary budget in 1987 resulted in massive credit expansion. The
ratio of bank loans to nominal GDP increased from 55 percent in 1984 to 90
percent in 1990. Housing prices rose by a total of 68 percent in 1987 and
1988. In 1989 the central bank increased interest rates and imposed reserve
requirements to moderate credit expansion. In 1990 and 1991 the economic
situation was exacerbated by a fall in trade with the Soviet Union. Asset
prices collapsed, banks had to be supported by the government and GDP
shrank by 7 percent. In Sweden a steady credit expansion through the late
1980s led to a property boom. In the fall of 1990 credit was tightened and
interest rates rose. In 1991 a number of banks had severe diculties because
of lending based on inflated asset values. The government had to intervene
and a severe recession followed.
Mexico provides a dramatic illustration of an emerging economy aected
by this type of problem. In the early 1990s the banks were privatized and
a financial liberalization occurred. Perhaps most significantly, reserve requirements were eliminated. Mishkin (1997) documents how bank credit to
private nonfinancial enterprises went from a level of around 10 percent of
44
GDP in the late 1980s to 40 percent of GDP in 1994. The stock market rose
significantly during the early 1990s. In 1994 the Colosio assassination and
the uprising in Chiapas triggered the collapse of the bubble. The prices of
stocks and other assets fell and banking and foreign exchange crises occurred.
These were followed by a severe recession.
These examples suggest a relationship between the occurrence of significant rises in asset prices or positive bubbles and monetary and credit policy.
They also illustrate that the collapse in the bubble can lead to severe problems because the fall in asset prices leads to strains on the banking sector.
Banks holding real estate and stocks with falling prices (or with loans to the
owners of these assets) often come under severe pressure from withdrawals
because their liabilities are fixed. This forces them to call in loans and liquidate their assets which in turn appears to exacerbate the problem of falling
asset prices. In other words there may be negative asset price bubbles as
well as positive ones. These negative bubbles, in which asset prices fall too
far, can damage the banking system and unnecessarily exacerbate problems
in the real economy. Just as monetary and credit policy can cause positive
price bubbles, monetary policy may also have a role to play in preventing
asset prices from falling too far. In the Scandinavian and Mexican examples,
discussed above, asset prices quickly rebounded and the spillovers to the real
economy were relatively short-lived. In Japan, asset prices did not rebound
and the real economy has been much less robust.
Theories of banking crises
There are two traditional views of banking panics. One is that they are
random events, unrelated to changes in the real economy. The classical form
of this view suggests that panics are the result of mob psychology or mass
hysteria (see, e.g., Kindleberger (1978)). The modern version, developed by
Diamond and Dybvig (1983) and others, is that bank runs are self-fulfilling
prophecies. Given the assumption of first-come, first-served and costly liquidation of some assets there are multiple equilibria. If everyone believes that
a banking panic is about to occur, it is optimal for each individual to try to
withdraw her funds. Since each bank has insucient liquid assets to meet
all of its commitments, it will have to liquidate some of its assets at a loss.
Given first-come, first-served, those depositors who withdraw initially will
receive more than those who wait. On the one hand, anticipating this, all
depositors have an incentive to withdraw immediately. On the other hand,
if no one believes a banking panic is about to occur, only those with immediate needs for liquidity will withdraw their funds. Assuming that banks
45
have sucient liquid assets to meet these legitimate demands, there will be
no panic. Which of these two equilibria occurs depends on extraneous variables or sunspots. Although sunspots have no eect on the real data
of the economy, they aect depositors beliefs in a way that turns out to be
self-fulfilling. (Postlewaite and Vives (1987) have shown how runs can be
generated in a model with a unique equilibrium).
An alternative to the sunspot view is that banking panics are a natural
outgrowth of the business cycle. An economic downturn will reduce the
value of bank assets, raising the possibility that banks are unable to meet
their commitments. If depositors receive information about an impending
downturn in the cycle, they will anticipate financial diculties in the banking
sector and try to withdraw their funds. This attempt will precipitate the
crisis. According to this interpretation, panics are not random events but a
response to unfolding economic circumstances.
A number of authors have developed models of banking panics caused by
aggregate risk. Wallace (1988; 1990), Chari (1989) and Champ, Smith, and
Williamson (1996) extend Diamond and Dybvig (1983) by assuming the fraction of the population requiring liquidity is random. Chari and Jagannathan
(1988), Jacklin and Bhattacharya (1988), Hellwig (1994), and Alonso (1996)
introduce aggregate uncertainty which can be interpreted as business cycle
risk. Chari and Jagannathan (1988) focus on a signal extraction problem
where part of the population observes a signal about future returns. Others
must then try to deduce from observed withdrawals whether an unfavorable
signal was received by this group or whether liquidity needs happen to be
high. Chari and Jagannathan are able to show panics occur not only when
the outlook is poor but also when liquidity needs turn out to be high. Jacklin
and Bhattacharya (1988) also consider a model where some depositors receive
an interim signal about risk. They show that the optimality of bank deposits
compared to equities depends on the characteristics of the risky investment.
Hellwig (1994) considers a model where the reinvestment rate is random
and shows that the risk should be born both by early and late withdrawers.
Alonso (1996) demonstrates using numerical examples that contracts where
runs occur may be better than contracts which ensure runs do not occur
because they improve risk sharing.
Building on the empirical work of Gorton (1988) and Calomiris and Gorton (1991) that nineteenth century banking crises were predicted by leading
economic indicators, Allen and Gale (1998) develop a model that is consistent
with the business cycle view of the origins of banking panics. In their model,
46
crises can improve risk sharing but they also involve deadweight costs if they
cause projects to be prematurely liquidated. A central bank can avoid these
deadweight costs and implement an optimal allocation of resources through
an appropriate monetary policy. By creating fiat money and lending it to
banks, the central bank can prevent the inecient liquidation of investments
while at the same time allowing optimal sharing of risks.
Theories of currency crises and twin crises
The large movements in exchange rates that occurred in many East Asian
countries in 1997 have revived interest in the topic of currency crises. In many
of the early models of currency crises, such as Krugman (1979), currency
crises occur because of inconsistent and unsustainable government policies
(see Flood and Marion (1998) for a survey of the literature on currency
crises). These models were designed to explain the problems experienced
by a number of Latin American countries in the 1970s and early 1980s.
In the recent East Asian crises, by contrast, many of the countries which
experienced problems had pursued macroeconomic policies that were consistent and sustainable. This characteristic of the recent crises has prompted a
re-examination of theoretical models of currency crises.
The other characteristic of the South East Asian crises that has received
considerable attention is that the banking systems of these countries also
experienced crises. Kaminsky and Reinhart (1999) have investigated the
relationship between banking crises and currency crises. They find that in
the 1970s, when financial systems were highly regulated in many countries,
currency crises were not accompanied by banking crises. However, after the
financial liberalization that occurred during the 1980s, currency crises and
banking crises became intertwined. The usual sequence of events is that
initial problems in the banking sector are followed by a currency crisis and
this in turn exacerbates and deepens the banking crisis. Although banking
crises typically precede currency crises, the common cause of both is usually
a fall in asset values due to a recession or a weak economy. Often the fall is
part of a boom-bust cycle that follows financial liberalization. It appears to
be rare that banking and currency crises occur when economic fundamentals
are sound.
Despite the apparent inter-relationship between currency crises and banking crises in recent episodes, the literatures on the two topics have for the
most part developed separately. Important exceptions are Chang and Velasco
(1998, 2000). The first paper develops a model of currency and banking crises
based on the Diamond and Dybvig (1983) model of bank runs. Chang and
47
(1998) to consider twin crises. A model is developed where the twin crises
result from low asset returns. Large movements in exchange rates are desirable to the extent that they allow better risk sharing between a countrys
bank depositors and the international bond market.
Bubbles and crises
As the historical summary at the beginning of the section indicated, crises
often follow apparent bubbles in asset prices. Allen and Gale (2000d) provide
a theory of bubbles and ensuing crises based on the existence of an agency
problem. Many investors in real estate and stock markets obtain their investment funds from external sources. If the ultimate providers of funds
are unable to observe the characteristics of the investment, there is a classic
risk shifting problem. Risk shifting increases the return to investment in the
assets and causes investors to bid up the asset price above its fundamental
value. A crucial determinant of asset prices is the amount of credit that is
provided for speculative investment. Financial liberalization, by expanding
the volume of credit for speculative investments, can interact with the agency
problem and lead to a bubble in asset prices.
An alternative theory of financial crises has been suggested by McKinnon
and Pill (1997) and Krugman (1998). They suggest that government guarantees are the fundamental cause of crises. Because deposits are guaranteed by
the government, banks are not subject to the usual discipline of the market.
This allows banks to engage in speculative investment, which bids up asset
prices and creates a bubble that eventually bursts. It can be argued that
while government guarantees can certainly exacerbate the situation, they are
neither necessary nor sucient for the occurrence of a crisis. Many crises
occurred when there was no prospect of a government guarantee for banks.
The US in the late 1920s and early 1930s witnessed a dramatic rise in asset prices and a subsequent crisis when no government guarantees existed.
The US in the 1950s and 1960s provides an example where government
guarantees of the banking system existed but no crisis occurred.
Contagion and financial fragility
The prevalence of financial crises has led many to conclude that the financial sector is unusually susceptible to shocks. One theory is that small shocks
can have a large impact. A shock that initially aects only a particular region or sector or perhaps even a few institutions can spread by contagion to
the rest of the financial sector and then infect the larger economy. There
are a number of dierent types of contagion that have been suggested in the
literature. The first is contagion through interlinkages between banks and
49
Concluding remarks
52
References
Admati, A. (1989). Information in Financial Markets: The Rational
Expectations Approach, in Financial Markets and Incomplete Information:
Frontiers of Modern Financial Theory, Volume 2, edited by S. Bhattacharya
and G. M. Constantinides, Totowa, NJ: Rowman and Littlefield, 139-152.
Admati, A., P. Pfleiderer and J. Zechner (1994). Large Shareholder Activism, Risk Sharing, and Financial Market Equilibrium, Journal of Political
Economy 102, 1097-1130.
Aghion, P., P. Bolton and M. Dewatripont (1999). Contagious Bank
Failures, working paper, Princeton University.
Aghion, P., O. Hart and J. Moore (1992). The Economics of Bankruptcy
Reform, Journal of Law and Economics 8, 523-546.
Alchian, A. (1950). Uncertainty, Evolution, and Economic Theory,
Journal of Political Economy 58, 211-221.
Allen, F. (1983). A Normative Analysis of Informational Eciency in
Markets for Risky Assets, mimeo, Nueld College, Oxford.
(1993). Stock Markets and Resource Allocation in C. Mayer and
X. Vives, eds., Capital Markets and Financial Intermediation, Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
(1995). Book review of Strong Managers, Weak Owners by M. Roe,
Princeton University Press, Journal of Economic Literature, 33, 1994-1996.
Allen, F. and D. Gale (1995). A Welfare Comparison of Intermediaries
and Financial Markets in Germany and the U.S., European Economic Review 39, 179-209.
(1997). Financial Markets, Intermediaries, and Intertemporal Smoothing, Journal of Political Economy 105 (1997) 523-546.
(1998). Optimal Financial Crises. Journal of Finance 53, 1245-1284.
(1999). Diversity of Opinion and the Financing of New Technologies,
Journal of Financial Intermediation 8, 68-89.
(2000a). Comparing Financial Systems, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
(2000b). Corporate Governance and Competition in Vives (2000).
(2000c). Optimal Currency Crises, Carnegie Rochester Series on
Public Policy (forthcoming).
(2000d). Bubbles and Crises, Economic Journal 110, 236-255.
(2000e). Financial Contagion, Journal of Political Economy 108,
1-33.
53
55
Bhattacharya, U. (1997). Communication Costs, Information Acquisition, and Voting Decisions in Proxy Contests, Review of Financial Studies
10, 1065-1097.
Bolton, P. and E. von Thadden (1998a). Blocks, Liquidity, and Corporate Control, Journal of Finance 53, 1-25.
(1998b). Liquidity and Control: A Dynamic Theory of Corporate
Ownership Structure, Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics
154, 177-223.
Boot, A., S. Greenbaum and A. Thakor (1993). Reputation and Discretion in Financial Contracting, American Economic Review 83, 1165-1183.
Boot, A., and A. Thakor (1997a). Financial System Architecture, Review of Financial Studies 10, 693-733.(1997b).
(1997b) Banking Scope and Financial Innovation, Review of Financial Studies 10, 1099-1131.
(2000). Can Relationship Banking Survive Competition? Journal
of Finance 55, 679-713.
Bordo, M. (2000). The Globalization of International Financial Markets:
What can History Teach Us, Working Paper, Sveriges Riksbank, Stockholm.
Bordo, M. and B. Eichengreen (2000). Is the Crisis Problem Growing
More Severe, Working Paper, Sveriges Riksbank, Stockholm.
Boyd, J. and B. Smith. (1996). The Co-Evolution of the Real and
Financial Sectors in the Growth Process, World Bank Economic Review
10(2), 371-96.
(1998). The Evolution of Debt and Equity Markets in Economic
Development, Economic Theory 12(3), 519-60.
Brown, D. (1989). Claimholder Incentive Conflicts in Reorganization:
The Role of Bankruptcy Law, Review of Financial Studies 2, 109-23.
Brealey, R. and S. Myers (2000). Principles of Corporate Finance, 6th
edition, New York: McGraw Hill Irwin.
Burkart, M. (1995). Initial Shareholdings and Overbidding in Takeover
Contests, Journal of Finance 50, 1491-1515.
Burkart, M., D. Gromb and F. Panunzi (1997). Large Shareholders,
Monitoring, and the Value of the Firm, Quarterly Journal of Economics
112, 693-728.
Cable, J. (1985). Capital Market Information and Industrial Performance, Economic Journal 95, 118-132.
Calomiris, C. and G. Gorton (1991). The Origins of Banking Panics,
Models, Facts, and Bank Regulation, in R. G. Hubbard (ed.), Financial
56
57
59
60
62
63
64
65
66
68
69
Table 1
Holdings of Corporate Equities in the U.S. (in percent)
_________________________________________________________________
Sector
1950
1970
1990
2000
_________________________________________________________________
Private Pension funds
0.8
8.0
16.8
12.9
0.0
1.2
7.6
10.3
1.5
1.7
2.3
5.4
1.8
1.6
2.3
1.1
Mutual funds
2.0
4.7
6.6
19.0
Closed-end funds
1.1
0.5
0.5
0.3
0.0
10.4
5.4
1.9
Foreign sector
2.0
3.2
6.9
8.9
90.2
68.0
51.0
39.1
0.6
0.6
0.7
1.2
Household sector
Other
__________________________________________________________________
Total equities outstanding
142.7
841.4
3,542.6
19,047.1
(billions of dollars)
__________________________________________________________________
Source: Federal Reserve Board Flow of Funds, www.bog.frb.fed.us. Figures
are for the end of period except for 2000, where the figures are for the third
quarter.
70
Table 2
Unweighted Average Gross Financing of Nonfinancial Enterprises 1970-1989 (% of total)
Internal
Bank Finance
Bonds
New Equity
Trade Credit
Capital Transfers
Other
Statistical Adjustment
US
91.3
16.6
17.1
-8.8
-3.7
-3.8
-8.7
UK
97.3
19.5
3.5
-10.4
-1.4
2.5
-2.9
-8
71
Japan
69.3
30.5
4.7
3.7
-8.1
-0.1
0
France
60.6
40.6
1.3
6
-2.8
1.9
-6.5
2.5
Germany
80.6
11
-0.6
0.9
-1.9
8.5
1.5
0
Table 3
An International Comparison of Banks and Markets in 1993
(All figures in billions of dollars)
U.S.
U.K.
Japan
France
Germany
GDP
Banking
Assets
(BA)
BA/GDP
$6,301
$824
$4,242
$1,261
$1,924
$3,319
$2,131
$6,374
$1,904
$2,919
53%
259%
150%
151%
152%
72
82%
140%
71%
36%
24%
Table 4
Total Gross Financial Assets Ultimately Owned by the Household Sector
Country
$ billion
Value relative
to GDP
% held directly
by households
U.S.
U.K.
Japan
France
Germany
20,815
3,107
12,936
2,689
2,900
3.00
2.97
2.71
1.90
1.46
58
40
71
62
67
Note:
% held by
pension funds
(public and
private)
17
24
10
2
4
% held by
insurance
companies
% held in
mutual funds,
etc.
13
27
16
17
20
10
7
3
19
5
1. Aggregation of direct asset holdings, pension fund assets, assets of insurance companies and assets
in mutual funds and other collective investment schemes at the end of 1994.
73
Table 5
Number of Members on Boards of Directors
U.S.1
Ford
15 (10)
Glaxo
16 (7)
Toyota
60 (1)
France1
Saint Gobain 16
IBM
14 (11)
Hanson
19 (8)
Hitachi
36 (3)
AGF
19 (5)
BASF
28 10
Exxon
12 (9)
Guinness
10 (6)
Matsushita
37 (6)
Usinor Sacilor
21 (5)
20 11
Mobil
16 (10)
10 (6)
Nissan
49 (5)
22
16
12 (4)
Toshiba
40 (3)
11
Bayer
22 11
14 (1)
Honda
37 (3)
Alcatel
Alsthom
Elf
Aquitaine
Renault
15
Philip Morris
British
Airways
Allied
Domecq
Grand
Metropolitan
BTR
Robert
Bosch
Krupp
18
20
10 (4)
Sony
41 (6)
Thomson
Daimler
Benz
Volkswagen
20
7 (1)
NEC
42 (5)
Thyssen
23 27
8 (0)
Fujitsu
36 (7)
Siemens
20 15
RJR Nabisco
U.K.1
(4)
9 (6)
Texaco
13 (11)
Johnson
& Johnson
GAP
14 (12)
11
(8)
Associated
British Foods
British Steel
Japan1
Mitsubishi
37
Electric
Mitsubishi
43
Motors
Mitsubishi
43
Heavy Industries
Nippon Steel
53
(3)
(4)
(3)
(1)
Mazda
45 (8)
Nippon Oil
22 (0)
Germany2
Hoechst
21 11
75
Table 6
Regulations on Shareholding of Financial Institutions and Nonfinancial Corporations
Banks
U.S.
Banks: Cannot hold shares of other corporations (GlassSteagall Act).
Bank holding companies: Holdings are limited to a
maximum of 5% of the shares of nonfinancial corporations
Trusts: Holdings are limited to a maximum of 10% of the
funds assets in any one companys shares.
Varies by state. For instance, under New York State Law
(which applies to 60% of all insurance companies),
investments must be less than 20% of assets or a maximum
of 50% of surpluses. Holdings of the shares of any single
company are limited to 2% of total assets.
Prohibition on holding a non-insurance company in its
entirety.
Tax penalty imposed on holdings in excess of 10% of the
stock of any single company.
Under the Employee Retirement Income Securities Act,
investment diversification is required. Holdings in excess of
10% of the pension funds own stock are prohibited.
Holding of stock which results in restricting competition is
prohibited.
76
U.K.
No special regulations on holdings. However, in the case of
large volume acquisitions of shares, advance permission of
the bank of England is required. A report to the Bank of
England is required when exposure (all claims including
shares invested) exceeds 10% of a banks total capital. (See
note 1.)
Voluntary self-limitation of holding of stock in any single
company (normally 2.5% of assets), for the purpose of
portfolio diversification. A maximum (normally 5% of
assets) is imposed on the amount of stock in any single
company which a pension fund or insurance company can
hold on its own.
Same as above
Under laws regulating financial services holding of stock
for the purpose of controlling a company is prohibited.
Same as for insurance companies.
Under The City Code on Takeovers and Mergers, the
mutual holding of shares the purpose of which is to prevent
the transfer of control of stock is prohibited.
Table 6 (cont.)
Banks
Japan
Under Article 11 of the AntiMonopoly Law holdings are limited
to 5% of the total number of issued
shares of a domestic company.
France
The holding of shares of any single
nonfinancial corporation is limited to
a maximum of 15% of the banks
capital. Total holdings of all shares
cannot exceed 60% of all the banks
capital.
Germany
Holdings greater than 10% are
permitted, but only up to the value of
the banks capital. (See note 1).
No regulations.
No regulations.
No regulations.
A subsidiary whose parent company
owns more than half of its stock
cannot hold stock in its parent
company.
Mutual holding of shares is possible,
but voting rights are limited to 25% of
all voting rights, even when a
company owns more than 25% of the
stock of another company.
Establishment of holding companies
is permitted (in the case of pure
holding companies and management
holding companies).
Notes: 1. The U.K. and Germany are scheduled to make modifications to their regulations as EU integration progresses.
2. Japan is scheduled to make changes to its laws on holding companies as part of the Big Bang reform of its financial system.
Source: Institute of Fiscal and Monetary Policy (1996), Chart III-2-3, p. 60.
77
Table 7
Comparison of Shareholders by Sector
(% of Total)
U.S.
U.K.
Japan
France
Germany
Individuals
Pension funds,
etc.
Financial
Institutions
Nonfinancial
Corporations
Public sector
50
20
23
34
17
20
31
5
30
41
23
22
14
3
25
21
42
0
4
1
2
5
Foreign
individuals
and
institutions
5
12
4
20
14
Other
6
6
Notes: 1. Data is for 1990 except for France which is for 1992.
Source: Prowse (1995), Table 2, p. 13 for U.S. and Institute of Fiscal and Monetary Policy (1996), Chart III-2-1, p. 59 for the other
countries.
78
Figure 1
Ja
pa
n
Fr
an
ce
G
er
m
an
y
U
K
25,000
20,000
15,000
10,000
5,000
0
U
S
$ billion
Figure 2
3.5
3
2.5
2
1.5
1
0.5
0
US
UK
Germany
79
France
Japan