Ecological Economics: Themes, Approaches, and Differences With Environmental Economics
Ecological Economics: Themes, Approaches, and Differences With Environmental Economics
Background
The eld known as ``Ecological Economics'' (EE) was
founded at the end of the 1980s. 1 It immediately attracted
a large number of researchers from various disciplinary
backgrounds that were involved in the study of environmental issues. EE very quickly developed into a eld that
was successful in several respects (Costanza and King
1999): many publications and citations to these were
produced; regular conferences and workshops were held;
and communication among disciplines and countries, as
13
Original article
14
Original article
5
ERE in general emphasises uncertainty and instability within the
economy (macroeconomic stability, business cycles) rather than environmental uncertainty. Nevertheless, ERE has made many contributions to studying environmental uncertainty in specic cases,
notably in the context of climate change modelling, and related to the
notions of option value and quasi-option value [see a special issue of
Resource and Energy Economics on ``Irreversibilities'' (Fisher 2000)]
15
Original article
Table 1
Differences in emphasis between EE and ERE
Ecological economics
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.
9.
10.
11.
12.
13.
14.
15.
16.
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.
9.
10.
11.
12.
13.
14.
15.
16.
Optimal scale
Priority to sustainability
Needs fullled and equitable distribution
Sustainable development, globally and North/South
Growth pessimism and difcult choices
Unpredictable co-evolution
Long-term focus
Complete, integrative and descriptive
Concrete and specic
Physical and biological indicators
Systems analysis
Multidimensional evaluation
Integrated models with causeeffect relationships
Bounded individual rationality and uncertainty
Local communities
Environmental ethics
Original article
especially in view of EE being diverse and not characterised by a univocal theory. Moreover, some of the
shortcomings of ERE (according to EE) can be resolved
within the traditional theoretical framework of neoclassical economics. For instance, environmental externalities
can be modelled by describing dynamic causality relationships on the basis of ecological insights. Crocker and
Tschirhart (1992) show that it is possible to incorporate
descriptions of ecosystems within a wider framework of
general equilibrium with externalities. Finally, the objective of sustainable development is also broadly supported
nowadays by ERE, although denitions and interpretations are not always consistent with those adopted by EE
(see next section).
In evaluating the differences between EE and ERE, it is
interesting to note that one of the most inuential biologists of this century, E.O. Wilson, has recently introduced the criterion ``consilience'' as a measure of good
science (Wilson 1998). This denotes that the methods and
starting points of one scientic discipline need to be
consistent with the accepted insights of other disciplines,
across all areas of science, including the natural and
social sciences. Gowdy and Ferrer-i-Carbonell (1999) offer a discussion of ``consilience'' between biology and
economics, the two most important disciplines supporting EE, in order to examine to what extent economists
and ecologists have inuenced each other's way of
thinking about environmental problems and their solutions. Within EE, a dominant idea is that ERE approaches
need to be made coherent with ndings in ecology and
thermodynamics. Nevertheless, this is complicated due to
distinct research traditions and methods (Shogren and
Nowell 1992). In addition, consistency with insights from
technical and other social sciences is also necessary.
Particularly with regard to modelling consumer and rm
behaviour for environmental policy analysis and monetary valuation, insights from psychology and sociology
could be useful.
17
Original article
International trade
and environment
The development of ERE during the 1990s is characterised by considerable attention to the international dimension of environmental problems and policy, in
particular the relationship between international trade
and environmental policy. The classical trade theories of
Ricardo and Heckscher-Ohlin state that, on the basis of
comparative advantages, international trade increases the
welfare of all contributing countries. Daly and Cobb
(1989) are, however, of the opinion that these insights no
longer hold as the assumption of immobile capital ows
is no longer satised in their view, the modern world is
characterised by free capital ows (capital mobility). This
viewpoint suggests the need for a fundamental discussion
about the relevance of traditional trade theories for formulating environmental policy. Daly and Cobb conclude,
by referring to statements of Maynard Keynes, which
reect the idea that production of products should,
whenever feasible, take place in the own country. An
additional argument for this view is that sustainability at
a regional scale can be better controlled in an autarchic
than in an open region.
In order to ``measure'' regional unsustainability Wackernagel and Rees (1996) have formulated the concept of the
``ecological footprint'' (EF) and applied it to countries (as
well as other spatial units). They conclude that many
countries, in particular small ones, use directly and indirectly more surface area than is available inside their
national boundaries. Evidently, this is compensated by
international trade. Wackernagel and Rees try to argue on
the basis of the EF that autarchy is to be preferred to a
trading region. Van den Bergh and Verbruggen (1999)
criticise the EF indicator and applications:
8
The work of Ruth and Cleveland (1996), which focuses on the
relation between extraction of mineral resources and fossil fuel (energy) resources, ts into this tradition. Extraction of resources is
associated with a transformation of enormous amounts of energy,
both in the extraction process itself and in subsequent processes, such 1. The EF is an example of ``false concreteness'': the
as concentration, smelting, ltering and rening. In order to extract
resulting land area is hypothetical and too crude a
resources from supplies with low concentrations of a desired material,
measure of various types of environmental pressure.
the amount of energy use per useful unit of output needs to rise, and
increasingly so. This means that energy use will follow a progressive 2. The EF method does not distinguish between sustainpattern over time. Technological improvements and recycling can
able and unsustainable land use, notably in agriculture.
slow down the unfolding of such a pattern, but not permanently
3.
Aggregation of different environmental problems
postpone it. Such a type of EE model of extraction is less partial than
occurs through an implicit weighting that lacks any
the traditional, Hotelling type of ERE model (see Dasgupta and Heal
justication.
1979)
18
Original article
A hierarchy of dynamics
In the earlier section on `Ecological versus traditional
environmental economics', it was indicated that EE is
more closely related to resource economics than to the
``economics of pollution''. Perhaps this is best illustrated
by the fact that simple models from population biology
(ecology) have been incorporated in ERE theory of
renewable resources. Specic models have been developed
for the analysis of sheries, forestry and water management.
EE uses more information from ecology for modelling
human inuences on nature and environment than ERE
(see Folke 1999). This includes population dynamics based
on interactive populations, such as symmetric (competition, mutualism) and asymmetric (herbivoreplant, parasitehost, predatorprey) relationships, on multiple
9
For a variety of opinions about the Ecological Footprint, see the
discussion in Ecological Economics vol. 31, no. 3, pp. 317321, as well
as the 12 contributions by economists and ecologists in the Forum of
Ecological Economics vol. 32, no. 3, pp. 341393
generations, or on spatially disaggregated (meta-) populations. Ecosystem models add relationships between biotic and abiotic processes to these population models, for
example the inuence of nutrients on the presence and
growth of certain plant species. An additional level of
dynamics is ecosystem succession, by which the composition, structure and functions of an ecosystem change
until a climax system has been reached An alternative view
proposes a cyclic process without any climax. The theory
often referred to in this context is the ``four-box model''
for terrestrial ecosystems (Holling 1986). It depicts ecosystems and their changes in a two-dimensional diagram
with ``stored capital'' (biomass) and ``connectedness''
(complexity of the foodweb) on the axes. Ecosystems can
then go through four phases: ``exploitation'', ``conservation'', ``release'' and ``reorganisation''. The ``release'' phase,
for instance, is triggered by forest res, storms and outbreak of diseases.
The dynamics of ecosystems has given rise to a question
about the stability and resilience of ecosystems. EE devotes
much attention to this issue. At the moment, resilience is
even examined as an analogy for the functioning of social
systems (bureaucracy, politics, economy, etc.; see Levin
et al. 1998). In the above-mentioned ``four-box model'',
management aimed at articially prolonging a certain
phase, notably ``conservation'', can reduce the resilience of
the system. For example, checking small forest res, which
leave seeds intact, will result in an accumulation of forest
biomass. This in turn will increase the probability of the
occurrence of a large forest re at a very high temperature,
which in turn can destroy plant seeds and thus prevent the
``reorganisation'' phase from occurring successfully.
A last level of dynamics that is studied within ecology and
EE is evolution. Within biology, evolutionary theory has
provided the necessary integration of various subdisciplines, such as molecular biology, genetics, cell biology,
physiology, development biology and ecology. Within EE,
(co-)evolution is regarded as a conceptual model for addressing the relationship between economy and environment in the long-run. This connects closely to an historical
approach to the analysis of the interaction between economic development, environmental change, technology
change and institutional change. Examples of such interactions are: the inception of the Industrial Revolution
(Wilkinson 1973; Norgaard 1994); the historical transition
from the huntergatherers era to primitive agricultural
societies (Gowdy 1994, 1998); and perhaps even the
current wave of technological innovations in the areas
of biotechnology and information and communication
technology.
Important implications of this hierarchy of dynamic processes are as follows. In the rst place, a sufciently large
disturbance by humans will not only create a temporary
removal from an equilibrium, but will also lead to dynamic
effects throughout the hierarchy of dynamics. This can
have irreversible consequences, for example when ecosystem components and functions are lost.
The complexity of temporal dynamics often requires an
explicitly spatial approach: for example, land use, water
19
Original article
Individual behaviour
and environmental policy
EE criticises the points of departure of ERE with regard to
individual behaviour but generally supports its central
ndings on policy, which can best be summarised as
``correct prices''. The criticism could, however, give rise to
a study of alternative models of individual behaviour and
their implications for environmental policy. The rst results of such a research programme suggest that price
instruments could certainly be less effective than is often
taken for granted (van den Bergh et al. 2000). Furthermore, inuencing preferences could become an important
pillar of environmental policy aimed at realising long-term
sustainable development (Norton et al. 1998). Normative
objections against preference-oriented policies are outmoded; indeed, preferences have long been moulded
through advertisements by private businesses for purely
commercial interests. Nevertheless, environmental policies
aimed at inuencing preferences will be effective only if
complementary instruments like environmental legislation
and other types of environmental regulation are employed
For example, to reduce speeding by cars one can combine:
downsizing of car engines, technical speed controllers on
engines, prohibiting advertisements of fast cars, and
obligatory driving-style courses.
A general difference between environmental policy
according to EE and ERE, as indicated in the section `Ecological versus traditional environmental economics', concerns the difference between the main goals. ERE focuses on
internalising, or more precisely ``optimising'', external
costs. Economic or market-based instruments t well in this
scheme as they provide incentives to individual producers
and consumers which, according to the theory, lead to social efciency (``marginal social costs equal marginal social
benets''). EE is aimed at sustainability and emphasises the
precautionary principle in dealing with complexity (ecosystems), surprises (environmental disasters) and uncertain developments (climate change). Common and Perrings
(1992) use a theoretical model to analytically illustrate that
economicecological systems are not completely ``observable'' and ``controllable'' via prices and instruments that
directly inuence prices. In other words, price instruments
fall short in the case of sustainability.
A number of instruments have been proposed to address
the uncertainty and complexity surrounding ecosystems
and sustainability. The notion of ``safe minimum standards'' (Ciriacy-Wantrup 1952) points to the fact that
efciency means exploring the borders, whereas in many
20
circumstances characterised by a large degree of uncertainty it would be better to take account of safety margins.
A exible instrument to do this is an ``environmental
bond'' (Costanza and Perrings 1990). An investment or
project that is surrounded by a great deal of uncertainty
concerning environmental consequences is complemented
by an insurance bond with a value equal to that of the
maximum expected environmental damage. This bond
functions as a deposit that is completely or partly refunded
(with interest) depending on the amount of environmental
damage that has resulted from the respective investment
project. If environmental damages are nil, the entire deposit is returned; if there are actual or threatening negative
environmental effects, the deposit serves to compensate or
prevent damage. This instrument can, inter alia, be applied
to land reclamation, investment in infrastructure, transport and treatment of hazardous (toxic, nuclear) substances, and location of agriculture and industrial
activities near sensitive nature areas. As a consequence of
environmental bonds, the (expected) private costs of such
activities will increase, causing investors to make more
conservative decisions, and so take account of environmental risks associated with human activities and investment projects.
Uncertainty within ERE is usually analysed by dening
``states of the world'' with associated probabilities, and
maximising an expected benet function. Fundamental or
complete uncertainty, i.e. surprises, implies, according to
EE, a different approach, namely, ``adaptive management''.
This is based on the idea that management of complex and
uncontrollable systems requires an interaction between
experimental research, monitoring, learning processes,
and policy choices, with the objective to learn from disturbances. This recipe has been applied to problems of
sheries, agriculture (ecological alternatives for pesticides)
and forestry. Adaptive management also covers the interaction between various disciplines, experts and ``stakeholders'' (Holling 1978; Walters 1986; Lee 1993;
Gunderson et al. 1995).
Finally, within EE, ideas can be found about economic
structural change, notably, relating to ``industrial ecology'' and ``industrial metabolism'' (see Ayres 1998; Duchin
et al. 1994; Socolow et al. 1994; Graedel and Allenby
1995). These emphasise spatial and sectoral adjustments
of economic activities to realise a minimal environmental
pressure caused by substance and material ows. For this
purpose, a balance between such strategies as ``dematerialisation", recycling and reuse, waste management and
increasing durability of products is needed.
Conclusion
The themes discussed in the previous sections illustrate
that a simple, one-dimensional opposition between EE
and ERE is impossible. Moreover, searching for interactions and complementarity between EE and ERE seems
fruitful. There certainly is overlap, partly because EE is
not strictly conned ERE represents a specialist, analytic
Original article
10
Spash (1999) notes that the European branch of the International Society for Ecological Economics tends to focus more on socioeconomics and political economy (including philosophy, environmental ethics, institutional economics, sociology and political ecology), whereas the American approach can be characterised as more
scientic. The most fundamental issue raised by the European EE in
this respect is perhaps that it looks for alternatives to free market
systems, as these ``...educate individuals to act as selsh hedonists and
create self-perpetuating power structures which reinforce inequity''
(Spash 1999, p. 428). Three journals, Environmental Ethics, Environmental Politics and Environmental Values, provide information
regarding these alternative perspectives
11
In the USA, the distinction between ERE and EE is clearer than
in Europe, presumably because ERE is more developed and more
strictly applied in Europe, there seems to be somewhat more room for
pluralism and pragmatism, as well as for discussion of the shortcomings of ERE
References
AYRES RU (1998) Industrial metabolism: work in progress. In:
Bergh JCJM van den, Hofkes MW (eds) Theory and implementation of economic models for sustainable development.
Kluwer, Dordrecht
AYRES RU, KNEESE AV (1969) Production, consumption and externalities. Am Econ Rev 59:282297
AYRES RU, BERGH JCJM VAN DEN, GOWDY JM (2000) Weak versus
strong sustainability: economics, natural sciences and consilience. Environ Ethics (in press)
BAUMOL WJ, OATES WE (1988) The theory of environmental policy, 2nd edn. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge
BERGH JCJM VAN DEN (1996) Ecological economics and sustainable
development: theory, methods and applications. Edward Elgar,
Cheltenham
BERGH JCJM VAN DEN, HOFKES MW (eds) (1998) Theory and implementation of economic models for sustainable development.
Kluwer, Dordrecht
BERGH JCJM VAN DEN, DE MOOIJ RA (1999) An assessment of the
growth debate. In: van den Bergh JCJM (ed) Handbook of environmental and resource economics. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham
BERGH JCJM VAN DEN, STRAATEN J VAN DER (eds) (1994) Toward
sustainable development: concepts, methods and policy. Island
Press, Washington, DC
BERGH JCJM VAN DEN, STRAATEN J VAN DER (eds) (1997) Economy
and ecosystems in change: analytical and historical approaches.
Edward Elgar, Cheltenham
BERGH JCJM van DEN, VERBRUGGEN H (1999) Spatial sustainability,
trade and indicators: an evaluation of the `ecological footprint'.
Ecol Econ 29(1):6374
BERGH JCJM VAN DEN, FERRER-I-CARBONELL A, MUNDA G (2000)
Alternative models of individual behaviour and implications
for environmental policy. Ecol Econ 32(1):4361
BLAMEY RK, COMMON MS (1999) Valuation and ethics in
environmental economics In: van den Bergh JCJM (ed) Handbook of environmental and resource economics. Edward Elgar,
Cheltenham
BOULDING KE (1966) The economics of the coming spaceship
earth. In: Jarret H (ed) Environmental quality in a growing
economy. Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore
BOULDING KE (1970) Economics as a Science. McGraw-Hill,
London
BOULDING KE (1978) Ecodynamics: a new theory of societal evolution. Sage Publications, Beverly Hills
BRAAT LC, VAN LIEROP WFJ (eds) (1987) Economic-ecological
modelling. North-Holland, Amsterdam
BRUYN SM DE, HEINTZ RJ (1999) The environmental Kuznets curve
hypothesis. In van den Bergh JCJM (ed) Handbook of environmental and resource economics. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham
CHRISTENSEN PP (1989) Historical roots for ecological economics: biophysical versus allocative approaches. Ecol Econ
1(1):1736
CIRIACY-WANTRUP SV (1952) Resource conservation: economics
and policies. University of California Press, Berkeley
CLARK CW (1973) The economics of overexploitation. Science
181:630634
CLARK CW (1990) Mathematical bioeconomics: the optimal
management of renewable resources, 2nd edn. Wiley, New York
CLEVELAND CJ, STERN DI, COSTANZA R (eds) (2000) The economics
of nature and the nature of economics. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham (in press)
COMMON M, PERRINGS C (1992) Towards an ecological economics
of sustainability. Ecol Econ 6:734
COSTANZA R (1980) Embodied energy and economic valuation.
Science 210:12191224
21
Original article
22
FOLKE C (1999) Ecological principles and environmental economic analysis. In: van den Bergh JCJM (ed) Handbook of environmental and resource economics. Edward Elgar,
Cheltenham
GALBRAITH JK (1958) The afuent society. Houghton Mifin,
Boston
GEORGESCU-ROEGEN N (1966) Analytical economics: issues and
problems. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA
GEORGESCU-ROEGEN N (1971) The entropy law and the economic
process. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA
GEORGESCU-ROEGEN N (1976) Energy and economic myths. Pergamon, New York
GIBSON CC, OSTROM E, AHN TK (2000) The concept of scale and the
human dimensions of global change: a survey. Ecol Econ
32(2):217239
GOWDY JM (1994) Coevolutionary economics: the economy,
society and the environment. Kluwer, Dordrecht
GOWDY JM (ed) (1998) Limited wants, unlimited means: a hunter
gatherer reader on economics and the environment. Island
Press, Washington, DC
GOWDY JM, FERRER-I-CARBONELL A (1999) Toward consilience between biology and economics: the contribution of ecological
economics. Ecol Econ 29:337348
GOWDY JM, MESNER S (1998) The evolution of Georgescu-Roegen's
bioeconomics. Rev Soc Econ 56(2):136156
GRAEDEL TE, ALLENBY BR (1995) Industrial ecology. Prentice Hall,
Englewood Cliffs
GUNDERSON LH, HOLLING CS, LIGHT SS (eds) (1995) Barriers and
bridges to the renewal of ecosystems and institutions. Columbia
University Press, New York
HARDIN G (1968) The tragedy of the commons. Science 162:1243
1248
HARTWICK J M (1977) Intergenerational equity and the investing of
rents from exhaustible resources. Am Econ Rev 67:972974
HERENDEEN RA (1999) EMERGY, value, ecology and economics.
In: van den Bergh JCJM (ed) Handbook of environmental and
resource economics. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham
HOLLING CS (1973) Resilience and stability of ecological systems.
Annu Rev Ecol Syst 4:124
HOLLING CS (ed) (1978) Adaptive environmental assessment and
management. Wiley, New York
HOLLING CS (1986) The resilience of terrestrial ecosystems: local
surprise and global change. In: Clark WC, Munn RE (eds)
Sustainable development of the biosphere. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge
HOLLING CS, SCHINDLER DW, WALKER BW, ROUGHGARDEN J (1995)
Biodiversity in the functioning of ecosystems: an ecological
synthesis. In: Perring C, Maler K-G, Folke C, Holling CS, Jansson BO (eds) Biodiversity loss, economic and ecological issues.
Cambridge University Press, Cambridge
HUETING R (1974/1980) New scarcity and economic growth: more
welfare through less production? (translated and updated from
Dutch, 1974). North-Holland, Amsterdam
ISARD W (1969) Some notes on the linkage of ecologic and
economic systems. Pap Reg Sci Assoc 22:8596
ISARD W (1972) Ecologic-economic analysis for regional
development. Free Press, New York
JANSSON A-M (ed) 1984) Integration of economy and ecology: an
outlook for the eighties. In: Proc Wallenberg Conf on Energy
and Economics, Sundt Offset, Stockholm
JANSSON A-M, HAMMER M, FOLKE C, COSTANZA R (eds) (1994)
Investing in natural capital: the ecological economics approach
to sustainability. Island Press, Washington, DC
KAPP KW (1950) The social costs of private enterprise. Harvard
University Press, Cambridge, MA
KNEESE AV, SWEENEY JL (eds) (1985/1993) Handbook of natural
resource and energy economics, vols 13. North-Holland,
Amsterdam
Original article
KRISHNAN R, HARRIS JM, GOODWIN NR (1995) A survey of ecological economics. Island Press, Washington, DC
LEE KN (1993) Compass and gyroscope: integrating science and
politics for the environment. Island Press, Washington, DC
LEONTIEF WW (1970) Environmental repercussions and the economic structure: an inputoutput approach. Rev Econ Stud
52:262271
LEVIN et al. (17 authors) (1998) Resilience in natural and socioeconomic systems. Environ Develop Econ 3(2):222235
MARTINEZ-ALIER J (1999) Ecological economics. In: International
encyclopedia of the social and behavioral sciences (in press)
MARTINEZ-ALIER J, O'CONNOR M (1999) Distribution issues: an
overview. In: van den Bergh JCJM (ed) Handbook of environmental and resource economics. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham
MARTINEZ-ALIER J (2001) Ecological economics. International encyclopedia of the social and behavioral sciences, article 4.9.9.
Elsevier, Amsterdam (in press)
MARTINEZ-ALIER J, MUNDA G, O'NEILL J (1998) Weak comparability
of values as a foundation for ecological economics. Ecol Econ
26:277286
MEADOWS DH, MEADOWS DL, RANDERS J, BEHRENS WW III (1972)
The limits to growth. Universe Books, New York
MISHAN EJ (1967) The cost of economic growth. Staples Press,
London
MOTT T (2000) In memoriam: Kenneth Boulding 19101993.
Econ J 110(464):430444
MUNASINGHE M, SUNKEL O, DE MIGUEL C (2000) The sustainability
of long-term growth. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham (in press)
MUNDA G, NIJKAMP P, RIETVELD P (1994) Qualitative multi-criteria
evaluation for environmental management. Ecol Econ 10:97112
NEHER PA (1990) Natural resource economics: conservation and
exploitation. Cambridge University Press, New York
NORGAARD RB (1984) Coevolutionary development potential. Land
Econ 60:160173
NORGAARD RB (1985) Environmental economics: an evolutionary
critique and a plea for pluralism. J Environ Econ Manage
12:382394
NORGAARD RB (1994) Development betrayed: the end of progress
and a coevolutionary revisioning of the future. Routledge,
London
NORTON B, Costanza R, Bishop R (1998) The evolution of preferences: why `sovereign' preferences may not lead to sustainable
policies and what to do about it. Ecol Econ 24:193211
ODUM HT (1971) Environment, power, and society. Wiley, New
York
ODUM HT (1987) Models for national, international and global
systems policy. In: Braat LC, van Lierop WFJ (eds) Economicecological modelling. North-Holland, Amsterdam
PAGE T (1977) Conservation and economic efciency. Johns
Hopkins University Press, Baltimore
PERMAN R, MA Y, MCGILVRAY J, COMMON M (1999) Natural
resource and environmental economics, 2nd edn. AddisonWesley/Longman, London
PERRINGS C (1998) Resilience in the dynamics of economy-environment systems. Environ Resour Econ 11:503520
PEZZEY J (1989) Economic analysis of sustainable growth and
sustainable development. Working Pap 15. Environmental Department, World Bank. Reprinted as Pezzey J (1992) Sustainable
23