Financial Time Series
Financial Time Series
INTRODUCTION
157
Overview
www.wiley.com/wires/compstats
0.05
SP500 returns
0.0
0.05
0.10
0.15
0.20
500
1000
1500
2000
2500
3000
=a+
p
2
ai Xti
+ Wt
(2)
i=1
(3)
158
time
a=
C
, and ai = ABi1 for i = 1, 2, . . .
1B
(4)
SP500 returns
(a)
1.0
ACF
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
0.0
0
10
20
30
Lag
(b)
ACF
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
0.0
0
10
20
30
Lag
where the coefficients k are (at least) squaresummable, and the series {Zt } is i.i.d. with mean zero
and variance 2 > 0. A linear time series {Yt } is called
causal if k = 0 for k < 0, i.e., if
Yt =
k Ztk .
(6)
k=0
F(w1 , w2 ) = (2 )2 3 (w1 )
(w2 )(w1 + w2 )
(7)
159
Overview
www.wiley.com/wires/compstats
p
k Ytk + Zt
(8)
k=1
i.e., that
E[t |Ft1 ] = 0 and E[t2 |Ft1 ] = 1 for all t. (10)
Following,21 we will use the term weakly linear for
a time series {Yt } that satisfies (9) and (10). As it
turns out, the linearity of the optimal prediction
function gn () is shared by all members of the family
of weakly linear time series;c for example, see Ref 23
and Theorem 1.4.2 of Ref 14.
Gaussian series form an interesting subset of the
class of linear time series. They occur when the series
{Zt } of Eq. (5) is i.i.d. N(0, 2 ), and they too exhibit
the useful linearity of the optimal prediction function
gn (); to see this, recall that the conditional expectation
E(Yn+1 |Y1 , . . . , Yn ) turns out to be a linear function of
Y1 , . . . , Yn when the variables Y1 , . . . , Yn+1 are jointly
normal.19
Furthermore, in the Gaussian case, all spectra of
order higher than two are identically zero; it follows
that all dependence information is concentrated in
the spectral density f (w). Thus, the investigation of
a Gaussian series dependence structure can focus on
the simple study of second-order properties, namely
the ACF (k) and/or the spectral density f (w). For
example, an uncorrelated Gaussian series, i.e., one
satisfying (k) = 0 for all k, necessarily consists of
independent random variables.
To some extent, this last remark can be
generalized to the linear setting: if a linear time
series is deemed to be uncorrelated, then practitioners
typically infer that it is independent as well.d Note that
to check/test whether an estimated ACF, denoted by
(k),
Yt =
i ti
(9)
i=0
(11)
(12)
Xt
s2t1
+ a0 Xt2 +
p
2
i=1 ai Xti
for t = p + 1, p + 2, . . . , n,
(13)
p
2
s2 +
ai Xti
t1
i=1
for t = p + 1, p + 2, . . . , n.
(14)
Given the initial conditions X1 , . . . , Xp , the information set FnX = {Xt , 1 t n} is equivalent to the
information set FnV = {Vt , 1 t n}. To see this, note
that with Eq. (14) we can recursively regenerate Xt
for t = p + 1, p + 2, . . . , n using just FnV and the initial
conditions; conversely, Eq. (13) defines Vt in terms of
FnX .
Equation (13) describes the candidate normalizing (and therefore also linearizing) transformation,
i.e., the operator H in Vn = H(Xn ); this transformation was termed NoVaS in Ref 31 which is
an acronym for normalizing and variance stabilising. Note that formally the main difference between
161
Overview
www.wiley.com/wires/compstats
normalised SP500
2
3
0
500
1000
1500
time
2000
2500
3000
162
ak = 1,
k0
|F(w1 , w2 )|2
.
f (w1 )f (w2 )f (w1 + w2 )
(15)
0.05
data quantiles
0.0
0.020
)
K (w 1, w 2
0.015
0.05
0.10
0.15
0.010
0.005
0.20
1.0
0.8
0.0
0.6
0.2
0.4
0.4
w1
0.6
w2
0.2
0.8
0
normal quantiles
1.0 0.0
3
0
1
2
4e-05
)
K (w 1, w 2
3e-05
-2
2e-05
1e-05
1.0
0.8
0.0
0
normal quantiles
0.6
0.2
0.4
0.4
w1
0.6
0.2
0.8
w2
1.0 0.0
163
Overview
www.wiley.com/wires/compstats
q1
the general form V n+1 = i=0 ci Vni . The ci
coefficients can be found by Hilbert space
projection techniques, or by simply fitting the
causal AR model
Vt+1 =
q1
ci Vti +
t+1 .
(16)
i=0
V
un (V) = h
1 a0 V 2
p
2
s2 +
.
ai Xn+1i
t1
i=1
(17)
Thus, a quick-and-easy predictor of h(Xn+1 ) could
then be given by un (V n+1 ).
A better predictor, however, is given by the
center of location of the distribution of un (Vn+1 )
conditionally on FnV . Formally, to obtain an optimal
predictor, the optimality criterion must first be
specified, and correspondingly the form of the
predictor is obtained based on the distribution of
the quantity in question. Typical optimality criteria
are L2 , L1 , and 0/1 losses with corresponding optimal
predictors the (conditional) mean, median, and mode
of the distribution. For reasons of robustness, let us
focus on the median of the distribution of un (Vn+1 ) as
such a center of location.
Using Eq. (16), it follows that the distribution
of Vn+1 conditionally on FnV is approximately
N(V n+1 , 2 ) where 2 is an estimate of 2 in Eq. (16).
Thus, the median-optimal one-step-ahead predictor of
h(Xn+1 ) is the median of the distribution of un (V)
where V has the normal distribution N(V n+1 , 2 )
CONCLUSION
An introduction to the statistical intricacies of financial time series was presented with an emphasis on the
ACKNOWLEDGEMENT
Many thanks are due to the Economics and Statistics sections of the National Science Foundation for
their support through grants SES-04-18136 and DMS-07-06732. The author is grateful to D. Gatzouras,
D. Kalligas, and D. Thomakos for helpful discussions, to A. Berg for compiling the software for the
bispectrum computations, and to R. Davis, M. Rosenblatt, and G. Sugihara for their advice and
encouragement.
REFERENCES
1. Bachelier, L. Theory of speculation. Reprinted In:
Cootner PH ed. The Random Character of Stock Market Prices (1964). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press; 1900,
1778.
2. Fama EF. The behaviour of stock market prices. J Bus
1965, 38:34105.
3. Davis RA, Mikosch T. The sample autocorrelations of
financial time series models. In: Fitzgerald WJ, Smith
RL, Walden AT, Young P, eds. Nonlinear and Nonstationary Signal Processing. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press; 2000, 247274.
4. Gabaix X, Gopikrishnan P, Plerou V, Stanley HE. A
theory of power-law distributions in financial market
fluctuations. Nature 2003, 423:267270.
5. Politis DN. A heavy-tailed distribution for ARCH residuals with application to volatility prediction. Ann Econ
Finance 2004, 5:283298.
6. Mandelbrot B. The variation of certain speculative
prices. J Bus 1963, 36:394419.
7. Engle R. Autoregressive conditional heteroscedasticity
with estimates of the variance of UK inflation. Econometrica 1982, 50:9871008.
8. Fan J, Yao Q. Nonlinear Time Series. New York:
Springer, 2003.
9. Bollerslev T. Generalized autoregressive conditional
heteroscedasticity. J Econom 1986, 31:307327.
10. Gourieroux C. ARCH Models and Financial Applications. New York: Springer, 1997.
165
Overview
www.wiley.com/wires/compstats
23. Poskitt DS. Properties of the sieve bootstrap for fractionally integrated and non-invertible processes. J Time
Ser Anal 2008, 29(2):224250.
24. Breidt FJ, Davis RA, Trindade AA. Least absolute deviation estimation for all-pass time series models. Ann
Stat 2001, 29:919946.
25. Fuller WA. Introduction to Statistical Time Series. 2nd
ed. New York: Wiley; 1996.
26. Romano JP, Thombs L. Inference for autocorrelations under weak assumptions. J Am Stat Assoc 1996,
91:590600.
38. [l1]Kugiumtzis
D.
Evaluation
of
surrogate
and bootstrap tests for nonlinearity in time
series. Stud Nonlinear Dyn Econom 2008,
12(1):14741474, article 4. Available at: http://www.
bepress.com/snde/vol12/iss1/art4.
a C, Tut
unc
u R. A non-stationary
28. Herzel S, Staric
paradigm for the dynamics of multivariate returns.
In: Bertail P, Doukhan P, Soulier P eds. Dependence
in Probability and Statistics, Springer Lecture Notes
in Statistics No. 187. New York: Springer; 2006,
391430.
31. Politis DN. Model-free vs. model-based volatility prediction, J Financ Econom 2007, 5(3):358389.
43. Politis DN, Thomakos DD. NoVaS transformations: flexible inference for volatility forecasting. Discussion Paper No. 2008-13, Department
of Economics, UCSD; 2008., Available at: http://
repositories.cdlib.org/ucsdecon/2008-13.
166