Market Welfare in The Early-Modern Ottoman Economy, A Historiographic Overview With Many Questions
Market Welfare in The Early-Modern Ottoman Economy, A Historiographic Overview With Many Questions
Market Welfare in The Early-Modern Ottoman Economy, A Historiographic Overview With Many Questions
Questions
Author(s): Relli Shechter
Source: Journal of the Economic and Social History of the Orient, Vol. 48, No. 2 (2005), pp.
253-276
Published by: BRILL
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/25165092
Accessed: 01-04-2015 13:30 UTC
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content
in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship.
For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].
BRILL is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Journal of the Economic and Social History of
the Orient.
http://www.jstor.org
This content downloaded from 194.27.202.75 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 13:30:54 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
In early-modern
Ottoman
tem that partially
stifled
equity
economic
from "above"
and "the state")
decentralization
when
(Istanbul
regulation
political
was
on the wane.
available
research
and raising questions
for future
Discussing
seemingly
from the "middle"
forms of regulation
by local officials/notables,
study, the article examines
in cities throughout
institutions
the Empire
and the role of consumers
courts, and economic
in a later era of
in economic
The article further suggests why economic
opening
regulation.
into the world
integration
economic
life.
economy
gradually
put an end
to an
inward-looking,
early-modern
ottomane
du debut de l'ere moderne
la notion, proposee
l'economie
(17e-18e
siecles),
voire etouffait par
ici, de bien-etre
par le marche
signifiait un systeme qui decourageait
une
et une equite
et efficacite
dans
le but d'assurer
stabilite
tiellement
competition
a ceux compris dans son perimetre. Un
tel systeme fonctionnait
toujours meme
economique
Dans
venue
alors que
la regulation
de decentralisation
dans un contexte
economique
politique,
? d'en haut?
la
et de ?l'Etat?)
semblait etre en train de s'affaiblir. Considerant
(d'lstanbul
recherche
des nouvelles
effectuee a ce sujet et soulevant
pour une future enquete,
questions
? et etablies
emanant
du ? milieu
locale
le present article etudie des formes de regulation
dans
ment par des fonctionnaires/dignitaires,
des tribunaux, et des institutions economiques
dans ce proces
ainsi que le role joue par les consommateurs
des villes a travers l'Empire,
sus. L'article
la periode
tente aussi
l'ouverture
durant
pourquoi
economique
d'expliquer
a
a mis
dans
celle de 1'integration
l'economie
mondiale,
fin, progressivement,
posterieure,
une vie economique
tournee vers 1'interieur qui a caracterise
le debut de l'ere moderne.
Keywords:
Markets,
welfare,
economic
history,
consumption,
Ottoman
Empire,
early modern
* Relli
Shechter, Department ofMiddle East Studies, Ben-Gurion University, Beer
Nimrod
and Dror
Iris Agmon,
Hurvitz,
on earlier versions
also like to acknowledge
of this article. I would
menting
useful suggestions.
readers who made many
of the two anonymous
?
Koninklijke
Also available
JESHO
Ze'evi
for com
the contribution
48,2
This content downloaded from 194.27.202.75 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 13:30:54 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
254 relli
shechter
Introduction
How are we to understand past economies? What economic goals guided
them? Under what principles, social, political, and cultural (religious), did they
operate? I approach these questions as a modernist, an economic historian who
is a visitor to the study of Ottoman history, but one who has followed the lit
erature emerging from this field for the past fifteen years or so. What triggers
nomic
eco
life.
a result, few attempts have been made to offer a broad overview of the princi
ples governing the Empire's economic life.2My intention here is to put forward
such an overview of what I consider the centerpiece of early-modern Ottoman
economy, namely the notion of welfare through themarket, which, consciously
or not, guided the economy during this period.
Three
such
endeavors,
and Society,
Economy
ed. Halil
1300-1914,
Empire,
see especially
Press,
1994),
Pamuk,
"Institutional
of Interdisciplinary
Revisited:
Regime
Empire,"
Politics
also
"The Ottoman
Inalcik,
inspired this article, are Halil
in An Economic
and Social History
1300-1600,"
of the Ottoman
Inalcik and Donald
Quataert
(Cambridge:
Cambridge
University
the section
"The Ottoman
Economic
Mind,"
44-54;
?evket
and the Longevity
of the Ottoman
Journal
1500-1800,"
Empire,
Ariel
"An Ancien
35, 2 (Autumn,
225-247;
Salzmann,
2004):
which
State:
Change
History
'Privatization'
and
Society
and Political
21,
(Dec.
in the Eighteenth-Century
Economy
393-423.
Pamuk's
A Monetary
1993):
Ottoman
History
of
on Ottoman
broad perspective
economics.
See also: Mehmet
"Reconsideration
of the
Bulut,
Economic
of the Ottomans
and Western
Concepts
Europeans
during the Mercantilist
Ages"
in
M.S.
(2002)
http://cas.uchicago.edu/workshops/meht/papers03/Bulut.doc;
Meyer,
in the Ottoman
"Economic
in the 14th-Early
19th Centuries,"
Archiv
Thought
Empire
57 (1989):
Orientali
Ahmet
of the Ottoman
"Outlines
Economic
305-318;
Tabakoglu,
System,"
TUrkiye,
in The Great
2000),
7-24.
Ottoman,
Turkish
Civilization,
vol.
2, ed. Kemal
?icek
(Ankara:
This content downloaded from 194.27.202.75 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 13:30:54 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Yeni
255
fare only briefly touches upon such matters in the case of waqfs (term explained
below). My main purpose here is to set the framework for a better understand
ing of economic and legal institutions, rather than social ones, that provided
economic relief to cities. This is not to assert in any way that social and private
action did not contribute to welfare. Even more so, in many cases, such as the
guilds, it is hard to distinguish between an economic and a social institution.
rather than real ones,
created here are thereforemethodological
to help me better develop the notion of market-welfare.
To the discussion on the historiography of Ottoman economic institutions and
The boundaries
legal systems in the first part of the article, I later add an analysis of the often
neglected demand and consumers' agency in determining the nature of Ottoman
markets (and market-welfare). The unique nature of Ottoman commerce in an
Aleppo, Cairo, Istanbul and Izmir. I used as my selection criteria their substan
tial size and the fact that these four markets represented a variety of Ottoman
commercial centers when
experiences: Aleppo and Cairo were well-established
were
carefully.
Ottoman markets were
can only be gauged from the discussion below, and needs further research.
Large city markets, however, were significant economic engines for Ottoman
I cite
the relevant
literature
on
in the appropriate
discussion
below.
This content downloaded from 194.27.202.75 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 13:30:54 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
256
RELLI SHECHTER
debate
over Ottoman
the project
ahead
economic
"decline"
has
of the Ottoman
the comprehensiveness
the impact of political decentralization on early-modern Ottoman economic life.
The term "command economy," sometimes implied by the notion of oriental
despotism, suggests an economy managed by the state from above, with little
function and
interference from society.4 The sultan and the central state bureaucracy, itwas
argued, tightly controlled economic surplus by efficient collection, which further
meant restricting capital accumulation beyond the state's elites. Resources were
later re-distributed according to principles denoted by the state.
The notion of "decline"
started as long ago as that era itself, with some
Ottoman writers lamenting the departed "golden-era" glory of theEmpire as against
the state
see Huri
in
On oriental despotism
"Introduction:
'Oriental
Islamoglu-Inan,
Despotism'
in The Ottoman Empire and theWorld-Economy,
ed. Huri Islamoglu
Perspective,"
World-System
Inan (Cambridge:
of the
3-7. In earlier historiography
Press,
1987),
Cambridge
University
a centralized
the notion of oriental despotism
Ottoman
mostly
Empire,
designated
political
econ
to the Empire's
devoted
system and raison d'etat;
past research
only scant attention
omy,
political
Eastern
considering
"essence."
and
of its cultural/religious
for exploration
in Middle
the oriental
paradigm
despotism
Middle
East History
beyond Oriental
Despotism,
it secondary
and redundant
on
For further discussion
World
Press,
University
Cambridge
6
For a critical discussion
"Introduction:
Roger Owen,
in his, The Middle
East
[1981]), 1-23.
151-156.
1999),
of the "decline"
The Middle
in the World
see:
in Ottoman
economic
history
paradigm
in the Period of So-called
'Decline',"
Economy
LB.
1800-1914
1993
Tauris,
(London:
Economy,
East
This content downloaded from 194.27.202.75 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 13:30:54 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
257
seemingly lost its power and failed to follow its older economic raison detat
based on three principles: provisioning of cities, army, palace, and state offi
economic
cials; increasing the fiscal revenue of the state (by encouraging
activity); and preservation of the traditional order.7
More recent historiography, however, shows that a hierarchical and central
ized state never existed independently of peripheral forces, and that the two
closely interacted.8 Consequently, with the exception of Istanbul, a "classical"
Ottoman
Eldem,
model
on its own
reconsider decentralization
Closely related to the notion of "decline" has been the standard convention
of using European mercantilism (comparison with Europe or different countries
in Europe) as an external yardstick to measure economic performance in the
7
in: Mehmet
"Ottoman
command
See analysis
of the Ottoman
Gene,
economy
Industry
in
in the Eighteenth-Century:
and Main
General
Trends,"
Framework,
Characteristic,
ed. Donald
in the Ottoman
and Turkey, 1500-1950,
Quataert
(Albany,
Empire
Manufacturing
in the
Rizk Khoury,
Dina
State and Provincial
NY:
SUNY
59-68;
Press,
1994),
Society
1540-1834
Press,
3-10;
1997),
University
(Cambridge:
Cambridge
Empire, Mosul,
and the
Stoianovich
Accumulation,
"Cities, Capital
11-13; Traian
Pamuk, Monetary
History,
in Cities and the Rise of States
in Europe,
Balkan
Command
Ottoman
1500-1800,"
Economy,
P. Blockmans
A.D.
1000 to 1800, ed. Charles
1994),
(Boulder, CO: Westview,
Tilly and Wim
63-65.
8
a mechanism
the central state co-opted
local forces,
Karen
by which
Barkey
suggested
Ottoman
a large Empire.
and Bureaucrats:
of governing
See her Bandits
the "costs"
thereby reducing
The Ottoman Route to State Centralization
Press, 1994). Regional
(Ithaca, NY: Cornell University
in which
of Ottomanization
elites, on their part, went
process
they
through a complimentary
as their own. See: Ehud
socio-cultural
and political
Toledano,
practices
adopted Ottoman
in the Middle
East and North Africa,
1700-1900,"
A History
and Moshe
ed. Ilan Pappe
from Within,
For case
that further
Tauris
145-162.
studies
Academic
Macoz
Studies,
1997),
(London:
in Ottoman
The Politics
demonstrate
this point see: Jane Hathaway,
Egypt:
of Households
State and
The Rise of the Qazdaglis
Press,
1997); Khoury,
Cambridge
University
(Cambridge:
Provincial.
9
to Peripheralized
in The Ottoman
Edhem
"Istanbul:
from Imperial
Eldem,
City
Capital,"
and
East and West, Aleppo,
Between
Izmir, and Istanbul,
Goffman,
by Edhem Eldem, Daniel
141.
Bruce Masters
Press,
1999),
University
Cambridge
(Cambridge:
"The
of Ottoman-Local
Emergence
in Middle
Politics
and
Eastern
Elites
Ideas:
This content downloaded from 194.27.202.75 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 13:30:54 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
258
RELLI SHECHTER
change and blocked the way to imported novelties. Such inflexibility stands in
structures, which facilitated
binary opposition to dynamic (evolving) European
the development
of new technologies, financial institutions, and trade, and
that its validity is
enjoyed export-led growth. This comparison is so widespread
usually taken for granted.
In using an external economic model, however, scholarship anachronistically
assumed that performance was indeed the Ottomans' main criterion. Furthermore,
I argue that in the early-modern Empire growth was one criterion among a
wider set of values related to the function of the economy, and that stability
was no less important. My argument is corroborated by recent and more
internally oriented appreciation of the Ottoman economy, emphasizing flexibil
ity and viability of existing institutions in providing the Empire with an ade
quate economic infrastructure,10 thus compensating for the lack of novel ones
like those developed in Europe. A good example here is Hanna's
study, which
courts
in supervising
shows the multi-purpose role of well-established Ottoman
contractual transactions and financial services such as credit, deposits, and loans
one
under
roof.11
modern Ottoman history "unfolds" between two distinct periods. It was preceded
by an earlier, "classical" era of Empire building that lasted roughly until the late
sixteenth century, when the Ottomans expanded their territories, placed new
economic resources (mainly agricultural lands) under state control, and engaged
in large-scale
commercial building projects to revive local economies
and
era
was
trade.
The
followed
another
distinct
early-modern
by
period
develop
that began around the middle of the eighteenth century, but became more
I
significant throughout the nineteenth century and lasted until World War
a
went
of
the
when
Ottoman
(WWI),
economy
process
through
semi-peripher
as it gradually merged
into the world economy.12 The study of
alization
10
See,
for
Pamuk,
"Institutional
example,
Change."
11
Nelly Hanna, Making Big Money in 1600: The Life and Times of Ismacil Abu Taqiyya,
NY:
Press,
1998). See especially
Egyptian Merchant
(Syracuse,
Syracuse
University
chapter
life of the merchant
Isma'il Abu
three, for the dominant
place of the court in the professional
of her book.
the protagonist
Taqiyya,
12
see Kenneth
M.
On Ottoman
into the world
The Pasha's
Cuno,
economy
integration
Peasants:
University
Land,
Press,
in Lower
and Economy
1740-1858
Society,
Egypt,
(Cambridge:
Cambridge
1760-1840
1992); Peter Gran, Islamic Roots
(Austin:
of Capitalism:
Egypt,
This content downloaded from 194.27.202.75 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 13:30:54 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
259
Ottoman
economic
itsmeaning.
operandi
"privatization"
and
of contemporary
economy
so, to
revisionist work
and other sources of revenue farming supplied the growing needs of the
Ottoman state for cash and served to raise large sums in advance when the state
Taxes
was
in critical financial
as a whole was
a more
suggest that
of Texas
Ottoman
The
Press,
Kasaba,
1979);
University
Islamoglu-Inan,
Empire',
Re?at
Ottoman
the World
The Nineteenth-Century
and
NY:
SUNY
Economy:
(Albany,
Empire
Middle
The Ottoman
and European
Press,
Owen,
Pamuk,
East,
1988);
?evket
Empire
and Production
1820-1913:
Univer
Investment,
Trade,
Capitalism,
(Cambridge:
Cambridge
Press, 1987).
sity
13
"Ancien Regime."
Salzmann,
14
fn. 10, n.p.,
Bulut, "Reconsideration,"
cited
from H.
inalcik,
"The Nature
of Traditional
This content downloaded from 194.27.202.75 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 13:30:54 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
a more
and services
Can we
vivendi emphasizing
even
welfare through themarket
though the centralized system that supported it
in the past was on the wane? I argue that implementing such a system did not
require a fully centralized, state-led command economy. Indeed, in a period of
decentralization, with the exception of Istanbul, itwas local economic institu
tions, such as religious endowments (waqf) and guilds (tariqa, ta'ifa, hirfa, in
Arabic or esnaf in Turkish) that operated midway between government and pri
vate interests to uphold economic welfare through tightmarket regulation. The
qadi and the court system also played a significant role in upholding justice
in markets. Furthermore, consumers (sometimes in the form of public opinion)
resisted economic injustices, and their agency in deciding what to buy was more
The system outlined above provided (mostly urban) populations with minimal
standards of living through fixing quantity and prices of commodities, especially
in times of shortage. In addition, it guaranteed industries a more or less regular
in Political
Modernization
in Japan
and Turkey,
ed. R. Ward
and D. Rustow
The Ottoman
and
Princeton
Press,
Itzkowitz,
(Princeton:
1964), also N.
Empire
University
for both citations; Meyer,
"Economic
Islamic Tradition
(New York: n.p., 1972). No page mentioned
on N. Berkes,
iktisat tarihi, vol. 2 (Istanbul:
307; based
n.p., 1972), 325.
Turkiye
Thought,"
15
See especially
Karl Polanyi,
The Great
Beacon
Press,
(Boston:
1957).
Transformation
chapter four.
Society,"
This content downloaded from 194.27.202.75 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 13:30:54 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
261
the operations of local waqfs. The crux of my argument here is that the Empire's
economy continued to be highly regulated even after decentralization. However,
such regulation was carried by a broad consensus from themiddle (in both geo
graphical and social terms) rather than being a top-down affair (regulated by a
command economy "from above").
Such economic regulation did not provide equality in the market for all. As
Raymond has emphasized, Ottoman city dwellers were far from being equal in
it did not mean that city
their earnings or their housing facilities.16 Moreover,
inhabitants were immune from being squeezed by local officials, for example,
this economic system did support exist
by special taxation (avariz). However,
ing interests of large social segments such as organized labor. It further allowed
embedded
in socio-cultural
and political
relations
that
Another gap in market regulation and the welfare through the market that it
implied was the treatment of the peasantry. The majority of Ottomans living in
the countryside were less protected from economic distress and natural or man
made disasters. Peasants surely resisted being squeezed of surplus in a variety
of ways, ranging from hiding part of the crops to abandoning the land or even
resorting to armed struggle. They also petitioned local officials or even the sul
such manifestations of peasant agency
tan, and aired injustices in court. While
should not go unnoticed, themain beneficiaries of the existing economic system
were
cities' middle-strata
porary Ottoman
Waqfs,
political
whose
voice
and economic
(and actions)
counted more
in contem
settings.
In light of the above, I now further elaborate on the notion of regulation from
the middle and market welfare by discussing the role of religious endowments
and guilds in early-modern times. During an initial period of Empire building,
16
Andre
Raymond,
"Islamic
City,
Arab
City:
Orientalist
Myths
and
Recent
This content downloaded from 194.27.202.75 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 13:30:54 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Views,"
well
of the waqf's
founder, and such "carrying
they were descendants
not
at
benefit
the
did
community
large. Nevertheless, waqf institutions
charges"
were important in the day-to-day running of the city economy.19 The waqf was
a significant player in commercial real-estate markets and as such it had a
where
major
mosques,
seminars
(madrase).21
immediate eco
It also provided
17
After
of Istanbul, Mehmet
the Conqueror
and built new
the occupation
reconstructed
in the city in order to revive the economy
at large
of his new capital and the Empire
reduced
"Ottoman
of Empire
State,"
18-19). The presence
(Inalcik,
security
significantly
a more or less unified legal and taxation
costs and facilitated
local, inter
system, enhancing
commerce.
in the case of Aleppo
and international
This was demonstrated
well
and
regional,
markets
vanserais
Hoexter,"
Waqf
Studies
in the Twentieth
Century:
The
State
new
cara
of Islam
(EI),
228
of the Art,"
Ibid.
Journal
480-483.
in Sefrou,"
in Meaning
in
and Order
The Bazaar
Geertz,
Economy
"Suq:
in Cultural
and
Geertz,
Society, Three Essays
Analysis,
by Clifford Geertz, Hildrad
123-244.
Rosen
Press,
1979),
University
(Cambridge:
Cambridge
as social and economic
in
role of waqfs
welfare
recently discussed
providers was
Clifford
Moroccan
Lawrence
21
The
inMiddle
Bonner, Mine
Ener, and Amy Singer, eds., Poverty and Charity
texts (Albany, NY:
Poor
SUNY
and
Press, 2003); Mine
Ener, Managing
Egypt's
1800-1952
Princeton University
Press, 2003),
(Princeton:
of Benevolence,
chapter
Michael
East
Con
the Politics
one.
This content downloaded from 194.27.202.75 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 13:30:54 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
263
nomic relief for the poor through imaret (kitchen soup) complexes attached to
further routed foodstuffs and raw material from the
large city mosques. Waqfs
to
cities.
countryside
Through such a direct, and possibly indirect (rent) welfare
urban economic
the encroachment
bargaining
employees,
contributed
Ghazaleh
reached
for Cairo:
22
This content downloaded from 194.27.202.75 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 13:30:54 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
264
RELLI SHECHTER
of other groups, by the existing laws, and by the economic policies and inter
ests of the state. Although not entirely instruments of government, they did sub
mit to various forms official oversight which affirmed the limits of their inde
pendent authority."25 The quotes above reinforce the impression that the guilds
were part of a "decentralized urban regime" of notables, suggested by Chal
craft,26which sits well with my argument of market welfare regulated from the
middle.
Economic
themarket
The legal system played a major role in the daily running of guilds as their
members brought their internal affairs to court. The court also resolved griev
ances between guilds and other players, including state officials who operated
in the same sphere. It further empowered the guilds in restricting competition
from outside, by creating legal barriers for entry into already established mar
suggested that during the eighteenth century, due to migration
into towns, the most common complaint of guilds to the courts was against
into trades.27 The courts facilitated cross
pressure of entry by newcomers
Indian
Ottoman and cross-Islamic economic activity (e.g., the case of Muslim
kets. McGowan
24
substituted modern
financial
institutions by
65.
"Guilds,"
on the Eve of Modernity,
in the Eighteenth
The Middle
East
Marcus,
Aleppo
173.
Press,
(New York: Columbia
1989),
Century
University
26
in
John Chalcraft,
"The Striking Cabbies
of Cairo
and Other Stories: Crafts and Guilds
25
Ghazaleh,
Abraham
dissertation
9-15.
1863-1914,"
(New York University,
2001),
Egypt,
unpublished
27
in Economic
Bruce McGowan,
"The Age of the Ayans,
and Social History,
1699-1812,"
see: Dror Ze'evi,
An Ottoman
in the
The District
697. For Jerusalem
of Jerusalem
Century:
"Crisis
and Change,"
524-525.
This content downloaded from 194.27.202.75 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 13:30:54 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
265
tury in Aleppo, the hisba disappeared altogether.31 In Egypt, the position of the
muhtasib was abolished only under Mehmet Ali.32 In Istanbul, the seat of gov
ernment, the hisba also lasted until the tanzimat (reforms) of 1826.33 However,
the immediate
impact of
impact of the qadi and the court went beyond regulating and adminis
trating practical solutions in the day-to-day running of markets. Their deep
involvement in market life meant that the courts were crucial in upholding the
principles guiding such economy. It may even be argued that they served as a
The
29
In her Making
Hanna
Big Money,
to the courts, convincingly
pointing out
See especially
chapter three.
30
in Ottoman
the hisba
On
(ihtisab
demonstrates
their significant
went
life.
see:
the institution of market
sources),
regulation
to a religious mandate
The muhtasib
of
3, 485-490.
operated
according
at least) three tasks:
assuming
(theoretically
"commanding
right and forbidding wrong" when
a living in the market
in both indus
conduct among
those who made
enforcing just business
in markets
in times of crisis to secure minimal
standards of living,
try and trade, intervening
and taxing the working
population.
31
173.
Middle
Marcus,
East,
32
inModern
Times
Gabriel
Guilds
Baer, Egyptian
(Jerusalem: The Israel Oriental
Society,
"Hisba,"
in EI,
vol.
1964), 44.
33
Inalcik
("Ottoman
of plenty."
State,"
This content downloaded from 194.27.202.75 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 13:30:54 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
46)
con
buffer between
This
"The law's interpretation could change. We have evidence of this in the allow al
of interest under the legal guise of terming it profit rather than usury and in the
seemingly antiguild rulings of eighteenth-century Aleppo. But even in these
cases, the underlying ideology of justice in the marketplace,
including the idea
of fair pricing, the sanctity of contract, and the right for labor to receive a just
economy was shaped under the (external and internal) impact of the integration
of the Empire into the world economy, especially during the nineteenth century.
laws and
The re-centralized (post-tanzimat) state stipulated new commercial
Provisioning,
take on many
the state. Second, itwas to ensure an adequate supply of foodstuffs and com
to markets in large cities where most state elites lived, and where
modities
35
Bruce
Mercantilism
University
Masters,
and
Press,
in the Middle
The Origins
Economic
Dominance
of Western
New
in Aleppo,
1600-1750
the Islamic
(New York:
Economy
1988), 221.
This content downloaded from 194.27.202.75 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 13:30:54 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
East:
York
267
Although other cities did not exert enough economic (and political) domi
nance to allow such an efficient siphoning off of surplus, and provisioning poli
cies were less strictly imposed, local authorities did pay much attention to sec
uring minimal standards of living for city dwellers. Indeed, supplying Damascus
with reasonably-priced grain was important enough to serve as an index for
good governance.37 Grain was crucial for the survival of the city's inhabitants.
Its availability in city markets in times of scarcity meant that local authorities
were savvy or powerful enough to organize its supply in face of competition
from other players who interferedwith the local grain market to enhance their
profits. Provisioning of cities in times of crisis would be a cause of much
from the countryside, where the authorities cared less about such matters.
pull
demonstrate
also deemed unsafe as a fire hazard. Taking either substance was initially out
lawed, at times under the strictest penalties. But theywere both enthusiastically
36
and Change,"
"Crisis
493.
Faroqhi,
in Eighteenth-Century
James Paul Grehan,
and Consumption
"Culture
Damascus,"
of Texas,
dissertation
110.
(Austin: University
1999),
unpublished
38
On
S. Hattox,
and Coffeehouses:
The Origins
coffee see: Ralph
of a Social
Coffee
in theMedieval
of Washington
Near East
Press,
(Seattle: University
1985); Cengiz
Beverage
Coffeehouses
of Ottoman
Kirli, "The Struggle Over Space:
Istanbul,
1780-1845,"
unpublished
37
dissertation
NY:
(Binghamton,
Binghamton
chapter one. On tobacco see Relli Shechter,
The Egyptian
Tobacco
Market
c!850-2000
State University
of New York,
2000),
University,
in theMiddle East:
Smoking, Culture, and Economy
LB. Tauris,
(London:
forthcoming),
chapter one.
This content downloaded from 194.27.202.75 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 13:30:54 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Even more, they were to differentiate between the ruling bureaucratic, military,
and religious elites and their subjects. This avenue of social stratification, how
ultimately decided what to wear, based more on personal and group preferences
than on official dictates. In fact, we may probably time the emergence of new
fashions in attire by the dates on which sumptuary laws re-emerged.40 For the
eighteenth century, Zilfi suggested that the many laws that attempted to re
impose past dress codes in fact clearly indicated an anxiety over erosion in the
power of the Ottoman government and over breakdown of communal identities
associated with past clothing regimes.41
Jirousek argued that between 1550 and 1800 men's wear changed slightly.42
clothes began to change earlier, around the turn of the eighteenth cen
while encouraging inter-elite competition this was kept indoors?
because
tury,
literally, within the Ottoman harems, and symbolically, within the boundaries of
Women's
state
the
In
elite.
this
context,
women's
clothing
other
and
forms
of
conspicu
ous consumption replaced older modes of internal elite competition, and stratifica
tion through consumption became politically
important. The introduction of
new fashions also
demands.
39
Marcus,
40
Donald
Middle
East,
Quataert,
98-99;
"Clothing
Masters,
Laws,
"Aleppo,"
State, and
58-59.
Society
in the Ottoman
Century
C.
Istanbul,"
"Goods
Zilfi,
in Consumption
in the Mahalle:
Studies
and
Encounters
Distributional
the History
of
the Ottoman
Empire,
1720
in Eighteenth
1550
Empire,
Empire,"
Jirousek,
in Consumption
"The
Transition
Studies,
211,
to Mass
based
This content downloaded from 194.27.202.75 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 13:30:54 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
269
In the early eighteenth century (the tulip era) notions of intra-elite compe
in the unprecedented
tition and stratification-through-consumption materialized
building of palaces along the banks of the Bosphoros. This activity raised the
demand for imported household and other luxury items, and changed elite food
consumption habits.44 The era itself received its name from the renewed craze
for outdoor gardens planted with expensive tulips and the decoration of a vari
ety of commodities in the shape of the tulip. In 1730, however, such conspicu
ous consumption was fiercely resisted, and brought to a halt by a revolt that
erupted from themost densely populated quarters of Istanbul.45
The revolt reflected dissatisfaction with contemporary politics (mainly the fall
of Tabriz to the Iranians, which triggered a sense of insecurity among the inhab
itants of the capital) and was not directed against upper class consumption
the
itself; such consumption provided work for many in Istanbul. Nevertheless,
revolt did set itself against the use of much needed public space for planting
tulips, and against lavish private spending at a time when the majority of the
The ending of the tulip era marked a temporary setback in elite consumption
preferences, but this process proved unstoppable in the changing economic and
political sphere of the Empire. During the eighteenth century a new commercial
44
of the Ottoman
in a Changing
Elite's
for 'Staples,'
Food Consumption:
Looking
Ariel
"The Age
of Tulips:
Salzmann,
Century;"
in
Modern
Culture
both
Consumer
(1550-1730),"
in Early
107-200
and 83-106
Studies,
Consumption
respectively.
45
see Salzmann,
On
the revolt and its consequences
94-98. The
revolt
"Age of Tulips,"
the elite's
consump
history of acts against
conspicuous
in Baghdad
criticism of court consumption
tion. See, for example,
Hanbali
habits
in Nimrod
to Mass
"From Scholarly
The Formation
Circles
Movement:
of Legal
Communities
Hurvitz,
in Islamic
The American
Historical
Review
I
994-998.
Societies,"
108, 4 (October,
2003),
to my attention.
thank the author for bringing
this information
46
Rise
Fatma Miige
Demise
Western
Ottoman
Gocek,
of the Bourgeoisie,
of Empire:
ization and Social
Press,
(New York: Oxford University
1996), chapter 3.
Change
was
not
in Islamic
This content downloaded from 194.27.202.75 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 13:30:54 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
270
RELLI SHECHTER
only during the nineteenth century that mass consumption patterns began to
the development of new consumption habits among the rul
change. However,
and
the commercial
elites
later
ing
paved the way for future
bourgeoisie
in much of the
changes in local demand. Such changes are little discussed
literature on the integration of the Empire into the world economy, where the
European impact on local markets is most often studied. Still, it has great poten
tial for explaining why some Ottoman players gradually replaced the notion of
market welfare with that of free market, which better suited their interests.
Capitulations,
century.47 This is true for the volume of imported as opposed to local trade and
for the financial contribution of imports and exports to the Ottoman economy.
Still, the impact of cross-border commerce was more significant than its imme
diate (concrete) contribution in "freeing" Ottoman markets from regulation and
commerce
existing
47
Subjects
Suraiya Faroqhi,
LB.
Tauris,
2000),
(London:
forestalling major
of the Sultan:
50; Donald
change
and Daily
Life
The Ottoman
Culture
Quataert,
in their political-econ
ble
in the Ottoman
Empire,
Empire
1700-1922
international
trade by giving favorable
regulated
trading rights to amica
some of its sovereignty
seceded
In the capitulations
the Ottoman
government
by
In
in the Empire
under favorable
conditions.
traders to conduct commerce
European
Ottomans
states.
allowing
restricted political
and economic
states, the Ottomans
rights to chosen
improved
allocating
also
the inflow of needed
ties with
these countries. The
assured
their political
capitulation
raw materials,
foodstuffs, and luxury items, the latter much
sought after by the local elite.
on imported
to fill their coffers from customs
duties
the Ottomans
further enabled
They
on friendly countries were also
the Ottomans'
favorable
goods. Thus,
trading rights bestowed
to their state. Halil
beneficial
188-190.
Inalcik, "Ottoman
State,"
49
a
trade was
Curtin
that apart from direct military
intervention, cross-cultural
suggested
powerful
external
stimulus
of change
and
disruption
in any
existing
socio-economic
This content downloaded from 194.27.202.75 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 13:30:54 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
system.
271
not allow
during the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries, merchants and domestic pro
in
of mercantilist
ducers?the
leading proponents and developers
policies
to
in
the
the
became
Ottoman
sway
empire
Europe?never
powerful enough
government to deviate from its traditional ways."50
To prove the Ottomans right in their suspicion of cross-boarder
the discussion
commerce,
in
of
the
role
international
trade
transforming
highlights
and gradually ending early modern regulation and market
below
interventions
relied on non-economic
themselves, French traders consciously
provided by their own political agents or imposed on the bureaucratic structures
of the Ottoman state itself."52 Foreign merchant communities were thus inte
grated into the Ottoman political economy that governed local markets.
One significant outcome of the above was that the implementation of capit
ulations in various urban markets depended on center-periphery relations within
the Empire. The presence of strong local officials or potent local notables meant
that the state found it hard to enforce agreements it signed, even after a foreign
send his complaint to Istanbul. During the first part of the seven
consul would
to relatively weak
social groups
trade. Philip D. Curtin, Cross-Cultural
1.
Press,
1984),
University
Cambridge
246.
"Institutional
Change,"
evil
such necessary
Delegating
tial threat of international
(Cambridge:
50
Pamuk,
51
Daniel
Goffman,
"The
Capitulations
and
the Question
the poten
largely mitigated
in World
Trade
History
of Authority
in Levantine
Eldem,
"Istanbul,"
192-193.
This content downloaded from 194.27.202.75 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 13:30:54 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Trade,
adhered
result, foreign merchants and their consuls gradually became significant pro
moters of export-led revenues and local power brokers in their own right, at
times even at the expense of central and local Ottoman ruling elites. This was
one of the most
Ottoman
integration, however, took place not only at the behest of European powers but
also as a result of local interest groups (producers, merchants, and consumers)
who had a stake in the process. Such opening up of the economy meant the
beginning of the end for an inward-looking and highly regulated early modern
economy, which benefited the state, local elites, and urban middle-strata.
Conclusion
The article argued for a broader view of the early-modern Ottoman economy,
expressed from the perspective of market welfare, which was embedded in the
system and the institutions that regulated economic life. This con
tinued to be the case even when a top-down command economy (of sorts) grad
ually disappeared and was replaced by local regulation from the middle. The
Ottomans opted for a "good enough," stable economy that protected the inter
local value
in the system.
the early-modern era of decentralization,
53
54
Daniel
Eldem,
Goffman,
"Istanbul,"
"Izmir:
from Village
191-192.
to Colonial
Port City,"
in Ottoman
City,
This content downloaded from 194.27.202.75 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 13:30:54 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
91-92.
273
justice. The same can be argued for Ottoman guilds and reli
gious endowments, both shielding city inhabitants against a variety of economic
upheavals. City took over state-led economic governance (to the extent that such
name of social
governance had existed in the past) in guiding the local economy. Although
treating such an arrangement as "civil society" in practice would be an anachro
is
nism, regulation from the middle (socially) or the city-level (geographically)
a far cry from past research that suggested a vacuum in city regimes.55
The early-modern Ottoman economy is hard to envision today, as we are
caught in a modern, neo-liberal paradigm that idealizes the economy as a free
benefiting from the old economy. If this analysis sounds familiar, it is not
it has often been applied in the context of the Ottoman Empire, but
because
because it echoes the economic dilemmas of Middle Eastern societies today.
Bibliography
Food
for
of the Ottoman
Elite's
Looking
Consumption:
"Aspects
in a Changing
In Consumption
Studies
and
'Delicacies'
Century."
An Introduction,
1550-1922:
ed. Donald
Quataert,
of the Ottoman Empire,
History
SUNY
200. Albany
NY:
Press, 2000.
Artan,
Tiilay.
'Luxuries,'
Baer, Gabriel.
1964.
Egyptian
Barkey, Karen.
NY:
Cornell
Bandits
in Modern
Guilds
and Bureaucrats:
Times.
The Ottoman
1994.
Press,
University
Mine
and Amy
Bonner, Michael,
Ener,
Singer,
NY:
SUNY
Contexts.
Press, 2003.
Albany,
Bulut,
Mehmet.
Europeans
"Reconsideration
during
of
theMercantilist
Jerusalem:
the Economic
Ages,"
(2002).
eds.
Route
Poverty
The
Israel
to State
and
'Staples,'
and
the
pp.
Oriental
Centralization.
Charity
in Middle
107
Society,
Ithaca,
East
of the Ottomans
and Western
Concepts
In http://cas.uchicago.edu/workshops/meht/
papers03/Bulut.doc.
John. "The
and Guilds
in
of Cairo
and Other
Stories:
Crafts
Chalcraft,
Striking Cabbies
New York: New York University,
dissertation.
1863-1914."
2001.
Unpublished
Egypt,
Peasants:
in Lower
Kenneth
M.
The Pasha's
and Economy
Land,
Cuno,
Egypt,
Society,
1740-1858.
55
Cambridge:
Raymond,
"Islamic
Cambridge
City,"
University
Press,
1992.
3-5.
This content downloaded from 194.27.202.75 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 13:30:54 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Curtin,
Press,
Trade
in World
History.
Cambridge:
"Istanbul:
and West,
Masters,
Ener, Mine.
Princeton
Press, 2003.
University
In An Economic
"Crisis and Change,
1590-1699."
Faroqhi,
Suraiya.
ed. Halil
Ottoman
Inalcik
and Donald
1300-1914,
Empire,
1994.
Press,
Cambridge:
Cambridge
University
Ottoman
-Approaching
-
History:
An
Introduction
and
History
of the
pp. 411-636.
Social
Quataert,
to the Sources.
Cambridge:
1999.
Press,
University
Cambridge
Culture
and Daily
in the Ottoman
London:
LB.
Empire.
Life
Subjects
of the Sultan:
2000.
Tauris,
in Sefrou."
inMoroccan
In Meaning
and Order
Geertz, Clifford. "Suq: The Bazaar
Economy
in Cultural
Hildrad
and
Three
Geertz,
Geertz,
Society,
Analysis,
Essays
by Clifford
Lawrence
1979.
Rosen,
Press,
pp. 123-244. Cambridge:
University
Cambridge
"Ottoman
General
Charac
Framework,
Gen9, Mehmet.
Industry in the Eighteenth-Century:
teristic, and Main
ed. Donald
In Manufacturing
and Turkey,
Trends."
in the Ottoman
1500
Empire
NY:
SUNY
1994.
Press,
Quataert,
pp. 59-68. Albany,
between
and Modernity."
In The State and Its
"The Guilds
Tradition
1950,
Pascale.
Ghazaleh,
to the Present,
in Egypt from Ottoman
Administration
Times
Servants,
in Cairo
The American
1995.
Press,
pp. 60-74. Cairo:
University
Fatma
Gogek,
and
Demise
Rise
Mtige.
of the Bourgeoisie,
of Empire:
New York: Oxford University
1996.
Press,
Change.
"The Capitulations
Daniel.
and the Question
of Authority
ed. Nelly
Hanna,
Westernization
Ottoman
Social
Goffman,
-
University
Cambridge
Edhem.
Eldem,
East
Cross-Cultural
in Levantine
Trade,
1600
to Colonial
In The Ottoman
East
Port City."
from Village
and
City Between
and Bruce Masters,
Izmir, and Istanbul,
Eldem, Daniel
Goffman,
Aleppo,
by Edhem
1999.
Press,
pp. 79-134.
Cambridge:
University
Cambridge
Peter.
Islamic
Roots
of Texas
Austin:
1760-1840.
Gran,
of Capitalism:
University
Egypt,
1979.
Press,
"Izmir:
West,
East History
World
Middle
Oriental
beyond
beyond
Despotism,
History
In New Frontiers
Article."
in the Social History
East,
of the Middle
Agenda
in Social
The
vol. 23, 2, ed. Enid Hill,
162-198.
Cairo:
Science,
pp.
Papers
in Cairo
American
Press, 2001.
University
"Modern
Hegel:
Cairo
An
in Eighteenth-Century
James
Paul.
"Culture
and Consumption
Damascus."
dissertation.
Austin: University
of Texas,
1999.
Unpublished
in 1600:
The Life and Times
Hanna,
of IsmaHl Abu Taqiyya,
Nelly. Making
Big Money
NY:
1998.
Press,
Egyptian Merchant.
University
Syracuse,
Syracuse
Jane. The Politics
in Ottoman
The Rise
Egypt:
of the Qazdaglis.
Hathaway,
of Households
1997.
Press,
Cambridge:
University
Cambridge
in theMedieval
The Origins
S. Coffee and Coffeehouses:
Hattox, Ralph
of a Social Beverage
Grehan,
Near
Hoexter,
East.
Seattle:
Miriam.
University
Studies
"Waqf
of Washington
1985.
Press,
in the Twentieth
Century: The
State
of the Art."
Journal
Nimrod.
Hurvitz,
Communities
"From
in Islamic
2003): 985-1008.
Circles
Scholarly
Societies."
The
to Mass
American
Movement:
Historical
The
Formation
Review
"The Ottoman
State: Economy
and Society,
1300-1600."
inalcik, Halil.
Social History
ed. Halil
Inalcik
1300-1914,
of the Ottoman
Empire,
1994.
Press,
pp. 9-409. Cambridge:
University
Cambridge
108,
of Legal
(October,
In An Economic
and Donald
This content downloaded from 194.27.202.75 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 13:30:54 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
of
and
Quataert,
Islamoglu-Inan,
The Ottoman
"Introduction:
and
Empire
'Oriental
the World-Economy,
in World-System
Despotism'
ed. Huri
Islamoglu-inan,
275
In
Perspective."
pp. 1-24. Cam
1987.
Press,
University
bridge: Cambridge
toMass
in the Later Ottoman Empire."
Fashion
"The Transition
Jirousek, Charlotte.
System Dress
An Intro
In Consumption
and
the History
1550-1922:
Studies
Empire,
of the Ottoman
NY:
ed. Donald
SUNY
Press, 2000.
duction,
pp. 201-241.
Quataert,
Albany
and
the World
The Nineteenth-Century.
The Ottoman
Kasaba,
Economy:
Empire
Re?at.
Khoury,
Rizk.
Cambridge:
Kirli, Cengiz.
dissertation.
Unpublished
New York,
2000.
M.S.
"Narh"
Kutukoglu,
R.
"Hisba"
Brill, 1997.
NY:
Binghamton,
In Encyclopaedia
Mantran,
in the Ottoman
Society
Empire, Mosul,
1997.
Press,
of Ottoman
Coffeehouses
Istanbul,
Space:
and Provincial
State
Cambridge
University
"The Struggle Over
In Encyclopaedia
new
edition,
edition,
vol.
of Islam,
of Islam,
new
on the Eve
East
Abraham.
The Middle
of Modernity,
Columbia
1989.
Press,
Century. New York:
University
Economic
Dominance
Bruce.
The Origins
Masters,
of Western
in Aleppo,
and
the Islamic
1600-1750.
cantilism
Economy
Marcus,
1988.
Press,
University
the Ottoman
"Aleppo:
West, Aleppo,
Izmir, and
State
University,
Binghamton
vol.
1540-1834.
1780-1845."
University
7, pp,
964-965.
3, pp, 489-490.
Leiden:
in the Eighteenth
Aleppo
in the Middle
New
of
York:
East:
Mer
New
York
In The Ottoman
East and
City."
City Between
and Bruce Masters,
Eldem, Daniel
Goffman,
1999.
Press,
pp. 17-78. Cambridge:
University
Cambridge
In An Economic
Bruce.
of the Ayans,
1699-1812."
and Social History
"The Age
McGowan,
Inalcik
and Donald
1300-1914,
Quataert,
pp. 637-758.
Empire,
of the Ottoman
by Halil
Cambridge:
M.S.
Meyer,
Cambridge
"Economic
Empire's
Istanbul,
University
Thought
Caravan
by Edhem
1994.
Press,
in the Ottoman
Empire
in the 14th-Early
19th Centuries."
in 1981.
in the World
East
The Middle
first published
Owen,
1800-1914,
Economy,
Roger.
London:
LB. Tauris,
1993.
Invest
The Ottoman
and European
1820-1913:
Trade,
Pamuk,
Empire
?evket.
Capitalism,
-
1987.
ment, and Production.
Press,
University
Cambridge:
Cambridge
A Monetary
History
of the Ottoman
Empire.
Cambridge:
Cambridge
2000.
"Institutional
and
Change
of Interdisciplinary
History
Ottoman
Gabriel.
Piterberg,
of California
University
Karl. The Great
Polanyi,
of the Ottoman
1500-1800."
Journal
Empire,
225-247.
2004):
at Play.
and Historiography
The
Berkeley:
Tragedy:
History
Press, 2003.
Boston:
Transformation.
Donald.
Ottoman
Raymond,
-
Press,
Beacon
1957.
Press,
in the Age
Revolution.
Cam
of the Industrial
Manufacturing
1993.
Press,
University
bridge: Cambridge
in the Ottoman
International
1720-1829."
Laws,
State, and Society
Empire,
"Clothing
Quataert,
-
the Longevity
(Autumn,
35, 2
University
Ottoman
Andre.
1700-1922.
Empire,
Cambridge:
"Islamic City, Arab City: Orientalist
Press, 2000.
University
Cambridge
and Recent Views."
British Journal
Myths
In Encyclopaedia
Leiden:
1997.
Brill,
of Islam, new edition, vol. 9, pp. 791-792.
"Suq."
"An Ancien
in the
and Political
Ariel.
Revisited:
'Privatization'
Salzmann,
Regime
Economy
Politics
and Society 21, 4 (Dec.
Ottoman
393-423.
1993):
Eighteenth-Century
Empire."
"The Age
in Early Modern
of Tulips:
Confluence
and Conflict
Consumer
Culture
This content downloaded from 194.27.202.75 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 13:30:54 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
London:
LB. Tauris,
forthcoming.
Command
Balkan
and the Ottoman
Accumulation,
"Cities,
Capital
to
in
A.D.
1000
In
the
Rise
States
1500-1800."
Cities
and
1800, ed.
Europe,
Economy,
of
CO: Westview,
1994.
P. Blockmans,
Charles
pp. 60-99. Boulder,
Tilly and Wim
In The Great
of the Ottoman
Economic
Ahmet.
"Outlines
Ottoman,
System."
Tabakoglu,
Yeni Turkiye,
2000.
vol. 2, ed. Kemal
Turkish Civilization,
pp. 7-24. Ankara:
?icek,
in the Middle
East
and North
Elites
Ehud.
"The Emergence
of Ottoman-Local
Toledano,
Market
cl850-2000.
Traian.
Stoianovich,
In Middle
ed. Ilan
and Ideas: A History from Within,
Eastern
Politics
1700-1900."
Tauris Academic
1997.
and Moshe
Studies,
Macoz,
pp. 145-162. London:
Pappe
in the 1600s. Albany,
NY:
Dror. An Ottoman
The District
Ze'evi,
Century:
of Jerusalem
SUNY
1996.
Press,
in Eighteenth-Century
in the Mahalle:
Encounters
Distributional
C. "Goods
Zilfi, Madeline
Africa,
Istanbul."
Introduction,
In Consumption
ed. Donald
Studies
and
Quataert,
pp.
the History
of the Ottoman
Empire,
NY:
SUNY
289-311.
Press,
Albany
1550-1922:
2000.
This content downloaded from 194.27.202.75 on Wed, 01 Apr 2015 13:30:54 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
An