Qualcomm Amicus Brief
Qualcomm Amicus Brief
Qualcomm Amicus Brief
NO. 14-35393
IN THE
UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
FOR THE NINTH CIRCUIT
MICROSOFT CORP.,
Plaintiff-Appellee,
v.
MOTOROLA, INC., MOTOROLA MOBILITY, INC., and GENERAL
INSTRUMENT CORPORATION
Defendants-Appellants.
Richard S. Taffet
[email protected]
Bingham McCutchen LLP
399 Park Avenue
New York, NY 10022
Patrick Strawbridge
[email protected]
Bingham McCutchen LLP
One Federal Street
Boston, MA 02110
Stephanie Schuster
[email protected]
Bingham McCutchen LLP
2020 K Street NW
Washington, DC 20006
Attorneys for Amicus Curiae
Qualcomm Incorporated
-i-
TABLE OF CONTENTS
TABLE OF AUTHORITIES.....ii
CORPORATE DISCLOSURE STATEMENT.v
STATEMENT REQUIRED BY RULE 29(c)(5)..v
INTEREST OF AMICUS CURIAE...1
SUMMARY OF THE ARGUMENT5
ARGUMENT.....9
I. A RAND Commitment Is A Contract, The Meaning And Scope Of Which
Must Be Determined Consistent With Established Contract Law..9
A. Fundamental Rules Of Contract Construction Should Guide The
Interpretation Of RAND Commitments.9
B. RAND Contracts Must Be Interpreted Based On The Terms Of The IPR
Policies Under Which They Arise, And Not Based On Theoretical Or
Policy Preferences....11
II. The Flaws Of The District Courts Approach To Interpreting The RAND
Contracts At Issue....17
A. The District Court Ignored The Objective Of Ensuring Adequate
Compensation For Innovators..18
B. The District Courts Concerns About Royalty Stacking And Hold-Up
Lacked Any Basis In Contract Or Evidence19
1. Purely theoretical concerns about royalty stacking do not properly
inform the interpretation of RAND terms...19
2. Using theoretical concerns about hold-up to inform the
interpretation of RAND terms was likewise misdirected...24
C. The Deviation From Established Principles Of Contract Interpretation
Led The District Court To Apply Additional Unsound Valuation
Limitations...27
1. The RAND contract provides no basis for the use of an ex ante
incremental value analysis for SEPs..27
2. The RAND contract does not support an arbitrary evaluation of a
patents value to a standard, in addition to the consideration of a
patents use in the infringing product29
CONCLUSION..30
-i-
TABLE OF AUTHORITIES
Page(s)
CASES
Apple Inc. v. Motorola, Inc.,
757 F.3d 1286 (Fed. Cir. 2014).16
Apple, Inc. v. Motorola Mobility, Inc.,
886 F. Supp. 2d 1061 (W.D. Wis. 2012).9
Baldwin v. Trailer Inns, Inc.,
266 F.3d 1104 (9th Cir. 2001).....9
Blue Mountain Meml Gardens v. Dept of Licensing Cemetery Bd.,
971 P.2d 75 (Wash. Ct. App. 1999)..10
Bort v. Parker,
42 P.3d 980 (Wash. Ct. App. 2002) ...9
Brogan & Anensen LLC v. Lamphiaer,
202 P.3d 960 (Wash. 2009)...11
Commonw. Sci. & Indus. Res. Org. v. Cisco Sys.,
No. 6:11-cv-343, 2014 WL 3805817 (E.D. Tex. July 23, 2014)7
Ericsson Inc. v. D-Link Sys., Inc.,
No. 6:10-cv-473, 2013 WL 4046225 (E.D. Tex. Aug. 6, 2013)...7, 22
Festo Corp. v. Shoketsu Kinzoku Kogyo Kabushiki Co.,
535 U.S. 722 (2002)..17
Georgia-Pacific Corp. v. U.S. Plywood Corp.,
318 F. Supp. 1116 (S.D.N.Y. 1970)....15, 23
Hearst Commcns v. Seattle Times Co.,
115 P.3d 262 (Wash. 2005)...11
Hollis v. Garwall,
974 P.2d 836 (Wash. 1999)...21
- ii -
- iii -
- iv -
-v-
patents
(SEPs)
subject
to
RAND
(reasonable
and
result, Qualcomm has also been a principal developer of the 4G technology that
forms the basis for the long term evolution (LTE) standards now being deployed
worldwide.
As the pioneer of CDMA and an extensive contributor to LTE, Qualcomm
has developed an industry-leading portfolio of technologies that are protected by
both SEPs and non-essential patents, consisting of approximately 36,000 patents
worldwide, with some 50,000 patent applications pending.
This portfolio
Qualcomm could not have made, or continue to make, the risky investments in
R&D at the levels needed to develop next-generation cellular technologies.
Qualcomm is not only a research and licensing company. It is also the
worlds leading supplier of the wireless communications chips that are the heart of
a mobile phone. As a large technology product company, Qualcomm obtains
licenses from others in the industry. Qualcomms dual position as a major licensor
and major licensee gives it an unusual and balanced view into the operation of
RAND commitments and licensing within standards-dependent industries.
In addition, Qualcomm has been an active participant in numerous SSOs,
including the Institute of Electrical and Electronics Engineers (IEEE) and the
International Telecommunications Union (ITU), which are relevant to this case.
Qualcomm regularly participates in SSO deliberations regarding RAND licensing
commitments. Based on the promise of adequate compensation, Qualcomm has
made hundreds of voluntary commitments to various SSOs to subject its patented
inventions to RAND obligationsincluding SEPs covering immensely valuable
inventions that make possible faster wireless data-transfer, greater networkcapacity, lower power-consumption in mobile devices, better cellular coverage,
and more.
Qualcommalong with the cellular industry worldwidehas experienced
-3-
extraordinary growth over the last two decades under existing SSO policies and
their balanced approach to RAND licensing. As both a driver and a beneficiary of
the investment, innovation, and rapid uptake of technology by consumers,
Qualcomm has an acute interest in ensuring the continuation of such growth based
on the accurate understanding and enforcement of RAND licensing obligations.
For this reason, Qualcomm is very concerned that, despite the remarkable success
of the standardized cellular industry at all levels of the value chain, SEPs and
RAND licensing have recently become subjects of intense controversy. Partisan
advocates mix alarmist warnings with favored policy prescriptions unmoored from
the terms of any SSO policy, RAND commitment, or the intent of the innovator
who made such a commitment. The chorus is focused on lowering returns to
innovators while decreasing costs for implementers. Qualcomm is concerned that
courts, like the District Court here, can unwisely lose sight of the need to
rigorously balance the interests of both innovator and implementer. This would
radically change a wildly successful standardization regime and stifle incentives
for innovation.
-4-
these two objectives. Instead, it focused almost exclusively on the single goal of
what it described as facilitating widespread adoption of standards. This not only
misstates one of the IPR policies goalsproviding standard implementers with
access to SEPsbut also ignores the equally important adequate compensation
goal altogether. Driven by this one-sided view, the District Court improperly
modified the Georgia-Pacific analysisoften used in patent cases to determine
reasonable royalties under 35 U.S.C. 284to disconnect its determination of a
RAND royalty from the specific contracts at issue and the patent law principles
they incorporate.
Further skewing its analysis, the Court gave near dispositive weight in
interpreting the RAND commitments to theoretical risks of royalty stacking and
patent hold-up. This approach, however, was consistent with neither the RAND
commitments nor the evidence presented below, and instead unfairly placed a
thumb on the scale in favor of the implementer (and against the innovator). This is
inconsistent with decisions by other courts that have adopted a more neutral
analytical framework. Notably, another court has twice taken the proper approach
(consistent with accepted contract and patent principles) to resolving RAND
disputes, rejecting proposals to modify the Georgia-Pacific factors based on
speculative risks of royalty stacking and hold-up, where there was no evidence that
-6-
It would
necessarily devalue all SEPs, regardless of the actual value each contributes to the
success of standardized products, and could form the basis for industrial policies
that inhibit incentives to innovate and develop successful standards activities. 3
See, e.g., Ericsson Inc. v. D-Link Sys., Inc., No. 6:10-cv-473, 2013 WL
4046225, at *18 (E.D. Tex. Aug. 6, 2013) (declining to instruct jury on alleged
effects of royalty stacking in calculating royalty) (appeal pending); Commonw. Sci.
& Indus. Res. Org. v. Cisco Sys., No. 6:11-cv-343, 2014 WL 3805817, at *12 (E.D.
Tex. July 23, 2014) (noting that specific adjustments to the [Georgia-Pacific]
framework are not necessary here).
3
Such a result would be unwarranted. The standards at issue in this case have
been wildly successful, and this particular dispute should not overshadow the
hundreds, if not thousands, of existing bilateral RAND licenses, which have
allowed the standards to flourish. Indeed, products incorporating these standards
are ubiquitous (routers, smartphones, printers, gaming devices, etc.), proving that
the existing, balanced RAND licensing regime works well.
That is why it is imperative that the Court identify those errors and either
reverse the District Court or, should it affirm the decision, state expressly that it is
limited strictly to its facts. Doing so is vital to ensure faithful interpretation of the
contractual RAND commitments of SEP owners, and maintain a RAND
environment that has allowed both innovation and adoption to flourish.
-8-
ARGUMENT
I.
constitutes RAND royalties for a particular SEP must give effect to the mutual
intent of the parties at the time they formed their agreement. Baldwin v. Trailer
Inns, Inc., 266 F.3d 1104, 1118 (9th Cir. 2001) (applying Washington law).
The best evidence of the parties intent is the language of the agreement.
See W. Plaza, LLC v. Tison, 322 P.3d 1, 3 (Wash. Ct. App. 2014) (In construing a
-9-
contract, we give the parties intent as expressed in the instruments plain language
controlling weight .). Terms generally bear their ordinary meaning unless
otherwise defined by the parties or by the dictates of the context. Scribner v.
Worldcom, Inc., 249 F.3d 902, 908 (9th Cir. 2001). [A] term of art in a given
field is given its technical meaning when used in an agreement within that field.
Blue Mountain Meml Gardens v. Dept of Licensing Cemetery Bd., 971 P.2d 75,
77 (Wash. Ct. App. 1999). A court cannot ignore the language agreed upon by
the parties . Pub. Emps. Mut. Ins. v. Sellen Constr., 740 P.2d 913, 915 (Wash.
Ct. App. 1987). [C]ourts do not have the power, under the guise of interpretation,
to rewrite contracts the parties have deliberately made for themselves.
McCormick v. Dunne & Black, P.S., 167 P.3d 610, 619 (Wash. Ct. App. 2007);
see 11 WILLISTON ON CONTRACTS 32:2 (4th ed.) ([Courts] can only enforce the
contract to which the parties themselves have agreed.).
Moreover, a fundamental rule[] of contract interpretation is that the
meaning afforded the provision and the whole contract must be reasonable and
consistent with the purpose of the overall undertaking. Newport Yacht Basin
Assn v. Supreme Nw., Inc., 285 P.3d 70, 79 (Wash. Ct. App. 2012). In other
words, if the principal purpose of the parties is ascertainable it is given great
weight. RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF CONTRACTS 202(1) (1981).
While a court may consider extrinsic evidence to help interpret a contract
- 10 -
term and determine the contracting parties intent, only objective manifestations
of the parties intenti.e. evidencemay inform contract interpretation. Brogan
& Anensen LLC v. Lamphiaer, 202 P.3d 960, 96162 (Wash. 2009). Unproven
theories and speculation must be disregarded. See Lillywhite v. Piha, 134 Wash.
App. 1009, 1009 (2006). And in all instances, generalized public policy concerns
cannot be used to rewrite a clear and lawful contract. Hearst Commcns v. Seattle
Times Co., 115 P.3d 262, 271 (Wash. 2005); accord Orange Belt Dist. Council of
Painters v. W. E. Stubblefield & Sons, 437 F.2d 754, 756 (9th Cir. 1971).
B.
Consistent with the foregoing, the meaning of the RAND contracts at issue
must be ascertained by first examining their sourcesthe IEEE and ITU IPR
policiesand then by considering available evidence regarding their underlying
purposes and the expectations of the parties. Any other approach would frustrate,
rather than implement, the contracting parties intent.
The IEEE and ITU IPR policies set forth the relevant RAND commitments:
[A] license for compliant implementation of the standard will be made
available under reasonable rates, with reasonable terms and conditions
that are demonstrably free of any unfair discrimination.
Standards Bd. Bylaws (IEEE IPR Policy) 6.2.
- 11 -
IEEE-SA
The patent holder is willing to negotiate licenses on a nondiscriminatory basis on reasonable terms and conditions.
Common
- 12 -
Balancing Innovation & Intellectual Property Rights In a StandardsSetting Context, ITU NEWS No. 9 (2012), available at https://itunews.itu.int/en;
see also ITU IPR Policy ([A] patent embodied fully or partly in a [standard] must
be accessible to everybody without undue constraints.); IEEE IPR Policy 6.2(b)
(providing process making SEPs available to an unrestricted number of applicants
on a worldwide basis).
5
Available at http://www.itu.int/dms_pub/itu-t/oth/06/14/T06140000030002
PDFE.pdf. Other IPR policies likewise emphasize this balance. E.g., ETSI IPR
Policy 3.1 ([T]he ETSI IPR POLICY seeks a balance between the needs of
standardization for public use in the field of telecommunications and the rights of
the owners of IPRs.).
- 13 -
costs of implementation.
Moreover, a proper construction of a RAND contract that respects the
parties expectations must be informed by applicable patent law. When contracts
(like those at issue here) employ terms that reflect well settled principles of
patent lawsuch as reasonable royalties6the pertinent language of the
contract[s] indicates convincingly that the parties intended for patent law to apply
in interpreting the Agreement[s]. Medtronic, Inc. v. White, 526 F.3d 487, 496
97 (9th Cir. 2008); see Synopsis, Inc. v. Magma Design Automation, Inc., No. C04-3923, 2007 WL 322353, at *24 (N.D. Cal. Jan. 31, 2007) ([T]erms common to
patent law and used in the [contract], such as invention, were to be understood
in accordance with their meaning under patent law.). That is especially so where,
as here, there is no evidence in the record that the parties to the RAND contract
intended otherwise.
Accordingly, in determining the reasonableness of RAND royalties, courts
should look to well-established patent damages principles for determining a
reasonable royalty. This includes the patentees fundamental expectation that
the investments and risks essential to invention will be rewarded. See Paltex Corp.
v. Mossinghoff, 758 F.2d 594, 600 (Fed. Cir. 1985) ([T]he encouragement of
See, e.g., McKeever v. United States, 14 Ct. Cl. 396, 425 (1878) (setting
patent damages as the fair and reasonable value of a license based upon such a
royalty as it may reasonably be presumed the defendants would have been willing
to pay and the claimant to accept if the matter at the outset had gone to an express
agreement).
- 15 -
contract.8 Proper application of the Georgia-Pacific factors ensures that each party
is put to its respective proof, and that the analysis does not bake in a bias that
favors one party over the other. This approach is consistent with the Federal
Circuits recent decision rejecting arguments that RAND-committed patents should
be treated differently when evaluating the other major patent remedyinjunctions.
See Apple Inc. v. Motorola, Inc., 757 F.3d 1286, 133132 (Fed. Cir. 2014)
(rejecting the departure from established legal principles because of the existence
of a RAND commitment).
This non-biased, flexible approach has allowed for the enormous success of
RAND licensing to date. While much has been written about this case and similar
litigation in the smartphone wars, licensing disputes over SEPs are rare. The
phenomenal success of the WiFi standard at issue here, and the 3G and 4G cellular
technology developed and deployed by Qualcomm, under the current regime
refutes any claim that RAND agreements need to be radically altered. For every
litigation involving an SEP-licensing issue, hundreds (if not thousands) of licenses
have been successfully negotiateda fact too often forgotten in RAND debates.
This success counsels caution, lest activism fundamentally disrupts a system that
has functioned well beyond any objective expectations to deliver ever-better
technologies and products to consumers.
emphasized the need for great caution before adopting changes that disrupt the
settled expectations of the inventing community.
Throughout its analysis, the District Court wrongly emphasized that the
central principle of a RAND commitment is the widespread adoption of a
standard.
2111217, at 456. The District Court used this to justify numerous limitations and
downward revisions during its RAND royalty analysis. See id. 55, 70, 110,
45960, 50910, 526 n.23, 558 (invoking widespread adoption as the purpose of
the RAND commitment). But the RAND policies at issue in this case are designed
to balance two principles, adequate compensation for SEP owners and access
to SEPs. See supra, pp. 1213. Neither principal is made any more central or
important than the other. By ignoring one of these goals (adequate compensation),
and misstating the other (widespread adoption of the standard rather than
access to SEPs), the District Court rewrote the balanced RAND commitment
from a right to access on reasonable terms into a one-sided directive that advances
only implementers interests in obtaining licenses at the lowest possible cost. This
- 18 -
innovate, and there is no basis in contract or patent law for placing the success of a
standard on the backs of patentees alone.
balance in crafting their IPR policies. The District Courts fixation on widespread
adoption fundamentally misstated the bargain struck by the RAND commitment,
and this error permeated the remainder of its analysis.
B.
- 19 -
proper methodology for determining a RAND royalty should address the risk of
royalty stacking by considering the aggregate royalties that would apply if other
SEP holders made royalty demands of the implementer. Microsoft, 2013 WL
2111217, at 6566 (emphases added). Elevating this hypothetical concern to
fact, the District Court adjusted certain Georgia-Pacific factors to cap the potential
royalty based on a mathematical comparison of the patents declared by that patent
owner as potentially essential, to the aggregate of all other potentially essential
patents for which a royalty could be charged, even if no royalties were being
charged or the asserted patents were in fact not essential.9 Id. 53946. The
District Court did this despite uncontroverted trial testimony that there was no
factual evidence supporting the existence of any actual stacking in this case. 10
Relying instead on the general opinions of litigation experts, the District Court
asserted that any royalty rate that implicates such clear stacking concerns does
not stand up to the central principle of the RAND commitmentwidespread
adoption of the standard. Id. 456.
9
The District Court adjusted factor 15 (the amount the licensee and licensor
would have agreed upon at the time infringement began), and cited RANDs antistacking principle to limit the upper bound of the RAND ranges for the patents in
question. Microsoft, 2013 WL 2111217, at 53839, 586, 605, 622.
10
See Nov. 13, 2012 Tr. 178:2124 (Murphy) (admitting that the evidence
[he] ha[s] seen shows that no stacking with the 802.11 standard); Nov. 16, 2012
Tr. 140:1519 (Lynde) (same); Nov. 13, 2012 Tr. 179:914 (Murphy) (admitting
that there is no evidence of stacking for the H.264 standard); Nov. 16, 2012 Tr.
140:23141:2 (Lynde) (same).
- 20 -
OF
IT
2.
The District Court also expressed great concern about the potential for patent
hold-up, which it characterized as the ability of a holder of an SEP to demand
more than the value of the patented technology and to attempt to capture the value
of the standard itself . Microsoft, 2013 WL 2111217, at 55. The District
Court stated that hold-up can threaten the diffusion of valuable standards and
undermine the standard-setting process, id. 57, and it ultimately modified
Georgia-Pacific factors 6, 8, 10, and 13 to account for the potential of hold-up, id.
103, 107, 109.
This approach again ignored the evidentiary record and raises several
interrelated questions about the value of a patent and the meaning of hold-up. As a
preliminary matter, there is no mention of hold-up in the RAND policies, including
those at issue here. The issue in any RAND case is whether the terms under
consideration are reasonable.11 More fundamentally, references to concerns about
hold-up cannot supply what is lacking from the language and purposes of the
RAND policies before the Court: evidence that the parties to RAND commitments
understood or should reasonably have understood that fees above those derived by
11
This is unsurprising given the language of the RAND commitment and the
established patent law governing the determination of a reasonable royalty (which
informs those commitments). In contrast, the various theories that implementers
have urged (i.e. patentees must be denied hold-up value or value that results
from standardization) lack any basis in the text of the IPR policies or in patent law.
- 24 -
See Nov. 13, 2012 Tr. 180:79 (Murphy) (admitting that whether hold-up
exists is an open question); Nov. 16, 2012 Tr. 67:410 (Simcoe) (admitting he
cant nail down any particular license from any company as an example of holdup); id. at 135:25136:1 (Lynde) (admitting he has no basis from economic
evidence to conclude whether or not patent hold-up is a real problem).
13
Such conduct not only undermines the balance of the RAND approach
This case is a prime example; the prospective licensee sought relief from
the court almost immediately upon receiving the first offer. See Appellants Br., at
78.
15
approach for valuing SEPs and a novel two-step approach for determining the
contribution of a patent to the value of an infringing product are examples.
Imposing either constraint on SEPs values cannot be supported under contract or
patent law.16
1.
17
- 29 -
Nothing in the RAND contract, IPR policies, or patent law supports this
approach. The devaluation inherent in the District Courts approach is yet another
step that frustrates innovators ability to obtain the adequate compensation
necessary for them to contribute to standards. Moreover, it is well-accepted that a
reasonable royalty should be based on the use made of the invention by the
infringer, LaserDynamics, 694 F.3d at 6667, not also weighed in the abstract
against the entirety of the standard.
CONCLUSION
The District Courts methodology for interpreting Motorolas RAND
commitments contravened the terms and purposes of the relevant contracts,
ignored the evidence in this case, and wrongly treated RAND-committed patents as
different from other patents.
- 30 -
Dated:
Respectfully submitted,
BINGHAM McCUTCHEN LLP
- 31 -
CERTIFICATE OF SERVICE
I hereby certify that on September 22, 2014, a copy of the Brief of Amicus
Curiae Qualcomm Incorporated was filed with the Clerk of the Court using the
Courts CM/ECF system, which will automatically send email notification of such
filing to all counsel of record.
- 32 -
CERTIFICATE OF COMPLIANCE
Pursuant to Federal Rules of Appellate Procedure 29(c)(7) and 32(a)(7)(C), I
hereby certify:
1. this brief complies with the type-volume limitation set forth in Rule
32(a)(7)(B) of the Federal Rules of Appellate procedure in that this
brief contains 6,998 words, excluding those parts of the brief
exempted from the type-volume calculation by Federal Rule
32(a)(7)(B)(iii) and Circuit Rule 32(b); and
2. this brief complies with the typeface and type-style requirements of
Rules 32(a)(5) and 32(a)(6) of the Federal Rules of Appellate
Procedure in that this brief is formatted in Microsoft Word 2010 using
a proportionally spaced typeface in 14-point Times New Roman font.
- 33 -