From Recession To Collapse: The Bush Administration and The Over-Valued Dollar
From Recession To Collapse: The Bush Administration and The Over-Valued Dollar
From Recession to
Collapse: The Bush
Administration and the
Over-Valued Dollar
By Dean Baker*
tel: 202-293-5380
fax: 202-588-1356
www.cepr.net
Dean Baker is the Co-director and an Economist at the Center for Economic and Policy Research in Washington, D.C.
Contents
Introduction ........................................................................................................................................................ 1
The Origins of the Trade Deficit: The Asian Financial Crisis and the Run-Up in the Value of the
Dollar. .................................................................................................................................................................. 2
The Exploding Trade Deficit ........................................................................................................................... 7
The Bailout........................................................................................................................................................10
Conclusion ........................................................................................................................................................11
Acknowledgements
These are remarks, as prepared for delivery, at the Conference on the George W. Bush Presidency,
at Hofstra University, in Hempstead, NY, on March 26, 2015.
Introduction
Accounts of the economic policy in the George W. Bush administration usually center on the tax
cuts in his first year in office and the economic collapse in his last year, a result of his failure to
effectively regulate housing finance. While these policies are important in the context of Bushs
presidency, most discussions miss the underlying dynamics of the economy in the Bush
administration. The key here is a backdrop of secular stagnation that had its basis in the large U.S.
trade deficit. The trade deficit was an enormous drain on demand, which could only be filled by
large budget deficits or asset bubbles. This trade deficit was in turn the result of a severely overvalued dollar, which can be dated to the Clinton Administrations design of the International
Monetary Fund (I.M.F.) bailout of countries affected by the Asian financial crisis.
There are two reasons this discussion may appear somewhat at odds with most assessments of the
Bush administrations economic record. The first is that it doesnt fit well with the story either
political party likes to tell. Republicans would like to tell a story whereby the tax cuts put in place in
2001 and 2002 boosted the economy out of recession. By contrast, Democrats pitch a tale where the
Bush administration threw away the budget surpluses from the Clinton years with unneeded tax cuts
and expensive wars. This analysis is at radically at odds with both perspectives.
The other reason that this account differs with those more frequently told about the Bush
administration is that it accepts that an economy can suffer from secular stagnation, defined as a
prolonged period where output is limited by inadequate demand. The idea that the economy could
suffer from an ongoing problem of inadequate demand has a long history, with Keynes being the
most prominent proponent. However, this perspective was largely drummed out of the profession
with the development of the neo-classical-Keynesian synthesis in the years after World War II.
In the synthesis view, shortfalls in demand could only occur during recessions. Recessions are
relatively short-term and self-correcting. The government may or may not be able to speed up a
recovery, but its action is certainly not necessary, since the economy would return to full
employment even without government action. From this perspective, secular stagnation is essentially
ruled out as a possibility, so there was no point in looking for it.
Now that we seem to be experiencing a prolonged period of below full employment levels of
output, secular stagnation is again an acceptable view within the economics profession. This analysis
puts it at the center of the economys problems during the Bush years.
From Recession to Collapse: The Bush Administration and the Over-Valued Dollar
From Recession to Collapse: The Bush Administration and the Over-Valued Dollar
The net effect of these actions by developing countries was a tremendous increase in the value of
the dollar. The real broad index constructed by the Federal Reserve Board, which adjusts for
differences in inflation rates, shows that the value of the dollar rose by 17.8 percent between August
of 1996 and August of 1998, measured against the currencies of our trading partners. This rise in the
value of the dollar had the predicted effect on the U.S. trade deficit: it expanded from 1.2 percent of
GDP in 1996 to 3.7 percent of GDP by 2000.
However, this trade deficit was not associated with a lack of demand, because it coincided with the
rise of the stock bubble. (The growth spurred by the bubble undoubtedly also partly fueled the rise
of the trade deficit.) At its peak, the ratio of stock prices to trend corporate earnings was well over
30 to 1. This is more than twice the historic average of 14 to 1. The wealth generated by the stock
bubble led to what was, at the time, an unprecedented boom in consumption. The saving rate fell to
4.2 percent of disposable income.1
In addition to the demand generated by bubble-driven consumption, the stock bubble also
generated demand through its impact on investment. This was a rare period in which there was a
substantial amount of investment being financed by the direct issuance of shares. (More typically,
companies first go public when the original shareholders want to cash out part of their investments.)
There was a huge amount of capital available to finance all manner of ill-conceived Internet and
technology ventures. Non-residential investment peaked at 14.6 percent of GDP in 2000. This
compared to a peak of just 12.7 percent of GDP in the 1980s business cycle.
The demand generated by the stock bubble ensured the economy remained strong, in spite of the
growing trade deficit, through the Clinton administration. However, after the bubble began to
collapse in 2000, the demand it had generated disappeared as well. Consumption and investment
both fell sharply in 2001, throwing the economy into a recession. The collapse of the bubble and the
resulting recession were, of course, the main reasons that the Clinton budget surpluses disappeared,
while the stimulus provided by Bush tax cuts and the rise in military spending associated with the
administrations wars were both positive from the standpoint of generating demand in the economy.
This does not mean that the tax cuts and the wars were the best ways to boost the economy. Tax
cuts that were more oriented towards the poor- and middle-income households certainly would have
led to more demand per dollar than the Bush tax cuts, which disproportionately went to high1
The saving rate may have even been lower than the official data indicate. Income-side GDP sharply outpaced expenditure-side
GDP. If the error in measurement was on the income side, for example from capital gains showing up as normal income, then the
true saving rate would actually be lower, since true income for GDP purposes would have been less than reported income. This
issue is discussed in Rosnick, David and Dean Baker, 2011. When Numbers Dont Add Up: The Statistical Discrepancy in GDP
Accounts. Washington, DC: Center for Economic and Policy Research,
http://www.cepr.net/index.php/publications/reports/when-numbers-dont-add-up.
From Recession to Collapse: The Bush Administration and the Over-Valued Dollar
income taxpayers. On the spending side, investments in infrastructure and education would have
had a larger demand-side effect, in addition to increasing productivity in future years. Nonetheless, if
the option was between the Bush tax cuts and military spending versus no stimulus, there can be no
doubt that the administrations tax cuts and spending increased growth.
It is important to recognize that even with the benefit of expansionary fiscal policy, the recession
was still quite severe from the perspective of the labor market. Measured in output terms, the 2001
recession was the mildest of the post-war era, but its impact on the labor market was arguably the
largest. While the recession officially ended in December of 2001, the economy continued to lose
jobs through 2002. It didnt start to create jobs again until September of 2003. Even then, the pace
of job growth was very weak, unlike the strong rebounds from prior downturns. The economy did
not gain back the jobs lost in the recession until January of 2005. Until the more recent recession,
this was the longest period without job growth since the Great Depression. As is now recognized, it
is not easy to recover from a recession caused by the collapse of an asset bubble.
When the economy did begin to create jobs again, it was on the back of the housing bubble. By
2002, home prices had already grown far out of line with their trend values. At that point, home
prices were already more than 30 percent above trend values, with no plausible explanation in the
fundamentals of the housing market.2
On the demand side, income growth had slowed sharply with the onset of the recession in 2001.
The countrys demographics were certainly not well-suited for a housing boom. Overall population
growth had slowed and the huge baby boom cohort was already in their 40s and 50s, ages when
many were looking to downsize into smaller houses or apartments. While many did argue that there
were supply constraints, such as environmental restrictions, that were pushing up prices by limiting
building, the data contradict this argument. The country had near record rates of housing
construction over the years from 2002 to 2006. Neither demand nor supply conditions supported a
run-up in home prices based on the fundamentals of the market.
The rental market provided further confirmation that there was a bubble in the market, rather than
fundamentals increasing the cost of housing. If the fundamentals of supply and demand were
driving up the cost of housing, then we should have expected to see an increase in rents that
paralleled the rise in sale prices. While the two would not necessarily move in tandem, if excess
demand for homes was causing the unprecedented rise in house prices, then surely there would also
be a substantial increase in rents as well. In fact, rents were doing exactly nothing. The consumer
2
The situation of the housing market at the time is discussed in Baker, Dean (2002), The Run-Up in House Prices: Is It Real or Is
It Another Bubble? Washington, DC: Center for Economic and Policy Research, available at
http://www.cepr.net/index.php/reports/the-run-up-in-home-prices-is-it-real-or-is-it-another-bubble/.
From Recession to Collapse: The Bush Administration and the Over-Valued Dollar
price index measure of owner equivalent rent (which excludes utilities) rose almost exactly in step
with the overall rate of inflation over the years 2000 to 2006.
If we needed additional confirmation of the bubble, we could also look to vacancy rates. These were
at record highs as early as 2002. Record vacancies are not consistent with a story of home prices
being driven up by a shortage of housing. They are consistent with a story of speculative demand
pushing up home prices. People will be prepared to hold a house and let it sit empty if they expect
the price to rise 15 to 20 percent a year, as was actually happening in many parts of the country.
In spite of the evidence of a dangerous housing bubble as early as 2002, the overwhelming majority
of economists in the country insisted that nothing was wrong. Somehow it was difficult for
economists to accept the idea that large markets could be subject to bubbles, even though we had
just witnessed the collapse of a massive bubble in the stock market. Most probably accepted the
views expressed by Alan Greenspan, who stated that the market was being driven by fundamentals.3
This was certainly the case with the public statements of the economic officials in the Bush
administration. They applauded the fact that ownership rates were rising, especially among
moderate-income families and minorities. Rather than being troubled by the spread of subprime
lending and exotic mortgage products, they argued these developments were examples of innovation
in the financial sector. This was all part of the growth of the ownership society.
The fact that the bubble grew undetected and the abuses in the industry went unnoticed is simply
inexcusable. The gap between home prices and their longer term trend levels continued to grow
larger, finally peaking at more than 70 percent in 2006. All of this time, rents remained essentially
even with inflation and the national housing vacancy rate continually hit new levels. The
deterioration of mortgage lending standards was also hardly a secret. The NINJA loan became a
common joke in the industry. NINJA stood for no job, no income, and no assets. The basic
numbers told the story. Subprime loans grew from 8 to 9 percent of the market in the late 1990s to a
peak of 25 percent in 2006.
Perhaps even more striking was the explosion in Alt-A loans. These went from being 1 to 2 percent
of the market in normal years to 15 percent at the peak of the bubble. This category is notable
because ALT-A borrowers are, in principle, people with good credit who cant qualify for prime
mortgages because they lack proper documentation of their income or assets. The conventional view
is that these borrowers are often small business owners who cant show evidence of their true
income because they failed to report all of their income on their tax returns. They pay a high price
Greenspan expressed this view in testimony presented to the Joint Economic Committee of Congress in April of 2002
[http://www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/testimony/2002/20020417/default.htm].
From Recession to Collapse: The Bush Administration and the Over-Valued Dollar
for the lack of documentation, typically being charged 1-2 percentage points higher interest than
they would pay on a prime mortgage. When the number of loans in this category exploded, it was a
clear warning sign that there were serious problems in the mortgage market. Still, no one in a
position of authority in the Bush administration seemed to notice or care.4
While the danger signs were flashing everywhere, the housing bubble did sustain a moderately
healthy recovery. Of course, there were the direct effects noted earlier. There was a huge expansion
in residential construction, with housing rising from its normal level of 3 to 4 percent of GDP to a
peak of 6.5 percent of GDP in 2005. Unsurprisingly, the wealth created by the bubble also led to a
surge of consumption through the housing wealth effect. The saving rate hit an all-time low of 2.5
percent of disposable income in 2005.5 The combined effect of higher construction and higher
consumption due to the wealth effect was equal to more than 4.5 percentage points of GDP at the
peak of the bubble. Assuming a multiplier on this spending of 1.5, the bubble was giving an annual
stimulus of close to 7.0 percentage points of GDP (at $1,260 billion in the 2015 economy) at the
peak of the bubble.
When the bubble began to collapse in 2006, all of this demand disappeared. In fact, the demand
from housing more than disappeared, as the enormous overbuilding of the bubble years led to
several years in which construction was far below its normal level. Remarkably, the falloff in
consumption following the collapse of the bubble was treated as somewhat of a mystery as
economists sought to explain it by the rise in debt as opposed to the simple and obvious explanation
that we had lost close to $8 trillion in housing wealth.6 It should not have been a surprise to anyone
that bubble-generated wealth had been driving consumption; Alan Greenspan himself had coauthored several papers on the topic as he touted the virtues of cash-out refinancing, which was
taking place on a large scale during the bubble years. Apparently, economists had forgotten basic
facts that had been widely known and discussed just a few years earlier.
5
6
Incredibly, Alan Greenspan told a Washington Post reporter that he just became aware of the surge in subprime loans in January of
2006, just as he was ending his tenure as Fed chair ( Bubble, Washington Post, June 15, 2008). If true, this would indicate an
astounding degree of negligence on his part. It would be comparable to the Secretary of Defense not noticing the attack on Pearl
Harbor in December of 1941.
There was also a large negative statistical discrepancy in the GDP accounts in the peak years of the bubble, which is consistent
with the view that capital gains in the housing market were showing up as income . If we pull the statistical discrepancy out of
income, then the saving rate at the peak of the bubble was essentially zero.
For example, see Mian, Atif and Amir Sufi, 2014. House of Debt: How They (and You) Caused the Great Recession and How We Can
Prevent It From Happening Again. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
From Recession to Collapse: The Bush Administration and the Over-Valued Dollar
7
8
These data can be found in the Bureau of Economic Analysis, National Income and Product Accounts, Table 1.1.5.
These data can be found at the Federal Reserve Boards website
[http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h10/summary/indexbc_m.htm].
From Recession to Collapse: The Bush Administration and the Over-Valued Dollar
In addition to the impact of the dollar, the trade deficit also rose because of a sharp run-up in the price of oil. Oil had been selling
for less than $15 a barrel in 1998. It had reached more than $70 a barrel in 2007 at the time recession hit
[http://www.eia.gov/dnav/pet/pet_pri_spt_s1_a.htm]. While the direct effect of higher oil prices for the United States is an
increase in the trade deficit, it would be expected that this rise would lead to a fall in the value of the dollar so that we increase net
exports of other goods and services.
10 These data are taken from the International Monetary Fund
[http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2014/02/weodata/weorept.aspx?pr.x=57&pr.y=9&sy=1997&ey=2019&scsm=1&s
sd=1&sort=country&ds=.&br=1&c=924&s=BCA_NGDPD&grp=0&a=].
11 Baker and Walentin, 2001. Money for Nothing: The Increasing Cost of Foreign Reserve Holdings to Developing Countries.
Washington, DC: Center for Economic and Policy Research.
From Recession to Collapse: The Bush Administration and the Over-Valued Dollar
of long-term U.S. government debt. In this context, it should hardly have been a surprise that longterm interest rates in the United States remained low, allowing the housing bubble and the resulting
distortions to grow ever larger.
The key policy mistake in this period was to look the other way as these imbalances were growing
ever larger, as though they would somehow correct themselves with no major impact on the
economy. Ideally, the Bush administration would have negotiated with China and other developing
countries to arrange a lower value for the dollar. This could have brought the trade deficit down far
more quickly, eliminating the gap in demand it was creating.
Failing action on reducing the dollars value, it would have been desirable to take steps to stop the
growth of the housing bubble instead of denying its existence, which was the policy of the Bush
administration and the Greenspans Fed. Having just seen the collapse of the stock bubble in the
years 2000 to 2002, it should not have required too much imagination to understand that bubbles
burst, and that when they do, the story is not pretty.
It also was 100 percent predictable that the fallout from the collapse of the housing bubble would be
far worse than the fallout from the collapse of the stock bubble. This is both due to the fact that
housing is a much more widely held asset and also that is much more heavily leveraged. In terms of
holdings, the vast majority of stock is held by people in the richest quintile of the population, with
the top 10 percent accounting for more than half. By contrast, roughly two-thirds of households are
homeowners, a number that expanded to 70 percent at the peak of the bubble.
Even in normal times, it is standard for people to buy homes with a 20 percent down payment.
During the bubble years, down payment ratios plummeted, with many homebuyers putting down
zero or less.12 In this context, it was virtually guaranteed that large numbers of mortgages would go
into default when the bubble burst, as homeowners would have great difficulty making payments on
mortgages that vastly exceeded the price of the home. It is difficult to understand how people in
policy positions and economic analysts could have been surprised by the financial stress resulting
from the bubbles collapse. While the exact course of the crisis would have required a detailed
knowledge of which institutions were holding and/or guaranteeing debt, the fact that there would be
massive losses for the financial system should have been obvious.
In short, the failure to recognize the housing bubble and the economic turmoil that would be caused
by its collapse is an astounding and inexcusable failure of the Bush administrations economic policy.
12 The National Association of Realtors reported that 43 percent of first-time homebuyers had down payments of zero or less in
2005 [http://usatoday30.usatoday.com/money/perfi/housing/2006-01-17-real-estate-usat_x.htm].
From Recession to Collapse: The Bush Administration and the Over-Valued Dollar
The fact that most of those outside of government did not perform better on this score than the
Bush administration is not an excuse. There has been an enormous amount of needless suffering
due to this massive failure of public policy.
The Bailout
The last major act of economic policymaking by the Bush administration was pushing the Troubled
Asset Relief Program (TARP) through Congress. By all accounts, this was a rushed effort. The
financial turmoil following the collapse of Lehman Brothers caught officials at both the Federal
Reserve (Fed) and the Treasury Department by surprise. This is also difficult to understand since
government officials surely recognized the turmoil in financial markets. Earlier in the year, Bear
Stearns, the huge investment bank, had been pushed to the edge of collapse and was only saved by a
Fed-engineered takeover by J.P. Morgan. Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac had both been pushed into
conservatorship the prior week. And, the spreads on even short-term lending were going through
the roof.
In these circumstances, it is difficult to imagine that the Fed and Treasury could be surprised that
the markets would react poorly to seeing a major investment bank pushed into bankruptcy.
However, somehow they were.
Their response was to rush to Congress to demand a $700 billion fund to buy up bad loans. The
original proposal from Treasury Secretary Hank Paulson was just three pages. Most of the space was
devoted to saying that the actions of Treasury would not be subject to future lawsuits. Congress was
not about to give a $700 billion blank check, but they were told that speed was essential, as the
whole financial system was near collapse.
There was much debate around the measure, which was eventually approved by Congress in a
considerably more detailed bill, after first having been voted down by the House of Representatives.
While a full discussion of the debate is beyond the scope of this paper, it is worth noting a major
deception that was at the center of the debate.
The ostensible gun to the head of Congress as it voted on the bill was that the commercial paper
market was shutting down in the wake of the collapse of Lehman. Insofar as this was true, it really
would have implied an economic collapse, since even completely healthy companies were dependent
on the commercial paper market for financing their ongoing operations. Had they not been able to
issue debt in the market, it would have meant they were unable to meet their payroll, pay for
From Recession to Collapse: The Bush Administration and the Over-Valued Dollar
10
supplies, and meet other ongoing obligations. Based on this fear, Congress approved a bill that
provided the money to keep the major banks in business, while requiring no major changes in their
operation.
In fact, this action by Congress was completely unnecessary if the goal was to ensure the continued
operation of the commercial paper market. The Federal Reserve Board had the ability to act
unilaterally to support the commercial paper market. It demonstrated this fact by establishing the
Commercial Paper Funding Facility. The Fed announced plans to establish this facility on October
14th, the weekend after the House of Representatives had voted to approve the TARP. It is almost
certainly the case that next to no members of Congress were aware that the Federal Reserve Board
had this authority at the time they cast their votes.
This was an extraordinary act of deception in which both the Fed and top officials in the Bush
administration were obviously complicit. They did not want Congress to know that a rushed passage
of the TARP was not necessary to ensure the continued operation of the commercial paper market
and to avoid an economic collapse. Their deception helped to ensure that Congress would not
consider large-scale reforms as a condition of bailing out the banking system. Instead, Congress
allocated the necessary funds, allowing the banking system to survive in its pre-crisis form.
Conclusion
The economic record of the George W. Bush administration is without a doubt the worst of any
president in the post-World War II era. He presided over a weak recovery from one recession and
then set up the conditions for the worst downturn since the Great Depression. Finally, in the last
major action of the Bush presidency, the administration conspired with the Federal Reserve Board
to conceal essential information from Congress, ensuring a taxpayer bailout of the Wall Street banks
with few strings attached.
The lone consolation is that the Bush administrations greatest errors were bipartisan in nature. The
leadership of the Democratic Party was completely accepting of the over-valuation of the dollar and
the massive trade deficit that it caused. In fact, they had engineered it during President Clintons
terms in office. They were also in complete support of the deregulation of the financial sector, which
had been put in place during the Clinton years. Top Democrats were every bit as eager to ignore the
housing bubble as the Bush administration and to applaud the spread of homeownership among
moderate-income and minority households. Finally, the bailout of the major banks was an entirely
bipartisan affair, with a larger percentage of Democrats supporting the bill than Republicans.
From Recession to Collapse: The Bush Administration and the Over-Valued Dollar
11
In short, the economic failure of the Bush administration was bipartisan in nature. The major errors
in policy were all jointly authored. This hardly exonerates the Bush administrations economic
policy, but it does mean that the leadership of the Democratic Party does not have much standing as
critics.
From Recession to Collapse: The Bush Administration and the Over-Valued Dollar
12