Capital Structure I
Finance Theory II (15.402) – Spring 2003 – Dirk Jenter
The Big Picture: Part I - Financing
A. Identifying Funding Needs
• Feb 6 Case: Wilson Lumber 1
• Feb 11 Case: Wilson Lumber 2
B. Optimal Capital Structure: The Basics
• Feb 13 Lecture: Capital Structure 1
• Feb 20 Lecture: Capital Structure 2
• Feb 25 Case: UST Inc.
• Feb 27 Case: Massey Ferguson
C. Optimal Capital Structure: Information and Agency
• Mar 4 Lecture: Capital Structure 3
• Mar 6 Case: MCI Communications
• Mar 11 Financing Review
• Mar 13 Case: Intel Corporation
2
Finance Theory II (15.402) – Spring 2003 – Dirk Jenter
The Key Questions of Corporate Finance
• Valuation: How do we distinguish between good investment
projects and bad ones?
• Financing: How should we finance the investment projects we
choose to undertake?
3
Finance Theory II (15.402) – Spring 2003 – Dirk Jenter
Financing Policy
• Real investment policies imply funding needs.
• We have tools to forecast the funding needs to follow a given
real investment policy (from Wilson Lumber)
• But what is the best source of funds?
→ Internal funds (i.e., cash)?
→ Debt (i.e., borrowing)?
→ Equity (i.e., issuing stock)?
• Moreover, different kinds of ...
→ internal funds (e.g., cash reserves vs. cutting dividends)
→ debt (e.g., Banks vs. Bonds)
→ equity (e.g., VC vs. IPO)
4
Finance Theory II (15.402) – Spring 2003 – Dirk Jenter
Capital Structure
• Capital Structure represents the mix of claims against a firm’s
assets and free cash flow
• Some characteristics of financial claims
→ Payoff structure (e.g. fixed promised payment)
→ Priority (debt paid before equity)
→ Maturity
→ Restrictive Covenants
→ Voting rights
→ Options (convertible securities, call provisions, etc)
• We focus on leverage (debt vs. equity) and how it can affect firm
value
5
Finance Theory II (15.402) – Spring 2003 – Dirk Jenter
Choosing an Optimal Capital Structure
• Is there an “optimal” capital structure, i.e., an optimal mix
between debt and equity?
• More generally, can you add value on the RHS of the balance
sheet, i.e., by following a good financial policy?
• If yes, does the optimal financial policy depend on the firm’s
operations (Real Investment policy), and how?
6
Finance Theory II (15.402) – Spring 2003 – Dirk Jenter
Sources of Funds: US Corporations 1979-97
Internal Debt Eq uity
120
100
80
% of total financing
60
40
20
0
79 80 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97
-20
-40
7
Finance Theory II (15.402) – Spring 2003 – Dirk Jenter
Companies and Industries Vary in Their
Capital Structures
Industry Debt Ratio* (%)
Electric and Gas 43.2
Food Production 22.9
Paper and Plastic 30.4
Equipment 19.1
Retailers 21.7
Chemicals 17.3
Computer Software 3.5
Average over all industries 21.5%
* Debt Ratio = Ratio of book value of debt to the sum of the book
value of debt plus the market value of equity.
8
Finance Theory II (15.402) – Spring 2003 – Dirk Jenter
4
Returns
Average rates of return on Treasury bills, government bonds,
corporate bonds, and common stocks, 1926-1997 (figures in
percent per year)
Average Average Risk Premium
Annual Rate (over T-Bills)
Portfolio Nominal Real
Treasury bills 3.8 0.7 0.0
Government bonds 5.6 2.6 1.8
Corporate bonds 6.1 3.0 2.3
Common stocks (S&P 500) 13.0 9.7 9.2
Small-firm common stocks 17.7 14.2 13.9
Source: Ibbotson Associates, Inc., 1998 Yearbook (Brealey & Myers p.155)
9
Finance Theory II (15.402) – Spring 2003 – Dirk Jenter
Plan of Attack
1. Modigliani-Miller Theorem:
→ Capital Structure is irrelevant
2. What’s missing from the M-M view?
→ Taxes
→ Costs of financial distress
→ Other factors
3. “Textbook” view of optimal capital structure:
→ The choice between debt and equity
4. Apply/confront this framework to several business cases
→ Evaluate when its usefulness and its limitations
10
Finance Theory II (15.402) – Spring 2003 – Dirk Jenter
M-M’s “Irrelevance” Theorem
MM Theorem (without taxes for now).
• Financing decisions are irrelevant for firm value.
• In particular, the choice of capital structure is irrelevant.
Proof: From Finance Theory I,
• Purely financial transactions do not change the total cash flows
and are therefore zero NPV investments.
• With no arbitrage opportunities, they cannot change the total
price.
• Thus, they neither increase nor decrease firm value.
Q.E.D.
11
Finance Theory II (15.402) – Spring 2003 – Dirk Jenter
Example
• Consider two firms with identical assets (in $M):
Asset (economic, not Firm A Firm B
book) value next year:
In state 1: 160 160
In state 2: 40 40
• Firm A is all equity financed:
→ Firm A’s value is V(A) = E(A)
• Firm B is financed with a mix of debt and equity:
→ Debt with one year maturity and face value $60M
→ Market values of debt D(B) and equity E(B)
→ Firm B’s value is (by definition) V(B) = D(B) + E(B)
• MM says: V(A) = V(B)
12
Finance Theory II (15.402) – Spring 2003 – Dirk Jenter
Proof 1
• Firm A’s equity gets all cash flows
• Firm B’s cash flows are split between its debt and equity with
debt being senior to equity.
Claim’s value Firm A’s Firm B’s Firm B’s
next year: Equity Debt Equity
In state 1: 160 60 100
In state 2: 40 40 0
• In all (i.e., both) states of the world, the following are equal:
→ The payoff to Firm A’s equity
→ The sum of payoffs to Firm B’s debt and equity
• By value additivity, D(B) + E(B) = E(A)
Q.E.D.
13
Finance Theory II (15.402) – Spring 2003 – Dirk Jenter
M-M Intuition 1
• If Firm A were to adopt Firm B’s capital structure, its total value
would not be affected (and vice versa).
• This is because ultimately, its value is that of the cash flows
generated by its operating assets (e.g., plant and inventories).
• The firm’s financial policy divides up this cashflow “pie” among
different claimants (e.g., debtholders and equityholders).
• But the size (i.e., value) of the pie is independent of how the pie
is divided up.
14
Finance Theory II (15.402) – Spring 2003 – Dirk Jenter
“Pie” Theory I
V
V
D
E E D
15
Finance Theory II (15.402) – Spring 2003 – Dirk Jenter
Proof 2
• In case you forgot where value additivity comes from…
• Assume for instance that market values are:
→ D(B) = $50M
→ E(B) = $50M
• MM says: V(A) = D(B)+E(B) = $100M
• Suppose instead that E(A) = $105M.
• Can you spot an arbitrage opportunity?
16
Finance Theory II (15.402) – Spring 2003 – Dirk Jenter
Proof 2 (cont.)
• Arbitrage strategy:
→ Buy 1/1M of Firm B’s equity for $50
→ Buy 1/1M of Firm B’s debt for $50
→ Sell 1/1M of Firm A’s equity for $105
Today Next year Next year
State 1 State 2
Firm B’s
-$50 +$100 $0
equity
Firm B’s debt -$50 +$60 +$40
Subtotal -$100 +$160 +$40
Firm A’s
+$105 -$160 -$40
equity
Total +$5 $0 $0
Note: Combining Firm B’s debt and equity amounts to “undoing
Firm B’s leverage” (see bolded cells). 17
Finance Theory II (15.402) – Spring 2003 – Dirk Jenter
M-M: Intuition 2
• Investors will not pay a premium for firms that undertake
financial transactions that they can undertake themselves (at the
same cost).
• For instance, they will not pay a premium for Firm A over Firm B
for having less debt.
• Indeed, by combining Firm B’s debt and equity in appropriate
proportions, any investor can in effect “unlever” Firm B and
reproduce the cashflow of Firm A.
18
Finance Theory II (15.402) – Spring 2003 – Dirk Jenter
9
The Curse of M-M
• M-M Theorem was initially meant for capital structure.
• But it applies to all aspects of financial policy:
→ capital structure is irrelevant.
→ long-term vs. short-term debt is irrelevant.
→ dividend policy is irrelevant.
→ risk management is irrelevant.
→ etc.
• Indeed, the proof applies to all financial transactions because
they are all zero NPV transactions.
19
Finance Theory II (15.402) – Spring 2003 – Dirk Jenter
Using M-M Sensibly
• M-M is not a literal statement about the real world. It obviously
leaves important things out.
• But it gets you to ask the right question: How is this financing
move going to change the size of the pie?
• M-M exposes some popular fallacies such as the “WACC
fallacy”.
20
Finance Theory II (15.402) – Spring 2003 – Dirk Jenter
10