CFA 1 Micro Economics
CFA 1 Micro Economics
CFA 1 Micro Economics
Economics involves the choices people make when matching their limitless
needs and wants with a scarcity of resources. The word "economics" is derived
from the Greek words "oikos", which means house, and "nomos", which means
manager. So the term originally referred to management of the household. Today,
the term has been broadened to refer to firms and all of society.
Another way of looking at economics is to consider the field as a set of tools for
analyzing people and groups and the choices that they make. Accountants are
trained to render an account of financial activity for a company. Lawyers are
trained into a certain mode of thinking so as to resolve issues in a legal
framework. Similarly, economists are trained to use a set of tools and principles
to analyze why individuals, firms, governments and other groups behave as they
do.
Models
Economists often use models, which are representations of what the economist
wishes to analyze. If, for example, an economist wishes to analyze the behavior
of a labor union, the economist will not try to include every possible aspect and
piece of data about labor unions in his or her model. Important factors will be
focused on, such as wages, benefits, alternative jobs, etc. Hopefully the
economist's model will include all of the important variables and will give little or
no weight to less critical variables.
Most economic analyses include the phrase "everything else is remaining the
same", so attention can be focused on the variables specified by the model. Of
course, this assumption is rarely true in real life. If one were trying to analyze
federal deficits and interest rates, for example, there would be plenty of change
during the time period analyzed.
In figure 3.1, we can see that at the price of $1, the suppliers are willing to
provide one million widgets (Point A), while the quantity demanded will be much
higher - eight million (Point B).
At a higher price, such as $5, suppliers will be willing to provide six million
widgets (Point D), while the quantity demanded is only one million (Point E).
Finally, at the price of $3, the quantity demanded is equal the quantity supplied
(Point C). This price is also referred to as the "market clearing" or equilibrium
price because no suppliers are left with the desire to provide goods at that price
and no buyers are left wishing to purchase the goods at that price either.
Look Out!
Note that supply and demand curves depict a quantity supplied or a quantity
demanded at a particular price, all other things remaining equal.
In the graph above D0 represents the original demand curve, while D1 shows the
new demand curve. Note that at a particular price level, such as $4, the quantity
demanded increases from three million to five million.
Suppose something happens where the quantity of a good supplied changes at
many particular price levels. For example, technological changes might occur
whereby computer memory manufacturers would be able to produce a particular
type of memory at a lower cost. So for many price levels, the quantity suppliers
are willing to provide will increase. This situation could be diagrammed as below:
S0 represents the original supply curve, while S1 represents the new supply
curve. At the price of $30 per 256MB chip, the quantity supplied will increase
from three million to four million units per month.
Supply and Demand Movements
Changes in quantity demanded strictly as a function of price are referred to as
movement along a demand curve. A shift of the entire demand curve is referred
to as a change in demand; this could be due to any factor(s) that affects demand,
other than price.
Changes in quantity supplied strictly as a function of price are referred to as
movement along a supply curve. A shift of the entire supply curve is referred to
as a change in supply; this could be due to any factor(s) that affects supply, other
than price.
Demand Curve Shifts
Some of the factors that can cause a demand curve to shift include:
1. Change in income - If consumer incomes increase, we might reasonably
expect that demand for some luxury goods will increase.
2. Change in preferences/tastes - If a product becomes more (less) liked,
the quantity demanded will increase (decrease).
3. Change in prices of goods that are complimentary - If the price of
gasoline goes up substantially, the demand curve for large SUV's should
shift down.
4. Changes in prices of goods that are substitutes - If the price of pork
increases (decreases), demand for beef would likely increase (decrease).
5. Advertising - An effective advertising campaign could increase the
quantity demanded of a particular good. It could also decrease the demand
for a competing good.
D0 is the original demand curve, and D1 is the new demand curve. The market
equilibrium price will increase from P0 to P1, at least in the short-run. The quantity
will also increase from Q0 to Q1.
Over time, in a market economy, two forces will come into play:
1. Buyers will have an incentive to search for substitutes, thereby decreasing
their purchase of the original good; this effect will tend to lower the quantity
demanded and the market price
2. Suppliers will have an incentive to supply more of the good, and more
resources will be allocated towards production of this good; this effect will
tend to increase the quantity and lower the market price
Shortages and Surpluses and their Effect on Equilibrium Prices.
A "shortage" exists when the quantity demanded at the current price is greater
than the quantity supplied. In the case of shortage, we would expect the market
price to go up. In this case, less motivated buyers do not purchase the good and
producers have a strong incentive to supply more at the higher market price. This
process will continue until the quantity demanded is equal to the quantity
supplied. A "surplus" exists when the quantity supplied is greater than the
quantity demanded. In this case, we would expect the market price to go down.
The lower market price entices more consumers into buying, but lower profits
create an incentive for producers to reduce the quantity supplied.
Now that you have completed the basics, let us move onto the various learning
outcomes on Microeconomics you should look to know for your upcoming exam.
Price Elasticity
In general, the elasticity of a particular variable is the percentage change in
quantity demanded or supplied, divided by the percentage change in the variable
of concern. This ratio is often called the elasticity coefficient.
Price elasticity is defined as the percentage change in quantity demanded
divided by the percentage change in price.
The price elasticity of demand can be expressed as:
Formula 3.1
The full elasticity calculation can be simplified by canceling out the 0.5 (one-half)
and 100. The more simplified expression can be stated as:
Example:
Suppose, to continue the example given above, that the change in quantity
demanded for the good (10 to 14) was in response to a price decrease from $8 to
$7. In that case, the elasticity would be expressed as:
Income Elasticity
Income Elasticity is defined as the percentage change in quantity demanded
divided by the percentage change in income. The calculations are similar to
those for price elasticity, except that the denominator would include a change in
income instead of a change in price.
Usually the amount of goods purchased will be positively correlated with income;
if consumers' incomes go up (down), more (less) goods will be purchased. Any
good with a positive income of elasticity of demand is said to be a normal good.
Luxury goods have high income elasticity (greater than one). The proportionate
amount of spending for those goods will go up as incomes increase.
The amount spent on some goods decrease as incomes goes up. Such goods
are referred to as inferior goods. Examples of inferior goods include margarine
(inferior to butter) and bus travel (inferior to owning a vehicle).
Formula 3.3
prices will direct resources towards those who value them most and can utilize
them most effectively.
Suppose consumer preferences change so that good A is now more desired than
good B. We would expect the price of good A to shift higher and the price of good
B to shift lower. This in turn will induce the production of additional units of good
A and the devotion of more input resources to good A, while similarly decreasing
production of B and its associated input resources.
In the real world today we have seen higher oil prices stimulate more drilling for
oil and more investment in oil substitutes. The wage rates of mainframe
programmers in the United States has decreased over the last several years in
comparison to the year 2000, as there less of a need for their services. The lower
wage rates have induced more mainframe programmers to retrain themselves
with other computer skills, or to leave the field.
Obstacles to achieving efficiency include:
Price Ceilings/Floors - Sometimes governments impose price ceilings, which
define a maximum price, or price floors, which define a minimum price. Effective
price ceilings or floors prevent normal market equilibrium.
Public Goods are goods available to everyone, even if they don't pay.
Examples include police protection and public parks. One reason competitive
markets don't produce the optimum amount of a public good is due to the "freerider" problem: those who don't pay get a "free ride" with regards to getting the
benefit.
Externalities reflect costs and benefits not borne by the person or firm making
the economic decision, which are imposed on or granted to others. Runoff from
large cattle feedlots can damage nearby farms, and this potential cost may not be
considered by feedlots when they look at their supply curve. A landowner who
chooses not to develop her land may benefit several other homes for purposes of
flood control. The benefit to others may not be taken into account when deciding
surplus is maximized.
Although price is the dominant means of allocating resources in a market
economy, it is not the only way for markets to allocate resources. A command
economy relies upon a central planning authority to allocate resources. Markets
can also allocate resources by majority rule (citizens vote on the desired
allocation of resources), lottery, or force and theft.
The Fairness Principle, Utilitarianism, and the Symmetry Principle
Economists often like to examine the "fairness" of a situation or economic
system. Ideas about fairness can be lumped into one of two categories:
"Results" must be fair.
"Rules" must be fair.
Utilitarianism, which is a moral philosophy developed in 18th and 19th century
Great Britain, posits that an action is correct if it increases overall happiness for
the performer of the act and those affected by the act. Utilitarians argued that
income should be transferred from the rich to the poor until complete equality was
achieved.
One problem with utilitarianism is the tradeoff between fairness and inefficiency.
An effort to transfer wealth by heavily taxing rich people will decrease incentives
for people to save money or work hard. This can lead to inefficient uses of capital
and labor. Another source of inefficiency is the administrative cost of transferring
money from the rich to the poor.
The symmetry principle is based on the intuitive principle that people in similar
situations should be treated the same. From an economic perspective, we would
like to achieve equality of opportunity. The symmetry principle adheres to the
viewpoint that "rules" must be fair.
Figure 3.6 illustrates the shortage that occurs when a price ceiling is imposed on
suppliers. Consumers demand QD while Suppliers are only willing to supply QS. If
the price ceiling is set above the equilibrium; consumers would demand a smaller
quantity than suppliers are producing.
Suppose that a state government imposes a tax upon milk producers of $1 per
gallon.
Figure 3.7: Incidence of Tax
Figure 3.7 shows the original price for milk was $2 per gallon. After imposition of
the tax, the supply curves shift up and to the left. Consumers pay $2.60 per
gallon. Sellers receive $1.60 per gallon after paying the tax. So sixty cents of the
tax is actually paid by consumers, while forty cents is paid by the milk producers.
The triangle ABC above represents the deadweight loss due to taxation, which
occurs because now there are fewer mutually beneficial exchanges between
buyers and sellers. Deadweight loss stems from foregone economic activity and
is a loss that does not lead to an offsetting gain for other market participants; it is
a permanent decrease to consumer and/or producer surplus.
Elasticity of Supply and Demand and the Incidence of Tax
If buyers have many alternatives to a good with a new tax, they will tend to
respond to a rise in price by buying other things and will, therefore, not accept a
much higher price. If sellers easily can switch to producing other goods, or if they
will respond to even a small reduction in payments by going out of business, then
they will not accept a much lower price. The incidence of the tax will tend to fall
on the side of the market that has the least attractive alternatives and, therefore,
has a lower elasticity.
Cigarettes are one example where buyers have relatively few options; we would
therefore expect the primary burden of cigarette taxes to fall upon the buyers.
A subsidy shifts either the demand or supply curve to the right, depending upon
whether the buyer or seller receives the subsidy. If it is the buyer receiving the
subsidy, the demand curves shifts right, leading to an increase in the quantity
demanded and the equilibrium price. If the seller receives the subsidy, the supply
curve shifts right and the quantity demanded will increase, while the equilibrium
price decreases.
A quota limits the amounts of a good that can be produced. If the quota is
greater than what would be produced under normal market conditions, then it will
have no effect. If the amount is less, than the market equilibrium that is achieved
will be at a higher price than what would occur without the quota, as consumers
will be willing to pay more.
Making a good or service illegally impacts demand, supply and market
equilibrium by imposing a cost (prosecution and punishment) on the buyer or
seller (or both) of the good/service. Quantities of illegal goods will always be less
than if they were legal, but the impact on price is determined by whether the
buyer or seller (or both) is punished. If the only the buyer is penalized, the
equilibrium price will be lower; the risk of punishment is regarded by buyers as a
cost, and reduces the price they will pay to the seller. If the seller is penalized, the
equilibrium price will be higher as the cost of punishment is factored into the
seller's cost. Prices will remain relatively unchanged if the risk and cost of
punishment is shared equally.
Explicit Costs
Explicit costs reflect monetary payments made to resource owners. Examples
include wages, lease payments and interest payments.
Implicit Costs.
Implicit costs are those associated with resources used by the firm, but with no
direct monetary payment. For example, there may not be an explicit monetary
payment associated with the work efforts of a sole proprietor; however, there is an
implicit cost associated with those work efforts as the sole proprietor could earn
wages elsewhere. For a firm's capital, there is an implicit cost involved as the firm
could be getting interest or earning a rate of return elsewhere. The implicit cost
associated with the highest-valued alternative opportunity is referred to as
the opportunity cost.
On the reverse side, particularly for an individual, there may be forms of implicit
("psychic") revenues; for example, a person may particularly enjoy "being his own
boss".
Economic Profit
Economic profit is equal to total revenues less both implicit and explicit costs. For
a firm to stay in business, both implicit and explicit costs must be covered. If firms
are receiving a negative economic profit in a market, they will leave that market. A
normal profit rate exactly covers wage costs and the competitive rate of return on
capital.
Accounting Profits.
Accounting profits are generally higher than economic profits, as they omit
certain costs, such as the value of owner-provided labor and the firm's equity
capital.
When calculating "economic profit", explicit and opportunity costs are taken into
account.
Example:
Suppose someone owns and runs a candy store that grosses $20,000 per month
and has operating expenses of $14,000 per month. The store owner particularly
enjoys socializing with the customers; this aspect of the business provides a
comfort to the owner which is worth $2,000 a month to her. The owner could
receive $3,000 a month in interest with the capital that is tied up in the store's
inventory. She could earn $5,000 a month at a different job.
An income statement would show an accounting profit of $6,000 a month:
Explicit Revenues $20,000
Explicit Costs $14,000
---------Accounting Profit $ 6,000
Answer:
The economic profit, which should determine the economic decision, would be
calculated as follows:
Explicit Revenues $20,000
Implicit Revenue
(value of socialization) $ 2,000
-----Economic Revenues $22,000
Explicit Costs $14,000
Implicit Costs:
Value of owner's labor $5,000
Required rate of return on
employees and raw materials. Market constraints limit what firms can
charge and enforce pricing on the input side.
Technology - economists view technology as the methods and processes
that firms use to produce goods and/or services. There is a "technology"
associated with any business, and the set of available technologies will
limit what a firm can do and impact its profit.
Technological vs. Economic Efficiency
Technological efficiency relates quantities of inputs to the quantity of output, while
economic efficiency relates the dollar value of inputs to the dollar value of output.
A firm would be operating with technological efficiency when it produces a certain
level of output with the least amount of input. Economic efficiency would be
achieved when a certain level of output is produced with the lowest cost of inputs.
Suppose there are two available methods to produce widgets, one that is highly
automated with industrial robots, and a mostly manual one that requires
significantly more workers. The automated method costs $50,000 per month to
produce 1,000 widgets over a monthly period, using three robots and one worker.
The manual method costs $40,000 per month to produce 1,000 widgets over the
same time period, with 10 workers that have a minimal amount of tools. We can't
say that either method is technologically inefficient - the automated method
requires fewer workers, while the manual method requires less capital for the
same quantity of output. However, we can say that the manual method is
economically efficient, since it produces 1,000 widgets at the lower cost.
Ways to Organize Production
There are two broadly defined methods of organizing production. A command
system utilizes a hierarchical organization whereby commands flow down from
the top of the organization. Armies typically are organized by this method. An
incentive system tries to provide market-like incentives to each layer of the
organization. Sales organizations predominantly use incentive systems.
Incentives also can be provided to personnel, such as assembly line workers, by
relating pay to certain production targets.
Partnerships
Partnerships are businesses that have two or more people acting as co-owners
of the business. Agreements are made beforehand as to how to share the risks
and rewards. As with proprietorships, owners are personally responsible for all
debts associated with the business. Law firms and accounting firms are
organized often as partnerships.
Corporations
Corporations are businesses that have been granted a charter so that they are
recognized as separate legal entities. Individuals in a corporation are not subject
to the liabilities of the firm; the most that they can lose is the amount they
invested. Taxes are paid, assets are acquired and contracts are entered into n the
name of the corporation. Corporations generally have easier access to capital
than proprietorships or partnerships.
Major factors promoting cost efficiency and customer service within the corporate
world include:
1. The threat of takeover - Inefficient corporate management can attract the
interest of outsiders, who will try to take over of the corporation with the intent of
running the corporation more efficiently, so as to increase shareholder value. The
takeover company most likely would remove the current management. The threat
of such a takeover gives management an incentive to serve the interests of
corporate shareholders.
2. Competition for capital and customers - Poor management will tend to drive
the price of a company's stock down, which will tend to make raising more capital
difficult. An efficient and/or innovative management will tend to cause the price of
a company's stock to go up, which will make raising additional capital easier. The
corporation's products must be competitive, in terms of both price and quality, in
order to attract customers. The production of inferior goods will tend to drive
customers away, which will decrease corporate revenues. Therefore, competitive
forces tend to limit the ability of management to serve their own needs in lieu of
stockholder and customer needs.
3. Management compensation - Compensation can be set up so that
management incentives are in line with those of the corporation. For example, a
significant amount of executive compensation can be in the form of stock options,
which are of value only when a certain stock price is met.
the market
Homogeneity of products - buyers can purchase the good from any seller and
receive the same good
Perfect knowledge about product quality, price and cost
No single buyer or seller is large enough to influence the market price
Sellers must take the existing market price and they will adjust the quantity of
their products so as to maximize profit at the market price. Because sellers must
take the current market price, a purely competitive market also is called a "price
takers" market.
Price-Searcher Markets
Price-searcher markets are characterized by:
1.Barriers to Entry
2.Firms in the Markets that have Downward-Sloping Demand Curves
While perfectly competitive markets have a homogeneity of goods, price-searcher
markets have a differentiation of goods. The differentiation could be in the form of
location, taste, packaging, design, quality and many other factors. Some
textbooks use the phrase "monopolistic competition" to describe markets
where each firm has something unique about its product while facing significant
competition. A good example would be a gas station. Although there are many
competing gas stations, an individual gas station is the only one at its particular
location and, therefore, to some degree it has a monopoly or is a sole seller. The
CFA text prefers the term "competitive price searcher".
Firms in a price-searcher market with low barriers to entry have some flexibility to
raise prices, as they will not lose all their customers if they do so. For example, if
Valvoline raises the price of its motor oil, some people will be willing to pay the
price for the motor oil they prefer. However, rival firms such as Pennzoil or Castrol
also provide similar motor oils. As Valvoline raises its prices, many customers will
switch to rival suppliers. The demand curve faced by firms in competitive price
Total Product: The total product is the total quantity of goods produced, in
association with specified levels of input.
Marginal Product: The marginal product is the change in output that
occurs when one more unit of input (such as a unit of labor) is added.
Average Product: The average product is the total product divided by the
number of input units, usually a variable input such as labor.
Example:
Suppose only one worker was present at an assembly plant and that worker had
to do all functions of the plant - order and stock supplies, assemble the good,
provide maintenance for the factory, prepare the good for shipping, etc. If a
second worker is added, there may be a larger increase in productivity, as the
two workers can allocate the tasks according to their abilities, and less time will
be lost going to and from various locations in the plant.
A possible schedule of plant output could be as follows:
In this example, hiring the fourth worker increases output by 110 units, which is
not as large as the increase created by hiring the third worker.
The cost of all production factors is equal to the firm's total cost (TC). Total fixed
costs (TFC) include all fixed costs, while total variable costs (TVC) include the
cost of all variable inputs such as labor. Marginal cost is the increase in costs
associated with producing additional output. At some point in time, marginal costs
will begin to increase because each additional worker contributes less to total
output. The average fixed cost (AFC) is the fixed cost per unit of output, while the
average variable cost (AVC) specifies the variable cost per unit of output. AFC
and AVC combined are equal to the average total cost (ATC). As production
increases, average fixed cost (total fixed cost divided by quantity) will decrease.
When marginal cost exceeds average total cost, average total costs will go up, at
which point the firm must receive higher prices if higher production is to occur.
The table below assumes that the firm has fixed costs of $1,000 per day, each
worker is paid $200 per day, and each unit produced has variable material costs
of $1 per unit.
From the table above we can see that both average total cost and marginal cost
initially decrease as production increase, but both start going up at certain levels
of production.
The average variable cost (AVC) curve will go down (but will not be as steep as
the marginal cost), and then go up. This will not go up as fast as the marginal
cost curve.
The average fixed cost (AFC) curve will decline as additional units are produced,
and continue to decline.
The average total cost (ATC) curve initially will decline as fixed costs are spread
over a larger number of units, but will go up as marginal costs increase due to the
law of diminishing returns.
The graph below illustrates the shapes of these curves.
Figure 3.8: Cost Curves
Economies of Scale
Economies of scale mean that goods can be produced at a lower cost per good,
as the quantity produced increases. Large-scale factory operations can permit
the most efficient specialization of machinery and labor. Average fixed costs will
decline as costs such as advertising can be spread across more and more units.
Diseconomies of Scale
Diseconomies of scale occur when per unit costs go up as output is increased. A
typical reason given is bureaucratic inefficiencies - more attention may be given
to administrative rules as opposed to innovation. Worker motivation is also more
difficult as the number of employees increases.
When economies of scale occur, the long-run average total cost (LRAC) curve
will be declining; with diseconomies of scale, the LRAC curve will be rising.
Figure 3.9: Long Run Average Total Curve
Low entry and exit barriers - there are no restraints on firms entering or
exiting the market
Homogeneity of products - buyers can purchase the good from any seller
and receive the same good
Perfect knowledge about product quality, price, and cost
No single buyer or seller is large enough to influence the market price
Sellers must take the existing market price; if they set a price above the market
price, no one will buy their product because potential buyers simply will go to
other suppliers. Setting a price below the market price does not make any sense
because the firm can sell as much as it wants to at the market price; selling below
the market price will just reduce profits.
Because sellers must take the current market price a purely competitive market is
also called a "price takers" market.
The firm can sell as much as it can produce at the existing market price, so
demand is not a constraint for the firm. Revenue will be simply the market price
multiplied by quantity produced.
Maximizing Profit in Perfect Competition
A price taker can sell as much as it can produce at the existing market price.
So total revenue (TR) will be simply P Q, where P = price and Q = quantity
sold.
Marginal revenue (MR), the increase in total revenue for production of one
additional unit, will always be equal to the market price for a price taker.
If the market price of a good is $15, and a firm produces 10 units of a good per
day, then its total revenue for the day will be $15 10 = $150. The marginal
revenue associated with producing an eleventh unit per day would be the market
price, $15; total revenue per day would increase from $150 to $165 (11 $15).
Marginal costs will vary, depending upon the quantity produced. We would expect
the firm to increase input up to the point where marginal cost is equal to the
market price. In the short run, a firm will produce as long as its average variable
costs do not exceed the market price. If the market price is less than the firm's
total average cost, but greater than its average variable cost, then the firm will still
operate in the short run. Its losses will be lowered by producing, since nothing
can be done about fixed costs in the short run. Over the long run, the firm will
need to cover all of it costs if it is to keep on producing.
If the market price at least covers the firm's variable costs, it may make sense to
keep on operating. Any price in excess of the average variable cost will at least
help to cover the fixed cost. Unless the firm decides to completely leave the
business, it will come out ahead by continuing to operate.
If the market price is below the firm's average variable cost, it will not make sense
for the firm to operate as it will lose even more money. If the firm believes that
business conditions will improve, it will temporarily shut down. Seasonal
businesses such as ski resorts or restaurants located by vacation areas will shut
down temporarily at certain times. Manufacturers temporarily might shut down a
factory and plan to reopen the factory when business conditions improve.
When Does a Firm Maximize Profit in Perfect Competition?
Profit () is equal to total revenue minus total cost. We can express this
mathematically by stating:
= TR - TC
In terms of calculus, we can state that profit will be maximized when the first
derivative of the profit function is equal to zero:
d = dTR -dTC= 0
dQ dQ dQ
We also can rearrange the terms to state that profit maximization occurs when:
Formula 3.4
dTR = dTC
dQ
dQ
The term on the left represents the change in revenue from producing one more
unit, which is called marginal revenue. The term on the right represents the
change in total costs resulting from producing one more unit, which is marginal
cost.
The firm's profit will be maximized at the level of output whereby the marginal
(additional) revenue received from the last unit produced is just equal to the
marginal (additional) cost incurred by producing that last unit. Maximum profit for
the firm occurs at the output level where MR = MC.
For a firm operating in a competitive environment, the marginal revenue received
is always equal to the market price. Therefore a firm operating under perfect
competition will always produce at the level of output where the marginal cost of
the last unit produced is just equal to the market price.
The following equation will hold:
Formula 3.5
MR = MC = P
Exam Tip!
You do not need to know calculus for the CFA level I exam. Just make sure you understand the
relationship above.
Microeconomics - Effects on
Equilibrium in the Short and Long Run
If a firm does not expect market conditions to improve then it may decide to go
out of business. This would be the preferred option as, by selling out, neither
fixed nor variable costs would be incurred.
Impact from Changes in Technology
The impact of a permanent change of demand on price and output for a market
will be influenced by the cost structure of suppliers in the market. The long-run
market supply curve in a competitive industry will depend on the returns to scale.
For a constant-cost industry, if demand increases, then firms temporarily will
make a profit as price will go above the minimum needed for the firms to stay in
business. This will cause firms to expand output or new firms to enter the
industry. Because costs are constant in the long run, the long-run supply curve
will be horizontal. In the graph below, as demand shifts from D1 to D2, over the
long run quantity will increase from Q1 to Q2. However, price will remain the same.
Figure 3.12: Long Run Supply: Constant Cost Industry
For an increasing cost industry, if demand increases, firms will need higher prices
over the long run in order to justify higher levels of production. For example,
prices for raw materials used in the industry may go up with higher levels of
production, which will force the long-run supply curve to slope upward.
Figure 3.10: Long Run Supply: Increasing Cost Industry
For a decreasing cost industry, if demand increases, in the long run firms can
provide more output at lower prices. The need to produce larger quantities of
goods and services in response to increased demand induces technological
change, which lowers costs for the producer and these savings are passed on to
consumers in the long run.
Figure 3.11: Long Run Supply: Decreasing Cost Industry
Microeconomics - Characteristics of
Monopolies
A monopoly is the single seller of a good for which substitutes are not readily
available. There should be high barriers to entry; i.e. other firms cannot enter the
market easily and provide the good.
Monopolies often are created due to legal barriers. Patent laws grant inventors
the exclusive right to produce and sell a product for a period of time (typically 17
years in the United States). Licensing restrictions often limit who is allowed to
provide a good or service in a particular geographic area.
In some instances, economies of scale exist so that there is a tendency toward a
natural monopoly - one firm can provide the good most efficiently. One traditional
example is the distribution of electrical power to a local community. Duplication of
power lines within a community would increase overall costs. With natural
monopolies, government policy to encourage more entrants may not make sense.
To some degree, natural monopolies occur in the computer industry, where
customers want to adhere to a common standard. The common standard for
personal computer operating systems is provided by Microsoft. Alternative
operating systems for personal computers (such as LINUX) do not make sense
for most consumers, so Microsoft has considerable monopoly power.
The Monopolist and Profit Maximization
The monopolist has control both over the quantity produced and price charged; it
also faces the entire demand curve for the good produced. Therefore, it will face
a downward-sloping demand curve. It follows the general rule for profit
maximization, MR = MC. As the monopolist does not know exactly how much
consumers are willing to buy at particular prices, it must "search" for the optimum
price.
As shown in the graph above, a monopolist facing demand curve D0 will produce
quantity Q0 and the price charged will be equal to P0.
What happens if the monopolist later faces a demand curve such as D1? In that
case, the monopolist cannot cover costs and will go out of business.
Microeconomics - Inefficiencies of
Monopolies
Monopolies vs. Perfect Competitions
A market characterized by monopoly has only a single seller, while a perfectly
competitive market has many sellers. There are high barriers of entry with the
monopoly, but little to no barriers to entry in the perfectly competitive market.
Because the product of a monopolist cannot be substituted readily, the
monopolist can set a higher price and still get sales. The seller in a perfectly
competitive market cannot get a higher price because potential buyers always
can get the product from other sellers.
up as much because more financial aid is being offered. The colleges reap high
revenues from wealthy families who can afford to pay high tuition while more
students from lower-income families can now attend college.
In general, higher output will occur with price discrimination. Furthermore, there
may be some businesses that could not exist without price discrimination. For
example, a dentist in a small town may not have a viable business without
performing price discrimination.
As price discrimination increases output and gains from trade, it reduces
allocative inefficiency. Firms that successfully price discriminate will benefit by
getting higher revenues.
Why Do Monopolies Exist?
If a natural monopoly is to exist, the government can regulate the price and
output. In the graph below, the monopolist would prefer to charge price P1 and
Q1 to maximize profits. A regulatory agency will often set the price at P2. At this
price, the monopolist receives enough to cover costs and, in effect, it receives a
competitive rate or return of its capital. The benefits to society from the increased
production outweigh the increased costs to the monopolist.
Figure 3.13: Results of Regulating Price and Output
Microeconomics - Monopolistic
Competition
A firm engaged in monopolistic competition which is considering reducing prices
in order to increase total revenue has two conflicting factors to consider.
Reducing prices will increase the quantity of a good sold, but the reduction in
price will also apply to quantities of the good that would have been sold at a
higher price.
The price searcher can maximize profit by adjusting output and the price until
marginal revenue is equal to marginal cost. Notice that the marginal revenue
curve lies below the firm's demand curve.
Figure 3.15: Marginal Revenue Curve In Monopolistic Competition
The phrase "contestable markets" describes markets where there are few sellers,
but they behave in a competitive manner because of the threat of new entrants.
For instance, an airline may serve a particular route exclusively, but does not
charge excessive prices because those prices would entice additional airlines to
offer that route.
Microeconomics - Oligopolies
What is an Oligopoly?
Oligopoly refers to a market with "few sellers". Oligopolies interact among
themselves. When an oligopolist changes a price, it must take into account how
other firms in the industry will respond. Within an oligopoly, the products can be
similar or differentiated. Oligopoly markets have high barriers to entry.
The Prisoner's Dilemma
The "prisoners' dilemma" was first described in the field of "game theory", which
is a branch of applied mathematics and economics dealing with choices made
under conflict and uncertainty. Suppose that the police believe Dave and Henry
have committed a felony, but the evidence is weak. The police have placed Dave
and Henry in jail, in separate cells. The police need the confession of at least one
of the prisoners in order to get a felony conviction. If neither prisoner confesses,
then the police can only convict them on a minor charge with a three-month
prison term. Each prisoner is offered the following deal: if one testifies against the
other while the other remains the silent, the one who testifies will not be convicted
of anything, while the one who remains silent will go to jail for 20 years. If both
confess, then each will receive a five-year jail term.
To sum up the situation:
The optimum result for the two together is to stay silent, in which Dave and Henry
will each get only three months prison time. However, each prisoner does not
have knowledge of what the other prisoner will do. The most rational response
from the individual is to confess. If the other prisoner stays silent, then that
person gets off free; if the other prisoner confesses, then the prison term will be
less (five years vs. 20 years).
The prisoners' dilemma illustrates a situation in which individuals arrive at a nonoptimal solution, due to a lack of cooperation and trust. A similar situation occurs
with oligopolies. If firms within an oligopolistic industry have cooperation and trust
with each other, then they can theoretically maximize industry profits by setting a
monopolistic price. Firms would then have to figure out how to fairly divide up the
profits.
If oligopolies collude successfully, they will set price and output such that MR =
MC for the industry overall. In figure 3.17 on the following page, this is depicted
as Pa and Qa. Without collusion, firms will lower prices to attract more customers.
Gradually, the price and output will move to Pb and Qb, which is identical to what
would be achieved with a competitive market.
Figure 3.16: Oligopolist Profit Maximization
Oligopolies have strong incentives to collude because while acting together, they
can restrict output and set prices so that economic profits are earned. The
individual oligopolist has an incentive to cheat because the firm's demand curve
is more elastic than the overall market demand curve. By secretly lowering prices,
the firm can sell to customers who would not buy at the higher price, as well as to
customers who normally buy from the other firms.
Oligopolistic agreements tend to be unstable due to these conflicting tendencies.
Obstacles to collusion within oligopolies include:
Low Entry Barriers - Particularly as time goes on, more firms will be attracted to
the potential economic profits, which will not be sustainable. For example, the
OPEC's raising of oil prices during the 1970s and early 1980s enticed more nonOPEC producers to produce more. The market share of OPEC producers was
drastically reduced and they had to reduce prices in order to gain market share.
In the long run, cartels are not usually successful at raising prices.
Antitrust Laws - these laws prohibit collusion. Although firms may make secret
agreements, those agreements will not be enforceable in a court of law.
Unstable Demand Conditions - These conditions will make collusion more
difficult, as firms are more likely to have disagreements as to what is the best
direction for the industry. Some may expect large increases in demand, while
others may disagree and prefer that industry capacity remains the same.
Increasing Number of Firms - An increasing number of firms in an oligopolistic
industry will make agreements harder to discuss, negotiate and enforce.
Differences of opinion are more likely. As the number of firms in the industry
increases, the industry will behave more like a competitive market.
Difficulties with Detecting and Stopping Price Cuts - These difficulties will
undermine effective collusion. Sometimes oligopolistic firms will cheat by
enacting quality improvements, easier credit terms and free shipping. If quality
changes can be used to compete, collusive price agreements will not be
effective.
Microeconomics - Conclusion
Within this Section we have focused on the basics of microeconomics, the
properties of demand and supply, price takers and searchers, and demand and
supply for resources and capital. For a quick review, we've summarized the