Oxford University Press The Society For Financial Studies
Oxford University Press The Society For Financial Studies
Oxford University Press The Society For Financial Studies
.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].
Oxford University Press and The Society for Financial Studies are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize,
preserve and extend access to The Review of Financial Studies.
http://www.jstor.org
Signaling, Investment
Previous drafts of this work were titled "Cash Flow Signaling Hypothesis
vs. Free Cash Flow Hypothesis: The Case of Dividend Announcements."
A previous version was presented at the annual meeting of the Western
Finance Association, Vancouver, Canada, June 1993. The authors would
like to thank Robert Bliss, David Chapman, Richard Green (the editor),
David Ikenberry, Meeta Kothare, Ken Lehn, John Martin, Roni Michaely,
Robert Parrino, A. J. Senchack, Tom Shively, two anonymous referees, and
especially Chris James and Paul Laux for helpful comments. Address correspondence to Laura T. Starks, Department of Finance, University of Texas
at Austin, Austin, TX 78712-1179.
Studies that document the wealth effects of dividend change announcements include Aharony and Swary (1980), Asquith and Mullins (1983), Bajaj and Vijh (1990), Eades, Hess, and Kim (1985), Kalay and Loewenstein
(1985, 1986), and Pettit (1972).
7he Review of Financial Studies Winter 1995 Vol. 8, No. 4, pp. 995-1018
1995 The Review of Financial Studies 0893-9454/95/$1.50
changes affect firm value. At the heart of this debate is the question
of exactly what information is being conveyed to the market by the
dividend change. The primary explanation has been the cash flow signaling hypothesis as developed in theoretical models by Bhattacharya
(1979), John and Williams (1985), Kalay (1980), and Miller and Rock
(1985). These authors argue that since managers possess more information about the firm's cash flows than do individuals outside the
firm, the managers have incentives to unambiguously "signal" that
information to investors. According to these models then, dividend
changes convey managers' information about future and/or current
cash flows.
An alternate, although not mutually exclusive, explanation is that
changes in dividends reflect changes in managers' investment policies given their opportunity set [John and Lang (1991) and Lang and
Litzenberger (1989)]. This explanation is based on the free cash flow
hypothesis suggested by Jensen (1986). The free cash flow hypothesis asserts that managers with substantial free cash flow will invest
it at below the cost of capital or waste it on organizational inefficiencies rather than distribute it to shareholders. On the other hand,
these managers could change their investment policies and increase
dividends, thus paying out current cash that would otherwise be invested in low-return projects or wasted [Jensen (1986), p. 324]. While
Jensen (1986) does not explicitly state that changes in dividends reflect changes in the managers' investment policies, his free cash flow
hypothesis predicts that changes in wasteful investments for firms
with poor investment opportunities should have significant valuation
effects.
Lang and Litzenberger (1989) focus on this implication of the free
cash flow hypothesis. They argue that the free cash flow hypothesis does a better job of explaining stock price reaction to dividend
change announcements than does the cash flow signaling hypothesis.
According to their argument, a significant stock price reaction would
be observed for dividend changes when the dividends affect the level
of cash flows available for wasteful investments. The rationale is that
for firms that are overinvesting, a dividend increase implies a reduction in management's policy of overinvesting, while a dividend decrease implies further overinvestment. Thus, the information content
of a dividend change announcement depends on the severity of the
firm's agency problems, that is, how much the firm is overinvesting.
According to Lang and Litzenberger (1989) a significant stock price
response should be observed only when dividend changes affect investors' expectations about the size of the firm's future investment in
negative net present-value projects. Note then that this interpretation
of the free cash flow hypothesis requires that dividend change an-
996
For example, evidence in favor of the free cash flow hypothesis is presented by Pilotte (1992) for
security offering announcements, Keown, Laux, and Martin (1992) for joint venture announcements, Lang, Stulz, and Walkling (1991) for tender offers, Perfect, Peterson, and Peterson (1994)
for self-tender offers, and Lehn and Poulsen (1989) for going-private transactions.
3 Servaes (1994) finds no evidence of overinvestment on the part of takeover targets. Howe, He, and
Kao (1992) find no difference between high-q and low-q firms in the market's reaction to one-time
cash flow events such as share repurchase and specially designated dividends. Denis, Denis, and
Sarin (1992) report that firms with Tobin's q less than one have significantly greater stock price
reactions to dividend change announcements largely because they pay higher dividends and their
dividend changes are of greater magnitude.
997
998
Opportunity
Set
1.1 Data
The sample of 3748 dividend increase and 431 dividend decrease
announcements over the period 1969 to 1988 consists of all NYSE
stocks from the Center for Research in Security Prices (CRSP) monthly
master file that satisfy the following criteria:
1. We restrict our attention to regular quarterly U.S. cash dividends
per share. Based on the naive expectations model, the unexpected
dividend change is defined to be the proportional change in dividends from the previous quarter. Warther (1994) argues that due to
the coarseness of the signaling equilibrium, not all dividend changes
contain information. In order to ensure that any potential information signal is significant, we impose the restriction that the dividend
change must be at least 10 percent.
2. The announcement does not represent a dividend initiation or
omission.
999
Studies/
v 8 n 4 1995
3. A stock split or stock dividend does not occur during the month
before or the month in which the dividend change announcement is
made.
4. Daily return data for the 200 trading days surrounding the announcement are available from the CRSP daily return master file.
5. Empirical estimates of Tobin's q ratios are available from the
National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) manufacturing sector
master file.4
1.2 Proxy for the investment opportunity set
A central issue in any test of the free cash flow hypothesis is the
question of a measure for firms' investment opportunities. We employ
two proxies, the often-used Tobin's q ratio and the direction of insider
trading. As suggested by Lang and Litzenberger (1989) and Lang, Stulz,
and Walkling (1991) our first proxy for the investment opportunities
available is Tobin's q ratio, defined as the ratio of the market value of
the firm's assets to their replacement costs. Although most empirical
estimates of Tobin's q ratios are built on Lindenberg and Ross (1981),5
the classification of q ratios into high-q and low-q firms varies by
author. For example, Lang and Litzenberger define a value-maximizing
firm as one with a one year q greater than unity, while Lang, Stulz,
and Walkling (1991) define a high-q firm as one with a three year
average q greater than one. Since a cutoff of one has some theoretical
appeal, we take a one-year q greater than one as a basic cutoff point
for high- and low-q firms. We also use two other cutoff points: a three
year average q greater than unity and a one year q greater than the
median within a calendar year.6
Although the estimated Tobin's q ratio is commonly employed as
a proxy for the investment opportunity set, it has several potential
problems. First, the estimate is of the average q ratio, but as pointed
the NBER file contains only industrial firms, the problems associated with dividend announcements for regulated firms are avoided.
4Since
5 The empirical estimates of Tobin's q ratios are computed slightly differently by authors, but most of
them are built on Lindenberg and Ross (1981). Perfect and Wiles (1994) construct four procedures
to estimate q ratios (primarily based on the methodology developed by Lindenberg and Ross).
Their results indicate that the methods tend to produce equivalent empirical results with one
exception: a q ratio computed using book values of long-term debt and total assets.
6 Servaes (1991) provides reasons why a cutoff of one may not be appropriate. For example, the
median Tobin's q may differ from one. Specifically, examining the median Tobin's q across all
firms in the NBER file each year over the period 1968 to 1987, we find that the median ranges
from 0.61 (in 1975) to 1.93 (in 1969). The median Tobin's q by year for our sample is consistent
with these population parameters. Since we find that the equality of the medians across years
can be rejected at any reasonable significance level, we checked the robustness of our results by
using the median Tobin's q ratio by year as an alternative cutoff point to separate high-q firms
from low-q firms. We also test the results with an industry median q ratio as a cutoff point. Our
results are not sensitive to the q classification process.
1000
Signaling,
Investment
Opportunities,
and Dividend
Announcements
in Firm Characteristics
1001
The free cash flow hypothesis predicts that these firm characteristics should systematically differ between high-q versus low-q firms.
In particular, Jensen (1986) argues that firms with more growth opportunities should have lower dividend yields. Consistent with this
prediction, Smith and Watts (1992) document that firms with more
assets-in-place and fewer growth options have higher dividend payout ratios. [This finding is also consistent with Easterbrook (1984) and
Rozeff (1982).] In addition, a firm's size is related to its q. As pointed
out by Smith and Watts, size is a function of the firm's investment
opportunity set. That is, those firms with more growth opportunities
are more likely to become larger. Thus, the free cash flow hypothesis
based on contracting arguments predicts a negative relationship between dividend yields and Tobin's q ratios, and a positive relationship
between size and Tobin's q.
On the other hand, cash flow signaling models generally do not
have direct predictions for differences across high-q and low-q firms
in terms of dividend yield, firm size, and the magnitude of dividend
changes.
Panel A in Table 1 reports the averages of dividend change, dividend yield, and firm size by the sign of the dividend changes and
the level of the Tobin's q ratios.7 In our sample there are 3748 dividend increases and 431 dividend decreases announced from 1969
through 1988. While there is not a large difference in the proportion
of dividend increase announcements for high-q and low-q firms, for
dividend decreases, 87 announcements (20 percent) are classified to
a group of high-q firms and 344 (80 percent) to a group of low-q
firms. This result is consistent with the view that firms in general cut
their dividend payments when their performance is poor [DeAngelo,
DeAngelo, and Skinner (1992)].
We find that the characteristics of dividend change announcements
for high-q firms tend to be systematically different from those of lowq firms. For both dividend increases and decreases, the means of the
anticipated dividend yield and the dividend change for high-q firms
are significantly smaller than those for low-q firms. In addition, for
dividend increases there is a significant positive relationship between
firm size and Tobin's q ratios: the equality of mean firm size between
the two groups can be rejected at any reasonable significance level.
I The anticipated dividend yield in this article is measured by dividing the sum of all dividend
payments for the year preceding the announcement by the end-of-year stock price. The firm's
size is measured as the market value of the firm's assets at the end of the year preceding the
announcement. The dividend change is computed by dividing the dividend change in dollars by
the end-of-month stock price before the announcement.
1002
Table 1
Dividend
2062 (55%)
1686 (45%)
Average yield
1215
2054
0.042
0.022
0.0021
0.0012
Mean difference
(q < 1) - (q > 1)
A.2. Dividend decreases
q < 1
q > 1
Average size
0.0009
(25.96)
344 (80%)
87 (20%)
-0.0082
-0.0061
Mean difference
(q < 1) - (q > 1)
-839
(-16.32)2
0.020
(41.68)
1,015
1,194
-0.0021
(-3.20)
0.072
0.040
-179
(-0.24)2
0.032
(12.52)
Log(size)
Yield
Tobin's q
1.00
-0.18
0.24
-0.37
1.00
-0.17
0.29
1.00
-0.65
1.00
Change
Log(size)
Yield
Tobin's q
Our sample consists of 3748 dividend increases and 431 dividend decreases announced over the
period 1969 to 1988 that meet the following criteria: (1) The announcement date is available
from the CRSP monthly master file. (2) Daily return data for the 200 trading days surrounding the
announcements are available. (3) The announcement does not represent a dividend initiation or
omission. (4) A stock split or stock dividend does not fall a month before or during the month
in which the announcement is made. (5) The dividend change is at least 10 percent compared
with the previous quarter. (6) Empirical estimates of Tobin's q ratios are available from the NBER
manufacturing sector master file. Tobin's q ratios are estimated as the market value of the firm's
assets divided by replacement costs, both are evaluated at the year end before the announcement
from the NBER tape. The change is computed by dividing dividend change in dollars by the
end-of-month stock price before the announcement. The size is the year-end market value of the
firm (in million $) obtained from the NBER tape. The yield is measured by dividing all dividend
payments for a year before the announcement by the end-of-year stock price. T-statistics are in
parentheses.
2
1003
correlations between the Tobin's q ratios and the three control variables presented in Panel B of Table 1. The correlations between the
q ratio and dividend yield, dividend change, and firm size are all statistically significant, being -0.65, -0.37, and 0.29, respectively, suggesting that the control variables may also be proxying for investment
opportunities.
In this section we have pointed out that the dividend change itself
depends on a firm's investment opportunities. In the next section we
measure the stock market reaction to the dividend change announcement, conditional on the market's prior information concerning the
firm's investment opportunities.
3. Investment
Opportunities
The free cash flow hypothesis implies that dividend changes by low-q
firms will lessen or aggravate the overinvestment and accordingly affect the market value of the firm. On the other hand, dividend changes
by high-q firms would not be expected to have a particular effect on
stock prices. There is no reason that a change in the dividend should
affect the level of the optimal investment because the firms are not assumed to be overinvesting [see Lang and Litzenberger (1989)]. Thus,
according to their hypothesis, dividend change announcements for
high-q firms should not have information content, not because they
are fully anticipated, but because dividend changes do not affect the
market's assessment of managers' investment policies. (Under some
plausible assumptions, Lang and Litzenberger derive these predictions
in their model.) Thus, for either dividend increases or decreases, the
prediction is that announcements of dividend changes by high-q firms
should have no significant impact on the firms' stock prices, whereas
announcements of dividend changes by low-q firms should have a
substantial effect on stock prices, implying that the absolute value of
the abnormal return is larger for low-q firms than for high-q firms. In
contrast, the cash flow signaling hypothesis predicts significant price
reactions regardless of the level of q ratios, implying a symmetrical
impact between high-q and low-q firms for either dividend increases
or decreases.
Table 2 reports three day cumulative average abnormal returns
(CAAR), summed over days -1 to + 1 relative to the announcement
date, and average abnormal returns on the announcement day by the
sign of the dividend changes and by the level of the Tobin's q ratios. Abnormal returns are estimated from the market model using the
CRSP equally weighted index and Scholes-Williams betas.8 We find
8 The estimation period covers days -100
1004
The announcement period abnormal returns are summed over days -1 to +1 due to possible
information leakage and announcements being made after trading hours on the announcement
day. Our results remain qualitatively the same with the CRSP value-weighted index rather than
the CRSP equal-weighted index as our market proxy. Similar results are also obtained when we
calculate the two day cumulative abnormal returns.
9 While, on average, our results indicate that stock prices react favorably to dividend increases and
unfavorably to dividend decreases, these results are not uniform across the sample. The stock
price reactions to dividend increase announcements for 43 percent of the high-q firms and 34
percent of the low-q firms are negative. Similarly, 24 percent of the high-q firms and 18 percent
of the low- firms have positive stock price reactions to dividend decrease announcements. While
these results could be interpreted as evidence counter to the cash flow signaling hypothesis, they
may be due to the problem of determining the market's conditional expected dividend, especially
for dividend increases. In our empirical analysis, we have adopted the naive dividend expectation
model, which implies that the expected dividend change is zero on average. However, this model
may not be realistic, not only because many firms tend to increase dividends in the same quarter
every year, but also because the model does not incorporate the market's most recent expectation
since the last dividend payment. The lower percentage of stock price reactions in the opposite
direction for dividend decreases than dividend increases supports the view that the problem of
determining the market's conditional expected dividend is more serious for dividend increases.
Regardless, the fact that there are a number of reactions in the opposite direction to the dividend
change does not present a serious problem in testing which hypothesis is more consistent with
the observed market reactions because the competing free cash flow hypothesis also does not
predict negative reactions to dividend increases and positive reactions to dividend decreases.
1005
Table 2
Cumulative
average abnormal
Dividend
increases
q<1
No. of obs.
CAAR
Percent positive
AAR
Dividend
decreases
2062
1.537 (17.41)
66%
0.969 (16.70)
q> 1
No. of obs.
CAAR
Percentage positive
AAR
1686
0.670 (7.18)
57%
0.350 (6.13)
0.867 (6.75)
0.619 (7.61)
-5.299
-3.197
344
(-14.67)
18%
(-12.24)
-2.689
87
(-6.14)
24%
(-5.13)
-0.700
-0.508
(-0.86)
(-0.87)
-4.599
3.762 (10.11)
2.228 (8.33)
3.929 (5.21)
2.339 (4.44)
Our sample consists of 3748 dividend increases and 431 dividend decreases announced over the
period 1969 to 1988 that meet the following criteria: (1) The announcement date is available
from the CRSP monthly master file. (2) Daily return data for the 200 trading days surrounding the
announcements are available. (3) The announcement does not represent a dividend initiation or
omission. (4) A stock split or stock dividend does not fall a month before or during the month
in which the announcement is made. (5) The dividend change is at least 10 percent compared
with the previous quarter. (6) Empirical -estimates of Tobin's q ratios are available from the NBER
manufacturing sector master file. Tobin's q are estimated as the market value of the firm's assets
divided by replacement costs, both are-evaluated year end before the announcement from the
NBER tapes. Abnormal returns are estimated from the market model using the CRSP equally
weighted index and Scholes-Williams betas. The estimation period is over days -100 to -8 and
days 8 to 100. CAAR refers to the three day (day -1, day 0, and day 1) cumulative average
abnormal returns. AAR refers to the average abnormal returns on the announcement day. Percent
positive refers to the percentage of positive cumulative abnormal returns. T-statistics are reported
in parentheses.
0.50
(t = 1.51)
481 CHANGE
(t = 8.73)
19.08YIELD
(t = 4.50)
0.14 LOG(SIZE) +
(t = -3.28)
0.09 Qigh q*
(t = 0.57)
1006
F-statistic = 4.75,
R2 = 0.05.
on Capital
We have presented evidence that the information revealed in the dividend change announcement appears to be more of a reflection of
cash flows than a reaction to managers' actions in the context of
the free cash flow hypothesis. A further test of this conjecture can
be obtained by examining whether changes in the firm's investment
policies after the announcements are consistent with the free cash
flow hypothesis predictions. Under the free cash flow hypothesis, an
announcement of a dividend change will have an effect on the firm's
stock price if the size of the firm's future investment in negative net
present value projects is expected to change. Thus, since low-q firms
invest in negative net present value projects, there should be a decrease in wasteful capital expenditures after dividend increases and an
increase in wasteful investment after dividend decreases. The implication is that a change in capital expenditures would cause significant
stock price reactions for low-q firms. It also predicts no significant
change in capital expenditures for high-q firms, implying no effect on
stock prices.
We use capital expenditures (COMPUSTATdata item 128) to measure new investment by the dividend change firms. The analysis measures the percentage changes in capital expenditures in the first three
full fiscal years after a dividend change (years +1, +2, and +3) compared to the last fiscal year before a dividend change (year -1).
We measure capital expenditures in levels and as a fraction of the
end-of-period total assets. To control for industry effects, we also
present an industry-adjusted percentage change in capital expendi-
1007
Table 3
Relations
tures,
between
dividend
change
<
announcements
and subsequent
capital expendi-
1
From year i to year j
-1 to +1
-1 to +2
-1 to +3
n = 1626
n = 1626
n = 1517
Percentagechange
39.68%***
52.10%***
8,31%***
1.13%***
65.87%***
1,11%***
n = 1626
n = 1626
n = 1517
11,13%***
0.70%***
12.22%***
11.54%***
4,59%***
0.30%***
-1 to +2
-1 to +3
n = 1168
n = 1175
n = 1083
Percentagechange
41.63%***
9.82%***
51.05%***
0.76%***
69.80%***
1.37%***
n = 1168
n = 1175
n = 1083
6.38%***
5.25%***
0.70%
0.00%
-0.57%
0.00%
tures. The industry-adjusted percentage change is defined as the percentage change in capital expenditures minus the median percentage
change over the same period for all firms in the same four-digit SIC
code as the dividend change firm.10 The results by sign of dividend
changes and level of q ratio are reported in Table 3.
Table 3 shows that there are significant increases (decreases) in
the level of capital expenditures after dividend increases (decreases).
This result holds regardless of the industry adjustment. The change in
capital expenditures is more pronounced for low-q firms than highWhen there were fewer than three firms in the same industry, that observation was excluded.
The results remain the same under the "same industry" definition with the two-digit SIC code.
1008
Table 3
(Continued)
Panel C: Dividend decreases and q
<
1
From year i to year j
-1 to +1
-1 to +2
-1 to +3
n = 269
n = 266
n = 245
-37.76%***
i24.92%***
- 18.49%***
-19.71***
-3.70%
-15.51%***
n = 269
n = 266
n = 245
-10.50%***
-2.76%***
Percentagechange
-33.39%***
-20.38%***
-16.30%***
-8.16%***
-1 to +1
-1 to +2
-1 to +3
n = 67
n = 72
n = 68
1.29%
-14.53%***
-4.53%
-17.32%***
16.26%**
-13.19%
n = 67
n = 72
n = 68
-13.47%
-3.19%
-21.00%**
-5.35%***
-9.63%**
0.00%
If the firm issues debt or equity to finance a dividend increase, a change in dividends will not
induce a corresponding change in investment. The conclusions are not affected by the exclusion
of those cases from our sample.
1009
The relationship between the previously observed wealth effects and the investment opportunity
set depends to some extent on how we define high- and low-q firms. For example, if we happen
to assign low-q firms to the high-q firm category by mistake, we could erroneously observe a
significant stock price reaction to dividend change announcements of high-q firms. In contrast,
our results employing capital expenditure changes are not diminished by a poor proxy. The free
cash flow hypothesis predicts a significant change in wasteful capital expenditures in the direction
opposite to that of dividend changes for low-q firms. It also predicts no particular change in capital
expenditures for high-q firms. In this case, if we assign low-q firms into the high-q firm category,
we may observe a significant decrease in capital expenditures after dividend increases and a
significant increase after dividend decreases for both high- and low-q firms. Conversely, if we
assign high-q firms into the low-q firm category, we may observe an insignificant change in capital
expenditures for both high- and low-q firms. Our evidence that dividend increase (decrease) firms
increase (reduce) their level of investment significantly for both high- and low-q firms is not related
to how we determine high- and low-q firms. This is strong evidence against the free cash flow
hypothesis as an explanation for the wealth effects of dividend change announcements.
1010
1011
Table 4
The impact of dividend
change announcements
q <
1(q
< l)(q>1
1221
1284
0.08
(0.00)
636/313/335
(0.06)
468/400/353
171
0.56
(0.00)
145/14/12
34
0.27
(0.00)
22/7/5
0.01
0.07
(0.00)
0.29
(0.00)
Our sample consists of 2505 dividend increases and 205 dividend decreases announced over the
period 1976 to 1988 that meet the following criteria: (1) The announcement date is available
from the CRSP monthly master file. (2) Daily return data for the 200 trading days surrounding
the announcements are available. (3) The announcement does not represent a dividend initiation
or omission. (4) A stock split or stock dividend does not fall a month before or during the
month in which the announcement is made. (5) The dividend change is at least 10 percent
compared with the previous quarter. (6) Empirical estimates of Tobin's q ratios are available from
the NBER manufacturing sector master file. (7) Firms should be included in the Investment Broker
Estimation System (IBES) database. The elasticity is measured by dividing percentage change of
postannouncement median earnings forecast compared to preannouncement median earnings
forecast by the percentage dividend change. The elasticity is set to 1 (-1) if it is greater (less)
than 1 (-1).
four groups have significantly positive mean elasticities. The one exception is the group of high-q firms that increased dividends. Note
that positive elasticity implies that the medians of analysts' earnings
forecasts change in the same direction as the dividend changes. The
most significant effect on cash flow expectations occurs for low-q
firms with dividend decreases. The mean elasticity is 0.56. Further,
out of 171 announcements, 145 have positive elasticity. For high-q
firms that decrease their dividend, the mean elasticity is 0.27. Out of
the 34 announcements, there were only 5 in which analysts revised
their forecasts in the direction opposite to the dividend change. Low-q
and high-q firms that increase their dividends have mean elasticities
of 0.08 and 0.01, respectively.13
According to the cash flow signaling hypothesis, the magnitudes of
signaling will be differentiated by the level of asymmetry in information between managers and shareholders. As shown in Table 1, low-q
firms tend to be smaller in size and have a larger dividend change.
13
Brous (1992) and O'Brien (1988) have found that analysts tend to be overly optimistic in their initial
annual earnings forecasts. Consequently, analysts' earnings forecasts are systematically lowered
each month up to the fiscal year end. The results reported in Table 4 do not control for this
optimism bias. To check for the extent to which an optimism bias may affect our results, we
follow the procedure discussed in Brous and Kini (1993) and find qualitatively similar results.
1012
1013
2
*,
in
-24The
4 3 2 1 0 -1 -2 -3 -4 Panel
4 3 2 1 0 -1 -2 -3 -4 Panel
to
B:
A:
***) Wilcoxon
month
-7
analysts'
Forecast
abnormal
and
n
signed7
denotes
130129130131131127124122116Dividend
876879877880883853831827815Dividend
forecast
to
rank
of 24)forecast
(**,
Table
5
Monthly
average
test.
increases
decreases
from
significance
five-year
revisions
the
forecast
at
Average
0.0001
0.0314
0.0389
0.0172
-0.0038
-0.0087
0.0035
-0.0002
-0.0349
-0.0237
-0.0047
-0.0196
-0.0024
-0.0048
-0.0047 revisions
-0.0036
-0.0030
0.0058
abnormal
All
are
the
growth
10,
forecast
5
rate
0.51
0.51
0.51
0.47
0.52
0.43
0.49
0.54
0.52
0.50
and of computed0.39**
0.38**
0.40**0.48**2
0.36***
0.32***
0.40***
0.33***
1
positive
by
revisions
Proportion
future
for
percent
i11110i1111211210810510498
subtracting
months
level, earnings
-4
from
to average
the4.
267269268269270258248246242
abnormal
forecast
revisions
of
the
five-year
forecast
Average
0.0001
-0.0413
-0.0086
0.0463
0.0390
-0.0244
-0.0147
-0.0072
-0.0192
0.0222
0.0142
-0.0108
0.0194
-0.0083
-0.0107
-0.0149
0.0028
-0.0106 revisions
q< growth
abnormal
The
respectively.
1
forecast
of
previous
forecast
0.46
0.49
0.49
0.47
0.48
0.46
0.48
0.47
0.50
0.45*
revisions 0.40*
0.41**
0.35***
0.31***
0.36***
0.39***
0.32***
0.35***
month.
earnings
positive
revision
Test
is
estimated
19 19 19 19 19 19 19 18 18
statistics
from
defined
on to the
thebe
Proportion
609610609611613595583581573
n
share'
the
forecast
Average
-0.0172
-0.0015
-0.0123
-0.0195
-0.0213
0.0029
0.0603
0.0286
0.0042
0.0012
-0.0052
-0.0014
0.0040
-0.0007
-0.0012
-0.0022 revisions
-0.0040
-0.0006
q>
abnormal
estimation
1
proportion
period
proportional
0.51
0.42
0.32
0.42
0.47
0.42
0.37
0.33
0.33 0.48*
0.53
0.53
0.53
0.53 0.52
0.50
0.16*
0.57**
positive
arechange
(months
per
positive
Proportion
1014
Comments
In this article we have provided tests of whether the information revealed by dividend change announcements is more consistent with
the cash flow signaling hypothesis or the Lang and Litzenberger (1989)
version of the free cash flow hypothesis. We find that the stock price
reaction to large (at least 10 percent) dividend change announcements
is generally consistent with the predictions of the cash flow signaling
hypothesis. Although we find that for dividend increases, the abnormal return for low-q firms is significantly larger than that of high-q
1015
firms, this differential reaction does not persist after controlling for
dividend change, dividend yield, and firm size.
Due to the relationships between the three control variables and the
investment opportunity set, we take an alternate approach to discriminate between the cash flow signaling and free cash flow hypotheses
as explanations of the wealth effects surrounding dividend change announcements. We directly examine the sources of the wealth effects
suggested by the two hypotheses. We find that dividend increase (decrease) firms experience significant increases (decreases) in capital
expenditures over the three years following the dividend change, a
result that is inconsistent with the implications of the free cash flow
hypothesis for dividend change announcements. We also provide significant evidence that announcements of dividend increases and decreases cause analysts to revise their current earnings forecasts in a
manner generally consistent with the cash flow signaling hypothesis.
In addition, we find that analysts tend to lower their long-term earnings growth forecasts following dividend decrease announcements,
but not following dividend increase announcements. This result potentially explains why dividend decreases cause a larger stock price
reaction than do dividend increases.
A central issue in any test of the free cash flow hypothesis is
the question of a measure for a firm's investment opportunities. Our
choices for proxies for the investment opportunity set were Tobin's
q ratio and the direction of insider trading. If our choices were poor
proxies for the investment opportunity set, our results on the market
reaction by the investment opportunity set are biased against the free
cash flow hypothesis. The examination of the sources of the valuation effects provides clearer evidence than the analysis of the wealth
effects, not only because the observed stock price reactions are affected by confounding factors, but also because our conclusion from
the examination of capital expenditure changes does not particularly
depend on how good a proxy Tobin's q ratio is. That is, we find significant changes in capital expenditures in the direction opposite to
the prediction by the free cash flow hypothesis for both high-q and
low-q firms, although the magnitude of the changes for high-q firms
are smaller than that of low-q firms.
Although our results indicate that the free cash flow hypothesis
does not explain the information effects of dividend change announcements, we cannot rule out the possibility that the free cash flow hypothesis explains the observed cross-sectional differences in dividend
policy. In particular, the fact that low-q firms have higher dividend
yield and larger dividend change than high-q firms is consistent with
the implications of the free cash flow hypothesis [Smith and Watts
(1992)].
1016
References
Aharony, J., and I. Swary, 1980, "Quarterly Dividend and Earnings Announcements
Stockholder's Returns: An Empirical Analysis," Journal of Finance, 35, 1-12.
and
Asquith, P., and D. Mullins, 1983, "The Impact of Initiating Dividend Payments on Shareholders'
Wealth," Journal of Business, 56, 77-96.
Bajaj, M., and A. Vijh, 1990, "Dividend Clienteles and the Information Content of Dividend
Changes," Journal of Financial Economics, 26, 193-219.
Bhattacharya, S., 1979, "Imperfect Information, Dividend Policy, and the 'Bird in the Hand'
Fallacy," BellJournal of Economics, 10, 259-270.
Brous, P., 1992, "Common Stock Offerings and Earnings Expectations: A Test of the Release of
Unfavorable Information," Journal of Finance, 47, 1517-1536.
Brous, P., and 0. Kini, 1993, "ARexamination of Analysts' Earnings Forecasts for Takeover Targets,"
Journal of Financial Economics, 33, 201-226.
DeAngelo, H., L. DeAngelo, and D. Skinner, 1992, "Dividends and Losses," Journal of Finance,
47, 1837-1863.
Denis, D., D. Denis, and A. Sarin, 1992, "The Information Content of Dividend Changes: Cash
Flow Signaling, Overinvestment, and Dividend Clienteles," working paper, Virginia Polytechnic
Institute and State University.
Eades, K., P. Hess, and E. Kim, 1985, "Market Rationality and Dividend Announcements," Journal
of Financial Economics, 15, 3-34.
Easterbrook, F. H., 1984, "Two Agency-Cost Explanations of Dividends," American Economic
Review, 74, 650-659.
Eddy, A., and B. Seifert, 1988, "Firm Size and Dividend Announcements," Journal of Financial
Research, 11, 295-302.
Fehrs, D., G. Benesh, and D. Peterson, 1988, "Evidence of a Relation between Stock Price Reactions
around Cash Dividend Changes and Yields," Journal of Financial Research, 11, 111-123.
Healy, P., and K. Palepu, 1988, "Earnings Information Conveyed by Dividend Initiations and
Omissions," Journal of Financial Economics, 21, 149-176.
Howe, K., J. He, and W. Kao, 1992, "One-time Cash Flow Announcements and Free Cash-Flow
Theory: Share Repurchase and Special Dividends," Journal of Finance, 47, 1963-1975.
Jensen, M., 1986, "Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow, Corporate Finance, and the Market for
Takeovers," American Economic Review, 76, 323-329.
John, K., and L. Lang, 1991, "Insider Trading around Dividend Announcements:
Evidence," Journal of Finance, 46, 1361-1389.
Theory and
John, K., andJ. Williams, 1985, "Dividends, Dilution and Taxes: A Signaling Equilibrium," Journal
of Finance, 40, 1053-1070.
Kalay, A., 1980, "Signaling, Information Content, and the Reluctance to Cut Dividends," Journal
of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 15, 855-869.
Kalay, A., and U. Loewenstein, 1985, "Predictable Events and Excess Returns: The Case of Dividend
Announcements," Journal of Financial Economics, 14, 423-449.
Kalay, A., and U. Loewenstein, 1986, "The Information Content of the Timing of Dividend
Announcements," Journal of Financial Economics, 16, 373-388.
1017
Keown, A., P. Laux, andJ. Martin, 1992, "JointVentures, Latent Assets and the Information Content
of Corporate Announcements," working paper, Virginia Polytechnic Institute and State University
and University of Texas at Austin.
Lang, L., and R. Litzenberger, 1989, "Dividend Announcements: Cash Flow Signaling vs. Free Cash
Flow Hypothesis?," Journal of Financial Economics, 24, 181-191.
Lang, L., R. Stulz, and R. Walkling, 1991, "A Test of the Free Cash Flow Hypothesis: The Case of
Bidder Returns," Journal of Financial Economics, 29, 315-335.
Lehn, K., and A. Poulsen, 1989, "Free Cash Flow and Stockholder Gains in Going Private
Transactions," Journal of Finance, 44, 771-789.
Lindenberg, E., and S. Ross, 1981, "Tobin's Q Ratio and Industrial Organization," Journal of
Business, 54, 1-32.
Lintner, J., 1956, "Distribution of Incomes of Corporations among Dividends, Retained Earnings
and Taxes," American Economic Review, 46, 97-113.
Long, M., I. Malitz, and S. Sefcik, 1994, "An Empirical Examination of Dividend Policy Following
Debt Issues," Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 29, 131-144.
Miller, M. H., and K. Rock, 1985, "Dividend Policy under Asymmetric Information," Journal of
Finance, 40, 1031-1051.
O'Brien, P. C., 1988, "Analysts' Forecasts as Earnings Expectations," Journal of Accounting and
Economics, 10,187-221.
Ofer, A., and D. Siegel, 1987, "Corporate Financial Policy, Information, and Market Expectations:
An Empirical Investigation of Dividends," Journal of Finance, 42, 889-911.
Perfect, S., D. Peterson, and P. Peterson, 1994, "Self-Tender Offers: Differentiating the Effects of
Free Cash Flow and Cash Flow Signaling," forthcoming in Journal of Banking and Finance.
Perfect, S., and K. Wiles, 1994, "Alternative Constructions of Tobin's Q: An Empirical Comparison,"
Journal of Empirical Finance, 1, 313-341.
Pettit, R., 1972, "Dividend Announcements, Security Performance, and Capital Market Efficiency,"
Journal of Finance, 28, 993-1007.
Pilotte, E., 1992, "Growth Opportunities and the Stock Price Response to New Financing," Journal
of Business, 65, 371-394.
Rozeff, M. S., 1982, "Growth, Beta, and Agency Costs as Determinants of Dividend Payout Ratios,"
Journal of Financial Research, 5, 249-259.
Servaes, H., 1991, "Tobin's Q and the Gains from Takeovers," Journal of Finance, 46, 409-419.
Servaes, H., 1994, "Do Takeover Targets Overinvest?," Review of Financial Studies, 7, 253-277.
Smith, C., and R. Watts, 1992, "The Investment Opportunity Set and Corporate Financing, Dividend,
and Compensation Policies," Journal of Financial Economics, 32, 263-292.
Warther, V., 1994, "Dividend Smoothing: A Sleeping Dogs Explanation," working paper, University
of Southern California.
1018