Lect Notes 2
Lect Notes 2
McGrattan (1999)), which, as PEA, may be thought of as a generalization of the method of undetermined coefficients to the higher order
but exploits some orthogonality conditions rather than relying on simulations;
Each method is illustrated by an economic example, which is intended to show
you the potential and simplicity of the method. However, before going to such
methods, we shall now see why linearizing many not always be a good idea.
The big question is then
What are we missing?
2.1
u(y, x)g(x)dx
The first order condition1 for choosing y is then given by (applying Leibniz
rule)
u(y, x)g(x)dx = 0
u(y, x)g(x)dx = 0
y
(2.1)
1
Note that since u(.) is concave and g(.) is positive, this condition is necessary and
sufficient.
y
x
1
y
Jy
hxx hxy
+ (y x)
u(y, x) = (y x)
x
Jx
hyx hyy
2
1
= Jy y + Jx x +
hxx x2 + (hxy + hyx )xy + hyy y 2
2
(2.2)
Note that in this case, we are not maximizing the expected value of the problem
but the value, taking into account the expected value of x. Given the functional
form (2.2), the first order condition is now
Jy + (hxy + hyx )
which is exactly the same as before. In other words, we have for the
quadratic formulation
Argmax E(u(y, x)) = Argmax u(y, E(x))
y
This is what is usually called the Certainty equivalence principle: risk does not
matter in decision making, the only thing that matters is the average value
of the random variable x, not its variability. But this is usually not a general
result. Let us consider, for example, the case of Burnsides [1998] asset pricing
model.
3
2.1.1
An assetpricing example
This model is a standard asset pricing model for which (i) the marginal intertemporal rate of substitution is an exponential function of the rate of growth
of consumption and (ii) the endowment is a Gaussian exogenous process. As
shown by Burnside (1998), this setting permits to obtain a closed form solution
to the problem. We consider a frictionless pure exchange economy a
` la Mehra
and Prescott (1985) and Rietz (1988) with a single household and a unique
perishable consumption good produced by a single tree. The household can
hold equity shares to transfer wealth from one period to another. The problem of a single agent is then to choose consumption and equity holdings to
maximize her expected discounted stream of utility, given by
Et
X
=0
ct+
with (, 0) (0, 1]
(2.3)
(2.4)
(2.5)
where xt , the rate of growth of dividends, is assumed to be a Gaussian stationary AR(1) process
xt = (1 )x + xt1 + t
(2.6)
(2.7)
Burnside (1998) shows that the above equation admits an exact solution of
the form2
yt =
(2.8)
i=1
where
and
2 2
2(1 i ) 2 (1 2i )
ai = xi +
+
i
2(1 )2
1
1 2
(1 i )
1
As can be seen from the definition of ai , the volatility of the shock, directly
bi =
enters the decision rule,, therefore Burnsides [1998] model does not make the
certainty equivalent hypothesis: risk matters for asset holdings decisions.
What happens then, if we now obtain a solution relying on a first order
Taylor approximation of the model?
First of all let us determine the deterministic steady state of the economy:
y ? = exp(x? )(1 + y ? )
x? = x? + (1 )x
such that we get
exp(x? )
1 exp(x? )
= x
y? =
x?
(2.9)
(2.10)
(2.11)
b
xt = exp(x? )Et (b
xt+1 ) + exp(x? )Et (b
xt+1 )
taking expectations and identifying, we obtain
=
exp(x? )
(1 exp(x? ))(1 exp(x? ))
N
1 X yt yet
E1 = 100
yt
N
t=1
and
yt yet
= 100 max
yt
where yt denotes the true solution to pricedividend ratio and yet is the ap-
the true solution, while E is the maximal relative error made using the approximation rather than the true solution. These criteria are evaluated over
the interval xt [x x , x + x ] where is selected such that we explore
6
99.99% of the distribution of x. Table 2.1 reports E1 and E for the different cases. Our benchmark experiment amounts to considering the Mehra and
Prescotts [1985] parameterization of the asset pricing model. We therefore
set the mean of the rate of growth of dividend to x = 0.0179, its persistence to
= 0.139 and the volatility of the innovations to = 0.0348. These values
are consistent with the properties of consumption growth in annual data from
1889 to 1979. was set to -1.5, the value widely used in the literature, and
to 0.95, which is standard for annual frequency. We then investigate the implications of changes in these parameters in terms of accuracy. In particular, we
study the implications of larger and lower impatience, higher volatility, larger
curvature of the utility function and more persistence in the rate of growth of
dividends.
Table 2.1: Accuracy check
E1
E
E1
E
Benchmark
1.43
1.46
=0.5
0.29
0.29
=0.5
0.24
0.26
=0.001
0.01
0.03
=0.99
2.92
2.94
=0.1
11.70
11.72
=-10
23.53
24.47
=0
1.57
1.57
=-5
8.57
8.85
=0.5
5.52
6.76
=0
0.50
0.51
=0.9
37.50
118.94
Note: The series defining the true solution was truncated after 800 terms,
as no significant improvement was found adding additional terms at the
machine accuracy. When exploring variations in , the overall volatility
of the rate of growth of dividends was maintained to its benchmark level.
Exact (high )
Exact (low )
Linear App.
18
16
14
12
10
8
6
4
2
0
0.15
0.1
0.05
xt
0.05
0.1
0.15
0.2
1. in terms of curvature,
2. in terms of level.
The first type of error is obvious, as the linear approximation is not intended
(as it cannot) to capture any curvature. The second type of error is related
to the fact that we are using a approximation about the deterministic steady
state. Therefore, the latter source of error is related to the risk component. In
fact, this may be understood in light of the ai terms in the exact solution which
include the volatility of the innovations. In order to be sure that this
error is related to this component, we also report the exact solution when we
cut the overall volatility by 25% (thick dashed line). As can be seen the level
error tends to diminish dramatically, which indicates that the risk component
plays a major role in this as the average error is cut by 20% then (5% as
far as the maximal error is concerned). Hence, this suggests that the linear
approximation may only be accurate for low enough variability and curvature,
which prevents its use for studying structural breaks.
2.2
We now consider another situation where the linear approximation may perform poorly. This situation is related to the existence of strong asymmetries
in decision rules or strong asymmetries in the objective functions the economic
agents have to optimize. In order to illustrate this situation, let us take the
problem of a firm that has to decide on employment and which faces asymmetric adjustment costs. Asymmetric adjustment costs may be justified on
institutional grounds. We may argue for example that there exist laws in the
economy that render firings more costly than hirings.
We consider the case of a firm that has to decide on its level of employment.
The firm is infinitely lived and produces a good relying on a decreasing returns
to scale technology that essentially uses labor another way to think of it
would be to assume that physical capital is a fixedfactor. This technology is
9
subject to
nt = t + nt1
(2.12)
1
= A wt +
Et t+1
1+r
(2.13)
(2.14)
10
50
40
30
20
10
0
2
1.5
0.5
0
t
0.5
1.5
Note that
j
Et (wt+j ) = wt + (1 )w +
j1
X
i=0
therefore
t =
d
= j wt + (1 j )w
2
w
1+r
(1 + r)A
wt
r
1+r 1+r
Then, t is given by
t = (wt ) C
0 1
(1 + r)A
w
1+r
wt
r
1+r 1+r
and we have
nt = (wt ) + nt1
11
wt
Since C 0 (.) may exhibit strong asymmetries, the decision rule may be extremely
nonlinear too to yield a decision rule of the form we depict in figure (2.3). As
can be seen from the graph, the linear approximation would do a very poor
job, as any departure from the steady state level (? = 0) would create a large
error. In other words, and as should have been expected, strong nonlinearities
forbid the use of linear approximations.
Beyond this point that may appear quite peculiar, since such important
nonlinearities are barely encountered after all, there exists a large class of
models for which linear approximation would do a bad job: models with binding constraints that we now investigate.
2.3
In this section, we will provide you with an example where linear approximation should not be used because the decision rules are not differentiable. This
12
is the case when the agent faces possibly binding constraints. To illustrate it
we will develop a model of a consumer who is constrained on its borrowing in
the financial market.
We consider the case of a household who determines her consumption/saving
plans in order to maximize her lifetime expected utility, which is characterized
by the function:
Et
=0
c1
t+ 1
1
(2.15)
(2.16)
with t ; N (0, 2 ). These revenus are then used to consume and purchase
assets on the financial market. Therefore, the budget constraint in t is given
by
at+1 = (1 + r)at + t ct
(2.17)
The first order conditions to this model may be obtained forming the
5
Et (.) denotes mathematical conditional expectations. Expectations are conditional on
information available at the beginning of period t.
13
X
c1
t+ 1
1
=0
(2.18)
t = t + (1 + r)Et t+1
(2.19)
(2.20)
t at+1 = 0
(2.21)
t > 0
(2.22)
t > 0
(2.23)
together with
c
= min ((1 + r)at + t ) , (1 + r)Et c
t
t+1
The decision rule of consumption is not differentiable in the point where assets
holdings are not sufficient to guaranty a positive net position on asset holdings:
((1 + r)at + t ) = (1 + r)Et c
t+1
Just to give you an idea of this phenomenon, we reported in figure 2.4 the
consumption decision rule for two different values of t as a function of cash
onhand which is given by (1+r)at +t .6 This nondifferentiability implies
obviously that linear approximation cannot be useful in this case, as they are
not defined in the neighborhood of the point that makes the household switch
from the unconstrained to the constrained regime. Nevertheless, if we are
6
14
120
Consumption (c )
100
80
60
40
20
0
0
50
100
150
200
cashonhand ((1+r)att)
15
250
300
to consider an economy with tiny shocks and where the steady state lies in
the unconstrained regime, the linear approximation may be sufficient as the
decision rule is particularly smooth in this region because of consumption
smoothing).
We therefore need to investigate alternative methods, which however require some preliminaries
16
Bibliography
Burnside, C., Solving asset pricing models with Gaussian shocks, Journal of
Economic Dynamics and Control, 1998, 22, 329340.
Christiano, L., Solving the Stochastic Growth Model by Linear Quadratic
Approximation and by Value Function Iteration, Journal of Business and
Economic Statistics, 1990, 8 (1), 2326.
Collard, F. and M. Juillard, Accuracy of Stochastic Perturbation Methods:
The Case of Asset Pricing Models, Journal of Economic Dynamics and
Control, 2001, 25 (6/7), 979999.
and
Marcet, A., Solving Nonlinear Stochastic Models by Parametrizing Expectations, mimeo, CarnegieMellon University 1988.
and G. Lorenzoni, The Parameterized Expectations Approach: Some
Practical Issues, in R. Marimon and A. Scott, editors, Computational
methods for the study of dynamic economies, Oxford: Oxford University
Press, 1999, pp. 143171.
McGrattan, E.R., Solving the Stochastic Growth Models with a Finite Element Method, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 1996, 20,
1942.
, Application of Weighted Residual Methods to Dynamic Economic Models, in R. Marimon and A. Scott, editors, Computational methods for
the study of dynamic economies, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999,
pp. 114142.
Mehra, R. and E.C. Prescott, The equity premium: a puzzle, Journal of
Monetary Economics, 1985, 15, 145161.
Rietz, T.A., The equity risk premium: a solution, Journal of Monetary Economics, 1988, 22, 117131.
Tauchen, G. and R. Hussey, Quadrature Based Methods for Obtaining Approximate Solutions to Nonlinear Asset Pricing Models, Econometrica,
1991, 59 (2), 371396.
18
Index
Asymmetries, 9
Binding constraints, 12
Certainty equivalence, 2
Nonlinearities, 9
19
20
Contents
2 Towards nonlinear methods
2.1
2.1.1
An assetpricing example . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
2.2
2.3
12
21
22
List of Figures
2.1
Decision rule . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
2.2
11
2.3
. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
12
2.4
15
23
24
List of Tables
2.1
Accuracy check . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
25