Jaffee & Stiglitz, Credit Rationing
Jaffee & Stiglitz, Credit Rationing
Jaffee & Stiglitz, Credit Rationing
CREDIT
RATIONING
DWIGHT JAFFEE
Princeton University
JOSEPH STIGLITZ
Stanford University
Contents
1.
2.
3.
Introduction
Basic notions
2.1.
Uncertainty
2.2.
Loan contracts
2.3.
2.4.
2.5.
2.6.
4.
3.3.
3.4.
3.5.
5.
Enforcement problems
4.2.
4.3.
4.4.
5.3.
5.4.
5.5.
5.6.
5.7.
Housing investment
Consumption expenditures
5.8.
References
Handbook of Monetary Economics, Volume H, Edited by B.M. Friedman and F.H. Hahn
@~ Elsevier Science Publishers B.V., 1990
838
839
839
841
842
845
847
849
853
855
858
859
860
862
863
863
864
866
868
869
869
873
874
876
877
88O
882
883
885
838
1. Introduction
Credit markets differ from standard markets (for chairs, tables, and pencils) in
two important respects. First, standard markets, which are the focus of classical
competitive theory, involve a number of agents who are buying and selling a
homogeneous commodity. Second, in standard markets, the delivery of a
commodity by a seller and payment for the commodity by a buyer occur
simultaneously.
In contrast, credit (in money or goods) received today by an individual or
firm is exchanged for a promise of repayment (in money or goods) in the
future. But one person's promise is not as good as a n o t h e r - promises are
frequently b r o k e n - and there may be no objective way to determine the
likelihood that the promise will be kept. 1 After all, for most entrepreneurial
investment, the project is sui generis. The need for credit is evidence of
change: those who control existing resources, or have claims on current wealth,
are not necessarily those best situated to use these resources. They thus
transfer control over their resources to others, in return for a promise.
The analysis of credit allocation can go astray in trying to apply the standard
supply and demand model, which, as well as it may work for the market for
chairs, is not totally appropriate for the market for promises. If credit markets
were like standard markets, then interest rates would be the "prices" that
equate the demand and supply for credit. However, an excess demand for
credit is c o m m o n - applications for credit are frequently not satisfied. As a
result, the demand for credit may exceed the supply at the market interest rate.
Credit markets deviate from the standard model because the interest rate
indicates only what the individual promises to repay, not what he will actually
repay (which means that the interest rate is not the only dimension of a credit
contract).
In the United States, a complicated, decentralized, and interrelated set of
financial markets, institutions, and instruments has evolved to provide credit.
Our discussion of credit rationing will focus on one set of these i n s t r u m e n t s loan c o n t r a c t s - where the promised repayments are fixed amounts. At the
other extreme, equity securities are promises to repay a given fraction of a
firm's profits. A spectrum of securities, including convertible bonds and
preferred shares, exists between loans and equity. Each of these securities
provides for the exchange of a current resource for a future promise. In our
~Moral hazard and adverse selection- special types of behavior we will describe l a t e r - m a y
affect the likelihood of loan repayment.
839
2. Basic notions
2.1. Uncertainty
Differences between promised and actual repayments on loans are the result of
uncertainty concerning the borrower's ability (or willingness) to make the
repayments when they are due. This creates the risk of borrower default. Some
aspects of uncertainty may be treated with the standard model, as illustrated by
the capital asset pricing model or other models where there is a fixed and
840
841
f(X).
842
two possible outcomes, that is when X b < (1 + r)B < X a. The expected repayment is then pa(1 + r)B + pbxb, reflecting repayment of the contracted
amount (1 + r)B when the good outcome occurs (with probability p a ) and
repayment of the available proceeds X b when the bad outcome occurs (with
probability pb).
Two fundamental features of loan contracts are illustrated by this result.
First, the expected repayment rises as the loan rate rises, since the promised
repayment (1 + r)B rises as the loan rate rises. Second, the expected repayment
falls as uncertainty rises, since the expected repayment is reduced by a lower
value for the bad outcome, but is unaffected by a higher value for the good
outcome [at most, the borrower pays back (1 + r)B]. Once a specific investment project is chosen and the loan rate is set, the borrower and lender
participate in a zero-sum game, with the borrower keeping that part of the
outcome not repaid to the lender. Consequently, other things the same,
lenders prefer safer projects and higher loan rates, while borrowers prefer just
the opposite.
Loan contracts also include t e r m s - called non-price t e r m s - which constrain
the borrower in order to reduce the likelihood of default. Collateral is among
the most important of these. Collateral consists of financial and tangible capital
assets that are pledged by the borrower to guarantee at least partial, if not
complete, loan repayment. If a loan defaults, then the collateral is used to
supplement the proceeds available to the lender (up to the repayment
amount). In the extreme case of a fully collateralized loan, the collateral value
is sufficient to cover any possible shortfall in loan repayment. In practice, even
highly collateralized loans do not generally warrant interest rates as low as the
rates on Treasury securities. We will look at some of the reasons for this,
including that the value of the collateral may be uncertain and that there may
be transactions costs associated with liquidating it. 4 As a result, collateral may
reduce, but generally does not eliminate, the risk of default.
843
844
one (because it provides the highest expected return). A lender can respond by
placing restrictive clauses in a loan contract, but the borrower's actions may
not be fully foreseen and costs may arise in later renegotiating such clauses.
Alternatively, lenders can influence the borrower's incentives, without directly
monitoring the borrower's actions, by controlling the size of the loan and
related terms of the loan contract. The returns from controlling the size of the
loan, however, may accrue to all of the firm's lenders, which leads to the next
point.
(3) Several important public good problems are associated with any classification of creditors. These problems arise when events occur which provide the
creditors, as a class, with some discretion over the actions of the firm. For
instance, many loan contracts contain a clause that states that the loan is in
default if any loan of the borrower is in default. This clause ensures that the
lender can maintain control of the collateral and can represent his interests in
the event of a reorganization of the borrowing firm. These public good
problems become paramount when bankruptcy occurs and the majority of the
creditors of any class must agree to any settlement. By the same token,
monitoring the firm's activities, to ensure that these adverse contingencies do
not arise, is a public good, the return on which accrues, at least to some extent,
to all creditors ]Stiglitz (1985)]. In brief, there is a natural incentive to
concentrate the sources of credit.
(4) Continuing relationships provide cost savings for lenders who make a
sequence of loans to the same borrower, since information obtained at one
date may also be used to assess risk at a later date. These cost savings are also
important for lines of credit, which are the basis for many business, credit card,
and consumer loans] In these cases, continuing customer relationships provide
the current lender a distinct advantage over competitors in assessing the
current riskiness of its customers.
(5) As a result of the information provided by a long-term customer
relationship, competitors may fear that winning away a customer means that
the previous lender learned of adverse developments. This illustrates clearly
why Akerlof's (1970) "lemons" principle is an important factor in loan
markets.
(6) Finally, the threat of termination of credit acts as an important incentive
device to encourage the firm to undertake safer actions this period [Stiglitz and
Weiss (1983)]. It is sensible that these "moral hazard" problems can be better
handled when there are exclusive relationships [see Arnott and Stiglitz (1985)].
Exclusivity arrangements limit, but do not eliminate, competition. When a
7Credit lines allow loans to be contracted on a forward basis. A credit line m a y serve an
insurance purpose: either protecting the borrower against an unexpected change in credit rating (if
the loan rate is fixed relative to the prime rate) or, less commonly, against a change in the level of
interest rates (if the specific level of the loan rate is fixed).
845
new borrower enters the market, for example, there will be competition to
become that firm's supplier of credit. Competition is limited, however, to the
extent that the costs of gathering information are sunk costs. So, given the
amount of ex ante competition, there will be less ex post competition. Hence, a
misclassification of a borrower's risk category may not be easily corrected
through competition.
846
of loans and their capital and loan loss reserves provide a further tier of
protection. 1
(3) The banking industry is competitive. This assumption applies to free
entry into the banking system as a whole, even though each bank is likely to
maintain exclusivity in its customer relationships. Until 1980, bank competition
in the United States was limited by Regulation Q deposit rate ceilings and by
various restrictions on bank charters, mergers, statewide branching, and
interstate banking. However, deregulation legislation and related developments have now removed most of the reasons for expecting bank markets to be
less (or more) competitive than say the market for chairs. Consequently, free
entry and zero expected profits are our maintained assumption, but imperfect
competition is considered where it may be relevant.
Competition causes expected bank profits to be zero, so banks pass through
their expected earnings on loans (net of operating costs) to depositors as
interest payments. Even though deposit rates equal expected loan returns, an
additional relationship is required to determine the common level for the two
rates. One possibility is to use the market-clearing condition of the Walrasian
demand and supply m o d e l - that the demand for loans (by borrowers) equals
the supply of deposits (by depositors)- to determine the equilibrium level of
the two rates.
Another possibility, developed below in Section 3, is that special features of
loan markets cause loan rates to be endogenously determined below the
Walrasian market-clearing level. To illustrate how this might work, without
going too far ahead, let us suppose that a binding usury ceiling exogenously
restricts loan rates below their Walrasian equilibrium level. 11 Competition will
force expected bank profits to be zero, so deposit rates must settle at the same
low level as the usury ceiling (default risk aside). As a result, there will be an
excess demand for loans - a simple example of credit rationing.
Imperfect competition in deposit and loan markets does not fundamentally
change the situation. If the special features of loans are ignored, then following
the standard model of monopoly, banks will maximize their profits by equating
the marginal cost of deposits with the marginal expected return on loans, while
satisfying all loan demand. On the other hand, if the special features of loans
cause loan rates to be quoted at a level lower than the monopoly level, then a
continuing state of excess demand may exist, just as in the competitive case.
~The recent experience of S and L's, however, suggests that in the absence of deposit insurance,
the reserves and capital m a y not suffice to protect depositors. The losses that depositors suffer as a
result of bank runs raise a different issue - bank liquidity - as discussed by D i a m o n d and Dybvig
(1983).
11Although the ecclesiastical sources of usury ceilings have presumably long passed, similar
ceilings still exist in m a n y states in the United States as part of c o n s u m e r protection laws for
unsecured c o n s u m e r and credit card loans.
847
Banks may also internally connect loans to deposits when the external
markets for these securities function imperfectly. Compensating balance requirements, for example, are a contractual a r r a n g e m e n t whereby a b o r r o w e r or
a holder of a line of credit is required to maintain a specified level of deposits
in the bank. This a r r a n g e m e n t can be interpreted as a "time-sharing" plan,
whereby a firm receives the right to borrow from time to time as part of its
compensation for maintaining deposits in the bank. Such arrangements m a y
allow banks to equilibrate the supply of deposits and the d e m a n d for loans
even when Regulation Q deposit ceilings and usury loan ceilings constrain the
m a r k e t levels of interest rates. Banks m a y also use these arrangements to
monitor a firm's financial condition by observing the patterns and trends in its
deposit balances.
In s u m m a r y , loan and deposit markets involve three different interest rates:
(1) the quoted loan rate determines the amount that borrowers promise to
repay; (2) the expected return on a loan is the quoted rate adjusted for the
lender's expected loss if default occurs; and (3) the deposit rate is the rate paid
to depositors to raise loanable funds. U n d e r competition, the deposit rate
determines the expected return a b a n k must earn on each loan. That is, a bank
determines the quoted rate for each loan so that it earns the required return;
or, if this is not possible, the bank will not m a k e the loan.
848
exists a market in which people or firms can borrow as much as they like at a
fixed rate of interest [see Stigler (1967) and Stiglitz (1970)].
(2) Divergent views rationing. Some individuals cannot borrow at the interest rate they consider appropriate based on what they perceive to be their
probability of default.
Remark. Although lenders relative to borrowers may commonly have more
pessimistic appraisals of default risk, this is also not the focus of our analysis of
credit rationing. ~2 For example, if the Treasury bond rate is 8 percent, the fact
that most firms are "excluded" from the market for 8 percent loans simply
reflects the market's judgment that loans to these firms are risky. From this
perspective, a borrower's perception of his risk is mainly relevant as a factor
determining his demand for credit.
There is an analogous kind of rationing in labor markets: there may be an
excess supply of those willing to be president of General Motors at the going
market wage, but (at least in the neoclassic story) the reason that the president
of GM receives such a high wage is that he has " m o r e efficiency units": he is
equivalent to, say, 100 ordinary laborers. A person who could only supply 50
efficiency units (even working 24 hours a day) would thereby be excluded from
the market for G M president.
(3) Redlining. Given the risk classification, a lender will refuse to grant
credit to a borrower when the lender cannot obtain its required return at any
interest rate. Moreover, loans which are viable at one required rate of return
(as determined by the deposit rate) may no longer be viable when the required
return rises. (The term redlining originally referred to the cross-hatched maps
used by urban mortgage lenders to designate neighborhoods in which they
would not lend. Our use of the term does not imply any type of discriminatory
behavior.)
Remark. The possibility of redlining is easily illustrated in an extreme
example where the borrower's project has a single outcome X m. If the required
return is 6, then a loan in excess of B* = xm/(1 + 6) clearly cannot yield the
required return, so the firm will be rationed out of the market. The same result
can apply to the expected return on a loan when there are various possible
project outcomes.
In a similar fashion, a firm, which received a loan when the supply of
deposits was high and the deposit rate was low, may be rationed when the
supply of deposits shifts and the deposit rate rises. This happens because a
"promise" to pay a higher rate on a loan may not translate fully (or even at all)
into a higher expected return for the lender. For these firms the availability of
credit (the supply of deposits) - not the quoted loan rate - determines whether
12Divergent views o n l o a n r e p a y m e n t s are c o m m o n b e c a u s e t h e y refer to the fulfillment of a
p r o m i s e , not to an a c t u a r i a l e v e n t such as w h e t h e r o r n o t it will rain.
849
they can borrow. These firms would feel they are being rationed out of the
market. 13
(4) Pure credit rationing. T h e r e m a y be instances in which some individuals
obtain loans, while apparently identical individuals, who are willing to borrow
at precisely the same terms, do not.
Remark. This is the purest f o r m of credit rationing, and we show below how
it m a y arise when there is imperfect information. When it does arise, changes
in the availability of credit, not changes in the interest rate, may determine the
extent of borrowing.
We also show that redlining (type 3 credit rationing) may be nearly
indistinguishable from pure credit rationing (type 4) when lenders classify
borrowers into a large n u m b e r of groups so that each group has a small n u m b e r
of borrowers. In this case, borrowers in a redlined group m a y have nearly the
same features as the borrowers in a group that does obtain loans.
850
~ l +r)B
alp=
Xf[X]dX+
f(K
I+~)8(I+r)Bf[X]dX-(I+6)B.
(2.1)
The first term accounts for the bank's income X when there is default
( X < (1 + r)B), the second term for the income (1 + r)B when the loan is
repaid in full, and the third term for the bank's cost of funds (1 + 6)B. The
bank's decision variables are the quoted loan rate r and the size of the loan B.
This formulation can be used to derive the bank's loan offer curve for the
borrower, showing the size of the loan offered B for each loan rate r. Under
competition, the offer curve is simply the zero profit locus of contracts for
which the bank's expected profit q~ is zero. The loan offer curve, as illustrated
in Figure 16.1, has three basic properties:
(1) It is a horizontal line at the deposit rate 6 over the range of small loan
sizes where the loan is risk-free (B < k/(1 + 6)).
~4This literature has been surveyed in Lindbeck (1962), Jaffee (1971), Koskela (1976, 1979), and
Baltensperger (1978).
851
\
Loan rate r
r: iiiiiiiii
io eman O
Firm demand D2
k/(l+~)
I~*
Loan size B
Figure 16.1. A bank loan offer curve and alternative cases for the position of the borrowing firm's
d e m a n d curve.
(2) It has a positive slope over the range where the probability of default
rises with the size of the loan, as higher loan rates compensate the bank for the
higher likelihood of default on larger loans.
(3) There may be a maximum loan size B* beyond which the offer curve
becomes backward bending. Otherwise, were the loan rate r and the size of the
loan B to rise together over the full range, at some point the contracted
repayment (1 + r)B would equal the firm's best possible outcome K and
default would be certain.
Freimer and G o r d o n (1965) used the loan offer curve construction to
develop a redlining theory of credit rationing. Their point was that the size of
the loan demanded by an individual borrower could exceed the size of the loan
offered at any interest rate, as illustrated by demand curve D 1 in Figure 16.1.15
Hence, the size of the loan demanded might exceed the maximum size of the
loan the lender was willing to offer. The model, however, did not carefully
delineate between the information available to the borrower and to the lender,
so that the type of credit rationing was unclear. These issues are clarified by the
theories of credit rationing discussed in Section 3 that focus on imperfect
information.
Rationing is eliminated when the demand curve intersects the offer curve, as
illustrated by the demand curve D 2 in Figure 16.1. In this case, the loan
~SThis assumes the offer curve is the locus of contracts with zero expected profits. Freimer and
G o r d o n , in fact, a s s u m e the lender is a monopolist making all or nothing loan offers, but similar
considerations apply. In particular, along the loan offer curve, the probability of default approaches 1 as the loan rate approaches infinity.
852
d e m a n d e d and the loan offered are equal at the market-clearing rate r2, so
credit rationing - in terms of the size of loan - will occur only if the quoted rate
loan is maintained below r 2. Several alternative approaches were taken to
motivate why quoted loan rates might be maintained below the market-clearing
level. However, as we will now see, they are all based on exogenous institutional factors.
853
Federal deposit rate ceilings used to provide one explanation for why deposit
rates might be constrained, but b a n k deregulation has now eliminated these
ceilings. In contrast, the theories of credit rationing discussed in the next
section show that imperfect information provides a consistent explanation of
why loan rates might be maintained below the market-clearing level and why
customer relationships remain so important.
As another variant of the customer relationship, Fried and Howitt (1980)
provided an implicit contract theory of credit rationing in which banks provide
firms with loan rate guarantees as part of risk-sharing arrangements. The
implicit contract notion, adopted f r o m labor economics, is a generalization of
the customer relationship. Fried and Howitt applied the concept to cases where
firms acquired protection against unexpected increases in their borrowing costs,
and they showed that what may a p p e a r as credit rationing can result as long as
it is costly to b r e a k contracts. The theory is subject, however, to the same
objections raised with regard to implicit contracts as a theory of u n e m p l o y m e n t
in labor markets. 17
In s u m m a r y , the theories reviewed in this section adopt the special characteristics of loan markets - such as the likelihood of default, the use of b o r r o w e r
classification schemes by banks, and the exclusive customer relationships that
arise between banks and b o r r o w e r s - to motivate why banks set loan rates
below the market-clearing level and then use credit rationing to balance the
d e m a n d and supply of credit. T h e r e is little doubt that these are important
features of loan markets and are part of the credit rationing process. H o w e v e r ,
the theories fail to explain the origins of the features as an integrated part of
their models. In contrast, we now turn to theories based on imperfect
information, which consistently explain both credit rationing and the special
characteristics of loan markets.
In this section we present the basic argument for why there m a y be credit
rationing in markets with imperfect information. In Figure 16.2 we have
17Implicit contracts do not provide a complete theory of rigid wage rates (or interest rates)
because the allocative role of the wage rate depends on the shadow price of labor for the marginal
worker, and this price may still be variable. See, for example, Stiglitz (1986).
18Large parts of this section are based on Stiglitz and Weiss (1981). The model with incentives
effects was independently analyzed by Keaton (1979). Recent surveys of the literature are
provided by Baltensperger and Devinney (1985) and Clemenz (1986).
The fact that markets in which there is imperfect information may be characterized by
non-market-clearing equilibria was noted in Stiglitz (1976a). In labor markets, models generating
these unemployment equilibria are referred to as efficiency wage models, as a result of the close
affinity of these models with those in which wages affected labor quality because of nutritional
effects [Leibenstein (1957), Mirrlees (1975a, 1975b), and Stiglitz (1976b)]. For recent surveys, see
Stiglitz (1987) and Yellen (1984).
854
Expected return
to the bank 'I,
plotted the expected return earned on a loan as a function of the quoted (or
promised) interest rate. Raising the rate of interest charged does not result in a
proportionate increase in the receipts of the lender, because the probability of
default may rise. Indeed, if the probability of default rises enough, the return
to the lender may actually decrease, as depicted in the figure. We denote the
quoted rate at which the lender's expected return is maximized as r*. No bank
will ever charge more than r*.
To see how credit rationing - a situation where there is an excess demand for
credit - may persist, recall the standard argument for market clearing. There it
is argued that if the demand for credit exceeds the supply of credit, lenders will
raise the rate of interest charged, which will increase the supply and decrease
the demand, until market clearing is restored. But at r*, no bank has an
incentive to raise its interest rate, because doing so only reduces the return it
receives. This is why the Walrasian (market-clearing) interest rate may not be
the equilibrium interest rate. Indeed, whenever the Walrasian interest rate
occurs at a level in excess of r*, the market equilibrium is characterized by
credit rationing: each bank would find it in its interest to lower the interest rate
to r*, even though the demand for credit exceeds the supply. 19
Therefore, to obtain credit rationing, it is only required that the expected
(certainty equivalent) return received by the lender does not increase monotonically with the rate of interest charged. 2 There are two basic reasons why the
relationship between the interest rate charged and expected receipts may not
be monotonic: adverse selection effects and adverse incentive effects. These
are now discussed in turn.
19With multiple Walrasian equilibria, if there is any Walrasian equilibrium with r in excess of r*,
then there exists a credit rationing equilibrium, though there m a y also exist another marketclearing equilibrium.
~That is, if there is ever a region of non-monotonicity, there is s o m e supply of credit (funds)
function such that the Walrasian equilibrium lies in the downward-sloping portion of the curve. In
this case, there will be credit rationing.
855
856
return is riskier (in the mean-preserving sense) have a higher expected profit.
We denote the riskiness of a project (firm) by 0, with higher 0 representing
greater riskiness. If (risk-neutral) borrowers have to put up a fixed amount of
equity of their own, e 0, then a project will be undertaken if
E ~ > e0(1 + 6 ) .
Since the expected profit d e p e n d s on a project's risk, there exists a risk level
such that firms with 0 > 0 undertake the investment, while others do not. We
plot ETr - (e0(1 + 6)) as a function of 0 in Figure 16.4.
(2) An increase in the quoted rate r reduces the expected profits for all
borrowers. This downward shift in the ETr curve means that the critical value
of 0 is higher, so fewer firms will demand loans. Moreover, it is the safest
firms - those with the lowest value of 0 - which drop out of the market. This is
the adverse selection effect.
(3) The negative effect on the lender's expected return can now easily be
seen. Because of the concavity of the lender's return function, the expected
return to the lender is smaller with higher 0; this follows immediately given our
assumption that all projects in the given category have the same expected
return. If the expected return to the borrower for high-risk projects is higher,
then the expected return to the lender must be lower. Thus, the total expected
r e t u r n - a v e r a g e d over all applications for l o a n s - m a y either increase or
decrease when the interest rate r is increased. There is a positive direct effect,
but a negative adverse selection effect, as the best risks (those with the lowest
0) drop out of the market.
Expected profits
of the firm
ETr-e (1+5)
Project risk @
Figure 16.4. Only firms with projects at risk level 0 or higher will carry out their projects.
857
The fact that the adverse selection effect can easily outweigh the direct effect
can be seen most easily in an example with just two groups in the population,
groups a and b, with each group having two possible outcomes. The unsuccessful outcome for both groups is a return of 0. The successful outcome for the
groups are X" and X b and the probabilities of success are pa and pb,
respectively. We further assume that
and
X a< X b
pa > p b
with
paxa = /obxb
so that the mean returns are equal but group a is safer and group b is riskier.
We also set the loan size B equal to 1. Thus, if the good group a represent a
proportion F of the total population, and all individuals apply for loans, the
mean gross return to the lender is
(l+r)/5,
where
/5=Fpa+(l_F)p
b,
while if only the high-risk individuals apply, the mean gross return is
(1 + r ) P b .
There is a critical interest rate, r*, at which the safer borrowers stop applying.
Thus, the return to the bank declines precipitously at r*, as illustrated in
Figure 16.5.
An adverse selection effect arises because a higher loan rate affects the safer
borrowers - who anticipate they will always repay the loan - more than it does
the riskier borrowers - who will recognize that the loan rate does not matter in
situations where they have to default on the loan. (At the extreme, an
individual who was fairly sure he would not pay back the loan fully would be
Expected return
to the bank q5
Both types
I pply fr
J
/
bOn]rYohiegrhrpk iy
858
almost indifferent to the promised rate of interest.) Thus, raising the loan rate r
adversely affects safer borrowers m o r e than riskier borrowers.
The argument that a higher loan rate creates an adverse selection effect m a y
b e c o m e even m o r e cogent in a competitive setting, in which loan applicants
apply to several different banks. If one b a n k then raises its quoted loan rate, it
knows that only those borrowers who have been refused loans at all other
banks will accept its loans. If the bank is not confident about its judgment of
the riskiness of the loan applicant, the fact that other banks have rejected the
given applicant conveys a lot of information. W h e n the given b a n k is quoting
precisely the same rate as all other banks, then the same information is not
conveyed when a borrowers accepts a loan. 22
859
Expected return
to the firm E~r
Figure 16.6. The safer project is chosen at loan rates below r*, the riskier project at loan rates
above r*.
undertaken if r < r*. Thus, there will be a precipitous decline in the bank's
return at r = r*, similar to that illustrated in Figure 16.5.]
i is-margmal
Type 1 is redlined
.
Quoted loan rate r
r*
Figure 16.7. Credit rationing status of different borrower groups.
860
861
return falls, given the quoted interest rate; but there is no a priori reason to
believe that the quoted interest rate at which the expected return is maximized
will either increase or decrease, as illustrated in Figure 16.8.
Consider first the incentives model. The curve relating a bank's expected
return to its quoted interest rate can be derived from a more fundamental
curve, which relates the probability of default to the quoted interest rate. It is
more convenient to depict the bankruptcy probability as a function of 1/1 + r;
for the slope of this curve is just P / ( 1 / 1 + r) = P(1 + r), the expected return
Hence, the bank's optimal interest rate is that interest rate at which the slope
of a line from the origin to the curve is maximized. An increase in uncertainty
(associated with a move into a recession) may be thought of as shifting this
curve upwards; at each r there is a higher probability of bankruptcy. But there
is no easy way of seeing whether the interest rate at which the slope is
maximized is likely to increase or decrease.
We illustrate this with the case where there are only two types of activities,
the safer (a) and the riskier (b). The critical interest rate, where the expected
return to the borrower is the same if he undertakes either project a or b, is
1 + r* = [P"X a - pbxb]/[Pa
--
pb].
(3.1)
If as the economy goes into a recession, the probability of success of both safer
and riskier projects is reduced proportionately, then there is no change in the
quoted rate of interest, in spite of the reduction in the expected return to
loans All of the adjustments must occur then through loan availability. On the
other hand, if, as the economy goes into a recession, risky projects have their
success probabilities reduced more than proportionately, then the quoted rate
of interest will increase in a recession, 24 in spite of the fact that the demand for
Expected return
to the bank ap
/
Case t
i
~
Case a
rb *
r*
ra *
Figure 16.8. In a recession, the expected return function shifts down, but the optimal loan rate
m a y increase (case a) or decrease (case b).
74
- D e f i n e z = P " / P . b T h e n we can rewrite equation (3.1) as l + r ~ = [ r X " - X
ferentiating with respect to ~-, we obtain d r * / d r = - [ X " - X b ] / [ ' c - 112> 0.
] / [ ~ ' - 1 ] . Dif-
862
CI= YI + B ,
(72 = Y2 - (1 + r ) B .
The basic model assumes that all consumers have the same income and
consumption preferences. Consequently, all consumers have the same loan
demand, which is assumed to be negatively related to the interest rate.
A "moral hazard" is introduced by the fact that consumer i will default on
his loan if his cost of default Z i is less than the loan repayment (1 + r)B. The
cost of default is interpreted broadly to include the lost access to further credit,
the social stigma, and similar factors. The cost of default is assumed to vary
over the population: some consumers have high Z i values, so they tend to
repay their loans (they are "honest" borrowers); while other consumers have
lower Zi values, so they may intend to default. Banks, however, cannot
identify the consumers who are likely to default. In fact, consumers who intend
to default will act exactly as their honest counterparts so as not to identify their
true character.
Loans are made through a competitive banking industry with access to
deposits at the constant rate 6. If a bank knows that F percent of its borrowers
25A11 of these results extend to the more general model, described below, where there is
collateral, and multiple forms of loan contracts offered by firms [Stiglitz and Weiss (1987a)].
863
= / ' ( 1 + r)B - (1 + 6 ) B .
Given that competition forces bank profits to be zero, the equilibrium value for
the loan rate r* will be such that
1 + r* = ( 1 + 6 ) / F .
This shows that the loan rate factor (1 + r) exceeds the cost of funds factor
(1 + 6) by an a m o u n t 1/F that compensates the b a n k for the borrowers that
default. Loans are m a d e in the size d e m a n d e d by honest borrowers at the loan
rate r*. This is a " p o o l i n g " contract since all borrowers are offered the same,
single contract.
The honest borrowers have an incentive to create a separate loan pool
because they are subsidizing the dishonest borrowers by the amount that the
contract rate r* exceeds the cost of deposits 6. H o w e v e r , the dishonest
borrowers always mimic the actions of the honest borrowers. Therefore, the
best the honest borrowers can do is to adopt a pooling contract that has a
smaller size than their loan d e m a n d at r*. Even though this contract still pools
honest and dishonest borrowers, fewer borrowers default, so the loan rate is
lower. It is easily d e m o n s t r a t e d that the honest borrowers are better off in this
26
case.
864
865
866
though increasing the value of their shares, decrease the value of debt. The
amount of this activity may increase the "closer" the firm is to bankruptcy; this
explains loan contract provisions which enable control of the firm to switch to
debtors when events occur that significantly increase the probability of the firm
being unable to meet its debt obligations, even though it currently is meeting
them. (Eastern Airlines went technically into default when it failed to obtain
wage concessions from its unions.)
4.3.1. Collateral
Several articles have suggested that credit rationing disappears when a bank
can set collateral requirements and interest rates simultaneously. The argument
is that the bank could offer a set of self-selecting contracts [Rothschild and
Stiglitz (1971)] that would fully reveal the risk character of each borrower; in
this case, credit rationing would not occur. For example, if the market
consisted of just two types of b o r r o w e r s - good risks and bad risks - then the
good risks might choose a contract with a lower interest rate and higher
collateral requirement (because it is unlikely they will default and lose their
collateral), while the bad risks might choose a contract with a higher interest
rate and a lower collateral requirement (because there is a higher probability
they will default and lose their collateral). As a result, if the only informational
imperfection concerned which borrowers were good risks and which bad, then
the bank could design contracts that reveal this information, and credit
rationing would not occur.
The fact that banks never have perfect information concerning the characteristics of their borrowers suggests what is wrong (or irrelevant) about this
argument: the conclusion holds only if individuals differ in just one dimension
(say wealth), so that a simple set of contracts can completely separate and
identify the different groups. 3 but if the groups differ in two dimensions (risk
aversion and wealth), then a perfect separation cannot be made with {interest
3Even then there may exist problems when there are a large number of groups. Under
monopoly, there may be partial pooling [see Mirrlees (1971), Stiglitz (1977), and a large
subsequent literature analyzing conditions under which the relevant functions are differentiable],
while under competition, there never exists an equilibrium.
867
rate, collateral} contracts. Of course, if individuals differ in just two dimensions, then it might still be possible to find a more complicated contract that
would perfectly identify the different groups. But so long as the dimensionality of the space of borrower characteristics is larger than the dimensionality of the space of contracts, it seems unlikely that perfect information can be obtained. 31
Stiglitz and Weiss (1981) showed that while increasing collateral requirements have a positive incentive effect, they could have a negative selection
effect. They argued that even if all individuals in society had the same utility
functions, wealthier individuals will, in general, be willing to take greater risks
(based on decreasing absolute risk aversion). Moreover, among those with
large amounts of wealth, there is likely to be a larger proportion of risk-takers:
individuals who gambled, and by chance won. Thus, as a result of such adverse
selection effects, it may not be desirable to require collateral to the point
where credit rationing is eliminated.
Stiglitz and Weiss (1986, 1987b) have also examined a model in which
adverse selection and incentive effects are both present, and in which interest
rates and collateral requ,.'rements are both used. They find that the equilibrium
may take on different forms:
(1) There may be a pooling equilibrium with credit rationing in which both
types of borrowers (high-risk and low-risk) adopt the same contract; collateral
is not increased, since doing so would have adverse selection effects; interest
rates are not increased, since doing so would have adverse incentive effects.
(2) Alternatively, equilibrium may be characterized by multiple contracts,
with credit rationing on each one. Some rich individuals who undertake risky
projects may have to accept low collateral, high interest rate contracts because
they do not receive high collateral, low interest rate contracts. The fraction of
those of each type at the low collateral contract is determined endogenously in
such a way to ensure that the expected return on a low collateral contract
exactly equals the expected return on a high collateral contract.
Since a loan application has no cost in the model, the extent of credit
rationing on different contracts does not serve as a screening device. However,
the role of rationing as a screening device can be examined using straightforward adaptations of similar models in the context of labor markets [Nalebuff
and Stiglitz (1983)].
3aSome of the papers that attempted to show that collateral requirements can eliminate credit
rationing did so by developing examples in which credit rationing does not occur. However, Stiglitz
and Weiss (1981) had pointed out earlier that credit rationing would occur only if the adverse
selection effect outweighed the direct effect of an increase in the interest rate. T h u s , creating an
example to show that credit rationing does not occur is an exercise directed at an irrelevant
question; they would have to show that credit rationing does not arise in any "plausible" model.
See, for instance, Bestor (1985).
868
869
870
Loan
rate r
T]...... ~.......
i
Loan
TOiiilrl
Q2
Q1 Q0
Loanquantity
Figure 16.9. A leftward shift in the loan supply curve raises the shadow price of loans.
d e m a n d curve Do) exceeds Q0- The shadow price of credit, r0, is determined
on the d e m a n d curve D O by the loan quantity Q0.
Now suppose that Federal Reserve action causes the supply curve of loans to
shift to the left, to curve S 1. This establishes a new equilibrium at a point such
as El, with a lower loan quantity Q1, a higher loan interest rate rl, and a
higher shadow price of credit r~. Moreover, the less the loan rate rises, the
m o r e the shadow price of credit rises. For example, if the loan rate were to
remain unchanged at the level r 0 - which the credit rationing theory in Section
3 indicates is quite possible - then the loan quantity falls to Q2 and the shadow
price of credit rises to r 2.
The actual pattern of real interest rates in the U.S. e c o n o m y since 1952 is
shown in Figure 16.10. The real interest rate is measured by the 6 to 9 m o n t h
commercial p a p e r rate minus the inflation rate for the Consumer Price Index.
Three distinct periods are evident.
(1) F r o m 1952 to the early 1970s the real interest remained in a narrow band
centered on 2 percent. (William McChesney Martin was Chairman of the Fed
for most of this period.)
(2) During most of the 1970s the real interest was negative, usually about
- 1 percent. (Arthur Burns was Chairman of the Fed.)
(3) During most of the 1980s the real interest rate was positive, sometimes
above 5 percent. (Paul Volcker was Chairman of the Fed.)
In the absence of credit rationing, the (before-tax) cost of capital to firms is
determined by the real interest rate. The cost of capital for a new capital
871
2-
-1
-2
-3
1962
1~
la6a
1~1
1~4
1~s7
197o
1973
1976
1979
1~2
l~s
872
COST
OF
CAPITAL
4-
3-
-1
--2
1962
1955
1968
'
1961
1964
1967
1970
197.3
1976
1979
i
19e2
CHNdOE
18
16
14
12
.~'
-,
_,
-6
-8
-10
-12
1962
w
1965
i
1968
1
1961
i
1964
l
1967
i
1970
i
1973
i
1976
i
1979
19e2
19e5
873
throughout the 1950s and 1960s. Other factors, including credit rationing, must
therefore account for the observed range of variation in capital investment. We
will now evaluate credit rationing as a factor that may affect capital investment.
874
875
Loan rate r
Loan supply
r0,.
Loan demand DO
()s
Qd
Loan quantity
Figure 16.13. The observed loan quantity is the minimum of loan demand and loan supply.
demand and supply is allocated. Whatever the specific case, if demand and
supply are not directly observed, then the amount of credit rationing is not
directly observed.
Nevertheless, Fair and Jaffee (1972) developed a basic technique for estimating the demand and supply curves for a market that may be in disequilibrium.
They assumed that transactions are voluntary, in the sense that the quantity
transacted Qt must be the minimum of demand and supply:
Qt = min{ Qa, Qs}.
In this case, only the darkened portions of the demand and supply curves in
Figure 16.13 would actually be observed. But it is still possible to obtain
maximum likelihood estimates of the demand and supply curves, and therefore
of the amount of credit rationing. Indeed, a large literature now exists for
estimating markets in disequilibrium, including applications to loan markets. 4a
There have also been attempts to measure credit rationing with proxy
variables and survey techniques: Jaffee and Modigliani (1969) developed a
proxy measure of bank credit rationing based on the percentage of banks loan
that are granted to low-risk firms; and the Federal Reserve carries out a
quarterly survey of the terms of bank lending that refers to availability of credit
[see Harris (1974) and Jaffee (1971)]. Although disequilibrium estimation,
proxy variables, and surveys all generally confirm that banks use non-price
rationing, these techniques do not directly provide evidence of the impact of
41The theory of disequilibrium estimation is developed in Maddala (1983) and Goldfeld and
Quandt (1975). Specificapplications to loan markets are discussed by Bowden (1978), Laffont and
Garcia (1977), and Sealey (1979).
876
877
On the other hand, the firms studied by F-H-P also represent about 85
percent of the total assets held by manufacturing firms. This highly skewed
distribution of firms by size suggests that the contribution of smaller firms to
aggregate investment may be limited. That is, even though credit rationing may
have a significant impact on the investment spending of smaller firms, these
firms might account for only a small part of the fluctuations in aggregate
investment. Additionally, if the large firms that dominate the statistics for
aggregate investment are rationed by banks, they might still have access to
non-bank capital markets for equity and debt or to other sources of funds. We
will now consider some of the reasons that raising funds in the capital markets
may not substitute for bank credit.
878
there will be a significant signalling effect, with only the worst firms (within any
category of firms) issuing equity. 43"44
(c) Agency (adverse incentive effects). The costs of monitoring managers'
activities imply that managers may have a wide discretion. This discretion is
limited by a large supply of outstanding debt in two ways. First, if managers
wish to avoid bankruptcy, then the necessity of meeting these fixed obligations
alters their actions. Second, and perhaps more importantly, banks (lenders)
monitor the actions of the firm directly, paying particular attention to actions
which adversely impact the likelihood that the loan will be repaid. They have
an effective t h r e a t - cutting off credit and demanding the repayment of outstanding l o a n s - not available to those who supply equity funds. This means
that effective control of managers is exercised as much by lenders as it is by
shareholders .45
As a result of these factors, firms may be reluctant to raise capital by issuing
new equities, even (or particularly) when they are credit constrained. Greenwald and Stiglitz (1986a, 1986b) refer to this as an equity constrained firm;
although firms have the option of issuing equity, the cost of doing so is so high
that they act as if they cannot do so. (Clearly, for large enough perturbations
to their environment, the constraint will no longer be binding.)
For many purposes the whole set of financial constraints is relevant; that is,
as a result of informational asymmetries, funds inside the firm are less
expensive than outside funds, whether obtained in the form of equity or in the
form of debt. Raising funds provides a signal, and outsiders' judgments, at
least in some cases, are likely to be more pessimistic concerning the firm's
prospects than insiders' judgments (or, in any case, less confident). Thus, what
the outsider expects to get may be less than the insider thinks he has promised
to give. 46 (Even in rational expectations models with risk neutrality, where
those who pay more than the market expects them to pay are exactly offset by
those who pay less, the informational asymmetries have real effects not only on
43This is demonstrated in the theoretical models of Stiglitz (1982), Greenwald, Stiglitz and Weiss
(1984) and Myers and Majluf (1984). Empirical confirmation is provided by Asquith and Mullins
(1986).
A n important aspect of the issue of equities is that they tend not to be issued continuously, but
rather in discrete amounts. With few exceptions, firms that enter the equity market do so only
infrequently. A dynamic model of equity issue which explains this is provided by Gale and Stiglitz
(forthcoming).
44Earlier models focused on the incentive of the original owners of the firm to sell their shares.
The willingness to do so had an adverse selection effect [Stiglitz (1974, 1982) and Leland and Pyle
(1977)]. Ross (1977) has argued that a firm's willingness to issue debt, and thus to incur
bankruptcy costs, has a positive signalling effect. In each of these instances, one needs to ask
whether there are alternative ways in which the given information can be credibly disclosed without
the costs (bankruptcy, lack of diversification, etc.) associated with the choice of financial structure.
45This is an old view. For a more modern rendition of the argument, explaining why the
free-rider problems which limit the effectiveness of shareholder control do not apply with equal
force to lenders, see Stiglitz (1985).
46This point was emphasized in Stiglitz (1972).
879
the allocation of capital, but also on the magnitude of investment; the increase
in investment by those who underpay for credit may be less than the decrease
in investment by those who overpay.)
5.5.2. Trade credit
Trade c r e d i t - loans between firms that are used to finance the purchase of
materials and goods in p r o c e s s - represents a way of redistributing credit
among firms, which could also serve as a substitute for bank loans [Meltzer
(1960), Jaffee (1971), and Duca (1986)]. The idea is that large firms, which are
not rationed by banks (or which use debt and equity capital markets), can
make loans to smaller firms that cannot obtain bank loans. Trade credit is a
major element in the U.S. credit system: trade credit outstanding is almost as
large as bank loans to business firms and as corporate bonds. 47
The price charged for trade credit by a lending firm is generally very high,
usually translating to an annual interest rate in excess of 24 percent. 48 This
implies that firms that borrow through trade credit have faced credit rationing
with respect to bank loans. In addition, most lending firms rarely change their
trade credit interest rate, so trade credit outstanding is basically determined by
the demand for the credit. (Of course, firms with very low credit ratings may
be denied access to trade credit.)
The existence of this trade credit system raises two basic questions:
(1) Why do lending firms extend trade credit, given that the borrowing firms
are likely to have been denied credit by banks?
(2) Why are lending firms willing to extend more trade credit when bank
credit rationing rises?
Earlier research tried to answer these questions by analyzing trade credit as a
sales expense (like advertising) of firms operating in imperfectly competitive
markets [Nadiri (1969) and Schwartz and Whitcomb (1980)]. However, a more
interesting and complete answer is provided by analyzing trade credit with the
same model we used in Section 3 to analyze the lending decisions of banks [see
Duca (1986)].
The key point is that trade credit allows for an efficient diffusion of
information in the form of risk-sharing arrangements that eliminates elements
of moral hazard. The idea is that firms which are selling goods to other firms
are likely to have better information about the profit prospects of the buyers
than would a bank lending to the same buyers. Trade credit can thus serve as a
risk-sharing arrangement between buying and selling firms.
47Accordingto the Flow of Funds accounts, the outstanding debts of non-financialbusiness firms
at the end of 1987 included trade debt of $546 billion, bank loans of $618 billion, and corporate
bonds of $790.
48For example, a firm may offer a 2 percent discount from its list price if payment is made
immediately (within 5 days); otherwise the list price must be paid within 30 days.
880
The result is that trade credit contracts and bank loan contracts can
represent two parts of a separating equilibrium: all borrowers first apply for
bank loans, and those who do not receive bank loans (due to redlining or to
pure credit rationing) then apply for trade credit. Firms that extend trade
credit will thus anticipate that their borrowers will have above average credit
risk, and therefore they would charge an above average interest rate. Moreover, since the trade credit interest rate mainly represents a premium for the
high risk of default, it would not be highly sensitive to the market interest rate.
49
881
882
evidenced by the huge losses suffered by thrift institutions when interest rates
soared in the early 1980s).
(2) Many states had l a w s - usury ceilings- which set maximum limits on
mortgage interest rates. When binding usury ceilings kept mortgage interest
rates below the level of rates on other loans or securities, lenders simply
stopped making mortgage loans. Furthermore, state legislatures were usually
slow to raise the usury ceilings, so the amount of credit rationing tended to rise
as market interest rates rose during the 1960s and 1970s. 51
The situation changed significantly beginning in 1980 when Congressional
actions (1) removed the state usury ceilings and (2) phased out all Regulation
Q ceilings over a 5-year period. These actions basically eliminated disintermediation and usury ceilings as a source of mortgage market credit rationing. 52
Other related changes in the mortgage market during the 1980s have also
tended to reduce the amount of credit rationing:
(a) The facilities for secondary market trading of seasoned mortgages have
improved, allowing lenders to separate the activity of making mortgage
loans from the activity of holding mortgage loans.
(b) A variety of mortgage pass-through securities (such as GNMAs) and
mortgage-backed securities now allow portfolios of mortgages to be
packaged for investors in a form comparable to other capital market
securities.
(c) Adjustable-rate mortgages have been developed to allow investors with
short-term funds to hold mortgages without facing a severe maturity
mismatch.
(d) Non-banking firms have entered the mortgage m a r k e t - for example,
General Motors Acceptance Corporation ( G M A C ) is now one of the
largest mortgage lenders in the United States.
5. 7. Consumption expenditures
It has been long debated in macroeconomics whether consumption depends on
current i n c o m e - the simple Keynesian t h e o r y - or on "wealth" (or the discounted value of future income) - the permanent income and life cycle theories
[Tobin and Dolde (1971)]. The existence of credit r a t i o n i n g - called liquidity
constraints in the consumption literature - is the factor that distinguishes these
5~Asmarket interest rates rose, banks would first ration more risky borrowers (those with lower
equity ratios and therefore higher loan rates). However, there were cases in which the usury
ceilings were below even the interest rates that lenders required on very safe mortgage loans.
52Congress allowed the states a period in which they could reinstate their usury ceilings by
passing new legislation, but no state took this action. Comparable usury ceilings still exist in many
states on consumer loans and credit card loans, but the states now tend to change these ceilings
more promptly when market interest rates change.
883
'
884
885
years have created large and unpredictable changes in the demand for money.
A key result is that since 1987, the Federal Reserve has not used the M1
money supply as an operating target for monetary policy. At the same time,
Friedman (1981) has shown that a broad measure of credit stands at least on
par with money as an instrument that (a) the Federal Reserve can control and
(b) forecasts future movements in nominal GNP.
References
Akerlof, G. (1970) 'The market for lemons: Qualitative uncertainty and the market mechanism',
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 84: 488-500.
Allen, F. (1983) 'Credit rationing and payment incentives', Review of Economic Studies, 50:
639 -646.
Arnott, R. and J. Stiglitz (1985) 'Labor turnover, wage structure, and moral hazard', Journal of
Labor Economics, 3: 434-462.
Asquith, P. and D. Mullins (1986) 'Equity issues and offering dilution', Journal of Financial
Economics, 15: 61-89.
Baltensperger, E. (1978) 'Credit rationing: Issues and question', Journal of Money, Credit and
Banking, 10: 170-183.
Baltensperger, E. and T. Devinney (1985) 'Credit rationing theory: A survey and synthesis',
Zeitschrift Fur Die Gesamte Staatswissenschaft, 141: 475-502.
Bernanke, B. (1983) 'Nonmonetary effects of the financial collapse in the propagation of the great
depression', American Economic Review, 73: 257-276.
Bernanke, B. (1984) 'Permanent income, liquidity, and expenditure on automobiles: Evidence
from panel data', Quarterly Journal of Economics, 99: 587-616.
Bernanke, B. and M. Gertler (1987), 'Financial fragility and economic performance', Princeton
University, mimeo.
Bestor, H. (1985), 'Screening versus rationing in credit markets with imperfect information',
American Economic Review, 75: 850-855.
Bischoff, C. (1971) 'Business investment in the 1970s: A comparison of models', Brookings Papers
on Economic Activity, 1971-1: 13-58.
Blinder, A. (1987) 'Credit rationing and effective supply failure', Economic Journal, 97: 327-352.
Blinder, A. and J. Stiglitz (1983) 'Money, credit constraints, and economic activity', American
Economic Review, 73: 297-302.
Bowden, R. (1978) The econometrics of disequilibrium. Amsterdam: North-Holland.
Calomiris, C., R. Hubbard and J. Stock (1986) 'The farm debt crisis and public policy', Brookings
Papers on Economic Activity, 1986-2: 441-479.
Campbell, J. and G. Mankiw (1987) 'Permanent income, current income, and consumption',
NBER Working Paper 2436.
Clark, P. (1979) 'Investment in the 1970s: Theory, performance, and prediction', Brookings Papers
on Economic Activity, 1979-1: 73-113.
Clemenz, G. (1986) Credit markets with asymmetric information, Lecture Notes in Economics and
Mathematical Systems 272. Berlin: Springer-Verlag.
Diamond, D. and P. Dybvig (1983) 'Bank runs, deposit insurance, and liquidity', Journal of
Political Economy, 91: 401-419.
Duca, J. (1986) 'Trade credit and credit rationing: A theoretical model', Research Papers in
Banking and Financial Economics, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Duca, J. and S. Rosenthal (1988) 'Mortgage rationing in the post-disintermediation era: Does
FHA make a difference?', Economic Activity Working Paper 83, Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System.
Eaton, J. (1986) 'Lending with costly enforcement of repayment and potential fraud', Journal of
Banking and Finance, 10: 281-293.
Eaton, J. and M. Gersovitz (1981) 'Debt and potential repudiations', Review of Economic Studies,
48: 289-309.
886
Eaton, J., M. Gersovitz and J. Stiglitz (1986) 'The pure theory of country risk', European
Economic Review, 30: 481-515.
Eisner, R. and M. Nadiri (1968) 'Investment behavior and neoclassical theory', Review of
Economics and Statistics, 50: 369-382.
Fair, R. and D. Jaffee (1972) 'Methods of estimations for markets in disequilibrium', Econometrica, 40: 497-514.
Fazzari, S., R. Hubbard and B. Petersen (1988) 'Financing constraints and corporate investment',
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1988-2: 141-195.
Flavin, M. (1981) 'The adjustment of consumption of changing expectations about future income',
Journal of Political Economy, 89: 974-1009.
Freimer, M. and M. Gordon (1965) 'Why bankers ration credit', Quarterly Journal of Economics,
79: 397-410.
Fried, J. and P. Howitt (1980) 'Credit rationing and implicit contract theory', Journal of Money,
Credit and Banking, 12: 471-487.
Friedman, B. (1981) 'The roles of money and credit in macroeconomic analysis', Working Paper
831, National Bureau of Economic Research.
Gale, I, and J.E. Stiglitz (forthcoming) 'The informational content of initial public offering',
Journal of Finance.
Goldfeld, S. and R. Quandt (1975) 'Estimation in a disequilibrium model and the value of
information', Journal of Econometrics, 3: 325-348.
Greenwald, B. and J. Stiglitz (1986a) 'Money, imperfect information, and economic fluctuations',
Symposium on Monetary Theory, The Institute of Economics, Academia Sinica, Taipei,
Taiwan.
Greenwald, B. and J. Stiglitz (1986b) 'Externalities in economies with imperfect information and
incomplete markets', Quarterly Journal of Economics, 101: 229-264.
Greenwald, B., J. Stiglitz and A. Weiss (1984) 'Informational imperfections in the capital market
and macroeconomic fluctuations', American Economic Review, 74: 194-199.
Greider, W. (1987) Secrets of the temple. New York: Simon and Schuster.
Gurley, J. and E. Shaw (1960) Money in a theory of finance. Washington: The Brookings
Institution.
Guttentag, J. (1960) 'Credit availability, interest rates, and monetary policy', Southern Economic
Journal, 26: 219-228.
Hall, R. (1978) 'Stochastic implications of the life cycle-permanent income hypothesis: Theory
and evidence', Journal of Political Economy, 86: 971-988.
Hall, R. and D. Jorgenson (1967) 'Tax policy and investment behavior', American Economic
Review, 74: 194-199.
Hall, R. and F. Mishkin (1982) 'The sensitivity of consumption to transitory income: Estimates
from panel data on households', Econometrica, 50: 461-482.
Harris, D. (1974) 'Credit rationing at commercial banks', Journal of Money, Credit and Banking,
6: 227-240.
Hawtrey, R. (1919) Currency and credit. New York: Longmans, Green & Co.
Hayashi, F. (1985a) 'The effect of liquidity constraints on consumption: A cross-sectional analysis',
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 100: 183-206.
Hayashi, F. (1985b) 'Tests for liquidity constraints: A critical survey', NBER Working Paper 1720.
Hellwig, M. (1977) 'A model of borrowing and lending with bankruptcy', Econometrica, 45:
1879-1906.
Hodgman, D. (1960) 'Credit risk and credit rationing', Quarterly Journal of Economics, 74:
258-278.
Hodgman, D. (1963) Commercial bank loan and investment policy. Champaign-Urbana: Bureau of
Economic and Business Research, University of Illinois.
Hubbard, R. and K. Judd (1986) 'Liquidity constraints, fiscal policy, and consumption', Brookings
Papers on Economic Activity, 1986-1: 1-51.
Jaffee, D. (1971) Credit rationing and the commercial loan market. New York: Wiley.
Jaffee, D. and F. Modigliani (1969) 'A theory and test of credit rationing', American Economic
Review, 59: 850-872.
Jaffe, D, and K. Rosen (1979) 'Mortgage credit availability and residential construction activity',
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1979-2: 333-386.
887
Jaffee, D. and T. Russell (1976) "Imperfect information, uncertainty, and credit rationing',
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 90:651-666.
Kane, E. and B. Malkiel (1965) 'Bank portfolio allocation, deposit variability and the availability
doctrine', Quarterly Journal of Economics, 79: 113-134.
Keaton, W. (1979) Equilibrium credit rationing. New York: Garland Publishing Company.
Keynes, J.M. (1930) A treatise on money. London.
King, M. (1986) 'Capital market imperfections and the consumption function', Scandinavian
Journal of Economics, 88: 59-80.
Koskela, E. (1976) A study of bank behavior and credit rationing. Helsinki: Academiae Scientarum
Fennicae.
Koskela, E. (1979) 'On the theory of rationing equilibrium with special reference to credit
markets: A survey', Zeitschrift fur Nationalokonomie, 39: 63-82.
Laffont, J. and R. Garcia (1977) "Disequilibrium econometrics for business loans', Econometrica,
45: 1187-1204.
Leibenstein, H. (1957) Economic backwardness and economic growth. New York: Wiley.
Leland, H. and D. Pyle (1977) 'Informational asymmetries, financial structure and financial
intermediation', Journal of Finance, 32: 371-387.
Lindbeck, A. (1962) The 'new" theory of credit control in the United States, 2nd edn. Stockholm
Economic Studies.
Maddala, G.S. (1983) Limited-dependent and qualitative variables in econometrics. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Meltzer, A. (1960), 'Mercantile credit, monetary policy, and the size of firms', Review of
Economics and Statistics, 42: 429-437.
Meyer, J. and E. Kuh (1957) The investment decision. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University
Press.
Mirrlees, J. (1971) 'An exploration of optimum income taxation', Review of Economic Studies, 38:
175 -208.
Mirrlees, J. (1975a) 'The theory of moral hazard and observable behavior: Part 1', Working Paper,
Nuffield College.
Mirrlees, J. (1975b) 'A pure theory of underdeveloped economies', in: L.A. Reynolds, ed.,
Agriculture in development theory. New Haven: Yale University Press, pp. 84-106.
Modigliani, F. (1963) 'The monetary mechanism and its interaction with real phenomena: A
review of recent developments', Review of Economics and Statistics, 45: 79-107.
Myers, S. (1977) 'Determinants of corporate borrowing', Journal of Financial Economics, 5:
147-175.
Myers, S. and N. Majluf (1984) 'Corporate financing decisions when firms have investment
information that investors do not have', Journal of Financial Economics, 13: 187-220.
Nakamura, L. (1984) 'Bankruptcy and the informational problems of commercial bank lending',
Financial Research Center Memorandum 54, Princeton University.
Nadiri, M. (1969) 'The determinants of trade credit in the U.S. total manufacturing sector',
Econometrica, 37: 408-423.
Nalebuff, B. and J. Stiglitz (1983) 'Equilibrium unemployment as a worker selection device',
Princeton University mimeo.
Patman Hearings (1952) 'Hearings before the Subcommittee on General Credit Control and Debt
Management of the Joint Committee on the Economic Report', 82nd Congress, 2nd Session.
Washington: Government Printing Office.
Riley, J. (1987) 'Credit rationing: A further remark', American Economic Review, 77: 224-227.
Roosa, R. (1951) 'Interest rates and the central bank', in: Money, trade and economic growth:
Essays in honor of John H. Williams. New York: The Macmillan Company, pp. 270-295.
Rosenthal, S., J. Duca and S. Gabriel (1987) 'Credit rationing and the demand for owner-occupied
housing', Economic Activity Working Paper 79, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve.
Ross, S. (1977) 'The determination of financial structure: The incentive signalling approach', Bell
Journal of Economics, 8: 23-40.
Rothschild, M. and J. Stiglitz (1971) 'Increasing risk: I. A definition', Journal of Economic
Theory, 2: 225-243.
Schwartz, R. and D. Whitcomb (1980) 'The trade credit decision', in: J. Bicksler, ed., Handbook
of financial economics. Amsterdam: North-Holland.
888
Sealey, C. (1979) ~Credit rationing in the commercial loan market: Estimates of a structural model
under conditions of disequilibrium', Journal of Finance, 34: 689-702.
Shapiro, C. (1983) ~Premiums for high quality products as returns to reputation', Quarterly Journal
of Economics, 98: 659-679.
Shapiro, C. and J. Stiglitz (1984) 'Equilibrium unemployment as a worker discipline device',
American Economic Review, 72: 912-927.
Smith, A. (1776) The wealth of nations, Modern Library Edition. New York: Random House.
Smith, B. (1983) 'Limited information, credit rationing, and optimal government lending policy',
American Economic Review, 73: 305-318.
Stigler, G. (1967) 'Imperfections in the capital market', Journal of Political Economy, 85: 287-292.
Stiglitz, J. (1970) 'A consumption oriented theory of the demand for financial assets and the term
structure of interest rates', Review of Economic Studies, 37: 321-351.
Stiglitz, J. (1972), 'Some aspects of the pure theory of corporate finance: Bankruptcies and
take-overs', Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 3: 458-482.
Stiglitz, J. (1974) 'Incentives and risk sharing in sharecropping', Review of Economic Studies, 41:
219-255.
Stiglitz, J. (1976a) 'Prices and queues as screening devices in competitive markets', IMSS Technical
Report 212, Stanford University.
Stiglitz, J. (1976b) 'The efficiency wage hypothesis, surplus labour and the distribution of income
in LDCs', Oxford Economic Papers, 28: 185-207.
Stiglitz, J. (1977) 'Monopoly non-linear pricing and imperfect information: The insurance market',
Review of Economic Studies, 44: 407-430.
Stiglitz, J. (1982) 'Ownership, control and efficient markets: Some paradoxes in the theory of
capital markets', in: K. Boyer and W. Shepherd, eds., Economic regulation: Essays in honor of
James R. Nelson. Ann Arbor: Michigan State Press, pp. 311-341.
Stiglitz, J. (1985) 'Credit markets and the control of capital', Journal of Money, Credit and
Banking, 17: 133-152.
Stiglitz, J. (1986) 'Theories of wage rigidities', in: J.L. Butkiewicz, K.J. Kotford and J.B. Miller,
eds., Keynes' economic legacy. New York: Praeger, pp. 153-206.
Stiglitz, J. (1987) 'The causes and consequences of the dependence of quality on price', Journal of
Economic Literature, 25: 1-48.
Stiglitz, J. and A. Weiss (1981) 'Credit rationing in markets with imperfect information', American
Economic Review, 71: 393-410.
Stiglitz, J. and A. Weiss (1983) 'Incentive effects of termination: Applications to the credit and
labor markets', American Economic Review, 73: 912-927.
Stiglitz, J. and A. Weiss (1986) 'Credit rationing and collateral', in: J. Edwards, J. Franks, C.
Mayer and S. Schaefer, eds., Recent developments in corporate finance. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, pp. 101-135.
Stiglitz, J. and A. Weiss (1987a) 'Macro-economic equilibrium and credit rationing', Working
Paper 2164, National Bureau of Economic Research.
Stiglitz, J. and A. Weiss (1987b) 'Credit rationing with many borrowers', American Economic
Review, 77: 228-231.
Tobin, J. and W. Dolde (1971) 'Wealth, liquidity, and consumption', Federal Reserve Bank of
Boston, Conference Series No 5.
Viner, J. (1937) Studies in the theory of international trade. New York: Harper and Brothers.
Wette, H. (1938) 'Collateral in credit rationing in markets with imperfect information: Note',
American Economic Review, 73: 442-445.
Wojnilower, A. (1980) 'The central role of credit crunches in recent financial history', Brookings
Papers on Economic Activity, 1980-2: 277-340.
Yellen, J. (1984) 'Efficiency wage model of unemployment', American Economic Review, 74:
200-205.