The document discusses perspectives on the role of incentives in the workplace. It begins by summarizing Alfie Kohn's argument that incentive plans typically undermine the very processes they are intended to enhance, based on numerous studies showing rewards do not create enduring commitment. While incentives may secure temporary compliance, research suggests they do not change underlying values or create lasting motivation. However, others argue incentives are necessary to link pay to performance and drive productivity in market economies. While incentives alone may not improve performance, reorganizing work to empower employees and share gains can boost performance, especially with job security.
The document discusses perspectives on the role of incentives in the workplace. It begins by summarizing Alfie Kohn's argument that incentive plans typically undermine the very processes they are intended to enhance, based on numerous studies showing rewards do not create enduring commitment. While incentives may secure temporary compliance, research suggests they do not change underlying values or create lasting motivation. However, others argue incentives are necessary to link pay to performance and drive productivity in market economies. While incentives alone may not improve performance, reorganizing work to empower employees and share gains can boost performance, especially with job security.
The document discusses perspectives on the role of incentives in the workplace. It begins by summarizing Alfie Kohn's argument that incentive plans typically undermine the very processes they are intended to enhance, based on numerous studies showing rewards do not create enduring commitment. While incentives may secure temporary compliance, research suggests they do not change underlying values or create lasting motivation. However, others argue incentives are necessary to link pay to performance and drive productivity in market economies. While incentives alone may not improve performance, reorganizing work to empower employees and share gains can boost performance, especially with job security.
The document discusses perspectives on the role of incentives in the workplace. It begins by summarizing Alfie Kohn's argument that incentive plans typically undermine the very processes they are intended to enhance, based on numerous studies showing rewards do not create enduring commitment. While incentives may secure temporary compliance, research suggests they do not change underlying values or create lasting motivation. However, others argue incentives are necessary to link pay to performance and drive productivity in market economies. While incentives alone may not improve performance, reorganizing work to empower employees and share gains can boost performance, especially with job security.
The passage discusses the debate around whether incentive plans are effective motivators in the workplace or undermine intrinsic motivation. While many managers believe incentives motivate employees, research suggests they only create temporary compliance and not enduring commitment.
Proponents of incentives argue they are necessary to link pay to performance and motivate employees like consumers respond to prices. Critics argue incentives undermine intrinsic motivation and focus employees on pleasing supervisors rather than excellence.
The passage cites numerous studies that found rewards typically undermine the very processes they are intended to enhance such as cooperation and interest in tasks. Incentives are also said to supplant rather than supplement intrinsic motivation.
P E R S P E C T I V E S
What role - if any - shouldf incenfives play in the v^orlcplace?
Rethinkinq Rewards It is difHcult to overstate the ex- tent to which most managers-and the people who advise t hem- be- lieve in the redemptive power of rewards, AHie Kohn argues in "Why l nccnt i vf Plans Cannot Work" (September-October 1993). Certain- ly, the vast majority of U.S. corpora- tions usf some sort of proj^ram in- tended to motivate employees by tyin^ compensation to one index of performance or another. But more striking is the rarely examined belief that people will do a better job if they have been promised some sort of incentive. This assumption and the practices associated with it are pervasive, but a Hfiwinj; collection of evidence snpports an opposing view. Accord- ing to numerous studies in labora- tories, workplaces, classrooms, and other settings, rewards typically nn- dermine the very processes they are intended to enhance. In Kohn' s view, the findings snggest that the failure of any given incentive pro- gram is dne less to a glitch in that program than to the inadequacy of the psychological assumptions that ground all such plans. Do rewards work? The answer de- pends on what we mean by "work." Research suggests that, by and large, rewards succeed at securing one thing only: temporary compliance. They do not create an cndnring com- mitment to any value or action. They merely, and t emporari l y, change what we do. According to Kohn, incentives in the workplace simply can't work. Nine experts consider the role of rewards in the workplace. G. Bennett Stewart III Senior Partner Stern Stewart & Co. New York, New York A world without A's, praise, gold stars, or incentives? No thank you, Mr. Kohn. Communism was tried, and it didn't work. The Soviet and Chinese econo- mies collapsed because people were not allowed to share in the fruits of their individual efforts. With gains from personal initiative harvested as a public good, innovation ceased. PHOTO BY TONY RINALDO 37 P E R S P E C T I V E S and productivity froze. "They pre- tend to pay us, and we pretend to work" was the Russian worker' s lament for the system Kohn now proposes. But for pay to mean any- thing, it must be linked to per- formance. Without that link, pay becomes nothing more than enti- tlement, a joh nothing more than a sinecure. Kohn is unhappy that rewarding some people necessitates penaliz- ing others. Winston Churchill's apt aphorism is the best response. He said, "The virtue of communism is the equal sharing of its misery, and the vice of capitalism is the unequal sharing of its blessings." You can't have it both ways, Mr. Kohn, You simply can' t have the equality of outcome you desire with the robust, dynamic economy we all want. Contrary to the small-sample psy- chology tests Kohn cites, the respon- siveness of ordinary citizens to in- centives is demonstrated daily in our economy. Consumers cut con- sumption in reaction to the "penal- ty" of a price increase and raise pur- chases in reaction to the "hrihe" of a lower price. The price system effi- ciently allocates scarce resources precisely because it rewards people who conserve and penalizes those who fail to respond. Can it be true, as Kohn seems to think, that people respond to monetary incentives when they spend their income but not when they earn it; If Kohn makes a useful point, it is when he says that people won't want to he paid for doing specific tasks. But here is where we disagree: peo- ple should he rewarded for an overall joh done well. To put the point in economic terms, the best incentive is having a piece of the action. Com- pany stock, however, is not the best approach to instilling ownership, for it frequently leaves too loose a link between pay and performance. The best approach often is to carve employees into a share of the profit contributed by their part of the com- pany. Profit should be defined in rel- evant cash-flow terms after covering the cost of all capital employed, a measure that Stern Stewart & Co. calls Economic Value Added. EVA provides employees with three clear 38 incentives: tu unpiovc piotitahility, to grow profitability, and to with- draw resources from uneconomic ac- tivities. In addition, it ties their deci- sions and energies directly to the "net present value" of their enter- prise. All key managers at Quaker Oats have been on an EVA sharing plan for several years, and Scott Paper Company introduced an EVA incentive program for all salaried employees at the beginning of 1993, to name but 2 of the 50 prominent companies that have adopted this approach in recent years. Eileen Appelbaum Associate Research Director Economic Policy Institute Washington, D.C. Companies today are under in- tense pressure to improve efficiency "A world without A's, praise, gold stars, or incentives? No thank you, Mr. Kohn. Communism was tried, and it didn't work/' G. Bennett Stewart III and quality at a time when their re- sources are severely limited. Fid- dling with compensation schemes appeals to many managers as a cheap way to improve their companies' performance hy providing individu- als with incentives to work harder. In fact, reliance on individual incen- tives to motivate workers and spur productivity has a long history in the United States. The U.S. human- resource model evolved in the 1950s partly in response to then-current theories of industrial psychology. By designing compensation schemes that recognize and reward individual differences, companies expected to reap the rewards of increased em- ployee motivation and improved job performance. This idea continues to inform present managerial thinking. In his article "Why hicentivc Plans Cannot Work," Alfie Kohn has per- formed an important service by mar- shaling the modern evidence on the psychological effects of incentives and by showing that rewards fail to improve, and may even reduce, performance. We arc still left, however, with questions ahout what improves a company's performance and what role compensation actually plays in that improvement. I would offer the following answers, based on an anal- ysis of nearly 200 academic case studies and consultants' reports, car- ried out with Rosemary Batt - a doc- toral candidate in labor relations and human-resource policy at MIT's Sloan School of Management-and published in The New American Workplace, forthcoming from the ILR Press in 1994. In the early part of the twentieth century, workplace innovations at- tempted to improve employee satis- faction and, at the same time, com- pany performance. In contrast, the move to high-performance work sys- tems since the mid-1980s is moti- vated by the need to improve quality and reduce costs simultaneously. In the mass-production model of work organization, whether the Taylorist or the U.S. HR version, improving quality raises costs-for inspection, supervision, rework, and waste. It was quite a shock to U.S. sensibili- ties, therefore, when Japanese auto P E R S P E C T I V E S manut';icturers demonstrated that new ways of organizing work could delivernoticeahly higher quality and customer satisfaction at signifi- cantly lower prices. It took nearly a decade for companies in the United States to realize that they would h;ivc to change. Our review of the evidence indi- cates an acceleration of experimen- tation with innovative workplace practices and the emergence since the mid-1980s of two distinctly American high-performance mod- els: a U.S. version of lean production that relies on employee involvement and a U.S. version of team produc- tion that relies on employee empow- erment for performance gains. Pro- Lluctivity and performance improve the most when work is reorganized so that employees have the training, opportunity, and authority to partic- ipate effectively in decision making; wlien they have assurances that they will not be punished for expressing unpopular ideas; when they realize that they will not lose their jobs as a result of contributing their knowl- edge to improve productivity; and when they know that they will re- ceive a fair share of any performance gains, assurances which unionized workers in high-performance com- panies cnioy. Attempts to improve performance by mani pul at i ng compensat i on packages have proven counterpro- ductive. However, reorganizing the work process to capitalize on em- ployee skills and participation has improved performance, especially in combination with employment se- curiiy, gaiiishiiriiig, and incentives to take part in training. In this sense, then, compensation packages are an important component of the human- restiurcc practices that are neces- sary to support high-performance work systems. vatitm and organizational effective- ness. But because certain practical considerations and cultural differ- ences arc not addressed, the argu- ment is flawed. Like Kohn, I have found that many managers in the United States and the United Kingdom-hut not, inci- dentally, in continental Europe or Japan-have deeply held assump- tions about the role of incentive pay in motivation. These assumptions lead them to engage compensation consultants in answering the wrong question: How should we design the incentive system in order to obtain the desired behavior? The more im- portant question is: What role, if any, should incentive compensation play? Like Kohn, I have found that assumptions about incentive com- pensation have led many managers to expect incentives to solve organi- Michael Beet Professor of Business Administration Harvard Business School Boston, Massachusetts Kohn has mounted an eloquent ar- gument, when it is considered in light of what we know about moti- ''If incentive systems do not motivate, what should managers do ahout compensation? Surely, Kohn would not suggest that everyone should he paid the same." Michael Beer zational pruhlems, when there are actually deeper underlying reasons for those problems. Managers tend to use compensa- tion as a crutch. After all, it is far easier to design an incentive system that will do management' s work than it is to articulate a direction persuasively, develop agreement about goals and problems, and con- front difficulties when they arise, The half-life of an incentive system is at best five years. When it stops paying off, employees turn against it. And the result is another dysfunc- tional by-product of incentive sys- tems: precious attention, time, and money is expended on endless de- hates about and redesigns of the in- centive system. If incentive systems do not mo- tivate, what should managers do about compensation? Surely, Kohn would not suggest that everyone should be paid the same. In some industries or functions-sales, for example-incentive compensation is the prevailing practice. In these areas, without paying for perfor- mance, an organization will lose its best people. Yet by paying for perfor- mance, the company rims the dan- ger of encouraging self interest in- stead of organizational commitment. This is a fundamental pay-for-per- formance dilemma that practicing managers confront and that Kohn neglects to address. It is undoubtedly true that in to- day's competitive environment, in- terdependence between different business units and functions as well as the need for custtimcr service and quality make incentive compensa- tion less appropriate than it once was. But there are circumstances in which it is the only solution avail- able: for example, managers of inde- pendent stores far from headquar- ters who don't have a motivating manager-subordinate relationship or salespeople whose performance is independent of other business units and who operate without supervision much of the time. Managers who agree with Kohn should pay for performance but strive to use incentive systems as lit- tle as possible. Pay is an exercise in continued on page 42 39 smoke and mirrors. Companies can- not stop paying for performance. However, they should avoid using incentives for all the reasons that Kohn suggests. What can managers do? They should focus on paying people equi- tably, rather than using pay as an instrument of motivation. They should avoid coupling pay with year- ly or quarterly performance, while promoting the top 10% or 15% of employees for outstanding long- term contributions. The poorest performers should be weeded out, while the rest should be praised for good performance and recognized through other means to promote self-esteem. We are indebted to Kohn for ring- ing the alarm, but he docs not provide managers with creative, practical solutions to the pay-for- performance dilemma. Andrew M. Lebby Senior Partner The Performance Group Washington, D.C. The effect of rewards on motiva- tion and performance is one of the most studied subjects in the man- agement literature. Year after year we validate the finding that employ- ees' perceptions of underpay result in decreased productivity, while in- creased pay doesn't result in in- creased productivity. Year after year we ask employees what motivates them, and year after year they reply: a sense of accomplishment in per- forming the work itself, recognition from peers and top management, ca- reer advancement, management support, and, only then, salary. If Kohn is unable to find data that support anything but a negative rela- tionship between finaneial incen- tives and performance, why is it that in the face of overwhelming evi- dence executives continue to hold onto ineffective methods; Why is it that they refuse to provide those things that employees say tbey want, that direetly relate to in- creased productivity, and that have little or no financial cost? When we stop to separate the physical nature of the reward it- i ''Intrinsic LOtivation- being motivated by cballenge and enjoyment-is essential to creativity. But extrinsic motivation- being motivated by recognition and money-doesn' t necessarily burt/' Teresa M. Amabile self from what the recipient finds rewarding, some possible answers appear. When we ask employees, "What was tbe last reward you re- ceived?" the most frequent response is some variant of "money." When we ask, "Wbat did you find reward- ing about money?" the most fre- quent response is that it was a tacit acknowledgment of the outstanding nature of their contribution. Just as it is easier for some parents to sbow love witb gifts tban with hugs, it is often easier for organizations and managers to sbow gratitude with money than with words. Our current notions of pay follow naturally from our antiquated, Tay- lorist, mechanistic models for de- signing work. The work we do and how we do it have shifted signifi- cantly, but our reward and salary structures remain essentially the same. Senior managers will end ti- nancial incentives only when they rethink what work is and how it is performed. Organizations that have redesigned work to reflect cross- functional business processes or tbose tbat bave implemented the actual principles of TQM bave had to rethink pay and performance. Employees have said, "Give us the tools, tbe skills, the information, the support, and the respect we need." In different words, "Give us real capital, intellectual capital, and symbolic capital, and we'll increase your-and our-financial capital." Money is an outcome of bigb per- formance. Satisfaction and respect are incentives to it. Teresa M. Amabile Professor of Psychology Brandeis University Waltbam, Massachusetts Kohn is absolutely right when he tells us that rewards can work against real commitment and cre- ativity. But he doesn't tell the whole story. There are important differ- ences between bribes and equitable compensation, and tbcrc are condi- tions under wbieb rewards can in- crease involvement and creativity. What matters is what those rewards actually mean. As Kohn points out, there is abun- dant evidence tbat interest and per- formance decline over the long run when people feel they arc controlled by incentive systems or any otber management system. What Kohn fails to point out is that people do not always feel controlled by re- wards. In a reeent study of profes- sional artists, my students and I found, as Kohn would bave predict- ed, that noncommissioned works were more creative tban commis- sioned works. However, what mat- tered was not the obvious fact of contracting for reward, but tbe de- gree to which tbe artist felt con- strained by the terms of the commis- sion; tbe more constraints, the lower the creativity. In fact, some artists considered some of their commis- sions enabling, allowing tbem to create an interesting work of art tbat they wouldn't otherwise have had 42 HARVARD BUSINESS REVIEW November-December 1993 the mciins tu do. When the reward presented the artist with new possi- bilities, in other words, creativity actually increased. Intrinsic motivation-being moti- vated by ehallenj;c and enioyment- is essential to creativity. But extrin- sic motivation-heing motivated by recognition and money-doesn't nee- essarily hurt. The most creative artists in our study tended to be mo- tivated more by challenge, but they also tended to be mot i vat ed by recognition, Kohn accurately docu- ments the evidence that rewards can undermine creativity. But he fails to mention the evidence tbat tangible rewards can actually enhance cre- ativity under certain circumstances, most notably when the individual's primary focus is on the intrinsic re- ward t)f the work itself. Bribes, as Kohn frequently notes, are bound to make people feel con- trolled, and he rightly points out their negative effect on people's work. But he implicitly includes salary in the same category as bribes when he argues that "pay is not a motivator." Certainly, there are some circumstances under which salary increases arc perceived as bribes. A few years ago, for example, I interviewed an R&D scientist who was widely considered to be one of the three most important innovators in a targe, suecessful company; he was also considered extremely ec- centric, "They offered me a pretty large salary increase this year, but I refused it," he recounted. "Right now, my lab is my playground; I pretty much come in here and do things the way I want. But the more they pay you, the more they think they own you." A much more common reaction, however, was the feelinj; expressed by other scientists that their salary increases recognized their creative contributions. Generous compensa- tion, including companywide profit sharing, need not be seen as a bribe, particularly when it is presented as the equitable outcome of creative competence. Although Kohn's article is clear about what managers should avoid, it has little to .say about alternatives to incentives. There is much that ''Appropriate rewards for improved performance have always made good sense, intuitively and practically. They aren't wrong. They aren't intrinsically demotivating." Jerry McAdanis can be said about redesigning work and the work environment so that extrinsie motivators become less central. Managers need to know how to use these alternative techniques before they can be expected to aban- don the incentive systems on which they have relied for so long. If Kohn can convince even a few managers that incentive plans are not the keys to innovative, high- quality performance, he will have made a significant contribution. But it would be a mistake to believe that reward and recognition must always have a negative effect on perfor- mance or that creative people can- not be motivated by both money and interest in the work itself. As the poet Anne Sexton once said, "I am in love with money, so don't be mistak- eti. But first I want to write good poems. After that, I am anxious as hull to earn money and tame and bring the stars all down." Jerry McAdams Vice President, Performance Improvement Resources Maritz Inc. Director Consortium for Alternative Reward Strategies Research St. Louis, Missouri A few years ago, Kohn did the business community a service with his book, No Contest: The Case Against Competition, which argues that competition is for the market- place rather than the workplace. The book makes a compelling ar- gument for focusing on teamwork instead of pitting one employee against another. The key to success, Kohn maintains, is to create an at- mosphere of cooperation, channel- ing employees' creativity and energy to affect the business objectives of the organization positively. Compe- tition between individuals, on the other hand, only gets in the way. Now Kohn argues that rewards get in the way as well. On the basis of my 20 years of researching; and de- signing reward plans for sales and nonsales employees, I disagree. Ap- propriate rewards for improved per- formance have always made good sense, intuitively and practically. They aren't wrong. They aren't in- trinsically demotivating. Data show they make good business sense. Of course, there is always a mar- ket for speeches, books, and articles that profess, through highly selec- tive academic research, that what is working really i.'iu 't. Kohn's article is a provocative exercise in attention- getting, niche marketing. Unfortu- nately, Kohn's article will probably be used by some to deny perfor- mance-improvement opportunities. I do agree with Kohn's point re- garding the negative aspects of the reinforcement of tasks, particularly when the reinforcement plan is piece-rate or merit-pay based. Mea- suring and rewarding on an individu- al level (sales excepted) does tend to become controlling. Tbe focus should he on business objectives, not tasks. The study, Capitalizing HARVARD BUSINESS REVIEW November-December 1993 43 P E R S P E C T I V E S on Human Assets, covering one-mil- lion employees and 432 compensa- tion plans and sponsored by the non- profit Consortium for Alternative Reward Strategies Research (CARS), shows that rewarding groups of em- ployees, usually wbole plants and of- fices, is a powerful business strategy. According to the study, this strat- egy pays off a median three-to-one return on the cost of the rewards. Employees earn from 2% to 15% of their base pay in incentives or non- cash awards. No layoffs appear to result from the improved perfor- mance. Interviews and extensive da- ta analysis of the 432 plans show positive employee-management co- operation and improved information sharing and employee involvement. Rewards are not bribes. Bribes are payments for behavior that may be in the organization's best interest but are clearly not in the individ- ual's. Rewards reinforce a "win- win" environment. The ohjective of a reward plan is not to "control or manipulate," as Kohn contends. It is to provide focus and reward im- proved performance. Tom Peters was right when he wrote about Kohn's thesis, "What we need is a lot more positive rein- forcement, and a lot less of the nega- tive kind, throughout the corporate landscape. And far from cautioning companies about the dangers of in- centives, we should be applauding those that offer their employees a bigger piece of the action" (INC, April 1988). The CARS research has done just that, looking at more plans in greater depth than any other study. The bottom line is simple: reward plans work when properly de- signed and supported; there can be something in it for everyone, I think it is time to focus on the productive use of people as assets to business not on the counterproduc- tive theories in Kohn's article. L. Dennis Kozlowski Chairman and CEO Tyco Laboratories, Inc, Exeter, New Hampshire I'll accept that elephants cannot fly and that fish cannot walk, but Kohn's argument that incentive plans cannot work ciuries the laws of nature at Tyco Laboratories. Tyco provides a compelling case study that incentives can and do work for both managers and shareholders. In fact, we believe our incentive com- pensation program is at the heart of our company's success. We view the relationship between Tyco's management and its share- holders as very straightforward: management works for the share- holders. It is our mission to create value for them through stock-price appreciation. In fact, our share price has closely tracked our earnings curve for many years, lending con- siderable weight to our determina- tion to encourage earnings growth in a prudent and consistent manner. Our compensation program, in turn, was designed to align the financial interests of our executives with 'TU accept that elephants cannot fly and that fish cannot walk, hut Kohn's argument that incentive plans cannot work defies the laws of nature at Tyco Lahoratories/' L. Dennis Kozlowski those of our shareholders. The basic rule is this: the more the executives earn for the shareholders, the more they earn for themselves. Tyco's 250 profit centers fall into four major businesses. Within the context of a few corporate financial controls, we tell each profit-center manager to run the business as if he or she owned it. A decentralized ap- proach lets us put the financial re- sources of a $3-billion corporation behind the entrepreneurial spirit, drive, and resourcefulness of man- agers who think and act like owners. It's the best of both worlds. Profit- center autonomy and responsibility go hand in hand. We encourage each unit's management team to share the unit's profits. The more profits the business unit earns for the share- holders, the more compensation the management team earns for itself. Our incentive plan has several im- portant and unique features. For one, incentive compensation is directly tied to each business unit's perfor- mance and not to corporate results or other factors beyond any individ- ual's control. In addition, the awards are not based on bow units perform against a budget or any other preset goal. Instead, awards constitute a preestablished percentage of earn- ings. Since we adopted this ap- proach, the quality of the budgeting process has substantially improved. Finally, award opportunities are un- capped, and, as a result, they encour- age the entrepreneurial spirit that we value. When designed effectively and integrated thoroughly into the man- agement process, executive incen- tive programs work well for manage- ment and shareholders alike. George F. Baker III Associate Professor Harvard Business School Boston, Massachusetts The problem is not that incentives can't work but that they work all too well. Kohn's analysis of the unin- tended and unwanted side effects of many incentive plans is perfectly apt; plans that provide incentives for the wrong behavior will produce the wrong results. However, Kohn's so- 44 P E R S P E C T I V E S lution to abandon iticcntivc plans entirely is misguided. Rather, man- agers must learn how to harness and use the power of ineentives to drive individual motivation and organiza- tional effectiveness. In several places, Kohn's asser- tions about the weakness of incen- tive plans only serve to highlight the power of such plans to influence he- havior. What Kohn says is absolute- ly true: if teamwork and cooperation are desired, and the incentive plan rewards only individual results, then the plan will generate counterpro- ductive results. However, a well-de- signed ineentive plan that rewards team prodtietivity not only will avoid such unproductive behavior hut also will induce employee coop- eration. This is the logical basis for the majority of profit-sharing and employee stock-ownership plans, whose effectiveness mounting evi- dence supports. Similarly, Kohn's ohservation that incentive plans cause employees to curry favor with the hoss and with- hold information ahout poor perfor- mance is often accurate. But the so- lution is not to eliminate the boss's ability to reward employees. Instead, supervisors should he trained to ig- nore or punish politicking. It is pre- cisely hecause incentives are so powerful that Kohn can predict that if managers reward politicking, poli- ticking will result. Reward plans need not be control- ling, as Kohn seems to imply. Con- sider the store-manager ineentive plan at Au Bon Pain. Store managers are given a profitability target and are allowed to keep a substantial fraction of any profits they earn above this target. The chain puts few constraints on how they achieve or exceed their targets. The plan has hardly been "the enemy of explo- ration." Rather, it has resulted in an explosion of entrepreneurial experi- mentation and innovation. Notice, h<jwever, that the Au Bon Pain plan is not, in Kuhn's words, "contingent on behavior." It is contingent on re- sults, and herein lies the crucial dif- ference. Plans that are contingent on behavior will encourage the pre- scribed hehavior and stifle initia- tion. However, plans that reward de- sired results arc likely to stimulate innovation. Perhaps the most disturbing omis- sion from Kohn's article is his failure to suggest an alternative to the use of incentive plans. If companies are to abandon extrinsic incentives as a way to motivate employees, what are they to use instead; Is Kohn rec- ommending that we live with the loss of individual motivation and lack of organizational innovation and flexibility that characterizes companies and societies without ex- trinsic incentives? Without some level of extrinsic incentive to sup- plement the intrinsic drive of indi- viduals, organizations beeome un- wieldy and inflexible, As a general prescription for the management of organizations, Kohn's approach is naive and Utopian. In the real world, organizations must manage incen- tives if they arc to be fluxibli;, inno- vative, and directed. "Incentives are neither all good nor all bad. Although not the right answer in all cases, they can he highly effective motivational tools/' Donita S. Wolters Donita S. Wolters Manager of Human Resources IMM Operational Serviees, Inc. Denver, Colorado While Kohn makes a number of valid points with respect to the dan- gers of ineentive plans, his summary execution of incentives is unwar- ranted. Incentives are neither all good nor all had. Although not the right answer in all cases, they can he highly effective motivational tools and should be employed under the appropriate circumstances. Without a doubt, finaneial re- wards can be, and have been, both overused and misused. Implement- ing a poorly designed or ill-suited incentive plan can do more harm than good because employees will inevitahly receive mixed, even con- flicting, messages from the organiza- tion about its values and priorities, leading to confusion and frustration. Incentives are no substitute for good management and should not be used indiscriminately to remedy prob- lems when more effective solutions exist. Kohn mentions training and goal setting as examples of effec- tive strategies for improving produc- tivity, and his advice is well-taken. Incentives cannot improve perfor- mance if employees are not properly trained to perform their tasks or have no idea what is expected of them. But something more is of- ten needed to elicit the necessary effort. The ioh-rate pay systems that typify unionized hlue-eollar environ- ments-where mediocrity and lack of innovation are the hallmarks, and employees do just enough to get hy - illustrate the point. I have observed, as a veteran of many employee-eounseling ses- sions, that employees are more apt to become disillusioned with incen- tive plans when they feel exploited because the expected rewards are not forthcoming, not when they are rewarded for something they were inclined to do in the first place. To avoid pereeptions of exploitation and manipulation, however, two de- continued on pa^e 48 45 P E R S P E C T I V E S sign features of the incentive pro- gram are imperative. First, the criteria for and the actual evaluation of performance must be seen as ohiectivc and within the per- former's control. This means that anyone should be able to predict the reward consistently and reliably based on given actions and results. The reward should not he deter- mined through highly subjective processes, such as a supervisor's in- dividual opinion. Kohn seems to support this view when he states that "not receiving a reward one had expected to receive is...indistin- guishable from heing punished." Second, the recipient should con- sider the reward equal to the effort that produced it. Too insignificant and the incentive will be insulting and thus ineffective; overdone and the balance of fairness will be upset. Insufficient attention to these dy- namics may underlie the apparent failure of many executive incentive plans, which could more accurately be termed entitlement programs. Kohn goes on to decry the inabili- ty of incentives to "create an endur- ing commitment to any value or ac- tion." I question the relevance of this criticism. The purpose of incen- Alfie Kohn Responds: The average U.S. company has come to resemble a game show: "Tell our employees about the fabulous prizes we have for them if their productivity improves!" None of my respondents doubts the pervasiveness of this men- tality. In fact, several profess incredulity that anyone would question the value of dangling rewards in front of people. In my experience, this reaction most often comes from the consultants who make their living selling incentive programs. What I hear aroLind the country from people with no axe to grind is a frank acknowledgment that incentive plans rarely work. Consider the following: D A human-resource executive at a major U.S. auto company re- cently surveyed her colleagues in various industries; they told her that, at best, their incentive plans didn't do too much damage. D Training Magcizine ran a cover story in August: "Why No One Likes Your Incentive Program." D As Michael Beer observes, pay- for-performancc programs are typically tossed out a few years after they are begun. D To the hest of my knowledge, no controlled study has ever found long-term improvement in the quality of performance as a result of extrinsic rewards. Of course, it is comforting to believe that incentives fail on- ly for incidental reasons, such as that they are "misused," as Donita Woltcrs would have it, or that they are offered "for the wrong behavior," as George Baker claims. But 1 helievc incentive plans must fail, hecause they are hased on a patently inadequate theory of motivation. Trying to undo the damage hy adopting a new pay-for-performance scheme is rather Uke trying to cure alco- holism by switching from vodka to gin. This argument makes a lot of people angry, as seems clear from Jerry McAdam's unpleasant speculations about my ulterior for-performance in particular. Neither can produce quality, but only the latter is positively harm- ful. I agree with Aniahilc that "generous compensation...need not be seen as a hrihe," but I dis- agree that "people do not always feel controlled hy rewards." Richard Ryan and his colleagues at the University of Rochester, pi- oneers in researching this ques- tion, have concluded that "re- wards in general appear to have a controlling significance to some extent and thus in general run the motives and from the amusing, if predictable, mutterings about communism hy G. Bennett Stew- art. If the attachment to carrot- and-stick psychology - or any dogma-is deep enough, ques- tioning simply isn't permitted. W. Edwards Deming, and oth- ers hefore him, have been telling us for years that money is not o motivator. Judging from Teresa Amabile's response, however, I may not have heen clear enough ahout the difference between compensation in general and pay- risk of undermining intrinsic mo- tivation." Offering good things to people on the contlition that they do what you tell them is, almost hy definition, a way of trying to exert control. But even someone who insists that it's possible in theory to de- vise a noncontrolling reward has to concede that control is what incentive plans in the real world are all about. Just listen to the de- fenders of these programs: the whole idea is to "direct [employ- ees'] behavior," as Wolters says. 48 DRAWING BY MARK STEELE tives is not to change employees' values but to direct their behavior in ways that will henetit the organiza- tion and the employees themselves. More telling is Kohn's failure to identity a viahle alternative to in- centives. Of course, the intrinsic re- wards he praises are extremely moti- vating where they happen to exist, but they are not always present and cannot usually be created, The current trend in organizations is toward less hierarchy and more t eamwork. For employees, this means that fewer promotions are available and greater eooperation among coworkers is required. For employers, this means that maxi- mum versatility and productivity must be summoned trom all mem- bers. The use of incentive plans rep- resents one strategy for aligning or- ganizational and individual goals by treating employees as partners in both the risks and the successes of the business. Kohn recognizes that the majority of companies in the United States utilize some sort of in- centive plan. Indeed, his assertions are being tested on the firing line and disproved by a persuasive cross sec- tion of U.S. business. _ ^ Reprint 93610 1 believe incentive plans must fail. No wonder the evidence shows that incentives do not "supple- ment the intrinsic drive of indi- viduals," as Baker believes, but tend to supplant it. As a rule, the more salient the extrinsic moti- vator, the more intrinsic motiva- tion evaporates. One could say, as Baker does, that incentives work too well, in the sense that they are destruc- tive of excellence and interest. But one cannot conclude from this that the problem is merely one of implementation. Baker behavior. Rather, the use of re- wards and the extrinsic orienta- tion tbey produce inexorably lead people to focus on pleasing those in charge of handing out the good- ies. Fine-tuning the incentive plan cannot solve the problem. Finally, a number of correspon- dents are understandably curious about my views on what should replace incentive plans. If a dis- cussion on this point was con- spicuously absent from the arti- cle, wbich was an excerpt from my book Punished hy Rewards, it errs in assuming that just because rewards undermine cooperation it follows that tbey can also cre- ate it. If something has the power to hurt, that doesn't mean more of it will motivate. Again, think of money: less of it can demoti- vatc, but that doesn't mean that more of it will motivate. I think Baker also misunderstands why employees try so hard to con- vince their reward-dispensing su- pervisors that everything is under control. It's not because the latter are deliberately rewarding such was due to limited space. I do grapple at length with alterna- tives to incentives in another chapter, "Thank God It's Mon- day." Here, a few words will have to suffice. On compensation, my advice is this: pay people well and fairly, then do everything possible to help tbem forget about money. I bave no objection to profit-shar- ing: it seems sensible enougb that the people who made the profit ought to have it. Nor am I keen to promote one criterion for com- pensation over another: for exam- ple, need, seniority, job responsi- bilities, training, market value. My concern is primarily to con- vince managers to stop manipu- lating employees witb rewards and puni shment s and to stop pushing money into their faces. My other concern is to empha- size the futility of fiddling with compensation schemes. Tbis is not the road to quality. Andrew Lebby, a consultant, and Eileen Appelbaum, a researcher, corrob- orate this, and each offers a way of thinking about where excel- lence actually comes from. I find it useful to think in terms of three C's: choice, collaboration, and content. Choice means that em- ployees should be able to partici- pate in making decisions about what tbey do every day. Collabo- ration denotes tbe need to struc- ture teams in order to facilitate an exchange ot ideas and a elimate of support. Content refers to wbat people are asked to do: as Freder- ick Herzberg said, "If you want people motivated to do a good job, give them a good job to do." An organization that provides these three ingredients in place of artificial inducements like incen- tive plans will not "lose its best people," as Beer worries. Inno- vation and excellence are the natural results of helping people experience intrinsic motivation. But intrinsic motivation cannot survive in an organization that treats its employees like pets. HARVARD BUSINESS REVIEW November-December 1993 49