The University of Chicago Press
The University of Chicago Press
The University of Chicago Press
S
C
H
A
R
A
C
T
E
R
I
S
T
I
C
S
D
e
p
e
n
d
e
n
t
V
a
r
i
a
b
l
e
:
I
n
v
e
s
t
m
e
n
t
C
l
i
m
a
t
e
V
a
r
i
a
b
l
e
S
h
-
i
n
v
e
s
t
-
n
(
%
)
(
1
)
S
h
-
w
o
r
k
-
c
a
p
i
t
a
l
-
n
(
%
)
(
2
)
S
h
-
s
a
l
e
s
-
c
r
(
%
)
(
3
)
M
n
g
-
t
i
m
e
(
%
)
(
4
)
D
a
y
s
-
i
n
s
p
e
c
t
i
o
n
s
(
l
o
g
)
(
5
)
B
r
i
b
e
(
Y
e
s
/
N
o
)
(
6
)
B
r
i
b
e
(
%
S
a
l
e
s
)
(
7
)
D
a
y
s
-
n
o
p
o
w
e
r
(
l
o
g
)
(
8
)
L
o
s
s
-
t
r
a
n
s
i
t
(
%
)
(
9
)
S
m
a
l
l
.
0
4
9
*
*
*
.
0
4
5
*
*
*
.
0
7
2
*
*
*
1
.
2
3
9
*
*
*
.
2
3
8
*
*
*
.
0
2
9
*
*
*
.
0
5
4
.
0
6
1
*
*
*
.
1
4
3
*
(
.
0
0
4
)
(
.
0
0
3
)
(
.
0
0
4
)
(
.
1
5
2
)
(
.
0
1
4
)
(
.
0
0
6
)
(
.
0
5
1
)
(
.
0
1
5
)
(
.
0
7
4
)
M
e
d
i
u
m
.
0
9
3
*
*
*
.
0
8
7
*
*
*
.
0
9
6
*
*
*
1
.
7
6
7
*
*
*
.
5
0
8
*
*
*
.
0
1
4
*
.
2
5
0
*
*
*
.
0
5
0
*
*
*
.
2
0
2
*
*
(
.
0
0
5
)
(
.
0
0
4
)
(
.
0
0
5
)
(
.
1
9
9
)
(
.
0
1
7
)
(
.
0
0
8
)
(
.
0
6
0
)
(
.
0
1
8
)
(
.
0
8
6
)
L
a
r
g
e
.
1
1
9
*
*
*
.
1
1
7
*
*
*
.
0
9
0
*
*
*
1
.
4
6
8
*
*
*
.
7
1
5
*
*
*
.
0
0
1
.
3
6
1
*
*
*
.
0
8
8
*
*
*
.
0
3
9
(
.
0
0
7
)
(
.
0
0
5
)
(
.
0
0
6
)
(
.
2
3
4
)
(
.
0
2
2
)
(
.
0
1
0
)
(
.
0
6
7
)
(
.
0
2
2
)
(
.
0
9
9
)
M
a
t
u
r
e
.
0
1
3
*
*
*
.
0
0
6
*
.
0
0
9
*
*
.
2
7
8
*
.
0
3
8
*
*
.
0
0
4
.
1
1
4
*
.
0
6
3
*
*
*
.
1
9
2
*
*
(
.
0
0
4
)
(
.
0
0
3
)
(
.
0
0
4
)
(
.
1
5
0
)
(
.
0
1
5
)
(
.
0
0
7
)
(
.
0
5
8
)
(
.
0
1
6
)
(
.
0
8
3
)
O
l
d
e
r
.
0
1
0
*
*
.
0
1
1
*
*
*
.
0
0
6
.
4
9
4
*
*
*
.
0
5
9
*
*
*
.
0
2
0
*
*
.
2
3
6
*
*
*
.
0
7
2
*
*
*
.
2
0
4
*
*
(
.
0
0
5
)
(
.
0
0
4
)
(
.
0
0
4
)
(
.
1
8
0
)
(
.
0
1
7
)
(
.
0
0
8
)
(
.
0
6
5
)
(
.
0
1
8
)
(
.
0
8
9
)
E
x
p
o
r
t
e
r
.
0
3
0
*
*
*
.
0
3
7
*
*
*
.
0
4
8
*
*
*
.
5
0
4
*
*
*
.
0
8
5
*
*
*
.
0
4
0
*
*
*
.
0
5
7
.
0
5
8
*
*
*
.
2
1
7
*
*
*
(
.
0
0
5
)
(
.
0
0
3
)
(
.
0
0
4
)
(
.
1
5
9
)
(
.
0
1
4
)
(
.
0
0
7
)
(
.
0
5
0
)
(
.
0
1
5
)
(
.
0
6
7
)
F
o
r
e
i
g
n
.
0
4
1
*
*
*
.
0
2
5
*
*
*
.
0
4
3
*
*
*
.
0
9
4
.
0
6
1
*
*
*
.
0
1
6
*
*
.
0
8
0
.
0
3
8
*
*
.
2
1
3
*
*
(
.
0
0
6
)
(
.
0
0
4
)
(
.
0
0
5
)
(
.
1
8
3
)
(
.
0
1
8
)
(
.
0
0
8
)
(
.
0
6
4
)
(
.
0
1
8
)
(
.
0
8
8
)
S
m
a
l
l
c
i
t
y
.
0
1
0
*
*
*
.
0
0
9
*
*
*
.
0
1
4
*
*
*
.
1
9
0
.
0
2
5
*
.
0
5
3
*
*
*
.
2
2
8
*
*
*
.
1
1
8
*
*
*
.
0
7
2
(
.
0
0
4
)
(
.
0
0
3
)
(
.
0
0
3
)
(
.
1
4
4
)
(
.
0
1
3
)
(
.
0
0
6
)
(
.
0
4
3
)
(
.
0
1
3
)
(
.
0
6
3
)
This content downloaded from 210.56.13.7 on Mon, 31 Mar 2014 09:24:45 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
623
G
o
v
e
r
n
m
e
n
t
.
0
3
5
*
*
*
.
0
1
3
*
*
.
0
4
1
*
*
*
.
5
9
9
*
*
.
0
0
0
.
1
3
2
*
*
*
.
4
9
6
*
*
*
.
1
1
2
*
*
*
.
0
7
8
(
.
0
0
7
)
(
.
0
0
5
)
(
.
0
0
6
)
(
.
2
4
2
)
(
.
0
2
6
)
(
.
0
1
0
)
(
.
0
6
4
)
(
.
0
2
5
)
(
.
1
2
5
)
E
x
p
a
n
d
.
0
4
1
*
*
*
.
0
2
9
*
*
*
.
0
2
9
*
*
*
.
4
9
1
*
*
.
0
1
8
.
0
5
3
*
*
*
.
1
4
2
*
*
.
0
9
8
*
*
*
.
2
4
3
*
*
(
.
0
0
6
)
(
.
0
0
4
)
(
.
0
0
5
)
(
.
2
0
9
)
(
.
0
1
9
)
(
.
0
0
8
)
(
.
0
6
9
)
(
.
0
2
0
)
(
.
0
9
8
)
C
o
n
t
r
a
c
t
.
0
2
7
*
*
*
.
0
4
0
*
*
*
.
0
4
4
*
*
*
1
.
7
7
1
*
*
*
.
1
4
0
*
*
*
.
0
8
8
*
*
*
.
5
2
3
*
*
*
.
0
5
9
*
*
.
4
3
5
*
*
(
.
0
0
9
)
(
.
0
0
6
)
(
.
0
0
7
)
(
.
3
0
8
)
(
.
0
2
7
)
(
.
0
1
2
)
(
.
1
0
5
)
(
.
0
2
8
)
(
.
1
6
9
)
S
u
r
v
e
y
#
S
e
c
t
o
r
x
e
d
e
f
f
e
c
t
s
Y
e
s
Y
e
s
Y
e
s
Y
e
s
Y
e
s
Y
e
s
Y
e
s
Y
e
s
Y
e
s
C
o
n
s
t
a
n
t
.
1
3
3
*
*
*
.
1
2
4
*
*
*
.
3
5
9
*
*
*
7
.
4
7
7
*
*
*
1
.
5
1
6
*
*
*
1
.
8
1
2
*
*
*
1
.
5
7
0
*
*
*
1
.
4
6
5
*
*
*
(
.
0
0
5
)
(
.
0
0
3
)
(
.
0
0
5
)
(
.
1
8
4
)
(
.
0
1
8
)
(
.
0
6
6
)
(
.
0
1
8
)
(
.
0
9
7
)
O
b
s
e
r
v
a
t
i
o
n
s
4
2
,
5
1
9
6
3
,
0
2
0
6
5
,
5
3
1
6
3
,
2
9
5
5
6
,
7
9
4
5
,
1
7
0
7
5
0
,
6
1
0
6
1
,
3
0
9
4
5
,
2
7
2
R
2
.
1
9
.
2
1
.
3
1
.
1
8
.
3
1
.
1
7
.
1
0
.
5
3
.
0
7
N
o
t
e
.
F
i
r
m
c
h
a
r
a
c
t
e
r
i
s
t
i
c
s
a
r
e
a
t
t
i
m
e
t
.
C
o
l
u
m
n
6
i
s
a
d
p
r
o
b
i
t
,
s
o
c
o
e
f
c
i
e
n
t
s
a
r
e
m
a
r
g
i
n
a
l
e
f
f
e
c
t
s
a
n
d
R
2
i
s
P
s
e
u
d
o
R
-
s
q
u
a
r
e
d
.
R
o
b
u
s
t
s
t
a
n
d
a
r
d
e
r
r
o
r
s
i
n
p
a
r
e
n
t
h
e
s
e
s
.
*
S
i
g
n
i
c
a
n
t
a
t
1
0
%
.
*
*
S
i
g
n
i
c
a
n
t
a
t
5
%
.
*
*
*
S
i
g
n
i
c
a
n
t
a
t
1
%
.
This content downloaded from 210.56.13.7 on Mon, 31 Mar 2014 09:24:45 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
624 economi c development and cultural change
variables may bias results. After all, environments characterized by ineffective
business regulations or high incidence of corruption are also often characterized
by poor infrastructure or low access to nance. To overcome some of these
concerns, we control for different indicators of business climate conditions and
their interactions with rm size simultaneously. Size dummies are dened in
four groups: micro, small, medium, and large, measured at the initial period
of observation. The omitted category is micro enterprises, employing between
1 and 10 employees. Age of the rm is specied in three categories: young,
from 1 to 5 years old; mature, between 5 and 15 years old; and older, above
15 years old; and it also refers to the initial period of observation. The other
rm characteristics are dated at period t, the only period for which such
information is available. We also control for ownership (foreign, government),
exporting status (exporter), and location, with variables dened as reported in
Section III.
To account for differences in demand conditions and productive structure,
the regressions also include a full set of sector-country interaction dummies.
11
Thus, our focus is on within-country rather than across-country variation. This
decision reects several factors. First, there is substantial variation of investment
climate indicators within countries, and we want to test whether its impact
is signicant. Second, it controls for potential omitted variables at the country
level. In addition, it could control for some possible measurement errors or
differences in implementation across countries. As Haltiwanger and Schweiger
(2005) note, in the ES there are some countries with particularly high net
employment growth rates. However, there is a strong country-specic com-
ponent, such that country effects yield relative magnitudes of job creation and
employment growth. They also noted that the relationships of employment
variations between size and age classes appear right. Thus, small and younger
rms have higher job creation and destruction than older and larger rms
within the country, when considering total employment. Therefore, statistical
methods that remove country level effects are appropriate to draw conclusions
within countries on the difference of the impact of investment climate on
different types of rms.
The construction of the investment climate variables requires some IC
ikc
explanation. A number of previous studies assess the investment climate ex-
perienced by rm i, using rm-level subjective measures. Such studies rely
on answers to questions of the form, How much (the dimension k of the
business climate) is an obstacle for the growth of your rm? with possible
answers ranking between 1 and 5 (Johnson, McMillan, and Woodruff 2002;
11
See table A2 for the list of sectors included.
This content downloaded from 210.56.13.7 on Mon, 31 Mar 2014 09:24:45 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Aterido, Hallward-Driemeier, and Page s 625
Beck et al. 2005; Pierre and Scarpetta 2006; Ayyagari et al. 2008). Subjective
assessments, while insightful, have a number of possible drawbacks. There is
a concern that rms perceptions of the business environment reect idiosyn-
cratic differences in the degree of optimism or pessimism of the individuals
responding to the survey. Answers are also likely to be strongly inuenced by
the experience and performance of the rm (see Hallward-Driemeier and Ate-
rido 2007).
Our analysis uses objective measures to gauge the relative importance of
the investment climate to rms. While, in principle, objective measures may
be less likely to be inuenced by rms performance than subjective measures,
the results presented in table 3 suggest that individual rms reported objective
investment climate conditions are likely to be endogenous to rmperformance,
a feature that we need to take into account when estimating the effect of
investment climate variables on rm performance.
To account for endogeneity, we construct a measure of the IC conditions
faced by rm i on dimension k in country c, by averaging the responses of
rms in the same country-location-sector-size cell, excluding the observation
from rm i in computing that average.
12
To ensure adequate numbers of rms
in each location-sector-size cell average, we drop one dimension of the cell
until an adequate number is reached (i.e., rst we substitute country-location-
size bins, then country-sector-size).
13
This captures the broader environment in which the rm operates and allows
the individual rms own contribution to the average to be excluded. The
approach also has the benet of not losing those observations where a rm
did not answer all the individual investment climate questions.
14
12
In some specications we also assess whether results vary if we instead compute IC conditions
by averaging the responses of rms in the same country-location-sector bins (i.e., excluding size
as a dimension). Here we use a ner disaggregation of location. Above, locations are aggregated
by city size (e.g., capital cities and those with a population above 1 million, and cities below 1
million people). In the country-location-sector averages, we construct the cells based on the actual
cities or towns the rms are located in. If the representation is low, locations are aggregated based
on ve size groups (capital cities or more than 1 million; 500,0001 million; 250,000500,000;
50,000250,000; less than 50,000).
13
If we were to keep always the original four dimensions same country-location-sector-size cell
there are approximate 5,000 observations that are lost and results do not change substantially. We
also used different minimum cell-size requirements (410 rms) and found results were robust.
Results presented use the cutoff of at least four rms in a cell.
14
This approach is very similar to using location-sector-size dummies as instruments (except that
the rms own value is not excluded in this calculation, the number of observations averaged in
a cell may be very small, and the additional observations cannot be recovered if a single investment
climate variable is not available). The test of overidentifying restrictions could not be estimated
using the full specication due to the large number of dummies and instruments. However, in
This content downloaded from 210.56.13.7 on Mon, 31 Mar 2014 09:24:45 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
626 economi c development and cultural change
In constructing these measures, we actually take two steps before entering
the averages into the regressions, with the second one being particularly im-
portant if endogeneity concerns are to be addressed. An issue is how the
investment climate indicators are calculated and matched to rms in the
regression. This requires differentiating between a rms current sizethat
can be important in the conditions they report facing nowand their initial
sizeand the average conditions faced by rms of the size they were initially.
Simply giving rms the average value of rms in their current size category
is giving them the ex post conditions, not the initial conditions. To justify
this, one has to assume that the conditions faced by rms have remained
constant over time, regardless of how they may have grown. The alternative
we present assumes instead that conditions faced by rms are likely to vary
as they grow. Rather, we make the less restrictive assumption that, within a
location and sector, conditions facing rms of a certain size now are the same
as the conditions facing the same-sized rm in the earlier period. For example,
we can use the information on conditions facing micro rms now to measure
what micro rms faced 3 years before.
Thus, in the rst step, we use the information that rms report about
investment climate conditions they face in the current period. While it would
be desirable to have the conditions they faced in the initial period 3 years
ago, this information was not collected. However, we also recognize that rms
that have recently changed size may report very different IC conditions relative
to what is typical for rms that have been in a given size category for a while.
To account for this we use a rms average size in constructing the location-
sector-size averages of investment climate conditions. We do so by constructing
averages of investment climate indicators within cells, which are dened ac-
cording to rms average size.
15
In the second step, we match these averaged
indicators to rmsbased on their initial, not current, size.
16
This procedure has a number of advantages. The rst is that as advanced
specications not using a full set of sector-survey interaction dummies, the restrictions could not
be rejected at the 0.3 level.
15
We repeated the exercise using current size in dening the cells for calculating the IC variables
and did not nd signicant differences. For rms that remain in the same size category there is
no difference between the two approaches.
16
An example may be useful to clarify our procedure. Let us consider, for example, a textile-
producing rm in the capital city of Chile, which was small in period t 3 and has grown to
be of medium size in period t, and the average size in the two periods is medium. We use its
responses on the investment climate indicators to construct the average of Santiago-textile-medium-
sized rms. However, this average is not what is then used for that rm in the regressions. Since
we want to capture the average IC conditions of that rm in period t 3, when it was small, we
match it to the average reported IC investment climate conditions of Santiago-textile-small rms.
This content downloaded from 210.56.13.7 on Mon, 31 Mar 2014 09:24:45 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Aterido, Hallward-Driemeier, and Page s 627
in the former paragraph, using IC averages based on rms average size allows
us to obtain a more accurate measure of the IC conditions facing a rm in a
given size category. Thus, if, for example, rms that have recently expanded
report lower access to capital than rms that have been large for a while, then
accounting for the observations of growing rms in the construction of the
IC may underestimate the average access to capital of large rms. A similar
effect may happen for rms that have recently contracted and report access to
capital or other IC which are more representative of rms that are large than
of rms that are small. Considering rms based on their average size ameliorates
this problem.
Second, constructing a measure of IC conditions based on the initial instead
of the current size is a key feature to minimize endogeneity problems. Thus,
if we consider again the example of a rm that expands from being small in
period t 3 to medium in t, it matters whether the rm is assigned the
average IC conditions of small or medium rms. The main point is that
matching based on current size reintroduces endogeneity, as rms that grow
are assigned higher access to credit just because they have grown, which creates
a positive correlation between the error term and the IC conditions. Our
procedure assumes that the conditions that matter for employment growth
are those prevalent in the past and that objective conditions remain constant
over time for size classes of rms, not for individual rms themselves. These
hypotheses allow us to construct measures that are exogenous to the rm and
control for the fact that rms may choose to grow/or not grow to face a
determined set of IC. We show in our estimates the importance of how the
IC variables are constructed for the results.
While we believe our constructed IC variables go a long way toward ad-
dressing endogeneity, a lingering concern is that our results may be capturing
the effects of shocks that are correlated across rms, which drive our constructed
average IC as well as individual rm performance. We reduce any possible
biases brought by these correlations by introducing as an additional regressor
the average employment growth of the cell used to compute the IC conditions
of rm i (excluding as usual, the employment growth of rm i in that cal-
culation). This variable is denoted as Empg-cell
i
.
VI. Results
We now describe the results attained with our estimation procedure and
presented in table 4, column 1. The results indicate important nonlinearities
in the effects of business environment constraints across rm size. They also
suggest that a weak business environment tends to hurt the growth of small,
medium, and large rms and benet in relative termsand for some variables,
This content downloaded from 210.56.13.7 on Mon, 31 Mar 2014 09:24:45 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
628
TABLE 4
IMPACT OF INVESTMENT CLIMATE ON EMPLOYMENT GROWTH
Dependent Variable: Employment Growth (Emp(t) Emp(t 3))/((Emp(t) Emp(t 3))/2)
Investment Climate Variable
(ICvar)
ICvar avg
Matched
to Initial
Size
(1)
Individual
Firm Re-
sponse
(2)
ICvar as in
Col. 1,
with Col. 2
Sample
(3)
ICvar avg
Matched
to Current
Size
(4)
ICvar Cell Av-
erage: Survey-
Sector-
Location
(5)
Sh-invest-n .055 .083*** .095 .583*** .008
(.059) (.018) (.074) (.075) (.033)
(Small) # Sh-invest-n .092 .022 .090 .039 .047
(.065) (.023) (.077) (.070) (.040)
(Medium) # Sh-invest-n .130* .028 .159* .024 .115**
(.075) (.024) (.086) (.083) (.045)
(Large) # Sh-invest-n .136* .019 .221*** .134 .110**
(.071) (.028) (.085) (.087) (.056)
Sh-mng-time .003** .001*** .005*** .011*** .002***
(.001) (.000) (.002) (.002) (.001)
(Small) # Sh-mng-time .005*** .002*** .008*** .004*** .004***
(.001) (.000) (.002) (.001) (.001)
(Medium) # Sh-mng-time .003 .001** .005** .003* .002**
(.002) (.001) (.002) (.002) (.001)
(Large) # Sh-mng-time .003* .002*** .007*** .005*** .002**
(.002) (.001) (.002) (.002) (.001)
Bribe y-n .051 .027*** .043 .015 .025
(.041) (.010) (.046) (.045) (.021)
(Small) # Bribe y_n .004 .035*** .023 .031 .012
(.045) (.014) (.047) (.048) (.024)
(Medium) # Bribe y-n .073 .058*** .032 .104* .041
(.054) (.016) (.053) (.058) (.030)
(Large) # Bribe y-n .056 .026 .025 .099* .029
(.051) (.017) (.055) (.058) (.033)
Days-no power .008 .009*** .016 .002 .006
(.008) (.003) (.010) (.009) (.004)
(Small) # Days-no power .006 .008* .011 .007 .008**
(.005) (.004) (.007) (.006) (.004)
(Medium) # Days-no power .014* .010** .021** .024*** .015***
(.008) (.005) (.009) (.008) (.005)
(Large) # Days-no power .015* .010** .020** .019** .014**
(.008) (.005) (.009) (.009) (.006)
(Small) .110*** .108*** .071** .136*** .103***
(.028) (.013) (.028) (.031) (.017)
(Medium) .149*** .162*** .151*** .143*** .162***
(.032) (.017) (.032) (.035) (.021)
(Large) .210*** .239*** .217*** .181*** .224***
(.031) (.019) (.034) (.037) (.023)
Firm controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Survey # Sector xed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 56,880 28,619 28,616 56,880 55,612
R
2
.15 .18 .18 .17 .15
Note. Firm controls: dummies for rm age (t 3), foreign or government owned, exporter status, if
in small city, I base years, average employment growth in cell, and a constant term. Size is t 3. See
denitions in Sec. III. Columns 1 and 3 cells based on survey-sector-location-avg-size (excluding own);
col. 4 uses current size. Standard errors are clustered on survey-location-sector-size.
* Signicant at 10%.
** Signicant at 5%.
*** Signicant at 1%.
This content downloaded from 210.56.13.7 on Mon, 31 Mar 2014 09:24:45 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Aterido, Hallward-Driemeier, and Page s 629
even in absolute termsthe growth of micro rms. As addressing endogeneity
is one of our chief concerns, columns 25 demonstrate the signicance of
alternative means of addressing itor of failing to do so.
For all specications, coefcients on rm characteristics (other than size),
the set of sector-survey interaction dummies, and the constant are not reported
due to space constraints. As expected, the coefcients on rm sizes categories
indicate that employment growth declines monotonically with rm size.
17
We
focus next on the coefcients on the investment climate and their interactions
with rm size.
A. Access to Finance
The impact of better access or lower cost of nances on rms growth has
been studied by a number of authors.
18
Beck et al. (2005) argue that nancial
access should favor small rms. In their work, they nd that rms self-reported
(subjective) constraints on access and cost to nance are associated with lower
growth of small rms relative to large rms. Table 3 showed that there are
differences in the amounts of nance available, which could already explain
why smaller rms are more likely to complain about nance. Here we test
whether, even for the same amount of nancing (measured as percentage of
investment nanced externally), the impact would be different across different
types of rms. Note that nance is dened such that a larger number implies
better access to nance. The results show strong nonlinearities across rm size,
and unlike earlier results, we nd a positive effect of increased access to nance
on the employment growth of medium and large rms and no signicant
effect among micro and small enterprises.
19
We investigate the sensitivity of
these results to different ways of estimating the IC measures and nd the
results to be quite sensitive to whether and how we account for endogeneity.
It is useful to compare our results in column 1 with those obtained using
rms individual own responses (table 4, col. 2). While the number of ob-
servations declinessince not all rms report information for such variables
17
There is a debate in the literature whether it is appropriate to use initial size or average size
in rm growth regressions (see Teal 1999; Bigsten and Soderbom 2006). Proponents of Gibrats
Law favor the latter, although even using average size can still lead to the result that smaller rms
grow faster than larger rms. We repeated our regressions dening the size controls and the
investment climate interactions based on average size and found very robust results. (Note that,
to keep from reintroducing endogeneity, what one must avoid is using a measure of size from a
time period prior to the one used in matching the investment climate averages to rms.)
18
See, e.g., Demirgu c-Kunt and Maksimov (1998), Rajan and Zingales (1998), and Beck et al.
(2005).
19
The test that the overall effect of access to nance on medium and large rms is equal to zero
is rejected at the 10% signicance level for large rms and at the 12% level for medium rms.
This content downloaded from 210.56.13.7 on Mon, 31 Mar 2014 09:24:45 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
630 economi c development and cultural change
we nd that using reported individual measures, access to nance has a positive
effect across all rms that does not differ substantially across rm size, sug-
gesting that not controlling for endogeneity may overestimate the effect of
nance on micro and small rms. Note that differences in coefcients across
columns 1 and 2 are not due to the smaller number of observations in column
2. Column 3 reports the results of reproducing the estimates presented in
column 1 for the same sample as in column 2, and the results do not vary
much: if anything, the nding that nance helps medium and larger rms if
endogeneity is properly controlled for becomes even stronger.
In table 4, column 4, we report the results when using IC measures that
are constructed as reported in Section III, but with the only difference that
the averages within country-city-sector-size cells are matched to current rather
than initial size. As mentioned, this is likely to reintroduce some level of
endogeneity, as growing rms are matched with higher levels of access to
nance. In this case we nd that all rms benet from access to nance, and
while the coefcients point to smaller benets for larger rms, differences
across rm size are not statistically signicant.
The fact that results are fairly similar when using individual rm responses
or cell averages matched to current size, and at the same time quite different
from the results when measuring IC based on cell averages matched to initial
size, suggests that (i) endogeneity is likely to bias the estimates when not
accounting for it and that (ii) using averages matched on current size does
not solve the endogeneity problem. Quite the opposite, it reintroduces en-
dogeneity in the IC measures due to the match.
Our ndings also suggest that the results found by previous studies that
access to nance benets mostly the smaller rms may be driven by endo-
geneity. In our sample, there are as many as 16% of the rms that start up
as micro and transit to larger rms. Depending on the procedure, such rms
either report higher access to capital for endogenous reasons (i.e., because they
have grown) or are matched with higher access to capital than the average of
initially small rms (i.e., are given the average access to capital of larger rms).
This creates a positive bias in the coefcient for micro and small rms. Con-
versely about 7% of large rms shrink and become smaller rms in our sample.
As they become smaller, they are likely to report lower access to nance or,
depending on the method, be matched to the access to capital of smaller rms.
This creates a downward bias in the coefcient of larger rms.
Table 4, column 5, presents the results of further assessing the robustness
of our main results when constructing the IC averages with country-sector-
location averages. Results conrm the ndings presented in our basic speci-
This content downloaded from 210.56.13.7 on Mon, 31 Mar 2014 09:24:45 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Aterido, Hallward-Driemeier, and Page s 631
cation (col. 1): increased access to external nance to fund investments seems
to benet mostly medium-sized and larger rms.
Why would micro or small rms not be positively affected by increased
access to nance? Jeong and Townsend (2007) show that with a wide range
of talent among micro-entrepreneurs, access to nance may not be the binding
constraint they face in growing their rms. If access to nance is restricted,
individuals with high entrepreneurial talent but low wealth are size con-
strained, and the demand for wage employment is low, which drives many
individuals to become entrepreneurs even when they do not have much en-
trepreneurial talent. Increased access to nance sorts the good from the less
talented entrepreneurs. Those who are good can grow their rms; those who
have lower entrepreneurial talent suffer as wages increase due to an increased
demand for labor. Our estimates, particularly the negative, albeit not statis-
tically signicant coefcient on micro rms, may then reect this selection
effect.
B. Regulatory Environment
Measures of the regulatory environment show that business regulations mea-
sured as the share of time that management devotes to dealing with govern-
ment regulations have differential effects across rm size. Our results suggest
that regulations create growth bottlenecks for small rms, which may fear/
avoid expansion to limit their exposure to red tape and increased enforcement.
Testing the overall signicance by size conrms that the overall effect of
regulations on employment growth for small rms (the sum of the coefcient
on micro and small rms) is signicantly different from zero, while those for
medium and large rms are not. Thus, business regulations do not appear to
affect the growth of larger rms. On the other hand, the positive effect for
micro rms suggests that micro rms benet from a generally lower enforce-
ment stand for micro rms, which may help divert some economic activity
to micro rms. Results are quite similar across all specications regardless of
how the IC variables are computed, suggesting that endogeneity may be a
less important concern in this case.
C. Corruption
Moving on to results for corruption, we nd that, as in the case of access to
nance, results vary substantially whether and how we account for endogeneity.
Results based on individual responses (table 4, col. 2) or cell averages matched
to current size (col. 4) would suggest that corruption helps micro rms, while
having a much smaller, and in some cases negative, effect on the growth of
larger rms. Measuring the incidence of corruption based on country-industry-
This content downloaded from 210.56.13.7 on Mon, 31 Mar 2014 09:24:45 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
632 economi c development and cultural change
location size averages matched to initial size or on country-industry locations,
in our opinion, two better ways of accounting for endogeneity, yields results
that go in the same direction but are not statistically signicant. This suggests
that while corruption may have differential effects across rm size, and possibly
adverse effects on medium-sized rms, the presence of endogeneity creates
biases that increase the probability of nding this result.
D. Infrastructure
With regard to infrastructure bottlenecks, measured as the incidence of power
outages, results are again quite sensitive to whether we control or not for
endogeneity. Using our baseline specication (col. 1), we nd evidence that
infrastructure bottlenecks tend to stunt the growth of medium and large rms.
Instead, the coefcient for micro rms is positive, indicating that again, micro
rms may benet from the troubles of larger, possibly more productive rms,
as some production may be diverted to micro rms. The coefcient on micro
rms, however, is not statistically signicant. But the difference between micro
and small/medium rms is larger, taking into account that small and medium
rms report more frequent outages than micro rms. This is consistent with
micro rms using less capital- and energy-intensive modes of production and
beneting that these processes can be sustained due to hardships hitting the
small and medium enterprises (SMEs).
Results appear stronger when individual rms responses are used to com-
pute IC, but the coefcients are of similar magnitudes as those reported in
table 4, column 1. This suggests that endogeneity does not appear as a large
concern and that results in column 3 are estimated with more precision as IC
varies at the rm level. Computing IC out of the average within country-
location-sector cells also yields similar but stronger results than in column 1.
All in all, the results suggest that poor infrastructure has a detrimental effect
on the growth of all rms but the micro ones.
VII. Robustness
We now examine whether our results are robust to changes in the denition
of variables, set of controls, and sample of countries.
A. Addressing Other Possible Sources of Endogeneity
Another source of potential endogeneity is whether better-performing rms
choose locations based on the quality of the business environment. To see if
this could be signicant, column 1 of table 5 reports the results if we restrict
the sample to domestic-owned, micro, and SMEs who are least likely to be
footloose and where the location tends to be associated with the places of birth
This content downloaded from 210.56.13.7 on Mon, 31 Mar 2014 09:24:45 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Aterido, Hallward-Driemeier, and Page s 633
or residence of the business owner. Foreign rms and large domestic rms are
the most likely to be selective in their choice of location. The results are very
robust.
B. Alternative Denitions of Investment Climate Indicators
The second set of robustness checks involves using alternative measures of the
different investment climate areas. The surveys generally provide various mea-
sures to choose from. Of particular interest are measures on access to nance.
There are two sets of results, that the nature of the nance being captured
matters and that the results are somewhat sensitive to whether variation across
sectors within a country is included or not.
To examine the different types of nance, two additional measures are
includedthe share of sales made on credit and access to working capital
from external institutions. The measures used so far capture a type of nance
that is relatively more difcult to access, namely, nancing for longer term
investment projects from formal nancial institutions. The other two alter-
natives presented in table 5 measure access to a more informal formof nancing
and to shorter term nancing from institutions. In the case of the share of
sales on credit, the results show that micro rms do not share in the benets
of access to this nancing, consistent with such credit being offered less by
micro rms. Small and medium-sized rms do benet. The impact on large
rms is not signicant, which again is not so surprising, as this type of nance
is relatively less important for them. For access to working capital (col. 3) the
benets are more widespread. If anything, this type of nancing is most
benecial for the micro rms, although the differences across sizes are not
signicant.
The second point is that these results are sensitive to whether one allows
for sectoral variation within countries to be included. Our results so far have
included the full set of interacted sector-survey dummies. However, here (table
5, cols. 24) the results are more signicant when sector and country dummies
enter separately. There are two interpretations that can be given to this nding.
First, the original rationale to include the broader set of dummies was in part
to control for demand shocks that could vary by country and sector. Failing
to control for sector-country shocks, endogeneity could be reentering the re-
gressions. Such shocks could affect rm performance and increase their demand
for nancing. This would imply caution in interpreting the results. However,
there is a second interpretation. Work by Rajan and Zingales (1998) points
to potentially important differences across sectors in the impact of improved
access to nance for growth. Beck et al. (2008) show that sectors with a larger
proportion of small rms stand to benet disproportionately from nancial
This content downloaded from 210.56.13.7 on Mon, 31 Mar 2014 09:24:45 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
634
TABLE 5
ROBUSTNESS
Dependent Variable: Employment Growth (Emp(t) Emp(t 3))/((Emp(t) Emp(t 3))/2)
Control for Possi-
ble Location Se-
lection Bias Alternative Measures of IC
Investment Climate Variable
(ICvar)
Sample Restricted
SMEs Domestic
(1)
Finance p Sh-
sales-credit
(2)
Finance p sh-
wkcap
(3)
Four Alterna-
tive IC
Variables
a
(4)
Finance .046 .039 .194** .272***
(.061) (.033) (.083) (.089)
(Small) # Finance .093 .092*** .108 .245***
(.065) (.033) (.072) (.075)
(Medium) # Finance .168** .066* .126 .237***
(.079) (.035) (.085) (.091)
(Large) # Finance .034 .111 .178*
(.037) (.084) (.093)
Regulations .003** .004*** .004*** .012
(.001) (.001) (.002) (.012)
(Small) # Regulations .005*** .006*** .005*** .029***
(.001) (.001) (.001) (.009)
(Medium) # Regulations .001 .004*** .003* .023*
(.002) (.001) (.002) (.013)
(Large) # Regulations .005*** .003* .017
(.001) (.002) (.014)
Corruption .047 .007 .033 .004
(.042) (.024) (.034) (.006)
(Small) # Corruption .013 .043* .007 .002
(.046) (.025) (.033) (.005)
(Medium) # Corruption .055 .001 .070 .003
(.057) (.029) (.044) (.007)
(Large) # Corruption .021 .043 .009
(.033) (.043) (.008)
Infrastructure .006 .008 .008 .000
(.009) (.005) (.008) (.004)
(Small) # Infrastructure .003 .000 .000 .000
(.005) (.004) (.005) (.004)
(Medium) # Infrastructure .012 .008 .006 .002
(.008) (.005) (.007) (.004)
(Large) # Infrastructure .007 .009 .003
(.006) (.007) (.005)
Firm controls Yes Yes Yes Yes
Survey # Sector xed effects Yes No No No
Survey and Sector xed effects No Yes Yes Yes
Observations 46,122 54,442 54,013 48,411
R
2
.15 .115 .122 .122
Note. Firm controls: dummies for rm size and age (t 3), foreign or government owned, exporter
status, if in small city, empg base years, average employment growth in cell, and a constant term. All
ICvar use cell average, matched to initial size; cells based on survey-sector-location-avg-size (excluding
own). Col. 1, nance pSh-invest-n; regulations pSh-mng-time; corruption pBribe y-n; infrastructure
p Days-no power. Results in cols. 2 and 3 use the same variables as col. 1 with exception of Finance
variable. Standard errors are clustered on survey-location-sector-size.
a
Column 4 IC alternative: nance psh-wkcap; regulations pdays-inspections; corruption pbribe (%);
infrastructure p loss-transit.
* Signicant at 10%.
** Signicant at 5%.
*** Signicant at 1%.
This content downloaded from 210.56.13.7 on Mon, 31 Mar 2014 09:24:45 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Aterido, Hallward-Driemeier, and Page s 635
development. Including interactions sector-survey dummies then shuts down
this channel, explaining why these two variables, share of sales sold on credit
and the share of working capital nanced externally, lose their signicance
when all the interactions are included in the regression.
Column 4 of table 5 also includes alternative measures for the other three
investment climate measures. They are days of inspections, the size of bribes
paid, and losses incurred during transportation delays. The measure of in-
spections has the same effect as that of management time spent dealing with
ofcials, deterring small and medium-sized rms from growing. However, the
new measures of corruption do not offer new insights, and the use of the
transportation-related variable provides weaker results. One conclusion is that
power, not transportation (at least when measured as percentage of sales lost
in transportation), is the more important dimension of infrastructure affecting
rm growth.
C. Variations in Denition of Size Categories
Table 6 investigates whether results are robust to variations in size classi-
cations. For comparison purposes, column 1 reproduces the results of table 4,
column 1. Column 2 of table 6 reports the results of dening micro rms as
rms with 510 employees and excluding from the estimation rms with
fewer than 5 employees. The other size categories remain unchanged. The
results on access to nance weaken for medium-sized rms, suggesting that
the differential effects of nance between micro and medium-sized rms are
in part explained by the more negative effect of nance on the smallest rms.
This lends additional support to the selection story proposed by Jeong and
Townsend (2007), as the very small rms are the ones that are likely to be
less productive and, therefore, are more likely to be hurt by increasing costs
of inputs driven by a higher supply of credit.
In column 3 of table 6 we follow the size category cutoffs used by Beck
et al. (2005), which implies combining most of our micro with all our small
into one category and combining our medium with many of our large into
the medium category and leaving only the very largest in the large category.
With these cutoffs, and controlling for endogeneity, we do not replicate their
nding that the smallest rms benet the most (although their result is
reproduced if we match conditions based on current rather than initial size).
The results also show that it is not the very largest rms that benet from
nance relative to the small but, rather, those in the mid-sized (50500
employees) range.
The results on regulations show that the positive relationship is driven by
the smallest rms; excluding those with fewer than ve employees leaves the
This content downloaded from 210.56.13.7 on Mon, 31 Mar 2014 09:24:45 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
636
TABLE 6
OTHER SIZE DEFINITIONS
Dependent Variable: Employment Growth (Emp(t) Emp(t 3))/((Emp(t) Emp(t 3))/2)
Baseline (Table 4,
Col. 1),
Micro (!10),
Small (1050),
Medium (51200),
Large (200)
Exclude ! 5,
Micro (510),
Rest of Sizes
as in Col. 1
(1)
Small (550),
Medium (51
500),
Large (500)
(2)
Excluding
Micro (!10)
(3)
Sh-invest-n .055 .078 .047 .032
(.059) (.069) (.048) (.046)
(Small, t 3) # Sh-invest-n .092 .084
(.065) (.070)
(Medium) # Sh-invest-n .130* .132 .114** .057
(.075) (.085) (.053) (.052)
(Large) # Sh-invest-n .136* .149* .062 .070
(.071) (.081) (.073) (.059)
Sh-mng-time .003** .002 .001 .002
(.001) (.002) (.001) (.001)
(Small) # Sh-mng-time .005*** .004***
(.001) (.002)
(Medium, t 3) # Sh-mng-time .003 .001 .002 .003**
(.002) (.002) (.001) (.001)
(Large) # Sh-mng-time .003* .002 .000 .002
(.002) (.002) (.002) (.002)
Bribe y-n .051 .014 .007** .008**
(.041) (.044) (.004) (.004)
(Small) # Bribe y-n .004 .037
(.045) (.043)
(Medium) # Bribe y-n .073 .026 .004 .005
(.054) (.055) (.005) (.005)
(Large) # Bribe y-n .056 .005 .019* .012
(.051) (.053) (.011) (.008)
Days-no power .008 .002 .004 .001
(.008) (.009) (.009) (.008)
(Small) # Days-no power .006 .002
(.005) (.006)
(Medium) # Days-no power .014* .010 .007 .007
(.008) (.008) (.006) (.006)
(Large) # Days-no power .015* .010 .009 .002
(.008) (.009) (.010) (.008)
Firm controls Yes Yes Yes Yes
Survey # Sector xed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 56,880 47,491 47,222 34,474
R
2
.15 .13 .12 .12
Note. Firm controls: dummies for rm size and age (t 3), foreign or government owned, exporter
status, if in small city, empg base years, avg. employment growth in cell, and a constant term. All ICvar
use cell avg, matched to initial size; cells based on survey-sector-location-avg-size (excluding own).
Standard errors are clustered on survey-location-sector-size.
* Signicant at 10%.
** Signicant at 5%.
*** Signicant at 1%.
This content downloaded from 210.56.13.7 on Mon, 31 Mar 2014 09:24:45 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Aterido, Hallward-Driemeier, and Page s 637
effect insignicant for the remaining micro rms. Still, the effect remains
negative for the small rms. In column 3, when all the micro are excluded,
the omitted category is now small and the effect is negative but not signicant.
Medium and large rms still have a more positive response to regulations
than the small. However, combining the rms into the larger size categories
misses the entire story, with no results appearing signicant.
For corruption, however, the story does become stronger once the micro
rms are dropped (table 6, col. 3) or absorbed with small rms (col. 2). Now
there is a positive and signicant effect for the smaller rms that is offset for
the larger rms, signicantly so for the very large rms. Combined with the
regulation results, small rms above the 10-employee thresholdthat is, those
that are large enough to nd evasion from regulations more difcultnd
measures of regulation more detrimental to their growth, but that corruption
offers a way of mitigating these effects. For medium rms, regulations are not
as detrimental as for small rms (in fact, they have a small net positive effect)
and corruption is correspondingly less benecial for medium-sized rms.
D. Age versus Size
It is well known that size is strongly correlated with age, as rms tend to
start operations small and grow over time. We assess whether differences in
the impact of business environment variables could be related to age rather
than size by adding a full set of interactions of age dummies with IC variables
to our baseline results (table 4, col. 1). Results for size # IC interactions
remain very similar; however, some interesting results emerge from the size
interactions (see table 7). We nd that regulations tend to affect the growth
of older, more established rms, relative to younger ones. Combined with the
size interactions, these results provide some interesting qualications to our
baseline results. They suggest that the adverse effect of regulations on the
growth of small rms is more visible among rms that are small but have
been in business for a while, rather than for rms that are small and young.
Similarly, these results allow us to qualify the statement that micro rms
benet from a poor regulatory environment. In fact, the rms that have been
around for a while are the ones that benet from regulations, while micro-
young ones do not. It may well be that a poor regulatory environment increases
the survival of low productivity rms (i.e., rms that do not have the entre-
preneurial ability to grow) because it penalizes more severely higher produc-
tivity rms.
Another interesting result of the size interactions is that corruption seems
to disproportionately benet older, more established rms. Perhaps age is
correlated with the access to networks and inuence channels. It may also be
This content downloaded from 210.56.13.7 on Mon, 31 Mar 2014 09:24:45 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
638
TABLE 7
IS IT SIZE OR AGE THAT MATTERS?
Dependent Variable: Employment Growth (Emp(t) Emp(t 3))/((Emp(t) Emp(t 3))/2)
Investment Climate Variable (ICvar) Continuation
Sh-invest-n .053
(.064)
(Small, t 3) # Sh-invest-n .093
(.065)
(Medium) # Sh-invest-n .127* (Mature, t 3) # Sh-invest-n .004
(.076) (.037)
(Large) # Sh-invest-n .132* (Older) # Sh-invest-n .003
(.072) (.041)
Sh-mng-time .005***
(.001)
(Small) # Sh-mng-time .005***
(.001)
(Medium. t 3) # Sh-mng-time .002 (Mature) # Sh-mng-time .002***
(.002) (.001)
(Large) # Sh-mng-time .002 (Older) # Sh-mng-time .004***
(.002) (.001)
Bribe y-n .029
(.042)
(Small) # Bribe y-n .011
(.046)
(Medium) # Bribe y-n .087 (Mature) # Bribe y-n .037
(.056) (.024)
(Large) # Bribe y-n .071 (Older) # Bribe y-n .058**
(.053) (.029)
Days-no power .006
(.009)
(Small) # Days-no power .006 (Mature) # Days-no power .003
(.005) (.003)
(Medium) # Days-no power .015* (Older) # Days-no power .003
(.008) (.004)
(Large) # Days-no power .015* Mature .086***
(.008) (.013)
(Small) .110*** Older .137***
(.029) (.016)
(Medium) .148*** Firm controls Yes
(.032) Survey # Sector xed effects Yes
(Large) .209*** Observations 56,880
(.032) R
2
.15
Note. Firm controls: dummies for whether rm is foreign or government owned, exporter status, if
in small city, empg base years, average employment growth in cell, and a constant term. Size and
age are t 3. All ICvar are cell averages, matched to initial size; cells based on survey-sector-loc.-
avg-size (excluding own). This is a single regression, reported in two columns due to the many
variables included. Standard errors are clustered on survey-location-sector-size.
* Signicant at 10%.
** Signicant at 5%.
*** Signicant at 1%.
This content downloaded from 210.56.13.7 on Mon, 31 Mar 2014 09:24:45 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Aterido, Hallward-Driemeier, and Page s 639
true that a corrupt environment makes the survival of certain types of rms
more likely, which then are observed as older at the time of the survey.
Addressing this form of sample selection is beyond the scope of this study.
E. Different Samples
The results so far have pooled countries together (with sector-survey xed
effects), but it could be that the effects vary by country groupings, along
dimensions that can reinforce or weaken the broader business environment.
To test whether the institutional development of countries matters, we divide
the sample according to the depth of credit markets (table 8, cols. 12), the
degree by which countries control corruption (cols. 34), and the strength of
their rule of law (cols. 56).
20
Quite interestingly, results for increased access
to nance turn out to be much stronger in countries with a more developed
nancial system, suggesting again that a marginal development in a countrys
nancial system tends to favor small, medium, and, to a lower extent, large
size rms, rather than micro rms. This also suggests that nance operates
better in economies with more developed nancial markets. This result is
further conrmed by the results in columns 34, which show that the effect
of increased access to nance is stronger in economies with higher control of
corruption and better rule of law, both hallmarks of better functioning econ-
omies.
Business regulations, measured as the percentage of management time spent
dealing with regulations, have a negative effect on the growth of small rms
throughout most samples of countries, suggesting that the conclusion that
stringent regulations may lead many small rms to grow less in order to hide
from the authorities is quite robust to the inclusion or exclusion of countries.
What is striking is that results are stronger in countries with either lower
control of corruption or a weaker rule of law. It may be that the quality of
the regulations in lower institutional environments is more burdensome, re-
sulting in the greater constraints on small rms. It is also possible that more
onerous regulations in a weak institutional setting open the way to corruption
or harassment on the part of ofcials, encouraging rms to remain small and
below the radar screen where possible.
The direct effects of corruption on the growth of rms tend to be more
signicant in countries with higher control of corruption. Corruption, in a
setting where corruption is not controlled, does not have much of an effect.
20
We also investigated whether there were signicant patterns by income or GDP per capital. As
the differences were less pronounced than those that capture the institutional environment, we do
not report them. We do note, however, that this implies that it is indeed the broader institutional
environment that matters rather than income itself.
This content downloaded from 210.56.13.7 on Mon, 31 Mar 2014 09:24:45 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
640
T
A
B
L
E
8
I
N
S
T
I
T
U
T
I
O
N
A
L
E
F
F
E
C
T
S
(
I
C
O
N
E
M
P
L
O
Y
M
E
N
T
G
R
O
W
T
H
)
D
e
p
e
n
d
e
n
t
V
a
r
i
a
b
l
e
:
E
m
p
l
o
y
m
e
n
t
G
r
o
w
t
h
(
E
m
p
(
t
)
E
m
p
(
t
3
)
)
/
(
(
E
m
p
(
t
)
E
m
p
(
t
3
)
)
/
2
)
D
o
m
e
s
t
i
c
C
r
e
d
i
t
t
o
P
r
i
v
a
t
e
S
e
c
t
o
r
C
o
n
t
r
o
l
C
o
r
r
u
p
t
i
o
n
R
u
l
e
o
f
L
a
w
M
e
d
i
a
n
(
1
)
1
M
e
d
i
a
n
(
2
)
0
(
3
)
1
0
(
4
)
0
(
5
)
1
0
(
6
)
S
h
-
i
n
v
e
s
t
-
n
.
0
7
0
.
1
1
2
.
0
2
0
.
1
1
0
.
0
3
5
.
1
5
8
*
(
.
0
9
4
)
(
.
0
7
6
)
(
.
0
7
9
)
(
.
0
8
1
)
(
.
0
8
0
)
(
.
0
8
5
)
(
S
m
a
l
l
)
#
S
h
-
i
n
v
e
s
t
-
.
0
9
7
.
2
0
2
*
*
.
0
1
5
.
1
8
5
*
.
0
1
7
.
2
2
2
*
*
(
.
0
9
3
)
(
.
0
8
4
)
(
.
0
8
1
)
(
.
0
9
9
)
(
.
0
7
9
)
(
.
0
9
6
)
(
M
e
d
i
u
m
)
#
S
h
-
i
n
v
e
s
t
-
.
0
1
9
.
2
0
3
*
.
0
5
1
.
2
0
4
*
.
0
1
6
.
3
1
1
*
*
(
.
1
1
3
)
(
.
1
1
6
)
(
.
0
9
6
)
(
.
1
1
3
)
(
.
0
9
6
)
(
.
1
2
7
)
(
L
a
r
g
e
)
#
S
h
-
i
n
v
e
s
t
-
.
0
2
6
.
1
4
5
.
0
2
6
.
0
9
6
.
0
0
5
.
1
9
7
*
(
.
1
1
5
)
(
.
0
9
7
)
(
.
0
9
3
)
(
.
1
2
0
)
(
.
0
9
7
)
(
.
1
1
2
)
S
h
-
m
n
g
-
t
i
m
e
.
0
0
1
.
0
0
6
*
*
.
0
0
2
.
0
0
2
.
0
0
2
.
0
0
2
(
.
0
0
2
)
(
.
0
0
3
)
(
.
0
0
2
)
(
.
0
0
3
)
(
.
0
0
2
)
(
.
0
0
3
)
(
S
m
a
l
l
)
#
S
h
-
m
n
g
-
t
i
m
e
.
0
0
2
.
0
0
9
*
*
*
.
0
0
3
*
*
.
0
0
5
.
0
0
4
*
*
.
0
0
4
(
.
0
0
2
)
(
.
0
0
3
)
(
.
0
0
2
)
(
.
0
0
3
)
(
.
0
0
2
)
(
.
0
0
2
)
(
M
e
d
i
u
m
)
#
S
h
-
m
n
g
-
t
i
m
e
.
0
0
0
.
0
0
5
.
0
0
0
.
0
0
2
.
0
0
0
.
0
0
1
(
.
0
0
2
)
(
.
0
0
4
)
(
.
0
0
2
)
(
.
0
0
3
)
(
.
0
0
2
)
(
.
0
0
3
)
(
L
a
r
g
e
)
#
S
h
-
m
n
g
-
t
i
m
e
.
0
0
1
.
0
1
0
*
*
*
.
0
0
1
.
0
0
6
*
.
0
0
1
.
0
0
4
(
.
0
0
2
)
(
.
0
0
3
)
(
.
0
0
2
)
(
.
0
0
3
)
(
.
0
0
2
)
(
.
0
0
3
)
B
r
i
b
e
y
-
n
.
0
4
9
.
0
4
3
.
0
1
6
.
1
3
6
*
*
.
0
0
8
.
0
0
4
(
.
0
4
8
)
(
.
0
6
4
)
(
.
0
5
1
)
(
.
0
6
5
)
(
.
0
0
6
)
(
.
0
1
3
)
This content downloaded from 210.56.13.7 on Mon, 31 Mar 2014 09:24:45 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
641
(
S
m
a
l
l
)
#
B
r
i
b
e
y
-
n
.
0
2
1
.
0
2
9
.
0
4
3
.
1
1
8
*
.
0
0
3
.
0
0
6
(
.
0
4
5
)
(
.
0
7
0
)
(
.
0
5
5
)
(
.
0
6
3
)
(
.
0
0
6
)
(
.
0
1
4
)
(
M
e
d
i
u
m
)
#
B
r
i
b
e
y
-
n
.
0
5
9
.
0
7
2
.
0
2
6
.
2
5
2
*
*
*
.
0
0
7
.
0
0
5
(
.
0
6
3
)
(
.
0
8
7
)
(
.
0
6
9
)
(
.
0
8
6
)
(
.
0
0
8
)
(
.
0
1
5
)
(
L
a
r
g
e
)
#
B
r
i
b
e
y
-
n
.
0
3
0
.
0
4
5
.
0
1
9
.
1
7
8
*
*
.
0
1
0
.
0
0
8
(
.
0
6
3
)
(
.
0
7
6
)
(
.
0
6
4
)
(
.
0
7
8
)
(
.
0
1
0
)
(
.
0
1
7
)
D
a
y
s
-
n
o
p
o
w
e
r
.
0
0
3
.
0
1
2
.
0
0
0
.
0
2
4
.
0
0
0
.
0
1
8
(
.
0
1
0
)
(
.
0
1
5
)
(
.
0
1
0
)
(
.
0
2
0
)
(
.
0
1
0
)
(
.
0
1
7
)
(
S
m
a
l
l
)
#
D
a
y
s
-
n
o
p
o
w
e
r
.
0
0
7
.
0
0
4
.
0
0
0
.
0
1
1
.
0
0
1
.
0
1
1
(
.
0
0
6
)
(
.
0
1
2
)
(
.
0
0
7
)
(
.
0
1
8
)
(
.
0
0
7
)
(
.
0
1
2
)
(
M
e
d
i
u
m
)
#
D
a
y
s
-
n
o
p
o
w
e
r
.
0
1
5
*
.
0
0
2
.
0
0
5
.
0
4
3
*
.
0
0
5
.
0
3
0
*
(
.
0
0
9
)
(
.
0
1
5
)
(
.
0
0
9
)
(
.
0
2
2
)
(
.
0
0
9
)
(
.
0
1
7
)
(
L
a
r
g
e
)
#
D
a
y
s
-
n
o
p
o
w
e
r
.
0
0
7
.
0
0
5
.
0
0
1
.
0
2
5
.
0
0
9
.
0
2
4
(
.
0
1
0
)
(
.
0
1
4
)
(
.
0
1
0
)
(
.
0
2
4
)
(
.
0
1
1
)
(
.
0
1
7
)
F
i
r
m
c
o
n
t
r
o
l
s
Y
e
s
Y
e
s
Y
e
s
Y
e
s
Y
e
s
Y
e
s
S
u
r
v
e
y
#
S
e
c
t
o
r
x
e
d
e
f
f
e
c
t
s
Y
e
s
Y
e
s
Y
e
s
Y
e
s
Y
e
s
Y
e
s
O
b
s
e
r
v
a
t
i
o
n
s
3
1
,
8
5
4
2
3
,
1
5
7
4
1
,
5
7
5
1
5
,
2
0
5
3
3
,
1
0
4
2
3
,
6
6
7
R
2
.
1
6
.
1
1
.
1
6
.
1
2
.
1
7
.
1
2
N
o
t
e
.
F
i
r
m
c
o
n
t
r
o
l
s
:
d
u
m
m
i
e
s
f
o
r
r
m
s
i
z
e
a
n
d
a
g
e
(
t
3
)
,
f
o
r
e
i
g
n
o
r
g
o
v
e
r
n
m
e
n
t
o
w
n
e
d
,
e
x
p
o
r
t
e
r
s
t
a
t
u
s
,
i
f
s
m
a
l
l
c
i
t
y
,
e
m
p
g
b
a
s
e
y
e
a
r
s
,
a
v
g
.
e
m
p
l
o
y
m
e
n
t
g
r
o
w
t
h
i
n
c
e
l
l
,
a
n
d
a
c
o
n
s
t
a
n
t
t
e
r
m
.
A
l
l
I
C
v
a
r
a
r
e
c
e
l
l
a
v
g
,
m
a
t
c
h
e
d
t
o
i
n
i
t
i
a
l
s
i
z
e
;
c
e
l
l
s
b
a
s
e
d
o
n
s
u
r
v
e
y
-
s
e
c
t
o
r
-
l
o
c
.
-
a
v
g
-
s
i
z
e
(
e
x
c
l
u
d
i
n
g
o
w
n
)
.
S
t
a
n
d
a
r
d
e
r
r
o
r
s
a
r
e
c
l
u
s
t
e
r
e
d
o
n
s
u
r
v
e
y
-
l
o
c
a
t
i
o
n
-
s
e
c
t
o
r
-
s
i
z
e
.
*
S
i
g
n
i
c
a
n
t
a
t
1
0
%
.
*
*
S
i
g
n
i
c
a
n
t
a
t
5
%
.
*
*
*
S
i
g
n
i
c
a
n
t
a
t
1
%
.
This content downloaded from 210.56.13.7 on Mon, 31 Mar 2014 09:24:45 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
642 economi c development and cultural change
However, if, in a stronger institutional environment, there is still corruption,
it provides incentives to keep operations small. The effects of corruption on
larger rms are signicantly negative in countries with better control of cor-
ruption. It thus appears that the distortions generated by corruption are more
important and distort rm growth more in countries where markets and
institutions are more developed and a higher share of resources is allocated
via markets. Finally, infrastructure bottlenecks appear as a constraint to the
growth of small, medium, and/or large rms in most samples of countries
although the levels of signicance vary across samples, with the stronger effects
for medium-sized rms.
All in all, the results above suggest that improving on some domains of
the investment climate constraints may be more important to the extent that
other aspects of the business climate and institutional development improve.
Thus, nancial market development brings higher development to medium
and large rms in regions where there is higher control of corruption and a
better rule of law. Similarly, improving business regulations may be more
important where institutional development otherwise lags. Cracking down on
corruption is still an issue even in more developed institutional countries,
with particularly deleterious effects on medium and large rms.
VIII. Conclusions
This study has provided new evidence of the role of the investment climate
in employment growth. The results indicate signicant differences across size
categories of rmsboth in terms of differences in objective conditions faced
by rms and in terms of nonlinearities in the impact of these conditions. The
study also devotes substantial effort to surmount endogeneity concerns between
investment climate measures and business performance and nds that ac-
counting for endogeneity reduces the differential effects of business climate
on the performance of different types of rms. Yet the results indicate that a
poor business climate tends to hurt the growth of small, medium, and large
rms and to benet in relativebut sometimes also in absolutecases, micro
rms.
It also nds that increased access to nance, particularly external nance to
fund investment, has a larger positive effect in the growth of small, medium,
and large rms, particularly in economies with more developed nancial sys-
tems or a better rule of law. Thus, unlike previous research, this study does
not nd that the impact on employment growth of an extra unit of external
nance is highest for micro rms. We interpret these results as evidence that
micro rms are not necessarily more credit constrained. Instead, many micro
entrepreneurs may have little willingness or capabilities to grow their rms.
This content downloaded from 210.56.13.7 on Mon, 31 Mar 2014 09:24:45 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Aterido, Hallward-Driemeier, and Page s 643
As access to nance increases, micro rms may endure input price increases
and production displacement caused by the growth of large, more productive
rms that attain higher benets of increased access to nance. The results also
reinforce the importance of differentiating the impact across size classes of
rms and allowing micro rms (fewer than 10 employees) to be different from
small rms.
Another important nding of this study is that business regulations mea-
sured as a higher share of management time spent dealing with regulations
or inspections may stunt the growth of small rms. Thus, as management
time dealing with authorities as well as inspections increases substantially with
rm size, the marginal increase in enforcement can act as a strong disincentive
to grow a rm.
What are the aggregate implications of these ndings for the size, efciency,
and dynamism of the business sector in developing countries? The results
found in this study suggest that a weak business environment displaces activity
from large, medium, and small rms to the benet of micro ones. To the
extent that larger rms are more productiveas suggested by many theoretical
models of rm dynamicsthis would imply substantial resource reallocation
from more productive to less productive ones, potentially leading to important
losses in aggregate productivity. In addition, given that enforcement of taxes
and regulations tends to be smaller in micro rms, a shift of economic activity
toward these rms is likely to imply that a larger share of rms remain informal
or semi-informal, reducing the capacity of the state to collect taxes and pay
for fundamental inputs for development such as education. Finally, if there
are substantial xed costs in activities like innovation or worker training, a
higher share of activity in micro rms may imply more rms and workers
locked in activities with limited innovation and growth opportunities.
This content downloaded from 210.56.13.7 on Mon, 31 Mar 2014 09:24:45 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
644
Appendix
TABLE A1
DATA SET
Country No. Obs. % Country No. Obs. % Country No. Obs. %
Albania2002 166 .29 Ghana2007 249 .44 Panama2006 550 .97
Albania2005 202 .35 Greece2005 539 .95 Paraguay2006 561 .99
Angola2006 274 .48 Guatemala2003 451 .79 Peru2006 603 1.06
Argentina2006 950 1.67 Guatemala2006 494 .87 Philippines2003 614 1.08
Armenia2002 170 .3 Guinea2006 181 .32 Poland2002 495 .87
Armenia2005 351 .62 GuineaBissau2006 129 .23 Poland2003 105 .18
Azerbaijan2002 162 .28 Guyana2004 152 .27 Poland2005 969 1.7
Azerbaijan2005 348 .61 Honduras2003 436 .77 Portugal2005 501 .88
Bangladesh2002 964 1.69 Honduras2006 419 .74 Romania2002 254 .45
Belarus2002 250 .44 Hungary2002 245 .43 Romania2005 586 1.03
Belarus2005 322 .57 Hungary2005 602 1.06 Russia2002 488 .86
Belarus2008 232 .41 India2006 2,919 5.13 Russia2005 592 1.04
Benin2004 182 .32 Indonesia2003 707 1.24 Rwanda2006 154 .27
BiH2002 171 .3 Ireland2005 499 .88 Senegal2007 473 .83
BiH2005 194 .34 Jamaica2005 70 .12 Serbia2003 399 .7
Bolivia2006 556 .98 Jordan2006 451 .79 Slovakia2002 163 .29
Botswana2006 253 .44 Kazakhstan2002 249 .44 Slovakia2005 208 .37
Bulgaria2002 245 .43 Kazakhstan2005 578 1.02 Slovenia2002 188 .33
Bulgaria2005 291 .51 Kenya2003 211 .37 Slovenia2005 221 .39
BurkinaFaso2006 131 .23 Kyrgyzstan2002 166 .29 SouthAfrica2003 551 .97
Burundi2006 215 .38 Kyrgyzstan2003 102 .18 SouthKorea2005 594 1.04
Cambodia2003 464 .82 Kyrgyzstan2005 199 .35 Spain2005 601 1.06
Cameroon2006 165 .29 Laos2005 225 .4 Swaziland2006 208 .37
CapeVerde2006 93 .16 Latvia2002 170 .3 Tajikistan2002 170 .3
Chile2004 942 1.66 Latvia2005 200 .35 Tajikistan2003 107 .19
Chile2006 962 1.69 Lebanon2006 345 .61 Tajikistan2005 199 .35
Colombia2006 936 1.64 Lesotho2003 44 .08 Tajikistan2008 316 .56
CostaRica2005 333 .59 Lithuania2002 193 .34 Tanzania2003 245 .43
Croatia2002 174 .31 Lithuania2004 230 .4 Tanzania2006 360 .63
Croatia2005 229 .4 Lithuania2005 196 .34 Turkey-b2005 1,238 2.18
Czech2002 261 .46 Madagascar2005 269 .47 Turkey2002 513 .9
Czech2005 327 .57 Malawi2005 150 .26 Turkey2005 544 .96
DRC2006 271 .48 Mali2003 123 .22 Turkey2008 900 1.58
Ecuador2003 411 .72 Mauritania2006 204 .36 Uganda2003 291 .51
Ecuador2006 592 1.04 Mauritius2005 177 .31 Uganda2006 509 .89
ElSalvador2003 459 .81 Mexico2006 1,343 2.36 Ukraine2002 463 .81
ElSalvador2006 620 1.09 Moldova2002 173 .3 Ukraine2005 586 1.03
Estonia2002 160 .28 Moldova2003 103 .18 Ukraine2008 733 1.29
Estonia2005 214 .38 Moldova2005 346 .61 Uruguay2006 540 .95
FYROM2002 165 .29 Montenegro2003 100 .18 Uzbekistan2002 255 .45
FYROM2005 194 .34 Mozambique2007 429 .75 Uzbekistan2003 100 .18
Gambia2006 126 .22 Namibia2006 242 .43 Uzbekistan2005 298 .52
Georgia2002 173 .3 Nicaragua2003 448 .79 Uzbekistan2008 361 .63
Georgia2005 199 .35 Nicaragua2006 461 .81 Vietnam-b2005 497 .87
Georgia2008 325 .57 Nigeria2007 2,005 3.52 Vietnam2005 1,109 1.95
Germany2005 1,195 2.1 Pakistan2002 937 1.65 Zambia2002 187 .33
This content downloaded from 210.56.13.7 on Mon, 31 Mar 2014 09:24:45 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Aterido, Hallward-Driemeier, and Page s 645
TABLE A2
SAMPLE COMPOSITION
Percent Percent
Region: Sector:
Sub-Saharan Africa 16.01 Textiles 5.3
East Asia & Pacic 14.45 Leather 1.15
East Europe & Central Asia 27.21 Garments 8.46
Western Europe 4.57 Agroindustry 6.65
Latin America 20.87 Beverages 7.17
Middle East & North Africa 6.72 Metals and machinery 9.42
South Asia 10.16 Electronics 1.55
Chemicals and pharmaceuticals 4.9
Income level: Construction 5.07
Low 31.43 Wood and furniture 5.02
Lower middle 44.59 Nonmetallic and plastic materials 4.37
Upper middle 16.36 Paper 1.98
High 7.62 IT services 3.85
Other manufacturing 1.39
Initial size: Advertising and marketing 1.73
Micro (110 employees) 39.36 Other services 7.28
Small (1150 employees) 33.64 Retail and wholesale trade 17.67
Medium (51200 employees) 16.39 Hotels and restaurants 3.41
Large (200 employees) 10.61 Transport 2.52
Mining and quarrying .46
Initial age: Other transport equipment .67
Young 15 30.71
Mature 615 38.34 Labor intensive 31.69
Older 16 30.95 Capital intensive 31.89
Services 36.42
Nonexporter 77.35
Exporter 22.65 Capital or city 1 million 35.27
City 500,0001 million 13.22
Domestic owned 88.82 City 250,000500,000 15.43
Foreign owned 11.18 City 50,000250,000 17.86
City ! 50,000 18.22
References
Ahsan, Ahmad, and Carmen Pages. 2009. Are All Labor Regulations Equal? Evi-
dence from Indian Manufacturing. Journal of Comparative Economics 37, no. 1:62
75.
Almeida, Rita, and Pedro Carneiro. 2009. Enforcement of Labor Regulation and
Firm Size. Journal of Comparative Economics 37 (March): 2846.
Autor, David H., William R. Kerr, and Adriana D. Kugler. 2007. Do Employment
Protections Reduce Productivity? Evidence from U.S. States. Economic Journal 117
( June): 189217.
Ayyagari, Meghana, Asli Demirgu c-Kunt, and Vojislav Maksimovic. 2008. How
Important Are Financing Constraints? The Role of Finance in the Business En-
vironment. World Bank Economic Review 22, no. 3:483516.
Batra, Geeta, Daniel Kaufmann, and Andrew H. W. Stone. 2003. Investment Climate
around the World. Washington, DC: World Bank.
This content downloaded from 210.56.13.7 on Mon, 31 Mar 2014 09:24:45 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
646 economi c development and cultural change
Beck, Thorsten, Asli Demirgu c-Kunt, Luc Laeven, and Ross Levine. 2008. Finance,
Firm Size and Growth. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 40, no. 7:1379
1405.
Beck, Thorsten, Asli Demirgu c-Kunt, and Vojislav Maksimovic. 2005. Financial
and Legal Constraints to Growth: Does Firm Size Matter? Journal of Finance 60,
no. 1:13177.
Besley, Timothy, and Robin Burgess. 2004. Can Labor Regulation Hinder Economic
Performance? Evidence from India. Quarterly Journal of Economics 119, no. 1:91
134.
Bigsten, Ane, and Mans Soderbom. 2006. What Have We Learned from a Decade
of Manufacturing Enterprise Surveys in Africa? World Bank Research Observer 21,
no. 2:24165.
Botero, Juan, Simeon Djankov, Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez de Silanes, and
Andrei Shleifer. 2004. The Regulation of Labor. Quarterly Journal of Economics
119, no. 4:133982.
Clark, Ximena, David Dollar, and Alejandro Micco. 2004. Port Efciency, Maritime
Transport Costs, and Bilateral Trade. Journal of Development Economics 75, no. 2:
41750.
Davis, Steven J., and John Haltiwanger. 1992. Gross Job Creation, Gross Job
Destruction, and Employment Reallocation. Quarterly Journal of Economics 107,
no. 3:81963.
. 1999. On the Driving Forces behind Cyclical Movements in Employment
and Job Reallocation. American Economic Review 89, no. 5:123458.
Demirgu c-Kunt, Asli, and Vojislav Maksimovic. 1998. Law, Finance and Firm
Growth. Journal of Finance 53:210737.
Djankov, S., R. La Porta, F. Lopez De Silanes, and A. Shleifer. 2002. The Regulation
of Entry. Quarterly Journal of Economics 117, no. 1:137.
Dollar, David, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, and Taye Mengistae. 2005. Investment
Climate and Firm Performance in Developing Countries. Economic Development
and Cultural Change 54, no. 1:131.
Galindo, Arturo Jose, and Alejandro Micco. 2007. Creditor Protection and Credit
Response to Shocks. World Bank Economic Review 21, no. 3:41338.
Fisman, Raymond, and Jakob Svensson. 2007. Are Corruption and Taxation Really
Harmful to Growth? Firm Level Evidence. Journal of Development Economics 83,
no. 1:6375.
Hallward-Driemeier, Mary, and Reyes Aterido. 2007. Comparing Apples with . . .
Apples: How to Make (More) Sense of Subjective Rankings of Constraints to
Business. Photocopy, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Haltiwanger, John, Stefano Scarpetta, and Helena Schweiger. 2006. Assessing Job
Flows across Countries: The Role of Industry, Firm Size, and Regulations. World
Bank Policy Research Working Paper 4070. World Bank, Washington, DC.
Haltiwanger, John, and Helena Schweiger. 2005. Allocative Efciency and the
Business Climate. Photocopy, University of Maryland.
Heckman, James, and Carmen Pages. 2004. Introductory Chapter. In Law and
Employment: Lessons from Latin America and the Caribbean, ed. J. Heckman and C.
Pages. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
This content downloaded from 210.56.13.7 on Mon, 31 Mar 2014 09:24:45 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Aterido, Hallward-Driemeier, and Page s 647
Hsieh, Chang-Tai, and Peter J. Klenow. 2009. Misallocation and Manufacturing
TFP in China and India. Quarterly Journal of Economics 124, no. 4:140348.
Jeong, Hyeok, and Robert Townsend. 2007. Sources of TFP Growth: Occupational
Choice and Financial Deepening. Economic Theory 32, no. 1:179221.
Johnson, Simon, John McMillan, and Christopher Woodruff. 2002. Property Rights
and Finance. American Economic Review 92, no. 5:133556.
Kaufmann, Daniel, Aart Kraay, and Massimo Mastruzzi. 2007. Governance Matters
VI: Governance Indicators for 19962006. World Bank Policy Research Working
Paper no. 4280, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Klapper, Leora F., Luc Laeven, and Raghuram G. Rajan. 2004. Business Regulations
as a Barrier to Entrepreneurship. Journal of Financial Economics 82, no. 3:591
629.
Loayza, Norman, Ana Maria Oviedo, and Luis Serven. 2006. The Impact of Reg-
ulation on Growth and Informality: Cross-Country Evidence. In Linking the Formal
and Informal Economy: Concepts and Policies, ed. Basuded Guha-Khasnobis, Ravi
Kanbur, and Elinor Ostrom. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Love, Inessa, and Nataliya Mylenko. 2005. Credit Reporting and Financing Con-
straints. Credit Technology 50 (October): 733.
Micco, Alejandro, and Carmen Pages. 2006. The Economic Effects of Employment
Protection: Evidence from International Industry-Level Data. Discussion Paper
2433, Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA), Bonn.
Petrin, Amil, and Jagadeesh Sivadasan. 2006. Job Security Does Affect Economic
Efciency: Theory, a New Statistic, and Evidence from Chile. NBER Working
Paper 12757, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
Pierre, Gaelle, and Stefano Scarpetta. 2006. Employment Protection: Do Firms
Perceptions Match with Legislation? Economics Letters 90, no. 3: 32834.
Rajan, Raghuram G., and Luigi Zingales. 1998. Financial Dependence and
Growth. American Economic Review 88, no. 3:55986.
Restuccia, Diego, and Richard Rogerson. 2008. Policy Distortions and Aggregate
Productivity with Heterogeneous Establishments. Review of Economic Dynamics 11,
no. 4:70720.
Rienikka, Ritva, and Jakob Svensson. 2002. Coping with Poor Public Capital.
Journal of Development Economics 69, no. 1:5169.
Teal, Francis. 1999. The Ghanaian Manufacturing Sector, 19911995: Firm
Growth, Productivity and Convergence. Journal of Development Studies 36, no. 1:
10927.
Tybout, James R. 2000. Manufacturing Firms in Developing Countries: How Well
Do They Do, and Why? Journal of Economic Literature 38, no. 1:1144.
World Bank. 2004. World Development Report 2005: A Better Investment Climate for
Everyone. New York: Oxford University Press.
. 2008. The World Bank Enterprise Survey Database. World Bank, Wash-
ington, DC. www.enterprisesurveys.org.
This content downloaded from 210.56.13.7 on Mon, 31 Mar 2014 09:24:45 AM
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions