Public Expenditure Theory 5. Public Goods and Publicly Provided Private Goods

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 25
At a glance
Powered by AI
The key takeaways are that public goods have the properties of non-excludability and non-rival consumption, and there is a spectrum between pure public goods and privately provided goods based on these properties.

The two critical properties of public goods are that it is impossible to exclude individuals from enjoying the benefits (non-excludability) and the marginal cost of an additional individual enjoying the good is zero (non-rival consumption).

A pure public good is one where exclusion is impossible and marginal cost of additional users is zero, while impure public goods may have some ability to exclude users or marginal costs for additional users. Many publicly provided goods fall somewhere in between.

Economics of the Public Sector

PUBLIC EXPENDITURE THEORY


5. Public goods and publicly provided
private goods
5.1. Public goods
5.2. Publicly provided private goods
5.3. Efficiency conditions for public goods
5.4. Efficient government as a public good
Public goods and publicly provided private goods public goods
Public goods have two critical properties:

It is impossible to exclude individuals from enjoying
the benefits of the goods (NON-EXCLUDABILITY)

The marginal cost of an additional individual
enjoying the good is zero (NON-RIVAL
CONSUMPTION). It is undesirable to exclude
individuals from enjoying the benefits of the goods,
since their enjoyment of these goods does not
detract from the enjoyment of others.
Public goods and publicly provided private goods public goods
PAYING FOR
PUBLIC GOODS
Bridges: How a User Fee Can
Result in Underconsumption

If the capacity is large enough, the
bridge is a non-rival good.
While it is possible to exclude
people from using the bridge by
charging a toll, p, this results in
an underconsumption of the
good, Q
e
, below the non-toll
level of consumption, Q
m
.

When consumption is non-rival,
user fees introduce an
inefficiency.
Price
(toll)
Number of trips taken
p
Q
e
Q
m
Q
c

Demand curve for trips
Bridge
capacity
The free rider problem
Public goods and publicly provided private goods public goods
PURE AND IMPURE PUBLIC GOODS
A pure public good is a public good where the marginal costs of
providing it to an additional person are strictly zero and where
it is impossible to exclude people from receiving the good.

While there are a few examples of pure public goods, such as
national defense, for many publicly provided goods exclusion
is possible, although frequently costly.

Charging for use may result in the underutilization of public
facilities.

For many publicly provided goods, there is some marginal cost of
an individual enjoying the good. While the marginal cost of an
individual using a completely uncongested road may be
negligible, if there is some congestion, the marginal cost may
be more significant.
Public goods and publicly provided private goods public goods
Publicly Provided Goods Pure public goods are characterized by
non-rival consumption (the MC of an additional individuals
enjoying the good is zero) and non-excludability (the cost of
excluding an individual from enjoying the good is prohibitively
high). Goods provided by the public sector differ in the extent to
which they have these two properties.
Marginal
cost of
use
Ease of exclusion
Congested
highway
PURE PUBLIC GOOD
National defense
Public health
PURE PRIVATE GOOD
Fire
protection
Publicly provided
private goods
Lighthouse
Public goods and publicly provided private goods public goods
PURE AND IMPURE PUBLIC GOODS

Costs of exclusion For many goods, the issue is not so
much the feasibility of rationing, but the cost. The costs
associated with exclusion for private goods as well as for
public goods are called transactions costs.

Externalities as impure public goods or better stated: public
goods can be viewed as an extreme form of externalities.
Public goods and publicly provided private goods publicly provided private goods
For many publicly provided goods, consumption is
rivalrous (consumption by one individual reduces
that of another) or the marginal cost of supplying an
extra individual may be significant, equal to, or even
greater than, average cost. These are called
PUBLICLY PROVIDED PRIVATE GOODS.
If they are provided freely, there will be
overconsumption.

For publicly provided private goods, some method of
RATIONING other than the price system may be
used. Sometimes queuing is used, while at other
times the good is simply provided in fixed quantities
to all individuals (uniform provision). Both of these
entail inefficiencies.
Public goods and publicly provided private goods publicly provided private goods
Distortions Associated
with Supplying Goods
Freely

(A) For some goods, such as
water, supplying the good
freely rather than at MC
results in relatively little
additional consumption.
(B) For other goods, such as
certain medical services,
supplying the good freely
rather than at MC results in
extensive
overconsumption.
Price
Price
Quantity
Quantity
MC
MC
Demand curve
Demand curve
Q
e
Q
m

Q
e
Q
m

Quantity
Welfare loss
from excessive
consumption
Welfare loss
from excessive
consumption
(A)
(B)
Public goods and publicly provided private goods publicly provided private goods
RATIONING DEVICES
FOR PUBLICLY
PROVIDED PRIVATE
GOODS
Transactions Costs
When transactions costs are
sufficiently high, it may be
more efficient to supply the
good publicly than to have
the good supplied by private
markets.
A
B
E F
D
MC=c
p*
Q
e
Q
o
Q
m

Transactions costs
c, production costs
Demand curve
Price
Quantity
Public goods and publicly provided private goods publicly provided private goods
RATIONING DEVICES
FOR PUBLICLY
PROVIDED PRIVATE
GOODS
Distortions Associated
with Uniform Provision
When publicly provided private
good is supplied in equal
amounts to all individuals,
some get more than the
efficient level and some get
less.
Quantity
Price
Q
2
Q
1
Q*
C
Demand curve of
high demander
Demand curve of
low demander
MC of
production
Public goods and publicly provided private goods publicly provided private goods
THREE METHODS OF RATIONING PUBLICLY PROVIDED GOODS
1. User charges
Advantage: Those who benefit bear costs.
Disadvantages: Results in underconsumption.
Administering pricing system adds transactions costs.
2. Uniform provision
Advantage: Saves on transactions costs
Disadvantages: Leads some to underconsume, others to
overconsume.
High demanders may supplement public consumption
increasing total transactions costs.
3. Queuing
Advantage: Goods (like health care) allocated not necessarily
on basis of who is wealthiest.
Disadvantages: Alternative basis of allocation (who has time to
spare) may be undesirable.
Time is wasted.
Public goods and publicly provided private goods publicly provided private goods
MEASURING THE WELFARE
COST OF USER FEES
Bridges: How a User Fee Can
Result in Welfare Loss

As a result of a toll, p, some
trips across the bridge are
not taken even though they
would be beneficial to
society as a whole.

Total welfare loss created by
the toll is represented by a
shaded region.
p
Price
(toll)
Numbers of
trips taken
Bridge
capacity
Q
e
Q
c
Q
m
Demand
for trips
Welfare
loss
Trips not
undertaken
as a result
of charging
a toll
Public goods and publicly provided private goods efficiency conditions for public goods
Pure public goods are efficiently supplied when the sum of the
marginal rates of substitution (over all individuals) is equal to
the marginal rate of transformation.

The MRS of private goods for public goods tells how much of the
private good each individual is willing to give up to get one
more unit of the public good. The sum of MRS thus tells us how
much of the private good all the members of society, together,
are willing to give up to get one more unit of the public (which
will be jointly consumed by all).

The MRT tells us how much of the private good must be given up
to get one more unit of the public good.

Efficiency requires, then, that the total amount individuals are
willing to give up the sum of the MRS must equal the
amount that they have to give up the MRT.
Determination of the
Efficient Level of
Production of
Public Goods

(A) If the level of public
goods is G, and the
first individual is to get
level of utility U
1
, then
the distance AB
represents the amount
of private goods left
over for the second
individual.
(B) The second
individuals welfare is
maximized at the point
of tangency of his
indifference curve and
the leftover curve.
U
1

A
B
B
G
U
2
U
2

Private good
Private good
Public good
Public good
Production
possibilities
curve
Crusoes
indifference
curve
Fridays
indifference
curve
Leftover
curve
A
(A)
(B)
Public goods and publicly provided private goods efficiency conditions for public goods
DEMAND CURVES FOR PUBLIC GOODS
Individuals do not buy public goods. We can, however, ask how
much they would demand if they had to pay a given amount for
each extra unit of the public good.
We call the extra payment that an individual has to make for extra
unit of public good his TAX PRICE.
Assume that the individuals tax price is p, that is for each unit of
the public good, he has to pay p. His budget constraint is:
C + pG = Y, where: C is his consumption of private goods,
G is the total amount of public goods, and Y is his income.

The individual wishes to obtain the highest level of utility he can. It
is attained at the point of tangency between the indifference
curve and the budget constraint.
The slope of the budget constraint tells how much in private
goods the individual must give up to get one more unit of
public goods.
The slope of the indifference curve tells how much in private
goods the individual is willing to give up to get one more unit of
public goods.
Individual Demand Curve
for Public Goods

The individuals most preferred
level of expenditure is the
point of tangency between
the indifference curve and
the budget constraint.

As the tax price decreases (the
budget constraint shifts
from BB to BB), the
individuals most preferred
level of public expenditure
increases, generating the
demand curve.
E
E
B
G
2
G
1

p
1

G
2

E
E
B B
Indifference curves
Budget constraints
Private consumption
Tax
price
Consumption of
public goods
p
2

G
1

Quantity of
public goods
Public goods and publicly provided private goods efficiency conditions for public goods
Collective Demand for
Public Goods
Since at each point on the
demand curve the price is
equal to the MRS, by adding
the demand curves vertically
we obtain the sum of the
MRS, the total amount of
private goods that the
individuals in society are
willing to give up to get one
more unit of the public good.
The vertical sum thus can be
thought of as generating the
collective demand curve for
the public good.
Tax price
paid by
Crusoe
Tax price
paid by
Friday
G
Quantity of
public goods
$
Collective demand curve
Crusoes demand
curve for public goods
Fridays demand
curve for public
goods
Public goods and publicly provided private goods efficiency conditions for public goods
The demand curve can be thought of as marginal willingness
to pay curve at each level of output of the public good, it
says how much the individual would be willing to pay for an
extra unit of the public good.

Thus, the vertical sum of demand curves is just the sum of their
marginal willingness to pay, that is, it is the total amount that all
individuals together are willing to pay for an extra unit of the
public good.

A supply curve for each level of output, the price represents
how much of the other goods have to be forgone to produce
one more unit of public goods. This is the marginal cost, or
marginal rate of transformation.
Public goods and publicly provided private goods efficiency conditions for public goods
Efficient Production of
Public Goods

An efficient supply of public
goods occurs at the point of
intersection of the demand
curve and the supply curve.
The collective demand curve
gives the sum of what all
individuals are willing to
give up, at the margin, to
have one more unit of public
goods, while the supply
curve gives the amount of
other goods that have to be
given up to obtain one more
unit of the public good.
Supply curve
Collective demand curve
Price
Quantity
Public goods and publicly provided private goods efficiency conditions for public goods
EFFICIENCY CONDITION FOR
PURE PUBLIC GOODS

Efficient production requires that the sum of the
marginal rates of substitution equal the marginal rate
of transformation.

Efficient production occurs at the intersection of the
collective demand curve, formed by vertically adding
the demand curves for each individual, with the
supply curve.
Public goods and publicly provided private goods efficiency conditions for public goods
PARETO EFFICIENCY & INCOME DISTRIBUTION

There are many Pareto efficient resource allocations: any point on
the utility possibilities schedule is Pareto efficient. The market
equilibrium in the absence of market failures corresponds to
just one of those points.

By the same token there, is not a unique Pareto optimal supply of
public goods. The fact that the efficient level of public goods
depends, in general, on the distribution of income has one
important implication: one cannot separate out efficiency
conditions in the supply of public goods from distributional
consideration.

Any change in the distribution of income, say, brought about by a
change in the income tax structure, will thus be accompanied
by corresponding changes in the efficient levels of public
goods production.
Public goods and publicly provided private goods efficiency conditions for public goods
LIMITATIONS ON INCOME REDISTRIBUTION AND THE
EFFICIENT SUPPLY OF PUBLIC GOODS
The fact that redistributing resources through the tax and welfare
systems is costly implies that the government may look for
alternative ways to achieve its redistributive goals. One way is
to incorporate redistributive considerations into its evaluation
of public projects.

DISTORTIONARY TAXATION AND THE EFFICIENT
SUPPLY OF PUBLIC GOODS
The fact that the revenue raised to finance public goods is raised
through distortionary taxes, such as the income tax, has some
important implications for the efficient supply of public goods.

The amount of private goods that individuals must give up to get
one more unit of public goods is greater then it would be if the
government could raise revenue ia a way that did not entail
distortionary incentive effects and that was costly to
administer.
Public goods and publicly provided private goods efficiency conditions for public goods
DISTORTIONARY
TAXATION AND THE
EFFICIENT SUPPLY OF
PUBLIC GOODS

The Feasibility Curve

It gives the maximum output
(consumption) of private
goods for any level of public
goods, taking into account
the inefficiencies that arise
from taxes that must be
imposed to raise the
requisite revenue.
The feasibility curve lies below
the production possibilities
curve.
Private good
Public good
Feasibility
curve
Production
possibilities
curve
Public goods and publicly provided private goods efficiency conditions for public goods
The amount of private goods we have to give up to obtain one
more unit of public goods, taking into account all inefficiencies,
is called the
MARGINAL ECONOMIC RATE OF TRANSFORMATION,
as opposed to the
MARGINAL PHYSICAL RATE OF TRANSFORMATION.

Thus we replace the earlier condition that the marginal rate of
physical transformation must equal the sum of the marginal
rates of substitution with a new condition, that the marginal
rate of economic transformation must equal the sum of the
marginal rates of substitution.

Since it becomes more costly to obtain public goods when
taxation imposes distortions, normally this will imply that the
efficient level of public goods is smaller than it would have
been with nondistorionary taxation.
Public goods and publicly provided private goods
efficient government as a public good
One of the most important
public goods
is the management
of the government

You might also like