Microeconomic Theory - Review For Final Exam

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 6

Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley May 10, 2007

Microeconomic Theory Economics 101A Spring 2007

Economics 101A: Microeconomic Theory Review for Final Exam

1
1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 1.5

Optimization
Concave Function Convex Function First Order Conditions Second Order Conditions Constrained Maximization

2
2.1

Consumer Preferences and Consumer Choice


Utility Function (preferences) and Indierence Curves

Utility function, sometimes referred to simply as preferences, capture how individuals trade like dierent amounts of goods. Some common utility functions: - Linear u(x1 , x2 ) = x1 + x2
- Cobb-Douglas u(x1 , x2 ) = x 1 x2
1 x2 - Leontief u(x1 , x2 ) = min{ x , }

Remember, for linear and Leontief preferences demand functions, indirect utility functions, and expenditure functions may not change smoothly as prices or income changes. In these cases more thought is required then simply chugging through a LaGrangian. Be especially careful about preferences such as
2 - Circle u(x1 , x2 ) = x2 1 + x2

These change smoothly, so it may appear that the LaGrangian is yielding an answer that makes sense however the tangency will give you the minimum possible utility subject to a budget constraint rather than the maximum possible utility. 2.2 Marginal Rate of Substitution
p1 . p2

Tangency condition equates M RSx1 ,x2 and ratio of prices

3
3.1

Indierence Curve Analysis


Utility Maximization Problem (UMP) max u(x1 , x2 ) s.t. p1 x1 + p2 x2 I
x1 ,x2

L(x1 , x2 , ) = u(x1 , x2 ) (p1 x1 + p2 x2 I ) The solutions to the UMP are the ordinary demand functions x1 (p1 , p2 , I ) x2 (p1 , p2 , I ) Plugging the ordinary demand functions back into the utility function gives the indirect utility function which tells us the maximum level of utility for a given set of prices and level of income. V (p1 , p2 , I ) = u(x1 (p1 , p2 , I ), x2 (p1 , p2 , I )) Taking the partial derivative of the value function with respect to a price we get V (p1 , p2 , I ) = x1 (p1 , p2 , I ) p1 a result known as Roys Identity. Taking the partial derivative of the value function with respect to income gives V (p1 , p2 , I ) = I revealing why we interpret the LaGrange multiplier as the shadow price of the constraint. It tells us how much maximized utility would increase if we had a dollar more of income. 3.2 Expenditure Minimization Problem (EMP)
x1 ,x2

min p1 x1 + p2 x2 s.t. u(x1 , x2 ) u0

The solutions to the EMP are the compensated demand functions


0 xc 1 (p1 , p2 , u ) 0 xc 2 (p1 , p2 , u )

Multiplying the compensated demand functions by their respective prices and summing gives the expenditure function which tells us the minimum level of dollars that we need to spend given a set of prices to achieve a level of utility, u0 .
0 c 0 e(p1 , p2 , u0 ) = p1 xc 1 (p1 , p2 , u ) + p2 x2 (p1 , p2 , u )

Taking the partial derivative of the expenditure function we get e(p1 , p2 , u0 ) 0 = xc 1 (p1 , p2 , u ) p1 a result known as Sheperds Lemma.
2

Comparative Statics

The Slutsky equation decomposes the demand response to a change in price into income and substitution eects
0 x1 (p1 , p2 , I ) xc x1 (p1 , p2 , I ) 0 1 (p1 , p2 , u ) = x1 p1 p1 I

where x0 1 is the optimal level of x1 demanded before the tiny change in price occurs. 4.1 Insta-Slutsky Derivation

Start with the identity that at an optimum ordinary and compensated demand are equal also note that at an optimum all income is spent so I = e(p1 , p2 , u0 ).
0 xc 1 (p1 , p2 , u ) = x1 (p1 , p2 , I ) = x1 (p1 , p2 , e(p1 , p2 , u0 ))

now take the partial with respect to p1 of both sides


0 x1 (p1 , p2 , e(p1 , p2 , u0 )) x1 (p1 , p2 , e(p1 , p2 , u0 )) e(p1 , p2 , u0 ) xc 1 (p1 , p2 , u ) = + p1 p1 e p1 x1 (p1 , p2 , I ) x1 (p1 , p2 , I ) c x1 (p1 , p2 , u0 ) = + p1 I x1 (p1 , p2 , I ) x1 (p1 , p2 , I ) 0 = + x1 p1 I

Market Level Supply and Demand

Often assume constant elasticities of supply and demand if we considering small changes in price or income. Elasticity is dened as: %x = %p Several types of elasticities - Price elasticity of demand (or elasticity of demand for short): xx = - Income elasticity of demand (or income elasticity): ex =
x I x px x x0 x0 p p0 p0

x p log x = p x log p

px x

I x x py

- Cross price elasticity of demand (or cross price elasticity for short): xy = - Elasticity of supply: x =
x px

py x

px x

Labor Supply

Similar to demand for goods, but endowment point changes. Instead of the goods x1 , x2 you consume x, all purchased goods and L, leisure. The endowment point changes beacuse everyone is born with leisure time then gets to sell their time in the labor market.

Consumption and Savings

Similar to demand for goods, but instead of two dierent goods x1 , x2 we are interested in the amount of all goods consumed in period 1, c1 and the amount of all goods consumed in period 2, c2 . Now the endowment point can be anywhere depending upon how much income the consumer is endowed with in period 1 and 2, y1 , y2 , respectively.

Firm Production and Cost

Suppose a rm produces output y which it sells in a competitive market at price p. The rm uses input factors a, b which it purchases in a competitive factor market at prices, wa , wb to produce y via the production technology summarized by the production function y = f (a, b). 8.1
8.1.1

Two-Step: Expenditure Min, Prot Max


Step One

min wa a + wb b s.t. f (a, b) = y


a,b

Solution of this problem yields the input requirement functions (IRF) or conditional factor demand functions a(wa , wb , y ) b(wa , wb , y ) These are analagous to the consumers compensated demand functions. Multiplying the IRFs by the respective factor prices and summing gives the cost function (analagous to the consumers expenditure function) C (wa , wb , y ) = wa a(wa , wb , y ) + wb b(wa , wb , y )
8.1.2 Step Two

max py C (wa , wb , y )
y

leading to the rst order condition p= C (wa , wb , y ) y

8.2

One-Step: Prot Maximization Problem max pf (a, b) wa a wb b


a,b

Supply Determination

Market supply curve equals the sum of supply curves for individual rms. Sum graphically by stacking horizontally. Remember to consider the rms decision to enter the market at all (prots > 0).

10

Consumer and Producer Surplus

- Deadweight Loss: Can approximate using formula for area of a triangle and elasticities of supply and demand. - Change in Consumer Surplus: CS =
px p0 x

x(px , py , I )dpx

- Compensating Variation: Amount of cash you need to get back to your old utility level under the new prices. CV =
0 0 0 0 - Equivalent Variation: EV = e(px , p0 y , u ) e(px , py , u )

If ordinary and compensated demand curves are equal everywhere then there are no income eects. In this case only, willingness to pay (CV or EV) is equal to the change in consumer surplus (CS ).

11 12

Monopoly Duopoly

Cournot Equilibrium (which is a Nash Equilibrium).

13

Game Theory

Nash Equilibrium

14 15

Choice Under Uncertainty Moral Hazard

Individual can vary the level of eort they put forth to prevent an accident. Under full coverage they dont make enough eort.

16

Adverse Selection

Two or more dierent types of people: low risk and risk risk. Similar to job market signalling model. Need a separating equilibrium for rms to stay in business.

17

Auctions

Auction types. Optimal bidding functions. Winners curse.

18
18.1 18.2

Finance
CAPM Ecient Market Hypothesis

19 20 21

Public Goods and Externalities Common Property and Congestion Empirical Methods

You might also like