EstimatingEconomicImpact PDF
EstimatingEconomicImpact PDF
Fellow, University of Minnesota, Department of Civil Engineering [email protected] Braun-CTS Chair of Transportation Engineering; Director of Network, Economics, and Urban Systems Research Group; University of Minnesota, Department of Civil Engineering, 500 Pillsbury Drive SE, Minneapolis, MN 55455 USA, [email protected] http://nexus.umn.edu
RP
Research
Abstract Transportation analysts and the public decision-makers they support are confronted with a broad range of analytical tools for estimating the economic impacts of improvements to transportation networks. Many of the available models operate at different scales and have distinctly different structures, making them more or less appropriate for analyzing the impacts of different types of projects. Here, we review several of the economic methods and models that have been developed for analyzing the impact of transportation improvements, giving special attention to types of projects that add highway capacity in urban areas. We review project-based methods, including benet-cost analysis and several analytical software tools developed by the Federal Highway Administration (FHWA) for economic analysis of transportation investment. We then move on to aggregate and disaggregate-level econometric methods, including regional economic models, hedonic price functions, production functions and cliometric analyses. We also devote some attention to the role of induced demand in economic evaluation, since it is often one of the most uncertain and confounding factors faced by those charged with conducting economic evaluation of transportation projects.
Introduction
When confronted with the problem of evaluating proposals for projects involving new highway capacity, public decision makers face a bewildering array of options for anticipating and assessing project-related economic impacts. On one hand, the issue of geographic scale is highly relevant. Local or project-level impacts may be very different from those estimated at regional and multiregional levels. Another salient issue is that there are many metrics for assessing economic impacts, ranging from direct user benets and changes in external costs of travel to more aggregate economic indicators, such as employment, income and productivity rates. Several types of economic benets arise from transportation improvements: reductions in travel costs, 1 more efcient supply chains, intra-rm scale economy effects (permitting individual rms to through larger scale operations at fewer locations), agglomeration (including inter-rm scale effects) whereby clusters of competing and complementary rms perform better than rms in isolation, and re-organizational benets, where rms can reorganize the way they produce output, and improve quality or even the goods that can be produced thanks to new infrastructure, just-in-time production is an example. All of these benets relate, and may be fully capitalized into the price of land, property and products. Project-level, disaggregate studies tend to focus on the rst of these effects, while more aggregate methods are applied to the next two. Almost no studies consider the longer term agglomeration or reorganization benets of improved infrastructure (20), and identifying the existence of positive externalities from infrastructure (i.e. gains that are not captured by users) is very difcult. The economic impacts of transportation improvements have been measured alternatively at either a macro or a micro scale. The former contain much of the theoretical literature underlying the calculation of impacts and can be traced back to early works such as (42). The latter have become associated with more general studies of the overall impact of transportation or public capital spending on aggregate measures of output. The development of methodological approaches to economic impact measurement has since evolved to t more practical applications, and these have mostly been carried out at smaller scales, taking the form of benet-cost analyses for particular projects (43), regional or corridor investment analyses (1; 18) , or studies of the impact of specic projects on local property values. This synthesis reviews several strands of relevant literature that aim to assess the basic issue of the economic impact of highways. It begins with a discussion of traditional, project-based economic analysis methods, based on microeconomic foundations and benet-cost analysis methods. Some attention is paid to the specic topic of induced demand, since this issue presents unique difculties for microeconomic analysis methods. Then, the discussion turns to regional
analysts consider reductions in travel costs a user benet, not an economic benet, but we nd it hard to see how users are not part of the economy. We do believe that user costs should be quantied distinctly from other benets and double counting of benets should be avoided.
1 Some
and macroeconomic methods, including input-output and econometric modeling. The nal section summarizes the previous discussion and offers some prospective ideas about evaluating the impacts of transportation improvements.
MicroBENCOST
MicroBENCOST (40) is a sketch planning tool for estimating basic benets and costs of a range of highway improvement projects, including capacity addition projects. In each type of project, attention is focused on corridor trafc conditions and their resulting impact on motorist costs with and without a proposed improvement. This type of approach may be appropriate for situations where projects have relatively isolated impacts and do not require regional modeling.
SPASM
The Sketch Planning Analysis Spreadsheet Model (SPASM) is a benet-cost tool designed for screening level analysis. It outputs estimates of project costs, cost-effectiveness, benets, and energy and air quality impacts. SPASM is designed to allow for comparison among multiple modes and non-modal alternatives, such as travel demand management scenarios. The model is comprised of three modules (worksheets) relating to public agency costs, characteristics of facilities and trips, and a travel demand component. Induced trafc is dealt with through the use of elasticity-based methods, where an elasticity of vehicle-miles of travel (VMT) with respect to travel time is dened and applied. Vehicle emissions are estimated based on calcuations of VMT, trip length and speeds, 4
and assumed shares of travel occuring in cold start, hot start, and hot stabilized conditions. Analysis is conned to a corridor level, with all trips having the same origin, destination and length. This feature is appropriate for analysis of linear transportation corridors, but also greatly limits the ability to deal with trafc drawn to or diverted from outside the corridor. (12) describe the model and its application to a freeway corridor in Salt Lake City, Utah.
STEAM
The Surface Transportation Efciency Analysis Model (STEAM) is a planning-level extension of the SPASM model, designed for a fuller evaluation of cross-modal and demand management policies. STEAM was designed to overcome the most important limitations of its predecessor, namely the assumption of average trip lengths within a single corridor and the inability to analyze systemwide effects. The enhanced modeling capabilities of STEAM feature greater compatibility with existing four-step travel demand models, including a trip table module that is used to calculate user benets and emissions estimates based on changes in network conditions and travel behavior. Also, the package features a risk analysis component to its evaluation summary module, which calculates the likelihood of various outcomes such as benet-cost ratios. An overview of STEAM and a hypothetical application are given by (13).
SMITE
SMITE (Spreadsheet Model for Induced Travel Estimation) is a sketch planning application that was designed for inclusion with STEAM in order to account for the effects of induced travel in trafc forecasting. SMITEs design as a simple spreadsheet application allows it to be used in cases where a conventional, four-step travel demand model is unavailable or cannot account for induced travel effects in its structure (11). SMITE applies elasticity measures that describe the response in demand (VMT) to changes in travel time and the response in supply (travel time) to changes in demand levels.
SCRITS
As a practical matter, highway corridor improvements involving intelligent transportation systems (ITS) applications to smooth trafc ow can be considered capacity enhancements, at least in the short term. The FHWAs SCRITS (SCReening for ITS) is a sketch planning tool that offers rough estimates of ITS benets, for screening-level analysis. SCRITS utilizes aggregate relationships between average weekday trafc levels and capacity to estimate travel speed impacts and vehiclehours of travel (VHT). Like many other FHWA sketch planning tools, it is organized in spreadsheet format and can be used in situations where more sophisticated modeling systems are unavailable or insufcient.
HERS
In addition to helping states plan and manage their highway systems, the FHWAs Highway Economic Requirements System for states (HERS-ST) offers a model for economic impacts evaluation. In once case, (37) use HERS-ST to conclude that Texas is under-invested in highways particularly 5
urban systems and lower-order functional classes by 50 percent. Combining economic priniciples with engineering criteria, HERS evaluates competing projects via benet-cost ratios. Recognizing user benets, emissions levels, and construction and maintenance costs, HERS operates within a GIS environment and will be evaluated under this project, for discussion in project deliverables. Well established software like HERS offer states and regions an oportunity to readily pursue standardized economic impact evaluations on all projects, a key advantage for many users, as well as the greater community.
Induced Demand
Since so many assessments of project benets are based on travel-time savings, the issue of induced or elastic demand merits special attention. Since (26) provided evidence of an elasticity of 0.9 between road supply (capacity) and the demand for road use (VMT) among Californias counties, there has been a great deal of concern over how the provision of new highway capacity might affect travel behavior and whether new capacity policies might be self-defeating. Such ndings may have important implications for the long-term economic and social effects of highway capacity provision. However, there is still a great deal that is not known about the fundamental causal structure underlying the phenomenon of induced demand. Research attempting to decompose the complex issue of induced demand (29; 31) has emphasized that there are both short-run and long-run effects of highway capacity additions. Specically, in the short run, movements along the demand curve for road use are observed, as travelers may switch routes or substitute destinations. In the longer term, xed adjustments by travelers and location decisions by households and rms in response to changes in travel time and accessibility may affect levels of overall travel, leading to an overall shift in the demand curve. Recent research has only begun to address these issues in practice by substituting micro-level data and methods for macroscopic anlayses (21; 33; 44; 49) and addressing the reciprocal relationship between supply and demand (10; 32; 34). The relationship between road capacity supply and demand is a dynamic process and is difcult to model with conventional models of travel demand. Since project-based microeconomic analysis techniques, including some developed by FHWA, use output from these models as inputs to benet or cost calculations, their results may be somewhat skewed. Even the elasticity-based techniques provided in models like STEAM are likely to overestimate the response of travel demand to new capacity. The lack of a dynamic element in these analysis tools means that they are likely to overestimate user benets due to a) an inability to capture short-term behavioral changes as the transportation network evolves toward a new equilibrium and b) an inability to capture the codevelopment process in the long run, whereby infrastrucutre and land use develop jointly over time in response to each other. While the benets for individual users may drop in response to induced demand that diminishes the travel time savings, the fact that demand rises when capacity is added is indicative both of gains to users in general (more users take advantage of the facility), and of other economic benets that this research aims to capture.
example, federal spending on public nonmilitary capital was shown to be roughly constant from 1950 to 1990, while state and local capital stocks (which tend to be much larger), grew considerably (23). Also, research that focused on industry-specic and state-level production functions, while controlling for unobservable differences in state-specic conditions, found much lower (and in some cases, statistically indistinguishable) rates of return (19; 30). (46) estimated the benets of highway investment at the national level between the 1950s and the 1980s and concluded that in the early years returns were as high as 35 percent per year, but that by late in the years of the construction of the Interstate system that contribution had dropped to roughly the same as the return from private capital, about 11 percent. One of the benets that has been associated with transportation improvements is the impact that increased accessibility has on agglomeration of urban areas. Agglomeration economies are an external benet that arise from the interaction and co-location of productive factors within an economy, such as infrastructure, suppliers and customers, as well as a pool of labor with the needed skills. This can provide added economic value to an economy. Agglomeration economies are mitigated by various diseconomies, such as congestion, that may also occur. Recent research by (22) has examined these impacts which may effect different industry sectors in different ways. The urry of economic research into the role of public capital and, in particular, highway infrastructure capital, shed light on an important way to measure the economic returns from transportation infrastructure investment, albeit at a highly aggregate level. With the aid of time series data, public infrastructure capital can be specied as a factor of production, and its contribution to productivity tracked over time. This information is critically important at a time when the U.S. National Highway System is essentially complete, and marginal improvements to the network must be evaluated. Care needs to be taken, though, in the specication and interpretation of the results from aggregate production function research. Denitions of public capital and other factors of production need to be rigorous (e.g. separating public highway capital from schools, airports, water systems, etc.). Also, the geographic scale of the research (local, state, national) needs to be clearly dened.
Cliometric Methods
Economic historians, utilizing so-called Cliometric methods (after Clio, the muse of history), have assessed the long-term retrospective impacts of major infrastructure investments. Among the more noted of these is the assessment by (17) of railroads and economic growth in the nineteenth century, which sought to estimate the incremental economic contribution of railroads compared with its precursor system of canals. Fogel concluded that railroads contributed an increment of only 0.4 percent per year of growth in economic output, compared with competing estimates as high as 4 percent per year (16). Fogel later won a Nobel Prize in Economics for his work. What is noteworthy about the economic history assessments of infrastructure assessments is that they underscore the profound difculty of a deep assessment of the impact of major infrastructure system implementations even a century after the fact. Of course, investments at a smaller scale pose less daunting challenges for analysis. The larger point is that the scale of investment is in many respects inversely proportionate to the difculty of measuring impacts. Thus, assessing the effects of a Washington Beltway is an order of magnitude more difcult that assessing the impact of adding a single link to an already deployed network. 9
wide variety of fundamental information, including employers valuations of employee commute time and anticipated, as well as, ultimately, perceived, effects of project construction (on employee and customer access, for example). (25) survey of residents in bypassed Texas towns illuminate a range of meaningful, perceived benets (including diminished downtown congestion and noise), even in the wake of reduced sales in these same communities (51). Such details can serve as a priceless supplement to more numeric studies, emphasizing modeled travel time savings, hedonic values, employment levels, and the like.
Conclusion
This paper has reviewed a variety of approaches that might be employed to analyze the economic impacts of a highway network improvement. Several types of project-specic and more aggregate econometric methods have been described, each with important limitations for modeling the effects of upgraded facilities. The project-based methods reviewed here share the common limitation of being insufciently dynamic to model accurately the short-term (much less longer-term) impacts of changes to the service level provided by highways. The issue of induced demand and its effect on both travel behavior and location choice cause estimates of user benets to be unreliable, particularly in the long run. On the other hand, the econometric modeling approaches to the evaluation of highway improvements may provide plausible estimates of the economic effects of highway investment at an aggregate level, though they perform less well at specifying this relationship at the level of an individual project. This is particularly true of aggregate production function approaches, which have emphasized macroeconomic modeling at the expense of actual transportation economics (50). Hence, they lack the policy sensitivity to accurately reect the economic impacts of small-scale changes to transportation networks. Noting these limitations, the best way to proceed with an evaluation of the impact of a new or upgraded transportation link might be to combine one or more of the above approaches, perhaps across spatial scales, and compare the results. For example, in the case of an upgraded highway in a small urban or rural area, one might choose to evaluate the impact of this new link by estimating the increment in land values near the highway, then comparing this result to results obtained by modeling city or county-wide employment and income with and without the upgraded facility. Both of these results could be compared with the benets estimated from standard engineering economic models of highway performance. If the results of the different approaches largely agree with another, then this is a sign that the different approaches are essentially measuring the same thing and can be used to bound the true value of the economic impacts. If they differ greatly, then some effort should be devoted to uncovering the different assumptions and methodological concepts that underlie each approach. A good evaluation approach should both provide consistent estimates of project impacts and provide insight into the process that generated those impacts, so that the results can be applied in a policy-relevant context.
11
References
[1] B.J. Allen, C.P. Baumel, and D.J. Forkenbrock. Expanding the set of efciency gains of a highway investment: conceptual, methodological, and practical issues. Transportation journal, 34(1):3947, 1994. [2] D.A. Aschauer. Is public expenditure productive? Journal of Monetary Economics, 23:177 200, 1989. [3] Michael W. Babcock and Bernt Bratsberg. Measurement of economic impact of highway and bridge construction. Journal of the Transportation Research Forum, 37(2):5266, 1998. [4] Joseph Berechman, Dilruba Ozmen, and Kaan Ozbay. Empirical analysis of transportation investment and economic development at state, county and municipality levels. Transportation, 33(6):537551, November 2006. [5] Joseph Berechman and Robert E. Paaswell. Accessibility improvements and local employment: an empirical analysis. Journal of Transportation and Statistics, 4(2/3):4966, Sept./Dec. 2001 2001. [6] M Bina and K. Kockelman. Location choice vis- a-vis transportation: the case of recent home buyers. In Proceedings of the 85th Annual Meeting of the Transportation Research Board., 2006. [7] M.G. Boarnet. Infrastructure services and the productivity of public capital: the case of streets and highways. National Tax Journal, 50(1):3957, March 1997. [8] M.G. Boarnet. Spillovers and the locational effects of public infrastructure. Journal of Regional Science, 38:381400, 1998. [9] J. Carey and J. Semmens. Impact of highways on property values: case study of the superstition freeway corridor. Transportation Research Record, pages 128135, 2003. [10] R. Cervero and M. Hansen. Induced travel demand and induced road investment: a simulataneous equation analysis. Journal of Transport Economics and Policy, 36(3):469490, 2002. [11] P. DeCorla-Souza and H. Cohen. Accounting for induced travel in evaluation of urban highway expansion. Online resource, U.S. Department of Transportation, Federal Highway Administration, 1998. [12] P. DeCorla-Souza, H. Cohen, and K. Bhatt. Using benet-cost analysis to evaluate across modes and demand management strategies. In Compendium of Technical Papers, 66th Annual Meeting of the Institute of Transportation Engineers, pages 439445. Institute of Transportation Engineers, ITE, 1996. [13] P. DeCorla-Souza, H. Cohen, D. Haling, and J. Hunt. Using steam for benet-cost analysis of transportation alternatives. Transportation Research Record, 1649:6371, 1998.
12
[14] Department of Transport and the Environment. Guidance on the Methodologies for MultiModal Studies. Technical report, Department of Transport and the Environment, 2000. [15] Kevin T. Duffy-Deno and Randall W. Eberts. Public infrastructure and regional economic development: a simultaneous equations approach. Journal of Urban Economics, 30:329343, 1991. [16] A. Fishlow. American Railroads and the Transformation of the Ante-bellum Economy. Harvard University Press Cambridge, 1965. [17] R.W. Fogel. Railroads and American Economic Growth: Essays in Econometric History. Johns Hopkins Press, 1964. [18] D.J. Forkenbrock and N.S.J. Foster. Economic benets of a corridor highway investment. Transportation Research, 24(4):303312, 1990. [19] Teresa Garcia-Mila, Therese J. McGuire, and Robert H. Porter. The effect of public capital in state-level production functions reconsidered. Review of Economics and Statistics, 78(1):177 180, February 1996. [20] W.L. Garrison and D. Levinson. The Transportation Experience: Policy, Planning, and Deployment. Oxford University Press, 2006. [21] P.B. Goodwin, Carmen Hass-Klau, and Sally Cairns. Evidence on the effects of road capacity reduction on trafc levels. Trafc Engineering and Control, 39(6):348354, 1998. [22] D.J. Graham. Variable returns to agglomeration and the effect of road trafc congestion. Journal of Urban Economics, 62(1):102120, 2007. [23] Edward Gramlich. Infrastructure investment: a review essay. Journal of Economic Literature, 32:11761196, September 1994. [24] M. Haider and E. Miller. Effects of transportation infrastructure and locational elements on residential real estate values: application of spatial autoregressive techniques. Transportation Research Record, 1722:18, 2000. [25] S. Handy, K.M. Kockelman, S. Kubly, S. Srinivasan, J. Jarrett, M. Oden, and H. Mahmassani. Economic effects of highway relief routes on small and medium-size communities. project report 1843-2. Technical report, Texas DOT. Center for Transportation Research, The University of Texas at Austin., 2001. [26] Mark Hansen and Yuanlin Huang. Road supply and trafc in Californina urban areas. Transportation Research, Part A, 31A(3):205218, May 1997. [27] Andrew F. Haughwout. Aggregate production functions, interregional equilibrium, and the measurement of infrastructure productivity. Journal of Urban Economics, 44:216227, 1998. [28] J. Heiner and K.M. Kockelman. The costs of right of way acquisition: methods and models for estimation. Journal of Transportation Engineering, 131(3):193204, 2005. 13
[29] Peter J. Hills. What is induced trafc? Transportation, 23(1):516, February 1996. [30] D. Holtz-Eakin. Public sector capital and the productivity puzzle. Review of Economics and Statistics, 76:1221, 1994. [31] Douglass B. Lee, Lisa A. Klein, and Gregorio Camus. Induced trafc and induced demand. Transportation Research Record, 1659:6875, 1999. [32] D. Levinson and Wei Chen. Access to Destinations, chapter Paving new ground: a Markov chain model of the change in transportation networks and land use, pages 243266. Elsevier, 2005. [33] D. Levinson and S. Kanchi. Road capacity and the allocation of time. Journal of Transportation and Statistics, 5(1):2546, 2002. [34] D. Levinson and Ramachandra Karamalaputi. Induced supply: a model of highway network expansion at the microscopic level. Journal of Transport Economics and Policy, 37(3):297 318, 2003. [35] David Levinson and Kevin Krizek, editors. Access to destinations. Elsevier, 2006. [36] D. Luskin and A. Chandrasekaran. Employer valuations of employee commuting time: case study of ofce tenants in North Dallas, Texas. Transportation Research Record, 1902:1017, 2005. [37] D. Luskin and Erin Mallard. Potential gains from more efcient spending on Texas highways. In Proceedings of the 84th Annual Meeting of the Transportation Research Board, January, Washington D.C., 2005. [38] F.J. Mart nez. Access: the transport-land use economic link. Transportation Research, 29:457470, 1995. [39] F.J. Mart nez. Handbook of transport modelling, chapter Towards a land-use and transport interaction framework, pages 145164. Elsevier, 2000. [40] McTrans. Microbencost. Web page, 2007. [41] Edwin Sadler Mills. The misuse of regional economic models. Cato Journal, 13(1):2939, Spring-Summer 1993. [42] H. Mohring and M. Harwitz. Highway Benets: An Analytical Framework. Published for the Transportation Center at Northwestern University by Northwestern University Press, 1962. [43] Herbert. Mohring. Maximizing, measuring, and not double counting transportationimprovement benets: a primer on closed- and open-economy cost-benet analysis. Transportation research. Part B: methodological, 27(6):413424, 1993. [44] P.L. Mokhtarian, F.J. Samaniego, R.H. Shumway, and N.H. Willits. Revisiting the notion of induced trafc through a matched-pairs study. Transportation, 29(2):193220, 2002.
14
[45] A.H. Munnell. Why has productivity growth declined? productivity and public investment. New England Economic Review, pages 322, January/February 1990. Reported infrastructure returns in excess of 100 [46] M.I. Nadiri and T.P. Mamuneas. Highway capital and productivity growth. In Economic Returns from Transportation Investment. Eno Transportation Foundation, Inc., Landsdowne, VA, 1996. [47] R.B. Noland. Transport planning and environmental assessment: implications of induced travel effects. International Journal of Sustainable Transportation, 1(1):128, 2007. [48] Kaan Ozbay, Dilruba Ozmen, and Joseph Berechman. Modeling and analysis of the link between accessibility and employment growth. Journal of Transportation Engineering, 132(5):385393, May 2006. [49] P. Parthasarathi, D. Levinson, and R. Karamalaputi. Induced demand: a microscopic perspective. Urban Studies, 40(7):13351351, 2003. [50] Chad Shirley and Clifford Winston. Firm inventory behavior and the returns from highway infrastructure investments. Journal of Urban Economics, 55:398415, 2004. [51] S. Srinivasan and K.M. Kockelman. The impacts of bypasses on small-and medium-sized communities: an econometric analysis. The Journal of Transportation and Statistics, 5(2):57 69, 2002. [52] I.M. Srour, K.M. Kockelman, and T.P. Dunn. Accessibility indices: a connection to residential land prices and location choices. Transportation Research Record, 1805:2534, 2002. [53] Yorgos J. Stephanedes. Distributional effects of state highway investment on local and regional development. Transportation Research Record, 1274:156164, 1990. [54] Yorgos J. Stephanedes and David M. Eagle. Highway expenditures and non-metropolitan employment. Journal of Advanced Transportation, 20(1):4361, 1986. [55] Yorgos J. Stephanedes and David M. Eagle. Highway impacts on regional employment. Journal of Advanced Transportation, 21(1):6779, 1987. [56] B. Ten Siethoff and Kara Kockelman. Property values and highway expansion: timing, size, location, and use effects. Transportation Research Record, 1812(1812):191200, 2002. [57] George I. Treyz, D.S. Rickman, and G. Shao. The REMI economic-demographic forecasting and simulation model. International Regional Science Review, 14:221253, 1992. [58] Pierre Vilain, Louie Nan Liu, and David Aimen. Estimate of commodity inows to a substate region: an input-output based approach. Transportation Research Record, 1653:1726, 1999. [59] Glen E. Weisbrod and Michael Grovak. Comparing approaches for valuing economic development benets of transportation projects. Transportation Research Record, 1649:8694, 1998. 15
[60] Glen E. Weisbrod and Frederick Treyz. Productivity and accessibility: bridging projectspecic and macroeconomic analyses of transportation investment. Journal of Transportation and Statistics, 1(3):6579, October 1998. [61] Martin Weiss and Roger Figura. Provisional typology of highway economic development projects. Transportation Research Record, 1839:115119, 2003. Review of weaknesses of REMI models. [62] Martin Williams and J.K. Mullen. Highway capacity spillover and interstate manufacturing activity. International Journal of Transport Economics, 25(3):287295, October 1998.
16