S. C. Mooney Usury: Destroyer of Nations
S. C. Mooney Usury: Destroyer of Nations
S. C. Mooney Usury: Destroyer of Nations
Destroyer of Nations
by
s.c. Mooney
a Theopolis publication
Sripture quotations are from the New American Standard translation,
unless otherwise noted.
Depicted on the cover is a graphic parable, which encapsulates the
thesis of this book. There looms the ghost of what once was a great oak.
What remains of it stands cold and bare, while the vines which caused its
death flourish about it. The parable that inspired this 'illustration comes
from the pen of a 16th century English Puritan preacher, Henry Smith,
whose own words now explain its meaning:
"For Christ said to his Disciples, Love one another, as I have loved
you. But it may be said of the Usurer, See how he hateth his brethem,
and hear how he loveth them: for he loveth them in words, and hateth
them in deeds. He sayeth that he loveth them, and that he lendeth for
compassion, but it is for compassion of himself, that he may gain by his
lending. The Usurer loveth the borrower, as the Ivy loveth the Oak: The
Ivy loveth the Oak to grow up by it, so the Usurer loveth the borrower to
grow rich by him. The Ivy claspeth the Oak like a lover, but it claspeth
out all the juice and sap, that the Oak can not thrive after: So the Usurer
lendeth like a friend, but he covenanteth like an enemy, for he claspeth the
borrower with such bands, that ever after he diminisheth, as fast as the
other increaseth."
This book will provide the attentive reader with answers to some of
the most puzzling questions that we face today about money and interest or
usury. This book was written because there is nothing else available today
which thoroughly covers this important topic from a foundation of God's
Word. How many investors today can remember their Pastor teaching on
the Biblical foundation for making interest-producing loans to individuals,
banks and other businesses? Is the Bible silent? No. Is the subject of
money and interest so far removed from the pressures and concerns of
every day life in modem America that it would be considered a distraction
from "real life" to provide instruction in these areas? No.
Traditionally, Pastors have lacked important economic related
instruction. One example of this lack is found in the otherwise
comprehensive Lectures on Calvinism, by the esteemed Abraham Kuyper.
This work was designed as a survey of the impact of the Christian faith in
all areas of life. The fields covered include theology, government, art, and
science. It is instructive to note that there is no section covering Biblical
faith as it relates to economic activity. In a similar vein, Gary North
laments that in all the centuries since the founding of the Church, there has
never been a economic commentary written on the books of the Bible.!
This neglect leaves Christians to borrow from the unbelieving world those
ideas which will be applied to the economic aspects of everyday life.
The lust for gain without pain is very powerful. Too often the Church
has no one to turn to when economic temptation presents itself. The truth
is that the vast majority of Pastors 1) have never been asked to study these
subjects in college or seminary and therefore 2) do not always recognize
the important need to understand them. We believe that everyone who uses
money, or aquires it through interest bearing investments, should both
understand the origin of money and be able to give an account regarding
righteousness of his actions. How can a man provide a godly witness
before an unbelieving world if his personal finances are not handled in a
distinctly, self-consciously Christian way?
Love characterizes God's covenant people; love must characterize any
truly Christian concept of economics. The sin which this book addresses
would not exist if we truly loved one another from the heart. As it is, we
have an economic system where profit for some depends on the continual
need of their brethren to borrow that which they lack. This is the effect of
usury on any and every sort of loan. Christians need to see that living this
way is not demonstrating God's truth to the world. What is more, the
prevalent notion is that usury is a normal aspect of an economy. However,
historically the church has long been opposed to usury by the conviction
that it is contrary to God's law. That is, the position taken here is not a
new one, but a call to return to what the church had believed for over a
thousand years.
It is no wonder when professing Christians ignore God's instructions
about loans, that instead of more affluence and freedom they receive higher
taxes, oppressive government, and more per capita indebtedness. The
United States is thought to be the world's wealthiest nation, while in reality
it is the world's greatest debtor. If the average citizen were proportionally
as far in the "red" as we are as a nation, every creditor who knew of his
plight would foreclose on all loans as fast as the paperwork could be
completed.
The United States is a nation under God's judgement and discipline.
Usury always leads to slavery. This time, because we have ignored God's
commands, we will end up the slaves. Every year a larger portion of
Christians' disposable income goes to support domestic and foreign debts.
Increasingly, the Internal Revenue Service relates more like the Pharaoh's
taskmasters toward citizens, churches, and Christian schools.
My hope is that righteousness might come to characterize our
economics as a Christian people. It is time that the Church teaches the
nations "to observe all that Christ has commanded". Let us no longer
borrow our economics from the world. Rather let them come to us for the
righteous economics of godly peace and prosperity. This is a goal to
which anyone involved in "Christian economics" would subscribe,
however, this goal cannot be realized as long as the sin of usury besets us.
This book is directed to the end that we would repent of usury as a people,
and achieve an economy in which all men love their neighbor as themselves
and thus fulfill the law of Christ.
David 8. Wiley
Director, Theopolis
God's Word tells us that, "When there are many words, transgression
is unavoidable" (Proverbs 10:19). Though the present writer has many to
thank for making possible the completion of this work (too numerous to
name), he nevertheless reserves to himself responsibility for the un-
avoidable transgressions.
Having already drawn upon the wit of Mr. Smith for the cover
concept, another appeal to him in the preface risks conveying to the reader
the mistaken impression that the present writing is but a narrow reiteration
of the Puritan position. Suffice it to say that the scope of this work is
much broader than that. Having so said, it is hoped that the reader once
again may appreciate the words of Henry Smith, whose introduction to his
sermons on usury is a most fit introduction to the spirit of the study which
follows.
Here thou hast the sermons which have been often desired, because of the
matter fit for this city. One sayeth, that he would never speak to usurers, and
bribe-mongers, but when they be upon their deathbeds: for he which liveth by
sin, resolveth to sin, that he may live. But when he goeth to hanging, Judas
will say, I have sinned. If I speak not to usurers upon their death-bed, yet I
speak to usurers which shall lie upon their death-bed. Three things do give me
hope. One is, that all hearts are in the hands of God, to call them at what hour
He list, and therefore Saul may become an Apostle. The next is, that the third
crow doth waken more than the former, and therefore after the crowing of
other, this crow may happily be heard. The last is, that there is no sin, but
some men have been reclaimed from it, and so may usurers from their sin.
Therefore go my book like David against Goliath, and fight the Lord's
battles against usurers. The Lord give that success to his doctrine in these
leaves, that it may consume usurers, as Joshua drove out the Canaanites before
him. If I could take but this one weed out of the Londoner's [American's]
garden, I were answered for my health and my strength spent amongst them.
Read with thy best mind, and thou shall profit more.
Foreword by David B. Wiley ii
Author's Preface v
Bibliography 240
Scripture Index 244
Subject Index 246
God commands us in Exodus 22:25, "If you lend money to My
people, to the poor among you, you are not to act as a creditor to him; you
shall not charge him interest." The KN puts it, "thou shalt not be to him
as an usurer, neither shalt thou lay upon him usury." Everyone agrees
that usury is a sin; that is, provided that everyone is allowed to define
usury for himself. Few, if any, would defend usury no matter how it is
defmed, but almost everyone would condemn usury according to some
definition. However, there is not a universal feeling that "interest" is
wrong. When the statute is expressed as prohibiting the charging of
"interest", it generally is supposed that this prohibition must hold only in
certain caSes. Some defme usury so that it may be lawful in certain cases,
and define "interest" so that it may be unlawful in certain cases. The
controversy over usury has centered on the problem of definition. In
order to receive the instruction of Exodus 22:25, and a number of other
texts, in their fullest sense, it is necessary that we understand what is
meant by "usury" in older translations, and "interest" in newer ones.
Gary North says, "The definition of usury is precise Biblically: any
increase taken from the poor in return for having made a loan." 1
Actually, "usury" is not defined in the Bible. It might be said that the
Bible circumstantially defines "usury", in the usage of the term in various
texts. It would be more true to say that the defmition of usury is as precise
as is one's interpretation of certain biblical texts. In the case of obscure,
little used words, their usage in context can give a clue as to their
meaning. However, the biblical terms which may be translated "usury"
are not of this type. In the case of usury, an exegetical problem arises
more from the fact that the economic teaching of God's Word comes to us
from a time when men had no discreet economic theories. Economics is a
young science. Usury in ancient times was not understood according to
discreet economical categories. The writers of the Bible did not have a
range of economically defined concepts from which to choose when
speaking on the subject. In their time there was nothing like the shades of
meaning between "interest" and "usury" that we have today. The modem
temptation is to read one's favorite economic doctrine back into the
Scriptures. Therefore, the order of the present discussion shall give a
treatment of the pertinent biblical texts only once the definition and
history of usury have been treated. This order does not imply a low view
of the Scriptures. The present writer holds to the orthodox confession,
that the Bible is the very word of God, inerrant in the original
manuscripts, and is man's only infallible rule for faith and practice. The
prior discussion of defmition and history is necessary because of the
misunderstandings of usury that are introduced by modem "interest
theories". That is, in order to gain an adequate understanding of the
requirement of Exodus 22:25, it is necessary that one know what is meant
by the terms "usury" or "interest", and yet the modem, popular
understanding of those terms is not sufficient.
It shall be difficult to exhaust the matter of the definition of usury
without going into the facts of its history. Indeed. a brief survey of
various ways of defining usury provides a general outline for the history
of usury. Usury is as ancient as civilization. From earliest records up to
the present, it has been understood to be an evil that lenders commit upon
borrowers. Variations of meaning occur within this general idea. The
popular conception of usury has evolved through the ages. The ancient
understanding of usury was largely an emotional one. Ancient thinkers
did not develop economic theories that were distinct from other
theoretical disciplines. Consequently, usury was considered nC?t
according to definite economic concepts, but according to its character as
it impacted the parties to a loan. This is illustrated by the language that
was used in ancient documents that treat of usury. There are two Hebrew
words that are translated "usury" in the Old Testament. Neshek spoke to
the character of usury vis-a-vis the borrower. Its root means literally "a
biting". In this tenn, the oppressive nature of usury was expressed. The
other word, Tarbith, has to do with the creditor's experience; it means
"increase".2 Numerous texts of ancient Mesopotamia, notably the
Babylonian Code of Hammurabi, deal with usury. The tenn in the
original language is Sibtu. It is related to another word, Asabu, that
means "to enlarge, to add, to increase in size or number". This parallels
the Hebrew Tarbith. Sibtu, however, carries a distinctly negative
connotation, as does the Hebrew Neshek. Besides its meaning of "usury",
it also means "attack" or "seizure" as in epilepsy, and also the violent
seizure of property by pirates. As well, it means "tax", "tribute" or
"levy", as a conqueror or lord would impose upon his vanquished.3 As
these tenns suggest, usury in ancient times was known for the hardship
and misery that it inevitably meant for borrowers, and the riches and
power that it meant for lenders. The difference between ancient Israel
and Babylon was simply that the fonner got her laws from God, and
consequently condemned usury, while the latter derived her laws from
pagan men, and accordingly pennitted and "regulated" usury.
This ethical and emotional conception of usury endured into the
medieval era, but near the close of this era economic theories began to
emerge into view. The technological advances in transportation and in
industry led to the maturation of the partnership in commercial
enterprise. Commercial activity stood to gain from loans of capital, but
such loans seldom were made because 1) lenders typically wanted usury
and 2) usury still had a bad reputation. In this context of developing
commerce, economical concepts also began to develop. The medieval
English tenn usury derived from the Latin usuria, and carried the more
theoretical idea of selling the use of property. In an attempt to rescue
money-lending from the stigma of "usury", an alternate concept was
Gary North faults the translators of the King James Version of the
Bible for translating the Greek Takos as "usury". He claims, "it doesn't
mean usury in the Greek; it means 'interest'. This is how modem
translations translate it. There is a difference between usury and interest."8
He goes on to suggest that, "Usury referred to interest taken from a poor
fellow believer, in other words, interest secured from a charitable loan."9
It is curious indeed how anyone can suggest that ancient writers knew
anything of modem distinctions between "interest" and "usury", when in
the Greek language there was but a single term -Takas - that was in use. It
is even more curious how the otherwise competent Dr. North can seriously
suggest that Takos means specifically" interest" .and not "usury". In fact,
its literal meaning is "birth". Thus, Christ is called the "firstborn" or
protatokas (Col.1:15). Would Gary North have us translate this "first-
interest"? Of course, neither would we give it as "first-usury". Translating
Takas as "usury" is interpretative of an ancient Greek metaphor. Our term
"usury" is more theoretically descriptive of the practice, whereas the
ancient concept was more visual. When more money is repaid than was
loaned, it was described by the metaphor that the money gave birth to more
money. Indeed, this metaphor was the basis of Aristotle's argument
against usury. His basic point was that money is barren, and thus does not
in fact beget more money. The point is that there is nothing in the Greek
itself to compel the translator to choose" interest" instead of "usury".
8. Gary North, Honest Money (Ft. Worth: Dominion Press & Nashville: Thomas
Nelson, 1986), p.70
9.ffiID
regardless of who borrowed it. As was noted, in the medieval era the
term "interest" was brought in as an alternative expression, though it is
evident that no real theoretical distinction between "interest" and "usury"
was entertained. In the 17th century, substituting "interest" for "usury"
was not meant to signify that there was any difference in theory or
practice, but only to give the one practice a less offensive appearance.
Roger Fenton published his A Treatise of Usurie in London in 1611, the
same year as the publication of the KJV. On the issue of terminology,
Fenton said of usurers,
They will not call it Usurie, lest the word should be offensive, or make the
thing odious. But it shall be termed Use or Usance in exchange, which are
smooth words as oyle [oil], never a biting letter in them. Or it shall be called
Interest, or Consideration, which are civill and mannerly terms, though by them
they meane indeed nothing else but plaine Usurie.10
The King James translators no doubt were acquainted with the term
"interest", which even in their day was still a fairly new term, but as well
they would have been acquainted with its intended utility as an escape
from the condemnation that was due to usury. "Usury" was the term that
had been in vernacular usage for centuries. They cannot be faulted for
choosing the common vernacular term (usury) that in its etymology
embodied a theoretical description of its meaning, rather than a lately
emerged alternate term (interest) whose only use was to avoid just
condemnation.
Gary North's peculiar understanding of the term "usury" was not the
understanding of the term held by English speaking people throughout the
medieval era. What they meant by "usury" is exactly what North means
by "interest". What North means by "usury" was unknown to the
medieval world, and consequently they had no word for it. Thus, the
King James translators were not, as Gary North charges, guilty of an
"error" in translation, and neither was it common until recently for men
10. Roger Fenton, A Treatise of U surie (1611; Norwood: Walter Johnson, inc.,
1975), p.4
to posit any legal or economical difference between "interest" and
"usury".
Nor will modern day moralizing suffice in a treatment of usury.
Modern moralists ignore a careful economic defmition of usury in favor
of a general concept of uncharitableness. G. K. Chesterton, for instance,
included greed, materialism, exploitation, etc. in a broad, ill-defined
concept that he called "usury".11 The problem with doing this is that it
turns a just opposition to "charging a fee for the use of property" into a
socialist opposition to "profit". A moralistic understanding of usury was
possible in ancient times since the oppressive consequences of usury
always were evident in the "natural economy". That is, usury could be
understood simply as a "biting" because the bite of usury always was
plainly evident. Today it is not so. In fact, early modern usury apologists
commonly based their arguments in favor of usury on the idea that in
business loans the bite of usury was gone. Since the borrower stood to
gain more in his enterprise than he had to pay in usury, they said, interest
on such loans no longer ought to be considered usury. However, usury
cannot be so sensuously understood any more than any other point of the
law, for in fact the "bite" of usury did not vanish with the emergence of
business borrowing; it merely became more difficult to recognize, since
the burden of it was distributed over the economy as a whole. The name
given to usury by the ancient Israelites (Neshek - a biting) is not
definitional, but a testimony to the calamity which necessarily attends
usury.
The only understanding of usury which will serve in a rigorous study
of its nature and history is the one which is proposed here: it is a fee that is
charged for the use of property; a "use charge", or as an obsolete Old
English term put it, "usance". Blackstone generally concurs, defming
usury as, ". : .when money is lent on a contract to receive not only the
principal sum again, but also an increase by way of compensation for the
use. "12 The weakness in Blackstone's definition is that it limits
consideration to loans of money. The present thesis goes beyond this to
From selling doth this lending also differ, because sale is a perpetuall
alienation of the propertie for a price. Lending is a free alienation for a time.
So that though lending and selling doe agree in this, that both doe alienate the
propertie with the use; yet in these two things they differ, that the one is liberall,
the other for a price; the one temporall, the other for ever.
It [the loan] differeth from exchange. Not only in time, as giving and
selling doth; but in the object; because exchange is the giving and taking of one
certaine thing for another. But in this kind of loane, only the like in the same
kind is required at the time appointed to be restored. Besides, in things
exchanged, there is some difference respected, either of kind, quality, or use;
which mooveth us to make an exchange. But in simple lending or mutuation,
both the same in kind, money for money, oyle for oyle, come for corne; the
same in quantitie, and the like in quality, so much and so good, without respect
of difference, is required. 14
16. Larry Burkett, Your Finances in Changing Times (Chicago: Moody Press,
1982), p.55
bondage in debt. BOlTowers, especially those who still can afford to make
their payments, do not see themselves as slaves; they think they are taking
shrewd advantage of "tax breaks". Also, many bOlTOWfearlessly,
knowing that modern bankruptcy laws will save them from indentured
servitude. If the proper idea of the loan were held in view, there would
not be a great crisis of debt in our land today, and neither would there be
rampant usury. If the loan were consistently held by the lender to be an
act of charity, then gain from his lending would be ruled out of
consideration for two reasons. First, with charity as a self-conscious
motive, the lender will not confuse his lending with either an exchange or
an investment, and thus will not expect to gain by it. Secondly, his motive
of charity will serve to keep him sensitive to the welfare of his debtor. He
would be careful not to aggravate the bondage of his debtor, and will
work with him to restore his freedom as quickly as possible. Usury does
not service such a motive; rather it totally subverts it. And, if the loan
were consistently held by the bOlTower to be a state of bondage for him,
then loans would be sought only in those cases where consequences of not
borrowing seem worse than the bondage of debt. If both elements were
held in view, the loan would be restored to its proper character, and usury
would be unthinkable.
The foregoing discussion defines usury, and as well provides a
rudimentary explanation of why it is wrong. Usury is a fee charged for
the use of property; it is wrong primarily because God's law prohibits it.
And it is not difficult for one to understand why it should be prohibited,
for usury contradicts the essential charity that lenders must have toward
their debtors. This gives a much better understanding of the requirement
of Exodus 22:25 (cited at the outset of this discussion) than that which
seems immediately to occur to the average modem reader. As soon as one
understands the nature of the requirement, the immediate response is a
profound sense of the need to repent. It becomes obvious that much that is
wrong with our economy today is directly the result of the sin of usury.
But, a powerful inertia that must be overcome is the assumption that usury
itself cannot be the problem. It has been an accepted institution for
several hundred years now. A brief survey of the history of usury will
help one rightly to esteem the merit of our present economy, and will aid
in his gaining a true conviction of God's law on the matter. The subject
shall be taken lip under three he;adings, viz. the three
of - Ancien!, Medieval, and Modem. The transitirms of economy
in paJrtic:ul,trthe evolution of the concept of shall
be noted. In this context the the laws, nature, and the
consequences usury shall be examined. Then the biblical texts
usury shaH be which treatment shall prove
co:ncllusivt~lythat usury unlawful.
Following the great flood, the earth once again was repopulated by
the sons of Noah; Shem, Ham, and Japheth. An incident in Noah's tent
revealed Ham to be a wicked man. Noah cursed Ham's offspring, and
ascribed a blessing to Shem and Japheth. A grandson of Ham was Nimrod
(Genesis 10:6-8), who became great and founded Babylon (v.IO). A
descendant of Shem, one of the blessed, was Abram (later known as
Abraham, Genesis 11: 10- 27). God made a covenant with Abram, to
make him a great nation and a blessing to all the earth (Genesis 12:1-3).
He called Abram out of Mesopotamia, specifically out of Ur, a sister city
with Babylon in the plain. It was in this "plain in the land of Shinar" that
the offspring of Ham gathered to build the Tower of Babel (Genesis 11: 1-
4). They sought to build this city and tower as a monument to themselves;
in order to make a name for themselves (vA). This was the ungodly
company out of which God called Abram. The godly, such as Abram and
his offspring, receive the name God bestows upon them; they do not seek
to make their own name. They do not seek to establish themselves in the
earth independently, but acknowledge their Creator who alone establishes
and displaces peoples and kingdoms according to His own good pleasure.
They receive their law from the mouth of God, rather than creating it out
of their own sinful minds. So it was that Abram listened to God, and
followed Him out of Ur. And so it was that God gave His law to Abram's
descendants, who became the people of God - Israel. Meanwhile, in
Babylonia sinful men were busy making their own laws, and becoming the
people - or rather the serfs - of their self-exalted rulers. From the depths
of their respective foundations to the furthest extent of their respective
structures, Israel and Babylon represent two utterly opposed and
irreconcilable religions, philosophies, and law-systems. They may be
spoken of in the broad generalities suggested to us by Augustine - "The
City of God", and "the earthly city". 1 Their differences may be explored
endlessly, however the present purpose is to recount the impetus each has
given to the phenomenon of usury. Israel, as The City of God, held in the
law of God the fountain of all opposition to usury, which endures to this
day. Babylon, with its antithetical Code of Hammurabi, became the
originator of usury apd the cultivator of idolatrous plunder and
covetousness, also which endures to this day. It shall be instructive to
explore these two sources, for their respective characters shall add
convincing proofs of the unlawfulness of usury.
According to the modem perspective "interest" commonly is thought
of in terms of a loan of money, however, "interest", or usury, was present
in ancient economies as far back as records go; even before there was any
such thing as money. Earliest records show that ancient trade at first was
what now is called "barter". As civilization began reconstruction
following the flood (Genesis 9-11) each household generally produced
what it needed. This included growing or hunting food, constructing
shelters, and manufacturing clothing, vessels, and other household
articles. Men were able to imagine greater quality and quantity of goods
than they actually were able to produce. This is not surprising, since men
still experience such limitations to this day. However, the ancient
limitations were much more restrictive than what are now experienced.
Back then, men were for the most part limited to whatever natural
resources they had on hand, and were resigned to produce only those
articles as their own personal talents would allow. The desire for
abundance of quality as well as quantity - whatever the motivation -
sparked the creativity of men to overcome the limits that they
experienced. They learned to accumulate a surplus of easily produced
goods, and trade them in barter for other goods that were needed. For
instance, one who was particularly talented in making rope could feel
fairly secure in devoting a substantial portion of his time and energy to
rope-making because he knew that others similarly were devoting
themselves to making other things, for which he could trade his surplus of
rope. Also, men of one region could concentrate on the production of
goods that required natural resources which were indigenous to their
land, and trade the surplus of them for goods produced in other regions
with resources that they themselves lacked. For instance, an area rich in
iron ore could produce an abundance of goods, such as tools, that are
useful all over the world, and trade from their surplus for some other
goods, like spices, which are found only in another part of the world. In
this way, a great variety of expertly made goods was made available all
over the then known world. This was what economists call a "natural
economy".
All was not, however, one happy household. The sinfulness of men
had expanded the violence which Cain had perpetrated upon Abel into a
deep-set enmity among peoples. In the manner of "the earthly city", some
men sought to exalt themselves by means of subjugating other men. The
needs of men's military pursuits provided the necessity which became the
mother of invention. Transportation methods, particularly sea travel,
began to be developed, though they would require centuries to perfect.
Advancing technologies and methods not only made military campaigns
more successful, but also provided for more efficient transportation of
goods. However, travel by any means was hazardous over great distances,
due to roving pirates and bandits. The strong centralized governments of
the ancient world realized the advantages of vigorous trade, and provided
security for the transportation of goods.
Such security was effective against alien threats, however, kingdom
after kingdom in the ancient world succumbed to internal strife and
disintegration. The causes of such internal turmoil were many, but
certainly not the least cause was usury. One historian maintains: "Interest
probably originated in Babylonia, and debt and excessive interest were
burdensome. The usual rate was twenty per cent, though higher rates
were frequent. "2 The pagan religious order was the center of life,
including commercial life. Their pagan temples served also as banks, and
3. The Reader is reminded of the significance of italics in the New American Standard
translation. It indicates a word supplied by the translators that does not occur in the
original text.
The complaint of the borrowers arose, "And now our flesh is like the
flesh of our brothers, our children like their children. Yet behold, we are
forcing our sons and daughters to be slaves, and some of our daughters
are forced into bondage already, and we are helpless because our fields
and vineyards belong to others." (v.5) Nehemiah discerned the nature of
the problem. ''Then I was angry when I heard their outcry and these
words. And I consulted with myself, and contended with the nobles and
the rulers and said to them, 'You are exacting usury, each from his
brother!' Therefore, I held a great assembly against them." (v.6,7) In the
assembly Nehemiah explained to them their sin of usury, and demanded
that they not only repent, but also return the fields and vineyards that
were seized through usury. It is evident that this was a remnant of the
City of God, for their repentance came quickly and cheerfully. The
repentant usurers declared, "We will give it back and will require nothing
from them; we will do exactly as you say." (v.12) Their society was
healed of this sin, and was restored.
Countless times pagan societies were in this same situation, and
instead of humility and repentance, there was revolution, bloodshed, and
chaos. The City of God calls her inhabitants to exalt not themselves, but
God. The people of God are to act not according to the base instincts of
their sinful hearts, but are to instruct their hearts with the law of God. In
keeping with their paganism, godless people indulge in self-gratification.
The restraining influence of their man-made laws usually arises from
practical necessity; sometimes it is practical to oppose usury rather than to
risk revolution. Ancient history records numerous instances when debts
were forgiven. This usually happened when power changed hands, and
power changed hands not only after wars, but after debtor uprisings as
well. Debt forgiveness was a very popular tactic for new rulers, but in
pagan societies it only mimicked godly justice. Such remissions were
cheap imitations of God's law, which were born not of righteousness, but
of pragmatic necessity. As such they were witnesses against the essentially
pagan and godless economies that spawned their necessity. In ancient
Babylonia, these edicts of remission of debts were called misarum, which
literally means "justice" or "equity".4 If the cancellation of debts was
called "justice" by the ancient Babylonians, it is little wonder that they
called the usury itself sibtu , a "seizure".
By the time of the height of Babylonia (about 2000 B.c.) trade had
developed to the point that men began to "mediate" their exchanges with
goods that had more or less universal appeal. In Babylonia this was silver.
This was not in coins, but lumps, and was traded by weigh~. Babylonia
achieved a highly developed and active trade, which was served by an
elaborate system of weights and measures. The well known "shekel" was
part of this system. (In Genesis 23:16 Abraham bought a burial site for
Sarah for "four hundred shekels of silver"). This was an example of a
most significant trade development known as "mediation of exchange".
This type of exchange was devised to overcome further limitations on the
productive creativity of man. Personal limitations were answered by
trading with other people and other lands, as was noted above. But the
possibilities that this created only served eventually to reveal in time a
new type of limitation. If men acquire goods from other men through
trade, what can be done if one cannot easily find another who desires what
he has to offer? Cunningham illustrates this problem of the exchange: "I
have a coat which I want to exchange for bread; you have bread which you
want to exchange for boots; unless a third party comes on the scene it may
be impossible for us to arrange any terms at all."5 Cunningham goes on to
recount an anecdote from the ancient market concerning an unfortunate
would-be trader: "He may be seen wandering in the Bazaar with a ball of
beeswax in his hand for days together, because he can't find anybody
willing to take it for the exact article he requires."6 R.C. Sproul, Jr.
theorizes how an ancient hermit economist might have addressed such a
problem. He comes up with a most improbable solution,
8. Will Durant, The Story of Civilization (New York: Simon & Shuster, 1954),
YoU, p.15
9. James B. Pritchard, ed., Ancient Near Eastern Texts (Princeton: Princeton
University Press, 1969), p.169
effect rather than righteousness. They desired to maximize wealth,
produced by the sweat of debtors, short of causing them to revolt.
The pagan societies of ancient Greece and Rome found themselves
burdened by the problem of usury. For their model, Greece and Rome
adopted the way of "the earthly city". Herrick reports, "A writer on
ancient law says that there is no legal conception or legal transaction of the
Roman law at the height of its development that does not find its
counterpart in Babylon."lO Durant concurs, saying of ancient Greek
banking, "The temples serve as banks, and lend to individuals and states at
a moderate interest ... Meanwhile the money-changer at his table
(trapeza ) begins in the fifth century [B.c.] to receive money on deposit,
and to lend it to merchants at interest rates that vary from 12 to 30 per
cent according to the risk ... He takes his methods from the Near East,
improves them, and passes them on to Rome, which hands them down to
modern Europe."ll Whether the alterations made by the Greeks are to be
considered "improvements" is a matter of perspective. Certain aspects of
the development (e.g. the benefit of coinage) would be considered an
improvement, even in the City of God, but such benefits hardly are worth
adopting the general Babylonian economy in sum.
Prior to the rise of Greece, exchange of goods was mediated with a
number of substances, but mainly silver and gold, as was noted above. It
also was noted that the introduction of mediation alleviated to some
degree the limitations of barter. However, when a gross problem is
solved, a more delicate problem is revealed. In this case, once the benefits
of exchange media became commonplace, the awkwardness and cumber-
somness of the media became more and more of a nuisance. Silver and
gold were traded by weight. That meant that there had to be a balance and
a set of standard weights on hand at every exchange. This not only was
inconvenient, but provided many opportunities for cheating. The weights
could be altered by the seller so that the buyer was tricked into giving
more silver than he thought he was giving, or they could be altered by the
buyer so that the seller was cheated. Also the silver itself could be altered
so that the lumps or bars were in reality only silver covered. Such
The poor, finding their situation worse with each year - the government
and the army in the hands of their masters, and the corrupt courts deciding
every issue against them - began to talk of a violent revolt, and a thoroughgoing
redistribution of wealth. The rich, unable any longer to collect the debts legally
due them, and angry at the challenge to their savings and their property,
invoked ancient laws, and prepared to defend themselves by force against a
mob that seemed to threaten not only property but all established order, all
religion, and all civilization. 15
. . . the holy and great council has decided that if anyone after the
publication of this decree receives interest for the services of a loan, or engages
in the business of usury in any way, or demands half again as much, or devises
any other scheme for fJ1thylucre, he is to be deposed from the clerical estate,
and his name stricken from the register.21
21. cited in, W.A. Jurgens, The Faith of the Early Fathers (Collegeville: The
Liturgical Press, 1970), YoU, p.254,255,286
22. Cleary, p.45
steps to transform the realm into a true "City of God". The social unrest,
due in part to usury, was never effectively addressed, as in the case of
Greece under Solon. The wage and price controls of Diocletian were a
failure, and legislation was enacted, and later confirmed by Constantine,
that cast the average tenant farmer into a virtual serfdom. This, along
with the decentralization resulting from the Barbarian conquest of the
Empire, ushered in the medieval era.
With the Barbarian conquest of Rome, the centralized control that
Rome had over virtually the entire then-known world was broken.
Broken along with the control also was the trade and commerce that rode
upon the imposed unity of the state. The Barbarian clans were pagan,
independent, and had very narrow loyalties. As well, they were virtually
self-sufficient in their chosen way of life. Trade among them was sparse,
and trade among others that required the transportation of goods through
the regions which the Barbarians controlled was nearly impossible and
highly risky. Thus, Europe plunged back into a "natural economy".
Coinage virtually disappeared. The Mediterranean Sea still provided an
avenue for trade in the Near East, but the emergence of Islam about this
time proved to hamper trading expeditions. What was left of Rome
reorganized around Constantinople as Byzantinum, and was distinctly
Christian in makeup. Both Islam and Byzantinum held their respective
religious values and principles in higher esteem than anything that
cooperative trade could have brought them, and their intense rivalry
severely hampered the fonner highly active trade.
The Byzantine empire achieved a high degree of Christianization,
relative to ancient societies as a whole. Economically, she had repudiated
the dishonest weights and measures of coin debasement, and maintained a
coinage of integrity for generations. The Byzantine Emperor, Justinian,
authored a body of law which preserved much of old Roman law and
incorporated a distinctly Christian conscience. However, Justinian's
approach to the matter of usury was more Babylonian than Christian.
Rather than prohibit usury, he attempted to regulate it. Perhaps it was
that he failed to correct the toleration of usury that was present in Roman
law at the time of her fall. Islam. on the other hand stood rigidly opposed
to usury. even though they exhibited a distinctly false religion.
Traditional Islamic law prohibits usury to this day. It would be simplistic
to say that for this reason alone Islam eventually won out over
Byzantinum. however it is at least interesting to note that those who came
to dominate trade in the Near East at this time were those who were
committed to carry it on without usury.
Meanwhile. in Europe. the decentralization of Barbarism was offset
only by the tight unity of the church that persisted over the continent.
Continuing the position of the ancient "Church Fathers" and the decrees of
the early councils. the church remained adamantly opposed to usury.
However, church censure of usurers remained directed mainly to the
clergy. Usury persisted among the laity without any specific censure by
the church. As was pointed out above. this was not due to any lack of
conviction on the matter. but because the church was reluctant to
contradict the toleration of usury in the Roman law. This eventually was
corrected during the reign of Charlemagne.
Charlemagne's rule was like an oasis amid the confusion and
backwardness of the early Middle Ages. He ascended by means of
military conquests. In Roman fashion he imposed unity upon the
splintered European states. Being a man of faith. he utilized his great
power to assure the growth of the church. and with it also there grew a
close church-state alliance. On Christmas day. 800 AD. Pope Leo III
crowned Charlemagne Emperor of what was considered a reorganized
Roman Empire. Charlemagne's civil laws. the Capitularies. repeatedly
prohibited usury. An enhancement of what had been the church's position
all along was that Charlemagne extended the censure to include laymen.
As Cleary put it. "The great characteristic of the period was the
prohibition of the practice of usury even for the laity. In 789 it was
decreed at Aix-Ia-Chapelle 'that each and all are forbidden to give
anything on usury'; and a capitulary of 813 reinforces the prohibition.
'not only should the Christian clergy not demand usury. laymen should
not.' "1 Punishments for usurers were severe, but this did not eliminate
usury. The close unity of the state, however, kept the ravages of usury to
a minimum.
In Charlemagne's rule there was great promise of fulfillment of the
ideals of "The City of God". This was evident not only in the case of
usury, but in the character of his reign on the whole. He combatted
illiteracy, established schools through the monasteries, and directed their
masters: "Take care to make no difference between the sons of serfs and
of freemen, so that they might come and sit on the same benches to study
grammar, music, and arithmetic. "2 Durant further characterizes the
Emperor himself: "he gave himself also, with never aging enthusiasm, to
science, law, literature, and theology; he fretted at leaving any part of the
earth, or any section of knowledge, unmastered or unexplored ... there
was in his thought and speech a directness and honesty seldom permitted
to statesmanship. "3 It is little wonder that he came to be known as
"Charlemagne", an adaptation of the Latin "Charles the Great". In his old
age he divided his kingdom between three sons. Two of them died before
their father, and the third, though incompetent, ascended to the
Emperorship months before Charlemagne's death. Charlemagne's shoes
proved too large for anyone to fill. The unity and character that his
kingdom had achieved began to crumble. Barons took advantage of the
ineptness of his successors to reassert their own lordship and the serfdom
of their tenants. Trade and commerce that had begun to revive in the
context that Charlemagne's rule provided now began to falter. Though he
had reinstituted a silver coinage modeled after the old Roman system, his
single lifetime was not enough to revive a "money economy". Europe was
once again fractured into hundreds of feudal manors. These manors were
mostly self-sufficient in their production of goods and in their legal
structures. Trade was once again virtually impossible. Transportation
was difficult because of a lack of security, and because of the ill-repair of
roads. Each manor exacted a toll for the passage of goods, so goods could
1. Rev. P. Cleary, The Church and Usury (1914; Hawthorn: The Christian Book Club
of America, 1972), p.60
2. Will Durant, The Story of Civilization (New York: Simon & Shuster. 1954).
Vol.IV. p.466
3. mID, p.470
not go very far without being consumed by tolls. Without a unified state,
the decree of the church against usury could not be enforced. Men of
conscience, citizens of the "City of God", voluntarily could abide by the
teaching of the church, but these were pitifully few. Most proved
themselves to be inhabitants of Babylon, "the earthly city", and found
ways to indulge in usury while escaping the stigma of church censure.
Two popular schemes were the "repurchase agreement" and the "gift".
Earlier, the "repurchase agreement" was described. The lender "buys"
some article from the borrower, "cash on the barrel head", and then
"sells" it back to him for a higher price, to be paid in installments over a
period of time. In the second case, usury is disguised as a "gift". The loan
is made out to be without usury, but by prior agreement the borrower
bestows a "gift" on the lender to expression his "appreciation" to the latter
for his making the loan. These and other equally subtle tricks were used
by the covetous to keep usury alive during this time of its universal
unpopularity.
A blessing in disguise was the threat of Islam in the East in the 9th
and 10th centuries, for conquests which they had begun to make into
Europe provided the necessity for Europe to unify against a common
enemy. The sum of European trade at the time was carried on as barter
among feudal manors at periodic "fairs". Usury was producing the
typical social stratification and debtor misery, and was not financing
anything in the way of commercial enterprise. However, there was a
manifest necessity to fmance the enterprise of the Crusades, to secure
safety for life and honor for the Christian religion. Usury was so high
that no one would voluntarily enter into debt. Those who did acted out of
desperation, to meet an urgent need. In order to gather the resources
needed to carry out the expeditions, loans were offered at no usury. The
Crusades were successful to the extent of driving Islam out of Europe.
The Crusade expeditions also served to unify Europe politically. The
various nations of the continent began to take form, providing more
uniform government and laws over wider regions.
With a stronger state came also a stronger church. The church,
relentless through the centuries in her opposition to usury, began to speak
out once again. Typical of her outspokenness in this period is a decree
from the second Lateran Council of 1139, "We denounce that detestable
and disgraceful rapacity condemned alike by human and divine law, by
the Old and the New Testament, that insatiable rapacity of usurers, whom
we hereby cut off from all ecclesiastical consolation; and we order that no
archbishop, that no bishop, or abbot, or cleric, shall presume to receive
back usurers except with the very greatest caution, that on the contrary
usurers are to be regarded as infamous and shall if they do not repent be
deprived of Christian burial."4 A third Lateran Council in 1179 issued a
similar denounciation, adding: "... we ordain that manifest usurers shall
not be admitted to communion, nor if they die in their sins receive
Christian burial, and that no priest shall accept their alms."S
This was the period of the "Scholastics" in the church, notable among
whom was Thomas Aquinas. Aquinas addressed virtually every
theological and legal topic in his voluminous writings, and not
surprisingly addressed the topic of usury as well. Characteristic of the
work of the Scholastics as a whole was the revival of classical ideologies.
They drew liberally upon the Greek philosophers and Roman law.
Aquinas has been charged with polluting the faith by attempting the
marriage of Scripture and Aristotle.6 The present writer concurs with
this analysis of Aquinas, yet critics generally agree with supporters that
Aquinas had a keen and penetrating intellect, and spoke with great
learning on a vast variety of subjects. His treatment of usury was
characterized by both his great insight and his appeal to classical thought.
He drew upon Aristotle's argument concerning the barrenness of money
in order to provide some theoretical underpinnings to the church's
opposition to usury. Up to his day, opposition to usury consisted merely
of expressions of outrage over the ruthlessness of creditors and the misery
of debtors. The only theoretical basis for this opposition was a simple
appeal to the law of God. As was noted earlier, Aristotle's argument was
not very developed, and Aquinas elaborated upon it, drawing also upon
Roman law.
Aquinas' analysis set a new tone for the discussion of usury, for he
treated it as a problem of law; "... it is by its very nature unlawful to take
4. Cleary, p.64
S. IBID
6. for one such thesis see Francis A. Schaeffer, Escape From Reason (Downers Grove:
IVP,1968)
payment for the use of money, which payment is known as usury: and just
as a man is bound to restore other ill-gotten goods, so is he bound to
restore the money which he has taken in usury."7 The former estimation
of usury, that was focused on the emotional impact of its character, did
not distinguish various legal circumstances under which usury was
exacted. Under Roman law, the loan had become a civil contract, and the
code distinguished four different kinds of loans. John T. Noonan, Jr.
explains: "The Roman law had known two parallel gratuitous contracts
and two parallel onerous contracts: the commodatum by which a good
was freely and temporarily transferred as to its use, and the mutuum by
which a good was freely and temporarily transferred as to its ownership;
the locatio, in which the commodatum was replaced by a charge for the
use, and the foenus , in which by an added, positive stipulation a premium
was charged for the 10an."8 The name "mutuum" was a play on words in
Latin. It was a contraction of the words "Mine" and "Thine". The essence
of the contract of mutuum was that "mine becomes thine". In other
words, the good loaned transferred not only as to use, but as to possession
and ownership as well.
The nucleus of Aquinas' argument was that usury (foenus) was
unwarranted in the case of mutuum because the use of the good cannot be
separated from the good itself. For example, the loan of bread is a
contract of mutuum since the use of the bread cannot be carried out
without consuming the bread. One cannot sell the use of the bread to
another while retaining ownership of it himself. In the case of loaning
bread "mine becomes thine". Repayment of the loan restores a like
quantity and quality of bread to the lender, but, assuming the bread was
used, it would not be possible to restore to the lender the very bread that
was used. The class of such goods is what is termed "fungibles". It was
argued that money belongs to this class since no borrower uses money
(according to its normal use) without divesting himself of it, and no
creditor expects to receive back the very coins that were loaned. Since
9. C.A. Herrick, History of Commerce and Industry (New York: Macmillan Co.
1920), p.145
10. W. Cunningham, The Growth of English Industry and Commerce (1910; New
York; A.M. Kelly, 1968), VoLl, p.199-208,286
doubt that they were cruelly used by the kings to generate revenues and
credit. But as well, their usurious practices caused much misery. In their
absence, usury continued under Christians, and more pressure was
brought to allow usury in certain cases, in particular the "business loan".
The enhanced arguments against usury provided by the Scholastics,
the strict outlawing of usury in the civil sphere, and the expulsion of
usurers from much of Europe, together made the prospects of
moneylenders appear rather dim indeed. Economic theory of usury had
not even begun to develop at this point, and it was difficult for anyone to
argue with the new contention that usury was necessary in order for
commerce to carry on, or that usury on "business loans" does not "bite",
and therefore ought not to be censured. There was a perverse sense in
which it did not seem "fair" that one who loaned money for a business
enterprise should not share in the profits of the venture. (Of course, the
same fair-minded concern was not so quick to call upon the moneylender
to share also in the losses of a venture that failed.) With no economic
theory in place, on which one might judge these notions, it was difficult
indeed not to succumb to their reasonings. One by one, special allowances
were made by which a moneylender might legitimately claim a payment
over and above the principal, which was not to be considered usury and
not liable under the usury laws. These allowances came to be known as
"Extrinsic Titles".
Cleary explains: "If any surplus might be taken, its legality arose not
from the contract of mutuum, but from a collateral contract, express or
implied, entitling the lender to compensation for losses incurred through
special circumstances extrinsic to the nature of the fundamental
contract."ll Principally, there were four such titles: Damnum Emergens
(accrued damages), Lucrum Cessans (lost profit), Poena Conventionalis
(penalty by agreement, basically a late fee), and Periculum Sortis
(compensation for risk). Theologians had debated these "Extrinsic Titles"
for centuries, but it was the late Middle Ages before they came into
general acceptance in the church and into popular usage. The first two
were entitlements to compensatory payments based on, first, damages
suffered by the lender because he made the loan, and second, the loss of
profits the lender might have realized if the loan was not made. Payment
under both of these titles was known as "interess". That word ought to
look vaguely familiar to the average reader. It means literally,
"compensatory payment"12, and is the source of the term "interest". It
came into usage under Extrinsic Titles in order to distinguish such
payments from usury. Today, the term "interest" is used to mean
precisely what "usury" meant in the medieval era. Compensatory
payments are not wrong or usurious in principle, but become so when
they leave the lender with more than what he loaned. If an article loaned
is damaged by the borrower, then return of the article plus a recompense
for damages will leave the lender the equivalent of what he had in the first
place. Appeal to these titles in order to reap gains on loans was simply
usury in disguise.
Poena Conventionalis was a late blooming title which stipulated that
the lender was due a fine if the borrower did not repay the loan by an
agreed upon due date. This one was particularly abused by the usurers.
As soon as it was recognized as a legitimate claim to compensation,
moneylenders began to grant loans with no usury on the condition that
they were to be repaid the next day. The borrower generally needed the
loan and readily agreed to such terms. Of course, the loan was not repaid
on time, the compensatory payments began, and the usurer was guiltless
before the letter of the law. That is how it works in "the earthly city", but
such still is usury before God, for it is usury that emanates from such a
lender's heart. It is the hearts of His people on which God writes His laws,
and it is the heart which He searches as Convictor and Judge. This title
operated solely as an excuse for usury, for there is no quantifiable damage
that arises in missing a due date. If the lender suffers other damages
because the loan was not repaid on time, that is another matter. Examples
would fill many pages, as each case would require individual
consideration. However, the tardiness of repayment itself cannot entitle
the lender to anything in addition to the principal.
Last to be accepted as a legitimate title, and for good reason since it is
so far fetched, is Periculum Sortis, or compensation for risk. The
eventual acceptance of this was a cause of celebration for usurers whose
pragmatism had prevented them from "risking" the practice of usury
amid the powerful sentiments against it. Now everyone could be a usurer
who wanted to be one, for anyone who granted a loan bore a risk. But, by
what logic does the risk bourne by the lender take precedence over the
risks experienced by the borrower? Herrick reports that conditions of
trade were so hazardous in the Middle Ages, that "Some held that if
money was loaned and at the end of a given period it was returned, an
obligation was due from the lender, for the borrower had been subject to
the danger and inconvenience of keeping the money, and therefore the
lender should pay interest".l3 A discussion to follow will handle this
matter of risk in greater detail. It will suffice in the present discussion
simply to assert that compensation on the basis of risk is unfounded.
This liberalization of usury laws under "Extrinsic Titles" was not
unopposed, nor was it without its own difficulties. Cunningham reports
that loans at usury for business purposes became a stumbling block to
many young, inexperienced traders. They easily became over-extended,
and many bankruptcies resulted.l4 The reasoning that usury was good for
trade held together as long as traders who owed usury were successful.
Those whose ventures failed found themselves deeply in debt, and the
usurer who wanted to justify his claim to a share of the profits now
became only a creditor demanding payment. Also, this idea of the
necessity of usury for trade was not totally without critics. Roger Fenton
contended as convincingly as was possible at the time that usury enriches
the usurer at the expense of the community. For him, an argument to
justify usury because of an alleged necessity was incredible.
Circumstances do not define good and evil. Since God's word already had
defined usury to be sin, Fenton rightly wonders, "if men or estates have
drawne a necessity of sinning upon themselves by the custome of sinne;
doth this extenuate or aggravate the fault?"15 The obvious reply is that
none of the contingencies of human life may be regarded as "extenuating
circumstances", and thus our responsibility before God remains.
19. cited in F.W. Ryan, Usury and Usury Laws (New York: Houghton Mifflin, Co,
1924), p.49·50
arguments that require treatment such as the present writing in order to
rebuff them.
The interface between the medieval and modem eras is rather fuzzy.
The beginning of the modem era may be marked with the Industrial
Revolution, the colonization of the New World, or a number of other
historical pointers. For the present purposes, modem times shall begin
with the advent of modem banking. The development of banking had
begun along with the recovery of trade in the late Middle Ages, and with
changes in national monetary systems. The next discussion shall cover
these developments in order to provide some continuity to the account of
modem banking and the impact it has on the problem of usury.
The recovery of a "money economy" in late medieval Europe was
attended by two other developments which were missing from the "money
economy" of the ancient world: 1) a greatly refined paper making
process, and 2) the invention of the printing press. The impact of paper
and the printing press has been felt in economics nearly as much as it has
in publishing. The phrase "paper money" is a subtle contradiction of
terms. It was noted that "money" strictly defined is gold and silver in coin
form. Nothing that is made out of paper can qualify as money. Another
question is: can paper serve the same purpose as money? There is some
intrigue in this notion that has resulted in attempts to circulate paper
instead of money ever since it was mechanically possible to do so. Hans
Sennholz explains, "...the universal use of paper monies today was made
possible only by their prior use as substitutes for real money, such as gold
and silver, for which there was an industrial demand. Only when men
grew accustomed to these substitutes, and governments deprived them of
their freedom to employ gold and silver as media of exchange, did paper
emerge as the only exchange medium."l Advocates of "paper money"
persist in modern times. For the most part, they indulge in the fantasy
that "money" functions merely as a token, and does not need to possess any
"intrinsic value", As a first step in understanding the economic changes in
the dawning of the modem era, some modem misunderstandings about
the history of money shall be examined. Two cases in point are theories
concerning the clay tablets of ancient Babylon and the "tally sticks" of
medieval England.
Ancient Babylon, "the earthly city", made extensive use of clay
tablets for the purpose of recording contracts and debts. The function of
these clay tablets was much the same as modem-day checks and
promissory notes. In fact one historian has said, "Babylonia was thus the
motherland of our modem commercial usages and commercial paper."2
While it perhaps is true that in concept paper money-substitutes are
begotten of Babylonian economics, it also is the case that in Babylonia clay
tablets were record-keeping devices, and did not circulate as exchange
media. A modern writer, RK. Hoskins, goes too far when he remarks
concerning Babylonian banks, "These banks offered almost every service
offered by banks today including the use of checking, savings, letters of
credit, and the Babylonian form of paper money - the clay tablet. The
banks kept the gold - naturally."3 In the first place, Babylonia had a silver
based economy, not gold. Secondly, while the clay tablets serviced all of
the banking functions that Hoskins lists; they were not used as money.4
Ancient men came by their goods with much difficulty. Production
techniques were burdensome, and the transportation of goods was
dangerous. An ancient man would not give real goods in exchange for
someone's promise to pay him later, recorded on a clay tablet, unless he
consciously was giving the other a loan.
Another misunderstanding of history that is used to promote "paper
money" involves the "tally sticks" of medieval England. These were
wooden sticks that were notched along one side and split lengthwise. One
half was kept in the royal treasury and the other in private hands. Since
the notches on both halves were to match, there was little likelihood that
the data encoded on the sticks could be corrupted. What was the function
of these tally sticks? Thoren and Warner, in The Truth in Money Book
5. Thoren & Warner, The Truth in Money Book (Chagrin Falls: Truth in Money, Inc.,
1984), p.228
6. British Museum Publications, 1978
7. Wm. Cunningham, The Growth of English Industry and Commerce (1910; New
York: A.M. Kelly, 1968), Vol. I, p.156,157
process of evolution is fairly subtle, and deserves some elaboration, for
the onset of "paper money" in modem times has served to provide the
"bite" of usury with a seemingly innocuous mask. "Paper money" has
tended to slow the inevitable upheaval that usury causes in a society,
because, as usurers absorbed too much of the available "money", more
could be printed. In order more fully to understand the dangers of this
false solution, its origins must be considered.
The use of paper to record debts greatly expanded in the late
medieval and early modem eras, along with greatly expanding trade and
newly emerging industry. Levels of wealth in silver and gold were
beginning to be amassed such as was not seen since ancient times. But the
advantages of these media as a store of wealth also presented a new
problem of security. Not only could great wealth reside in a relatively
small place in the form of silver and gold coins, but as well, great wealth
could fairly easily be stolen in the form of silver and gold coins. Not only
did these exchange media provide a convenience to the merchant, but to
the thief also. Metal smiths, who's livelihood involved large quantities of
silver and gold. had installed security measures such as vaults. It
happened that those who had a security problem with their money made
arrangements with metal smiths so that the smiths would store the money
in their vaults. Of course a receipt was issued entitling the owner to the
correct 'quantity of money. This receipt was the basic paper record of a
claim to money.
Another type of this paper record was the "bill of exchange". As
commerce spread over greater and greater distances, it began to
encompass not only all of Europe, but to reach beyond the Mediterranean
Sea and the Atlantic Ocean. The shipment of goods over these distances
still was hazardous, but not to the extent as the shipment of silver and
gold. In order to alleviate the problem of shipping large quantities of
silver or gold, merchants began to accept "bills of exchange" instead of
immediate payment for their goods. These bills entitled them to payment
of the correct sum through one of the buyer's associates in a location that
was closer to home for the merchant. In this transaction, one party would
give up goods and in return he would receive but a piece of paper. This
sort of thing was unthinkable in earlier centuries due to the lack of any
certainty whatever that the promise to pay ever would be made good. It
became thinkable to receive paper in return for goods only by the
organization of the metal smiths into larger and internationally associated
banks. The utility of the bill of exchange depended on the confidence of
the participants in the system. Lacking the confidence that a bill could be
redeemed for money, a merchant hardly would accept one in exchange
for goods.
Actually, such an arrangement was not an exchange. It was the
initiation of an exchange, but the exchange would not be complete until
the bill was redeemed for money_ Once the buyer has his goods and the
seller has his money, and only then, could it be said that there was an
exchange. That may sound like an irrelevant technicality, however, the
reader must remember his own context. The late 20th century man does
not view paper "money" as a contract or a promissory note. As its
appellation implies, it is viewed as if it were itself money. However, the
medieval and early modem merchant had no such concept. For him the
value of the bill of exchange lay in its promise of a future payment of
money (silver or gold coin).
The convenience of receipts for deposit of money and bills of
exchange served to reveal other inconveniences. Both the receipts and the
bills entitled a particular person to a particular sum of money. But, if one
had the confidence to hold paper for a time to represent his claim on
money, he could expect that those with whom he dealt also would be
willing to do so, and in most cases it was likely that they already were
doing so in the matter of their own personal accounts. So, in making a
purchase locally, why not simply sign over one's receipt for money to the
seller, instead of getting the money out of the vault, handing it over to the
seller, and him turning around and depositing it back into the vault under
his name? Or, in the case of bills of exchange, would it not be
advantageous if they were useful in the course of one's journey - to be
exchanged for goods in the same manner in which one originally had
received them? The problem to be overcome was the constant noting and
dating each use of the paper in exchange, in order to identify the new
payee. Certain changes in the makeup of the paper were needed in order
to make them more suitable for this purpose. First, they had to be made
anonymous, entitling whomever had them in their possession to the
money which they claimed. Secondly, they had to refer to standard
denominations of money instead of a particular account balance or the
price of a particular sale. In this way, various combinations of the bills
could better serve transactions of any amount. These changes greatly
facilitated trade, however, they also made for a subtle change in the nature
of bank paper. Now, instead of bank paper representing the claim of a
particular person for a specific quantity of money, it now represents the
money itself. If money, in standard denominated units, was payable on
demand to whomever held a piece of paper which represented it, then
once again a convenience for trade proves also to be a convenience for the
thief. The reason that the silver and gold is in the vaults is in order to
secure it from thieves. If pieces of paper are out in general circulation,
which represent the silver and gold, and which carry the commitment to
pay the silver and gold, on demand, to whomever has the paper in his
hand, then the security problem is presented all over again. Now a vault is
needed in which one may secure his anonymous paper receipts and bills
from thieves.
The entrance of banks into the exchange of goods by providing
redeemable paper signals the beginnings of an economy of questionable
merit. It already was noticed that it is the pragmatic inhabitant of
Babylon, "the earthly city", who will disregard what ought to be done in
favor of what can be done. Each step in the evolution of "paper money"
was dictated by convenience. Convenience surely is a legitimate
consideration in one's contemplation of a course of action, but it ought not
to be made in his mind the ultimate standard of value. Men ought rather
to prove themselves to be citizens of "The City of God", who "take every
thought captive to the obedience of Christ:' (II Corinthians 10:5). They
must weigh the overwhelming inconvenience of transgressing the law of
God more heavily than anything else. Banking practices based on
redeemable paper are not sinful in themselves. But, 1) they quickly turn
into banking practices based in irredeemable paper, which shall be
discussed in turn, and 2) while not in violation of the law, they do run
counter to the counsel of God, which shall be discussed presently.
Repeatedly the Wisdom (Proverbs 6:1; 11:15; 17:18; 20:16; 27:13)
warns about the dangers of "going surety". "Surety" is sharing
responsibility with another for a debt. Contemporary Christian financial
counselors appeal to the Proverbs which warn of surety as a basis for
warning against co-signing for a loan.8 This is sound advice, however, it
does not cover all instances of surety. If a buyer owes a seller some
money in exchange for goods, and if he presents to the seller a bill of
exchange, in essence the buyer and the banker have entered into a surety
arrangement together to pay the money. If the bank for some reason does
not pay the money, the seller may still require it of the buyer. If the bill is
not presented for payment, but is passed on to yet another seller in
exchange for goods. the surety for payment passes to the new buyer. With
the changes in bank paper described above, paper began to circulate as a
medium of exchange. Banking became a clearing house operation. Banks
would track the credits and debits of each transaction involving their
paper, and only periodically make actual money payments to settle
accounts. Such a system was not strictly unlawful, but inasmuch as it was
based on surety, it manifestly was not a good idea.
The inadvisability of the circulation of bank paper as a substitute for
money was further indicated by the fact that it quickly reverted to
schemes that blatantly were unlawful. Yet these schemes were nothing
new, they merely were a new way of committing the ancient sins of
inflation and usury. The reader will recall that in ancient times rulers
inflated their currency by a process of "debasement". They could mint
more coins than before because they put less silver into each one, so the
silver went further. Banks in the early modem era accomplished the same
thing by issuing receipts promising to pay a greater quantity of money
than they actually had in their vaults. As the paper itself began to be
accepted as media in exchanges, it was noticed that the great majority of
the precious metals was allowed to rest in the vaults. The paper
representatives were out doing the job of money. so there was little
demand for the silver or gold itself. The paper still certified that a certain
amount of money was payable on demand to the bearer of the paper, but
it was difficult not to notice that most of the people most of the time were
content not to demand it. Banks easily could carryon their functions with
only a fraction of the silver and gold in the vaults. Although it never
would have entered the mind of a righteous man, however, this meant that
8. e.g. Larry Burkett, Your Finances in Changing Times (Chicago: Moody Press,
1982)
1) some of the metal could be loaned out at usury and not be missed, and
2) more paper could be printed and loaned out at usury. The former was
tempting in the case of international loans and usury; the latter in the case
of domestic loans and usury. Inflation by means of the printing press
proved to be a help and a hinderance to usury. It was a help in the sense
that the stock of paper in which the loans were payable was less obviously
finite in dimension than silver or gold. If usury was close to absorbing all
of the paper, more could be printed to keep the usury payments flowing,
and thus the social unrest that attends wide spread defaults could be
postponed. The hinderance to usury was that continuously inflating the
supply of paper in such a manner is ruinous of the economy, because the
exchange value of the paper is eaten away. The usury continues, but the
paper in which it is paid is less and less valuable. Usurers complain about
inflation, and adjust the level of usury to compensate for the devaluation
of paper, but on the whole it seems that they are willing to trade a little
loss of value for a gain of social stability. Of course, the stability is only
illusory, because inflation itself is destablizing, since it eventually ruins
the economy. The semblance of stability actually is only the delay of the
"day of reckoning". The illusion of social stability that comes by way of
unrighteous manipulation is but the storing up of wrath for a day of even
more severe judgement.
There remained one last obstacle to the solidification of this inflate-
and-lend approach to usury in modem banking. If the paper lost too
much value through inflation, people would choose not to use it because
the declining value of the paper would tend to neutralize the convenience
of the paper. What was needed was a means of protecting the
"investment" of inflating paper, so that there was some assurance that
when it came back with usury it still could be "spent" for real goods. This
problem was solved by the arbitrary decree of governments, who by this
point were surviving on bank loans, and had a vested interest in the
solution of the problem. Their answer was "legal tender" laws. The idea
basically was a government decree that certain privileged bank paper was
declared to be money, and must be accepted if it is offered in payment of
debts, "public and private". This, of course was a gross loss of freedom,
and an unrighteousness in itself. The British financier, Sir Thomas
Gresham, observed that "Bad money drives good money out of
circulation", (Gresham's Law). That is, if paper will circulate as money,
and do the job of money, then why spend money? Lately, Hans Sennholz
has pointed out that "legal tender" laws are the power behind Gresham's
Law, and that if people were free to enter into exchanges with whatever
they wanted to use, then paper would not be accepted and Gresham's Law
would operate in reverse: money would drive paper out of circulation.9
Modem banking may be considered as commencing in 1694, with the
establishment of The Bank of England. This bank was given a charter by
Parliament to issue paper notes (over and above the stock of money) to be
loaned to the government and to commerce upon usury. Fourteen years
after the bank was chartered, Parliament granted to it an exclusive
monopoly on the issue of notes. In 1797, the Bank of England suspended
the payment of money for its notes. The problem was a lack of silver and
gold, or, looked at another way, too much paper. England has no silver
or gold mines, and always has relied on international conquest or
commerce for the influx of the metals into the land. Since the bank was
pursuing an inflationary course, it had extended many more pounds in
paper notes than it had pounds sterling of silver with which to pay them.
All seemingly was well as long as people generally were content to hold
and trade paper, but a threat of invasion by France stimulated the general
population to desire money instead of paper. From there, the bank's notes
traversed a steady course of depreciation. No longer payable in money,
all restraint on the quantity of issue of the notes was gone. There was a
plan devised for the resumption of the redemption of notes in money, but
it could not reverse the ill effects of the inflation of paper because it
involved the arbitrary government control of the price of the precious
metals. Governments cannot create value, and therefore cannot
effectively control prices. The outcome in this case was a change of the
Bank's charter in 1833, declaring its notes to be "legal tender". 10
The printing of a piece of paper that is denominated in some weight
of silver, and pretends to be payable in silver on demand, when in fact
9. Sennholz, Money and Freedom (Cedar Falls: Center for Futures Education, Inc.,
1985)
10. see G. Tucker, The Theory of Money and Banks Investigated (1839; New York:
Greenwood Press: NY 1968), p.333-340
there is no silver that is dedicated to the redemption of that paper, is
rightly to be considered the creation of money out of nothing. The
principle may seem alarming to one who is beginning to understand it for
the first time, but it was rather frankly and bluntly stated by William
Paterson in 1694, upon obtaining the charter for the Bank of England,
"The Bank hath benefit of interest on all moneys which it creates out of
nothing." 11 This is the startling feature of the course of usury in modem
times. Heretofore, some work or labor was required in order to generate
something to be loaned. Granted, it usually was not the sweat of the
usurer that provided him with excess to loan, but the usury paid to him
came from some one's productive efforts. Now, the initial principal of a
loan of "money" comes from nowhere. The moment before the loan was
granted, the "money" did not exist. Whether by means of printing some
bank notes, or by the even subtler means of simply crediting the
borrower's account, the banker, by the stroke of his pen, brings into being
what the legal tender laws say that merchants must receive in exchange for
their goods. The borrower has no privilege from the state to create
"money" out of nothing. The paper with which he will repay the loan
must be acquired by means of the sweat of his brow, and that with usury as
well. There is an injustice inherent in one loaning solely by means of
one's wrist reflex what another must repay by means of sweat. On top of
that, the one who sweats must repay a greater quantity of what the banker
created. But the banker did not create enough for the borrower to repay
with usury; he only created enough to make the loan. The borrower still
can repay his loan with usury, if the velocity of circulation is high enough,
that is, if money changes hands fast enough, but velocity of circulation
cannot increase indefinitely. Eventually there will be defaults and
foreclosures.
This problem was painfully evident in the ancient world, but the
modem employment of paper served to obscure the threat of usury on the
economy. By the nineteenth century, usury was a non-issue among the
new breed of economists. Adam Smith, who may be considered the father
of modem economics, did not devote so much as a paragraph to the
11. cited in Carroll Quigley, Tragedy and Hope (New York: Macmillan Co., 1966),
p.49
defense of usury in his very large work, The Wealth of Nations (1776).
The controversy over usury had engaged thinking men for centuries, and
had spawned thousands of pages of debate, yet consider the ease with
which Smith dismissed the issue. He simply observes: "In some countries
the interest of money has been prohibited by law. But as something can
every-where be made by the use of money, something ought every-where
to be paid for the use of it."12 That is it. He provides no analysis of the
biblical texts, the ancient philosophers, the church fathers, or the
scholastics. The indication is that Smith considered the opposition to
usury to be so unworthy as to merit not even an argument. All opposition
is set aside merely on the basis of the instinct of covetousness. If someone
gains from a loan, then the covetous lender is not satisfied to receive back
only what was loaned. Rather than feeling blessed because the borrower
taught him a profitable way to employ his goods, the covetous lender
would attempt to justify a claim on the borrower's goods. When covetous
men stand to gain much through little or no work, almost anything can be
justified in their minds.
It was this wide-spread dismissal of opposition to usury that provided
the appropriate ideological context for the "national bank". "Usury" now
was understood to mean "excessive interest", and now "usury laws" no
longer prohibit interest taking plain and simple, but restrict interest
taking to an arbitrary statutory limit. Only the near-sighted could
interpret this as economic progress. The heritage of Western
Christendom is the plain and simple prohibition of usury. The regulation
of usury is nothing but a reversion to the ancient course of Babylon. True
progress is defined in terms of the ideals of God's word. Europe,
however, abandoned the quest for the "City of God", and followed
covetousness into the mire of the "earthly city". The abandonment of the
biblical idea of usury, together with the irredeemable "paper money"
ploy, allowed the "national bank" idea to be pursued with great vigor.
Paper, which could be printed at will, promised to solve the problem of
usurers absorbing all the money. But the appetite which usury incites is
insatiable. The more "money" that exists, the more there is to be absorbed
12. Adam Smith, The Wealth of Nations (Cannan edition, New York: Random House,
1937), p.339
through usury. The day of reckoning may be postponed by various
means, but it cannot entirely be evaded. This was experienced in the
extreme by France at about this same time. Tucker's summation of their
fiasco is enlightening:
THIS
IS
NOT
a::.~
.~
'f:<
RJl<G
BABY
BUT
A'
~E~
.BABY,
the Commission promptly went to Europe - the source of the problem - in
search of answers. The American public was turning into the duped and
intimidated body which it is today. They had become convinced that
economics and monetary concerns were much too complex for the
untrained mind, but that they need not worry, because the government's
panel of experts surely would come up with a solution. Of course, in
Europe, the Commission learned all about the National Bank concept: a
privately owned Bank, with an exclusive monopoly on usury reaping
paper, which is declared by the government to be legal tender. Naturally,
this is the scheme which they were to propose. In 1910, the German
Banker, Paul Warburg, held a secret meeting in which was drafted the
legislation to accomplish this very thing. It became known as the "Aldrige
Plan", named after U.S. Senator Nelson Aldrige, who participated in the
secret meeting. Strong opposition arose in Congress, and the plan failed
ever to be considered for a vote. After elections, new support was gained
for the measure. It was lightly gone over and re-submitted as new
material, under a new name: The Federal Reserve Act. On December 23,
1913, with the thoughts of most of the nation fixed on Christmas,
President Wilson signed it into law.
As an ideal, the Federal Reserve System closely approximated the
goal of a monetary school that sometimes is called "social credit" or
"monetary science". In fact, one of this school's learned advocates at the
time, Senator Robert Owen, was a principal author of the original version
of the Federal Reserve Act. Since this school of thought still enjoys a
measure of popularity, it would be good at this point to glance at its basic
position, and its idea of usury. A rudimentary concept of "monetary
science" is that money is only a "token". It is supposed to be a claim on the
products and services of a society. This is a fundamental error, which
guarantees the fallaciousness of the entire system. In a free society, sellers
are not compelled to sell. No one has a valid "claim" on any product based
only on his possession of a piece of paper. The tyranny of "legal tender"
laws is that if one chooses to sell something, then he must accept a certain
type of paper in payment for it. Of course, if money is viewed as a claim
ticket, then this suggests the obvious problem:who has the authority to
issue such tickets?
Those of the "monetary science" school rightly were alarmed by the
pretense of some bankers to create money out of nothing. What
apparently had escaped their notice, however, was that the banker's
creation was not a claim ticket for existent products and services, but for
non-existent silver and gold. They rightly analysed the potential for
corruption in such a system; indeed such a system is corrupt in its very
design. But their proposed solution aimed to cure the corruption in the
wrong way. They had no quarrel with the creation of money as such, but
withwho was creating it, and forwhat purpose. Their proposal was to take
the money creation powers away from the bankers and give it to
politicians! Gertrude M. Coogan, one of the early writers in this vein,
states as an essential element of an "honest money" system: "The power to
create money should be vested in a Monetary Trusteeship appointed by
and answerable to the United States Congress. "22 This is a classic case of
putting the fox in charge of the chicken coop. It did not seem to occur to
Miss Coogan, and others of this school, that ethically no one ought to be
"creating" money - not the banks, nor the government.
A rudimentary principle of the American government is that rulers
derive their just powers from the consent of the governed.23 That is, the
interests which a legitimate government protects for society are the same
which an individual would be justified in protecting for himself, e.g.
defense, the guarding of property, etc. If an individual would like to
enter into exchanges of property with others, it is necessary that he first
produce something that he may contribute to such exchanges (even if this
is only his labor). He would be totally unjustified in simply printing up
some paper that he declares to be a claim on the products of others. Of
course, no one would take seriously any such claim. If one meant to press
this sort of a claim, he probably would have to resort to intimidation or
threat (legal tender laws), and any degree of success he had in thus
acquiring the property of others would be considered extortion. If such a
course is unthinkable for the individual, then how does it become
thinkable for a "government"? How can a body of individuals delegate to
a "government" a right and a power that none of them have as individuals?
22. G.M. Coogan, Money Creators (1935; Hawthorn, CA: Omni, 1982), p.334
23. Declaration of Independence
Of course, legitimately they cannot. Frederic Bastiat enunciated this
principle in a pampWet titled "The Law", first published in 1850:
The law is the organization of the natural right of lawful defense. It is the
substitution of a common force for individual forces. And this common force is
to do only what the individual forces have a natural a lawful right to do: to
protect persons, liberties and properties; to maintain the right of each, and to
cause justice to reign over all.24
24. F. Bastiat, The Law (1850; Irvington-on-Hudson, NY: FEE, 1984), p.7
25. Rev. Denis Fahey, Money Manipulation and Social Order (1944; Hawthorne, CA:
Ornni, 1986), p.69
therefore not enough "money" exists to pay both the principal and
interest. Rev. Denis Fahey has written, "The payment of the interest of
money brought into existence as a debt involves the payment of more than
is issued. This cannot be done without further borrowing, so the process
means steady progression into debt for the society as a whole."26 But this
is true only if a "dollar" can be spent only once. In reality, there is a
"velocity" of circulation of "money", determined by the number of times
it changes hands in a period of time. Given a high enough velocity, one
"dollar" could pay all loans and usury. There is a practical limit to
velocity, such that usury eventually will become an arithmetic problem,
however, it is not a good course to oppose usury only for the pragmatic
reason of an arithmetic difficulty. Opposition to usury must have as its
fundamental concern that usury is contrary to God's law, and therefore is
immoral. This is not the position expressed in the "monetary science"
school. Consequently, it is not surprising to find these writers giving an
inconsistent treatment of usury. Their problem with usury is only in case
the principal was something which the lender created out of nothing. In
the case of loans of existing assets, their system allows for usury. Miss
Coogan, for instance, has said,
Note carefully that the original issuance or creation of money, paid into
circulation, should always be interest free. Carefully distinguish this original
issuance of money upon its creation with the lending of real money, which has
been obtained by those who have earned it by rendering personal services or
real goods in exchange for that money. In actually lending real money so
earned, one may expect a fair interest rate.27
Meet Ralph, the average American taxpayer who each year sends the
government some of his paycheck to finance defense, national parks, Amrrack,
education, welfare, subways, sewers, environmental protection and more.
Ralph probably doesn't know it, but this year [1986] the government will
take $699.23 of his $3,537 in federal income taxes to fund something that
delivers no services at all. That is the payment of interest on the government's
unpaid debts.
These payments comprise the third largest item in the budget unveiled by
President Reagan, after Social Security and defense.34
Usury now approaches 20% of the Federal budget, on a debt in
excess of two. trillion "dollars" - that is 2,000,000,000,000. Part of the
convenience of having a Federal Reserve System, which creates "money"
out of nothing, is that if a debtor cannot repay his loan on time, it can be
"refinanced" with the creation of additional "money". In this way, usury
payments continue to flow, though they continue also to mount. Debts,
and usury, eventually mount up to a level that is even more impossible to
pay. That precisely is the main problem in the "farm crisis" of the 1980s.
Farmers by the thousands each year are losing their farms to banks
because they cannot meet their debts. Their debts got to be as high as they
were because they could not meet prior debts, which simply were
refinanced. The source of all the trouble is that their loans are loans upon
usury. In addition to the Federal debt and the Farm debt, there is the
Home Mortgage debt and Consumer debt of individuals, which amounts to
another two trillion" dollars", debts of business and industry amounting to
2.4 trillion, and the debts of state and local governments totalling 559
billion. This adds up to a grand total U.S. debt of over seven trillion
"dollars".35
One way of looking at this is the way in which the Washington Post
article put it: "If Ralph earns $36,600, the median U.S. income for 1985,
he has to work for 1 1/2 weeks this year just to pay the interest on the
government'-s debt." With private debt at the same level as Government
debt, the average individual has to work another week and a half to pay
the usury on the private debt. And then there is the debt of state and local
governments. As it stands now, the average worker labors nearly a month
out of every year to accomplish nothing but the payment of usury. Does
America perceive herself as slowly but surely entering into indentured
servitude? When will there be a general public outcry, as there was in
ancient times? Will we need to be totally enslaved, working twelve
months a year to pay usury?
E. L. Anderson has graphed the performance of the National Debt,
Usury on the National Debt, the Consumer Price Index, and Federal
35. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, "Flow of Funds Accounts,
First Quarter 1986", (Z.l June 1986, Flow of Funds, 1986:Ql), p.viii
Budget Deficits over the last several decades)6 These curves are
reproduced on the following page. What is immediately apparent upon
only a glance at these curves is that "something has got to give". Though
Anderson's data is a bit old now, the situation has only worsened since
1979. His thesis is that the situation which these curves represent cannot
continue, mainly because the line is converging on the vertical. Upon
reaching vertical, time stops, which is an impossibility. What, however,
is not an impossibility is that soon - no one can say how long it will take -
usury payments will reach a critical threshold proportion of the Federal
Budget, absorbing a critical threshold percentage of the Gross National
Product, and the debt simply will be repudiated. As Mises said,
The Financial history of the last century shows a steady increase in the
amount of public indebtedness. Nobody believes that the states will eternally
drag the burden of these interest payments. It is obvious that sooner or later all
these debts will be liquidated in some way or other, but certainly not by
payment of interest and principal according to the terms of the contract.37
36. E.L.Anderson, "The Upright Spike of '79: Doomsday for America", (Washington:
Government Education Foundation, 1978)
37. Mises, Human Action, p.227
38. for more on the concealed tyranny of Presidential "Executive Orders", see: Gary
North, Government By Emergency (FI. Worth: ABBR.), and F. Tupper Saucey, The
Miracle On Main Street (Sewanee, 1N: Spencer Judd)
loans. These loans are guaranteed by the U.S. Government. That means
that if the foreign debtors do not pay, then the American taxpayers will
pay. Either way the bankers will have their usury. When popular belief
in Tinkerbell fails, professional usurers no longer will have any recourse
for collecting debts. They are banking - literally - on the hope that
widespread petty usury among the general population will provide
enough popular incentive to keep the myth of Tinkerbell alive. This
actually amounts to a religious faith in the modem world that is not unlike
the idolatry of ancient Babylonia. Now that so many are caught up in the
web of usury, it will cost the average debtor a great deal to repudiate the
mythology. There is a great vested interest to keep the "faith", even
though to an objective glance the ridiculousness of Tinkerbell is obvious.
The basic character of usury has not changed over the centuries. The
idea of usury has evolved into highly complicated "interest theory", but
the function of usury, no matter what it is called, remains the same.
Regardless of whether the loan is for business, or for meeting an urgent
need; whether it is a loan of money, a loan of goods, or a loan of raw
"purchasing power" in the form of paper or electronics, it remains
unchanged that usury on the loan is gain to the usurer for which he did not
labor, and is that for which the borrower did labor, but does not enjoy the
benefit. The modem face of usury is 1) the abstract nature of the loan
principal; being in most cases that which a banker created by the stroke of
his pen, and 2) the vast web of surety and petty usury into which the
borrowing public has plunged. These developments highly complicate the
matter, which complication hardly is to regarded as accidental. Now, it is
only with difficulty that one can detect the hurt that usury is causing him.
And our culture is so secularized, and so self-centered, that virtually no
one perceives nor cares that usury is causing great hurt to our nation as a
whole.
Those who ought to occupy the City of God are for the most part
welcoming the day of calamity, because they expect that its coming only
signals the imminence of "the rapture". However, in ever larger
numbers, Christians are waking up to the fact that Christ is not the Lord
of a defeated church. We must not desire escape, as though at last resort
we would wish for the mountains to fall down and cover us. We have
permitted the inhabitants of Babylon, the "earthly city", to infest our land
even from its very fonndation. For all that is right and true and glorious
in our land, we never have had a truly righteous economy. The failure of
our present unrighteous economy does not signal the imminent escape of
the church, but the fall of Babylon. In order to establish righteousness in
our midst, our first step is not to attempt to identify certain individuals or
groups whom we feel are- responsible for our troubles. It is we who are
responsible. The initial step of reform is repentance. We must show
ourselves to be in truth God's people, citizens of His City, by keeping His
law, in His power and by His grace. There is no substitute for this.
The lessons of history are obscured, and we appear bound to re-Ieam
them. Usury eventually and always destroys a nations economy. This
appeared to happen more readily and more violently in the ancient world
only because the ancient economies were not buffered with "money" that
privileged men could create out of nothing. Once the commodities that
were used in exchange were in sufficient measure absorbed by usurers, no
recourse was left to the debt~rs but to choose slavery or revolution. Of
the many iniquities that have plagued economies through the centuries,
usury is the most destructive. Will we learn from history, or will we be
forced to re-Iearn what ought to be crystal clear? One way or the other,
the reality of the plague of usury shall become apparent. It is probable
that the current economy has festered to the point that it cannot be
reformed; it must be replaced. In that event we who are of the household
of God ought not to pine for Babylon. For "the earthly city", it is too late;
but for the City of God, a new era of righteousness will have just begnn.
The preceding discussion is by necessity very sketchy. The main
point of this present writing is not to provide exhaustive historical detail,
but to demonstrate the consistently disastrous results of usury throughout
time. It is probable that as well as doing that, the preceding discussion
also raised some questions in the reader's mind that were not adequately
addressed. It is recommended that the reader pursue such questions on his
own. For general history, the series by Will Durant, The Story of
Civilization, is recommended (New York: Simon & Shuster). Though
Durant's non-Christian bias plainly is evident, still he is most helpful in
supplying historical sequence and detail. For economic history
specifically, the reader should consult W. Cunningham's, The Growth of
English Industry and Commerce (New York: A.M. Kelly). Though it
centers on England, it provides many helpful insights concerning the
development or evolution of economic relationships, which are typical of
mankind. For the topic of usury itself, the recommended text is Rev.
Patrick Cleary's, The Church and Usury (Hawthorne: The Christian Book
Club of America). His approach is general, much like the present treatise,
though there is less axe-grinding. However, there are many helpful
insights. One area that especially requires further study is the
conspiratorial aspect of the development of modern banking. A
recommended starting point is W. Cleon Skousen's, The Naked Capitalist
(privately published, 2197 Berkeley St., Salt Lake City, UT 84109). Also
of interest will be A. Ralph Epperson, The Unseen Hand, an Introduction
to the Conspiratorial View of History, (Publius Press: Tuscon, AZ). To
obtain these, and other helpful books, the reader is urged to locate an
American Opinion Bookstore. For a good expose of The Federal Reserve
System, see Eustace Mullins, The Secrets of the Federal Reserve
(Staunton: Bankers Research Institute). The FED does a fair job of
exposing themselves. For a frank account of how they create "money"
with the stroke of a pen, and the operations of "Fractional Reserve
Banking", write to "Public Information Center, Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago, P.O. Box 834, Chicago, IL 60690", and ask them to send, free
of charge, their revealing booklet, "Modem Money Mechanics".
Repair the bell - freedom ring!
The preceding historical sketch was meant to demonstrate two facts:
1) That money strictly speaking is gold and silver coin; therefore what
passes as "money" today in our land (and indeed throughout most of the
world) not only is not money, but does not even represent money, and 2)
that because of I above usury is given an economic context in which to
fester seemingly indefinitely, without the instability of slavery or
revolution. The significance of these facts may be weighed in accordance
with one's convictions on the moral character of usury. In the case that
usury is accepted, the present context, which promises to support usury
without social upheaval, is welcomed as progress. The contention of the
present writing, however, is that usury is wrong, and that this sort of
promise actually amounts to simply a self-serving, short-term grasp for
momentary riches, while deferring the social upheaval, which must come,
to the next generation. Indeed, the horror of abortion is not the only
exhibition of our generation's contempt for posterity.
These historical realities provide an understanding of usury which
allows one to appreciate God's word on the subject. But this is not to say
that history is autonomous, or that it is a standard by which Scripture may
be interpreted. The testimony of Scripture provides the basis for a true
interpretation of history. However, a pro-usury idea is inconsistent with
an otherwise biblical view of history. Historically, the character of
usurers, and the consequences of usury are entirely contrary to the
biblical vision of godliness and charity. It is fitting, therefore, that the
discussion turn now to a survey of the biblical teaching on the subject of
usury.
"If you lend money to My people, to the poor among you, you are not
to act as a creditor to him; you shall not charge him interest."
Moses had led the people Israel out of bondage in Egypt and the Lord
had brought them to Mt. Sinai. While the people waited at the base of the
mountain, Moses went up and communed with God. The Lord spoke at
length with Moses and delivered unto him the law. The most well known
aspect of this body of law is what is known as the Ten Commandments.
Rushdoony makes the point that in fact these Ten Commandments form
the foundation of law, all other statutes being derived from them as case
law) Among these other statutes is the above quoted rule concerning
usury. As case law, this may be considered derived from the eighth
commandment, "You shall not steal" (Exodus 20:15). Calvin,
Rushdoony, and other expositors of God's law treat of usury under the
head of the eighth commandment.
The first thing that must be noted in this statement, is that the word
"money" in this verse is given in translation of a word that actually means
"silver". The economic context of this occasion was that which has been
termed a "money economy". Silver and gold, in lumps - not coins, had
come into service as media for exchange. Anticipated in this rule was a
loan given in media, which still was quite different from current loans.
Loans in that case would entail the transfer of some physical substance.
This rule, then, was to prohibit charging a fee for the use of the property
loaned, which often is manifested by the repayment of an amount of
substance that was greater than what was loaned. Before considering in
detail the nature of this prohibition, and to whom it applies, let us first
look briefly at the term which is translated "interest".
Our word "interest" comes from the Latin "interess", which means
"compensatory payment", and originally had this meaning also. Older
English translations, e.g. the King James Version, 1611, gives "usury"
instead of "interest". Modern translations almost always use "interest".
1. R.I. Rushdoony, The Institutes of Biblical Law (Nutley: Presbyterian & Reformed,
1973), p.1O-12
Rushdoony points out that since the word has come to mean the same thing
as usury, and that usury now is thought to mean "excessive interest", then
confusion may be avoided by using "interest" where actually is meant
"usury".2 The Hebrew word in this verse is Neshek and comes from a
related word Nashak, which literally means "bite". It is used mostly of
serpents (Numbers 21:6,9; Proverbs 23:32; Ecclesiastes 10:8,11;
Jeremiah 8:17; Amos 5:19;9:3). However, in one instance the NASB
translates Nashak differently. Habakkuk 2:7, "Will not your creditors
(Nashak) rise up suddenly, and those who collect from you awaken?
Indeed, you will become plunder for them." The related term Neshek is
used only in reference to the practice of usury. It is translated "usury"
every time in the KJV and "interest" every time in the NASB.
It is not very difficult to discern the requirement of this law. Clearly,
usury, or the charging of "interest" on a loan, is prohibited. Some have
said that this applies only in the case of "charitable" loans to the "poor",
because the text specifies "to the poor among you". While the poor are
mentioned specifically as the recipients of a loan, nevertheless the
exclusive applicability of this law to loans to the poor is not shown by any
specific contrast of "poor" with "rich". The real emphasis in this law is
not "the poor", but "My people". It says, "If you lend money to My
people ... ", and from there goes on to say" ... to the poor among you".
"The poor" are mentioned as a further definition of exactly who among
His people might be in receipt of a loan. Who, indeed, besides a poor man
would be borrowing? If a man has what he needs, why (and what) would
he borrow? In our modem times, almost everyone is a borrower in some
way. In ancient times, men borrowed only because they had an urgent
need. The question now becomes: does our modem practice mitigate the
requirement of God's law? God has stated specifically that his people are
not to be borrowers (Deuteronomy 15:6; 28:44) and that rather they are
to prosper to such an extent that they shall be lenders to others. Any who
fall "poor" among His people are to receive assistance from his brethren,
and that without usury. A more comprehensive treatment of this question
will appear later.
"Now in case a countryman of yours becomes poor and his means
with regard to you falter, then you are to sustain him, like a stranger or a
sojourner, that he may live with you. Do not take usurious interest from
him, but revere your God, that your countryman may live with you. You
shall not give him your silver at interest, nor your food for gain."
3. John Calvin, Commentaries on the Four Last Boob of Moses (Grand Rapids:
Eerdmans, 1950), VoLIII, p.130
fulfillment of the law is not simply to abstain from the negative, but also
to embrace the positive. The "people consciousness" that ought to pervade
the church would disallow, with an inner moral constraint, any plunder of
one brother by another, which results from usury, and in its place this
"people consciousness" would have us sustain the unfortunate among us.
One must revere our God, and sustain - not plunder - his brother. This
further exemplifies the point made above, that the emphasis in the
command is "My people", not "the poor". The broader context of this text
is the law concerning the Sabbatical year and the Jubilee. Some have
sought to infer from this that the usury statute has particular reference to
the oppression of the poor. The wording of the statute in this case does
seem to suggest a particular application to "the poor". Indeed, if this were
the only occurrence of the statute, a limited scope of applicability would
be difficult to deny. However, the command occurs with a broader scope
in two other places (one just previously examined, and the other to be
examined below), and provides that the present text must be taken as a
special reemphasis of the law for the sake of the poor. Whereas,
borrowing in ancient times generally was limited to cases of personal need
(Le. "consumer credit" and "commercial loans" were entirely unknown),
an emphasis on the poor in the law was actually in reference to most cases
of borrowing. But this does not exclude from the proper jurisdiction of
the law such cases as one who is not poor borrowing a cup of sugar from
his neighbor. The affinity that God's people are commanded to have with
one another is not limited to a particular class. The "poor" brother enjoys
a special mention only because he is the one who is most liable to the
plunder of usury.
"Y ou shall not charge interest to your countrymen: interest on
money, food, or anything that may be loaned at interest. You may charge
interest to a foreigner, but to your countryman you shall not charge
interest, so that the Lord your God may bless you in all that you undertake
in the land which you are about to enter to possess."
"And I consulted with myself, and contended with the nobles and the
rulers and said to them, 'You are exacting usury, each from his brother!'
Therefore, I held a great assembly against them. And I said to them, I •••
This text embodies two of the three occurrences of the word "usury"
in the NASB. This version usually gives "usury" for Tarbith. In the
present text, "usury" is given for a different word - Mashsha. It has the
meaning of "exaction". Here it speaks of the coldness and indifference
with which one brother related to another. Those under usury saw
themselves slipping into slavery, while those to whom they were indebted
apparently did not care. How did such a distressing situation emerge in
Israel? The events which led up to Nehemiah's exhortation are
characteristic of man's propensity to sin, and the blessings of repentance.
As the history of the people Israel advanced, they proved themselves
to be a stubborn and "stiff-necked" people. They ignored God's laws,
intermarried with, an idolatrous people, sacrificed to their idols, and
corrupted themselves. God raised up the kingdoms of Babylon and
Assyria for the purpose of disciplining His people. Those who dwelt in
and around Jerusalem were defeated in battle, and carried off into exile in
Babylon. The book of Nehemiah chronicles the close of this period of
captivity, and the return of many of the people Israel, under the
leadership of Nehemiah, to Jerusalem to rebuild the city. They were not
free from the threats and aggression of the pagan people that God had
used to discipline them, and there was an inner corruption (the reason for
their captivity in the first place) that they needed to overcome. Although
there are many aspects to this, however, the concern here is to note the
extent to which they required re-instruction in the law.
Famine conditions arose (possibly because of the sudden influx of
people returning from captivity). Instead of sustaining the brethren as
required by the law, as was seen above, those in need were subjected to
usury. "We are mortgaging our fields, our vineyards, and our homes that
we might get grain because of the famine ... We have borrowed money
for the king's tax on our fields and our vineyards. And now our flesh is
like the flesh of our brothers, our children like their children. Yet
behold, we are forcing our sons and our daughters to be slaves, and some
of our daughters are forced into bondage already, and we are helpless
because our fields and vineyards belong to others." (5:3-5) Instead of
becoming kings and owners in the land, they were swiftly entering into
slavery under usury at the hands of their own brothers. This greatly
angered Nehemiah (v.6), and he called not only for the cessation of this
usury (see text quoted at the head of this paragraph), but also called for
restitution, "Please, give back to them this very day their fields, their
vineyards, their olive groves, and their houses, also the hundredth part of
the money and of the grain, the new wine, and the oil that you are exacting
from them" (v.U). The usurers were moved by this plea, and readily
agreed to repent and return the property. It is interesting to note that this
restitution included "also the hundredth part of the money ... " This
dramatically illustrates the fact that the usury prohibition has nothing to
do with degree. An "interest rate" of I % is as unacceptable as 40%. This
text is a great problem for the notion that usury merely is "excessive
interest", for I % hardly could be considered excessive.
The people had exhibited a great lack of understanding of the law.
Their readiness to repent of usury indicated the redemption of their
hearts, but their tendency to sin by way of usury indicated an ignorance of
the law. All during their captivity they had learned the pagan ways of
Babylon. Now it was necessary for them to learn once again the law of
God. Ezra, a priest, held a great assembly, and read to the people from
the law of God "from early morning until midday" (8:3). This was rich
and fulfilling time for Israel. Repentance was complete and sincere.
Their whole outlook on the world was altered radically by their new
understanding of what God required of them. They took immediate and
concrete steps to bring their lives into conformity to the requirement. It
appears that a similarity exists between our own generation and Israel in
the time of Nehemiah. We likewise have rampant usury among the
brethren. We likewise have learned the ways of Babylon, and display
either an ignorance of, or indifference to, the law of God. Will there be
an Ezra in our day? Is the reader, by reading the present work, in a
position that is even remotely similar to those who heard the law read
under Ezra? Will he likewise repent?
"He does not put out his money at interest, nor does he take a bribe
against the innocent. He who does these things will never be shaken."
For by grace you have been saved through faith, and that not of
yourselves, it is the gift of God; not as a result of works, that no one should
boast. For we are His workmanship, created in Christ Jesus for good works,
which God prepared beforehand, that we should walk in them. (v.8-1O)
If the modern church will not do His good works, and rather would
continue in usury in opposition to the requirement of His law, then let her
not suppose that she will escape the shaking of His discipline.
"He who increases his wealth by interest and usury, gathers it for him
who is gracious to the poor."
Isaiah the prophet warned Judah (the Southern people of Israel who
occupied Jerusalem and the surrounding region) of the impending
captivity in Babylon. This was the same captivity out of which Nehemiah
and company later emerged, as was discussed above. In graphic tenns
Isaiah warns the people of the utter destruction which God was about to
bring upon them for their unfaithfulness. Verse 1 relates this in imagery
involving a geologic catastrophe; v.2 then pictures some of the
sociological consequences of this upheaval. Generally, there is portrayed
a leveling, or equalization of all persons under the destruction. Defeat
and captivity is no respecter of persons. Nor is hunger or disease. While
there is no word in v.2 that may be rendered as "usury", the KJV gives" as
with the taker of usury, so with the giver of usury to him". It shall be left
to scholars to debate whether there actually is any usury involved here,
however, the flow of images in v.2 tends to reinforce what already has
been learned from Proverbs 22:7, "the borrower becomes the lender's
slave." As enslavement mounted in this fashion among God's people, this,
as well as a host of other sins brought the judgement of God upon them.
As is depicted so dramatically, the effects of this judgement, among other
things, was to obliterate this shameful distinction between lender and
borrower in Israel. If this distinction is not kept out by keeping God's
law, it will be forced out as borrower and lender alike enter into captivity.
"Woe to me, my mother, that you have born me as a man of strife and
a man of contention to all the land! I have neither lent, nor have men lent
money to me, yet every one curses me."
"In you they have taken bribes to shed blood; you have taken interest
and profits, and you have injured your neighbors for gain by oppression,
and you have forgotten Me," declares the Lord GOD.
Those in modem times who would like some biblical justification for
their own involvement in usury find much comfort in this parable, and a
similar one in Luke 19, for they certainly have nothing to comfort them in
the Old Testament. (Due to the similarity between Matthew 25 and Luke
19, in-so-far-as this parable, both of them are treated together). But a
sensible reading of this text readily will dissolve such comfort, for the
character of usury, and the ordinances of God concerning it, have not
changed from the beginning.
A certain master was planning a long journey. While preparing to
leave, he called to him his servants, and entrusted to them varying
amounts of money (talents, minas, Le. a certain weight of silver). Several
of his servants went out and "traded" with the money, and earned a profit,
but one servant hid away the money for safe-keeping. Upon the master's
return, he called to himself his servants once again, to learn what each had
done with the money that was entrusted to them. Having learned of the
success of their trade, he praised the thrifty servants and increased their
status. However, he became very displeased with the one servant who
merely had hidden away the money that was entrusted to him.
In an interpretation of this parable, one usually does not have
difficulty identifying the master as Christ, our Lord. Likewise, one
readily sees himself as the servant, and the spiritual teaching of this
parable is taken as both a warning and an encouragement for one to do his
best to utilize the gifts that God has given him for His Kingdom, and His
greater glory. So far, so good. But there seems to be an incredible
inconsistency that arises when there is a shift of focus onto the popular
economic teaching of this parable. All would agree, apparently, that some
sort of teaching on usury may be gleaned from this account. But, in their
attempt to characterize Jesus as approving usury, many commentators
also accept without question the evaluation of the master that is given by
the wicked slave. That is, in order for an approval of usury to result from
this text, the master must be made out to be a harsh and thieving man. Let
us examine in what manner this is so.
Here is what the servant who had hidden the money said to the master
in the parable, "Master, I knew you to be a hard man, reaping where you
did not sow, and gathering where you scattered no seed. And I was afraid,
and went away and hid your talent in the ground ... " (Matthew 25:24,25)
In Luke (19:21) this servant calls the master an "exacting" man. The
word in Matthew 25:24 translated "hard" (skleros) means hard in the
sense of "rough", and is elsewhere translated "harsh". The word
translated "exacting" in Luke 19:21,22 (austeros) is used only in these
two instances. It is derived from a word meaning to dry or burn, and has
the meaning of harsh or severe. This is the testimony of the servant
concerning the master. Now what does the master say concerning the
servant? "You wicked, lazy slave" (Matthew 25:27), and "You worthless
slave" (Luke 19:22). It is evident that these are incompatible evaluations.
Is it really a great problem to decide whose words are truth? If it already
has been said that the master represents Christ, would it not be
inconsistent to doubt the evaluation he gives of that servant? If His
evaluation is accepted, and we come also to view this one as a worthless,
wicked, and lazy slave, then how much stock would we put in his image of
the Master? Not a great deal at all. Does Jesus reap where He has not
sown, or take up where he has not laid down (steal)? We know that this is
untrue. Then why do some read the remainder of the master's comments
as though he were admitting that the slave was right? He says, "... you
knew that I reap where I did not sow, and gather where I scattered no
seed? Then you ought to have put my money in the bank, and on my
arrival I would have received my money back with interest." (Matthew
25:26,27). What the master is saying here is something like, "If that
really is what you thought of me, then this is what you would have
done ..." Indeed, the Luke version comes very close to saying it just that
way when the master says, "By your own words I will judge you, you
worthless slave, , ," (19:22). It is only by the word of the slave that the
master is those evil things, never by any admission of the master. The
word of the slave does not determine that the master is evil, rather the
slave, by his own words, has proven himself to be evil, for the master is
good definitively.
reality of the the fantasy of the
and faithful servants wicked and lazy slave
So what is the master really saying when he says "you ought to have
put my money in the bank"? Many "investment" counselors today take this
as a straightforward recommendation by the master. For instance, Gary
North says of this parable, "Jesus was affirming the legitimacy of both
profit through trade and the normal rate of return which is secured by
lending money The two forms of activity are not the same, as the parable
indicates, but both are legitimate."4 Also, it is an exceedingly difficult
thing to fmd a commentary on this passage that does not represent Christ as
sanctioning usury. Oddly, it is Calvin, who may be regarded as the father
of the current evangelical view, who stands virtually alone in his
commentary: "For Christ did not intend to ... applaud usury".5 Also,
Calvin Elliot, in his book on usury, gave an interpretation much the same
as is offered here. 6 But the popular idea ignores the master's evaluation
of this slave. The statement about what the slave ought to have done is
couched in terms of what the slave claimed to believe concerning the
master. The fact that the slave did not put the money in the bank showed
that he really did not believe that the master was a thief, and was only
trying to make excuses when he said those things. If he really thought that
the master was a thief, then he should have gone to the banks to get usury
(in violation of the eighth commandment, and all of the ordinances that are
noted above).
No, there is not much comfort here for the modem dabbler in usury,
unless one perceives his Lord to be the harsh and thieving master that the
wicked slave tried to make him out to be. Thc.:n,like the wicked slave, he
shall be judged by his own words, and found wanting.
4. Gary North, Honest Money (Ft. Worth: Dominion Press & Nashville: Thomas
Nelson, Inc., 1986), p.71
5. Calvin, A Hamwny of the Evangelists (Grand Rapids: Eerdmans, 1949), p.444
6. Calvin Elliot, Usury, A Scriptural, Ethical, and Economic View (Millersburg, OR:
The Anti-Usury League, 1902)
The summation of this brief survey is a remarkably consistent and
integrated principle. Then again, it should not seem too remarkable to us
that the law of God is integrated. It is one's own schizophrenia that
renders law and grace - Old and New - as an exceedingly complex
problem.
God has condenmed theft in His law. In particular, he has condenmed
usury - the practice of charging a fee for the use of property, which
commonly is manifested as demanding in return for a loan an amount that
is greater than what was loaned. His ordinances are clear on this. The
modern distinction of "charitable" vs. "commercial" loans may not be
read back into these ordinances simply because 1) this is an artificial
distinction in the first place, since no economic transaction may be
divorced from personal life (is a home mortgage "charitable" or
"commercial"?) and, 2) whatever success there may be in establishing
some reality to this distinction is of no account since there was nothing
like the modem "commercial" enterprise at the time the command was
given, i.e. the command does not explicitly cover such a distinction.
Rather, the concern in the Pentateuch has been shown to be one of
sustaining the brethren. The history of Israel, as given in the prophets
bears out the dangers of this sin. As Nehemiah demonstrates, keeping
God's law not only is right (though that is enough) but also there is great
utility in doing so. The impotence that is experienced in this generation,
and the slavery into which it steadily is sinking, is attributable largely to
this very sin. As in antiquity, the current generation faces the watershed
of either repentance or judgement.
A familiarity with the history of usury and the biblical doctrine of
usury does not seem automatically to produce in some a conviction that
usury is wrong. Incredible as this may appear, it is due to a common
tendency in man. It is easy for one to perceive the sinfulness of something
except when he is completely immersed in it. If one has not disciplined
himself to judge all of life by the standard of God's word, then common
worldly customs in which he indulges, even though they are sinful, will
hold in his mind an authority that is equal to or greater than the authority
of God's word. In this case, one's own preference to continue in usury
will make it seem necessary for him to explain away the testimony of
history and Scripture concerning the evil of usury. Henry Smith
eloquently expounded on this curious psychology of sin in his
"Examination of Usury", in 1591:
Sin is never complete until it be excused: this is the vantage which the
devil getteth by every sin, whensoever he can fasten any temptation upon us,
we give him a sin for it, and an excuse to boot, as Adam our father did. First
he sinned, and then he excused: so first we sin, and then we excuse: first an
Usurer, and then an excuser. Therefore every Usurer will defend Usury with
his tongue, though he condemn it with his conscience. If the Image makers of
Ephesus had not lived by Images, they would have spoken for Images no more
than the rest: for none stood for Images but the Image makers (Acts 19:25): so
if the Usurers did not live by Usury, they would speak for Usury no more than
the rest: for none stand for Usury but Usurers. 1
Presupposing the custome and corruption of these times wherein men will
not lend freely as they ought; is there not a necessitie of usurie? Admit that be
granted; who did impose this necessitie? If God; then is this reason good,
Usurie is necessarie therefore la»ful. But if men or estates have drawne a
necessitie of sinning upon themselves by the custome of sin; doth this extenuate
or aggravate the fault? Woe be unto them (saith the Prophet Esay [Isaiah)) who
draw sinne, as with cart.ropes .3
When you make your neighbor a loan of any son, you shall not enter his
house to take his pledge. You shall remain outside, and the man to whom you
make the loan shall bring the pledge out to you. And if he is a poor man, you
shall not sleep with his pledge. When the sun goes down you shall surely
return the pledge to him, that he may sleep in his cloak and bless you; and it will
be righteousness for you before the LORDyour God.
You shall not oppress a hired servant who is poor and needy, whether he
is one of your countrymen or one of your aliens who is in your land in your
towns. You shall give him his wages on his day before the sun sets, for he is
poor and set his heart on it; so that he may not cry against you to the LORD and
it become sin in you.
If there is a poor man with you, one of your brothers, in any of your
towns in your land which the LORD your God is giving you, you shall not
harden your heart, nor close your hand from your poor brother; but you shall
freely open your hand to him, and shall generously lend him sufficient for his
need in whatever he lacks. Beware, lest there is a base thought in your heart,
saying, "The seventh year, the year of remission, is near," and your eye is
hostile toward your poor brother, and you give him nothing; then he may cry to
the LoRD against you, and it will be sin to you. (15:7-9)
Yet, amazingly, the very ones who claim that the mention of the
"poor" in Exodus 22:25 and Leviticus 25:35 qualifies the usury statute,
also bluntly state, without any qualification, that all debts are to be
cancelled after six years. A few examples will suffice. R.I. Rushdoony
espouses the "poor/rich" distinction as a qualification of the usury statute,
and yet in the same volume states, "...no man is allowed to tax his own
future by means of debt. The length of a debt is limited to six years (Deut.
15:1-4). No man has a right to mortgage his future, since his life belongs
to God."6 Also, Gary North, another proponent of the "poor/rich"
distinction as a qualification of the usury law, has said, "This, too, is basic
to a Biblical social order: no loans to the faithful for over seven years
(Deuteronomy 15:1-2)."7 He expresses the same thought more clearly
elsewhere, "... a six-year debt limitation is the maximum that is morally
legitimate (given the provisions of the sabbatical years regarding the
cancellation of all debts ... )"8 How is it that these scholars can find an
inference in Exodus 22:25 and Leviticus 25:35 that usury is lawful in
many cases, and yet fail to find a similar inference in Deuteronomy 15:1-
II? Why do they not hold that only the debts of "poor" brethren are to be
cancelled, and infer from this that it is lawful for one to continue to exact
the debts of the "rich"? The present writer agrees with their views
concerning the remission of debts, particularly as cited above. The
wonder is that they do not similarly expound on the usury statute, which is
given in a similar fonn.
In summary: 1) The usury statutes in Exodus and Leviticus mention
the "poor", but they do not confonn to the structure of those laws that
make specific allowance for special handling of cases involving the
"poor". 2) Therefore, those two texts do not provide any basis on which
to determine whether anyone is "poor". 3) Therefore, the notion that the
As touching the political law, no wonder that God should have permitted
His people to receive interest from the Gentiles, since otherwise a just
reciprocity would not have been preserved, without which one party must needs
be injured. God commands His people not to practice usury, and still lays the
Jews alone, and not foreign nations, under the obligation of this law. In order,
therefore, that equality (ratio analogica) might be preserved, He accords the
same liberty to His people which the Gentiles would assume for themselves; for
this is the only intercourse that can be endured, when the condition of both
parties is similar and equal.2
2. John Calvin, Commentaries on the Four Last Books of Moses (Grand Rapids:
Eerdman's, 1950), p.128
God is the Creator of all men. "He made from one, every nation of
mankind to live on all the face of the earth ... " (Acts 17:26) Men are
distinguished from one another not by metaphysical characteristics; not in
their duty and obligation to their Creator; but only by their faith. God's
people, by faith, keep His laws. Those who are not His people evidence
this fact by hating and transgressing His law; perhaps not continuously and
exclusively, but at least habitually ("By this the children of God and the
children of the devil are obvious: anyone who does not practice
righteousness is not of God, nor the one who does not love his brother." I
John 3:10) All men are responsible to God, and the wicked and
unbelieving are exposed as such in that they do not fulfill this
responsibility. It is not that we, His people, are any better in ourselves
than the wicked. We keep His law only because He has by His Holy Spirit
empowered us to do so (Romans 8:1-4). The law of God binds all men.
Some men are not His people, not because they are not bound by His law,
but because they are in rebellion against it. Some observations of Greg
Bahnsen will suffice to conclude this point.
Since God is the living Lord over all creation and immutable in His
character, and since all men are His creatures and morally accountable to Him,
we are led to believe that God's law (as reflecting the righteousness of God)
applies to every man irrespective of his position in life, situation in the world,
nationality, or place in history .... The conclusion must be. then, that God's
law was binding upon the Gentile as well as the Jew in the age of the Older
Testament. Thus the law itself specified that even the alien was to be judged by
the magistrate in accordance with the standard of God's law (Deut.1:16-17).
"There shall be one standard for the stranger as well as the native, for I am the
Lord your God" (Lev.24:22. NASV; cf Num.15:16, "one law and one
ordinance") .... What is sinful within the borders of Canaan is not condonable
outside, and this is because the Mosaic law does not represent the ethic of a few
Palestinian tribes but the universal and divine standard of righteousness.3
But the people of the Jews had a fuller and higher law, not only with
regard to the repayment of loans but ... with regard to the lending to the
Gentiles on interest and taking usury, namely, by divine authority, which
establishes and permits this very thing. For He is God and Lord of all; He
takes away not only money and goods but also kingdoms and empires from
whomever He wills and however He wills, and gives them to whomever He
wills. If, therefore, for the sake of vengeance on the Gentiles, God wants to
punish them through usury and lending, and commands the Jews to do this, the
Jews do well obediently to yield themselves to God as instruments and to fulfill
His wrath on the Gentiles through interest and usury. This is no different from
when He commanded them to cast out the Amorites and the Canaanites ....
This answers the question how the Jews were permitted to lend on interest.
The answer is: It was not and is not permitted them because of their merit or by
common law but through the wrath of God over the Gentiles, which He wants
to fulfill through the Jews as instruments of His wrath.5
7. Roger Fenton, A Treatise of Usurie (1611; Norwood: Walter Johnson, Inc., 1975),
p.46
8. cited in Jacob R. Marcus, The Jew in the Medieval World (Atheneum: New York,
NY 1969), p.439
some how makes their usury more lawful than in any other case. The
stipulation of the law, to do violence on the wicked, is offensive to
modem-day Evangelicalism. They are frightened by any "us vs. them"
stance vis-a-vis the world. Therefore, for instance, the above cited
Committee Report turned the "countryman/foreigner" distinction of the
text into the mythological "charitablelcommercial" distinction. As much
as modem excusers would like to "break down the dividing wall", and do
away with the "countryman/foreigner" distinction, they do so for the
completely opposite reason that this wall was removed by ancient and
medieval theologians. The 16th century Englishman Fenton maintained
that now God's law prevails on both sides of where once there was a wall,
whereas 20th century usury apologists seem to want the pagan Code of
Hammurabi to prevail. If there no longer is any "Deuteronomic Double
Standard", then there is but a single standard now in force. Is it proper to
universalize the standard of the "brother" side of what once was a wall?
In this case, one ought to relate to all men as brothers, and view lending in
charitable terms in all cases. There would be no "exceptions" in which
case usury is allowed. This is what the Puritans taught. Or is it proper to
universalize the standard of the "foreigner" side? In this case all men
relate to one another not as brothers, but as "foreigners" - not simply men
from another country, but Nokri, i.e. detestable. This would provide the
appropriate social context for the rampant usury that now in fact swarms
over our land today, but it hardly fulfills the biblical vision of Christians
as God's people, who love one another, and compassionately sustain their
poor (in whatever they lack) with loans. Yet this is what the average
"Christian" economist teaches.
Until recently, the passing of the "countryman/ foreigner" distinction
meant the passing of any mitigation of the law, and therefore meant that
usury simply is universally unlawful. Today there is the suggestion that
the "countryman/ foreigner" distinction represents a "qualification" of the
law, which leaves usury lawful regardless of whether the borrower is a
"countryman" or a "foreigner". In order for this modem suggestion to be
upheld, the militaristic nature of the Deuteronomic provision must be
denied. Men may attempt to deny it by means of some brand of
scholarship, however, what cannot be denied is the essentially violent and
oppressive nature of usury. The suggestion that Christians bear an
adversarial relation to other men is shocking to most Evangelicals, yet it is
this very concept which explains the Deuteronomic Double Standard.
Usury is permitted in the case of loans to "foreigners" not because usury is
permitted on "business" loans, but because usury is an act of war (usury is
Neshek, a biting) and "foreigners" are the enemy. It is not suggested here
that some men ought to be identified as "foreigners", against whom
Christians ought to wage war, and loans to whom lawfully may include
usury. Many other questions must be addressed, and many other
assumptions must be brought out into the open, before one can pursue this
idea of warfare. It is something that Evangelicals would rather avoid
discussing. That is why the essence of the Deuteronomic Double Standard
is ignored in favor of the spurious and erroneous poor/rich and
charitable/commercial distinctions. The point in stressing the violent
nature of usury is not to force the issue of warfare between the City of
God and the earthly city. The present study does not afford an
appropriate context in which to state any thesis or position on this subject.
Rather, the objective is to stimulate the brethren, who would not even
consider warfare against unbelievers, also to put off the warfare of usury
among themselves.
One need not decide whether there ought to be warfare between
"them and us", nor stipulate of what it would consist, in order to reach the
conviction that warfare, in the particular form of usury, ought not to exist
among the brethren. As was seen in previous discussions, usury always is
a calamity. If one who is paying usury does not experience its calamity, it
is only because he has managed to pass on to others its calamitous effects.
The array of financial "instruments" which provide a vehicle for usury
these days affords a great population of small-time usurers the luxury of
knowing neither the names nor the faces of those whom they bite. One
must not attempt to justify usury only because he cannot see the pain and
oppression that it brings upon an individual brother. A sincere concern
for the individual alone hardly will uncover the sin of usury. Needed is
the development of a "people-consciousness". A true consciousness of
brotherhood within modern Evangelicalism would almost instantaneously
bring with it the conviction that it is warfare which is waged in the pursuit
of gain through usury, and that it surely must not be waged among the
brethren.
It may seem surprising to some that this exercise of addressing
popular excuses for usury should include a discussion of John Calvin.
Calvin, of course, was a prominent "reformer" during the Reformation of
the church in the 16th century in Europe. Most Christians today at least
have heard of the theological (and philosophical) system that bears his
name: Calvinism. There is a great deal of misunders!anding and
misinformation regarding Calvinism today, but it is not within the scope
of our present purpose to address this problem. Our purpose here is to
discuss Calvin's contribution to the centuries-old controversy on usury.
Whatever the reader's conception of Calvinism, he probably has the
well-founded tendency to associate Calvinism with political and economic
conservatism. Modern Calvinists, such as Gary North, fulfill this
expectation in their writings. In this light, it may surprise some to learn
that Calvin was instrumental in liberalizing the Church's stand on usury.
This explains why it is that even the most strict and conservative Christian
scholars in modem times still hold to what would by medieval standards
be a liberal position on usury. The modern ideas concerning "the poor",
"business loans", and "the Deuteronomic double standard" find their
origin in the writings of John Calvin. Whatever feelings this fact may
evoke in the reader depends on his previously held convictions concerning
both Calvin and usury. Such feelings are of little use. The present
discussion of John Calvin ought in no way to influence the manner in
which the Arminian or Evangelical reader tends to esteem Reformed
theology or world view. The issue of usury not withstanding, the modem
Evangelical has a lot to learn from Calvin. On the other hand, it would be
the height of foolishness for the Reformed reader to embrace the sin of
usury only on the strength of the fact that Calvin liberalized it. The
present procedure will be to survey and evaluate Calvin's teaching on
usury.
As was noted in the previous discussion, the so-called Deuteronomic
Double Standard was a stumbling block for Calvin. Having mis-
interpreted the permission, given in Deuteronomy 23:20, to exact usury
from the "foreigner", Calvin could not bring himself to declare that usury
was inherently evil. There was much more involved than simply the
interpretation of a verse of scripture. His circumstances may help
explain, though not excuse, Calvin's liberal view.
Calvin's life traversed the interface of the medieval and modem eras.
He saw the height of the Renaissance with the consequent blossoming of
the arts and sciences. As well, commerce and industry were gearing up to
an extent that the ancient world never knew. This tended to change the
problem of usury. Loans at usury to capitalize a commercial or industrial
enterprise did not seem to entail the "bite" for which money-lending had
become infamous. Surely, it was thought, commerce and industry would
grow to unimaginable heights if only usury were not restricted. Great
pressure was brought to bear for a loosening of the standard, to allow the
financing that business men sought. Many European states had outlawed
usury, having been convinced by the church. But the loyalty of the state to
the church typically has been pragmatic in nature. As soon as business
interests had succeeded in convincing the state differently - that usury is
desirable so that commerce and industry could be capitalized - the various
states were not slack in converting their loyalties, and legalizing usury. A
host of secular theorists had begun loudly and openly to come to the
defense of usury, and were joined, though less enthusiastically, by a
number of Reformers. 1 Among them, of course, was Calvin. Perhaps
Calvin had come automatically to question whatever position Rome had
taken. In any case, the pro-usury course that he had adopted was not as
defensible as were other points of reform, nor were his pro-usury
arguments as confident and eloquent as his other discourses.
In his struggle to achieve his usual consistency, the maintenance of
the pro-usury position presented a two-fold problem. First, Calvin
wished to remain loyal to the Bible, and to the heritage of the ancient
fathers, who were unequivocally opposed to usury. But, secondly, he
needed to refute the arguments of Aristotle, which had for hundreds of
years dominated the church's theoretical case against usury.
In many passages, Calvin displays his instinct to carry the banner that
is unfurled in the Bible and handed down through the Fathers and
Scholastics. In his commentary on Ezekiel 18 he says, "In a well regulated
1. see Bohm-Bawerk's historical discussion in Capital and Interest (1890; New York:
Kelly & Millman, Inc., 1957), VoLl, p.25ff
state, no usurer is tolerated: even the profane see this : whoever therefore
professedly adopts this occupation, he ought to be expelled from
intercourse with his fellow men. . .. that of the usurer is an illiberal trade,
and unworthy of a pious and honourable man ... And surely the usurer
will always be a robber; that is, he will make a profit by his trade, and will
defraud, and his iniquity will increase just as if there were no laws, no
equity, and no mutual regard among mankind."2 In his commentary on the
Eighth Commandment he comments on the nature of usury that, "it can
hardly be but that usurers suck men's blood like leeches."3 Also, in his
commentary on the Eighth Commandment, Calvin chides those who play
with terminology in order to escape the requirement of God's law. He
accused Israel of calling usury Tarbith (increase) instead of Neshek
(biting), in order to escape the condemnation of the Eighth Commandment.
He says, "For, where He complains of their unjust modes of spoiling and
thieving in Ezekiel, and uses both words as He does here by Moses, there
is no doubt but that He designedly cuts off their empty excuses (Ezek.
xviii. 13.) Lest any, therefore, should reply, that although he derived
advantage from his money, he was not on that account guilty of usury,
God at once removes this pretense, and condemns in general any addition
to the principal. Assuredly both passages clearly shew that those who
invent new words in excuse of evil, do nothing but vainly trifle. I have,
then, admonished men that the fact itself is simply to be considered, that all
unjust gains are ever displeasing to God, whatever colour we endeavor to
give to it."4 In all of this Calvin echoes the sentiments of the church from
earliest times. It certainly was not his purpose to break radically with this
tradition.
However, he failed to hold radically to the tradition. Calvin's view of
usury is not as monolithically traditional as the above quotations, taken by
themselves, might suggest. Due to the pressures described above, his
thinking apparently was confused, or at least inconsistent. For example,
directly following the fairly strong statement that was just quoted, Calvin
adds, "But if we would form an equitable Judgment, reason does not
5. IBID
6. Calvin, Commentaries on Ezekiel, VoI.II, p.228
some theory to explain why it was inherently evil, they were largely at a
loss. Mostly, their practical problem with usury referenced the
ruthlessness of usurers and the miserable lot of debtors. For any
argument that was discreetly theoretical, they were forced to turn to the
pagan philosophers. Since the basic thesis of Aristotle formed the essence
of the theoretical case against usury in the Middle Ages, Calvin rightly
saw the need to refute his arguments. Like Calvin, the present writer as
well holds Aristotle's argument to be flawed, however, unlike Calvin the
present interest in refuting it is not in order to establish the lawfulness of
usury, but to replace a weak and inadequate argument against usury with a
better one.
Aristotle's argument was not highly developed. The basic principle
was that "money is barren"; that is, money does not beget money. On the
strength of this observation, Aristotle declared that gain through usury is
wholly unnatural. This idea held sway for centuries, and formed the basis
for the theoretical arguments of the Scholastics, such as Thomas
Aquinas.? The view is flawed, as were many views of Aristotle, and
Calvin was brave enough to challenge it. To challenge Aristotle required
bravery simply because of the colossal stature he commanded throughout
the Middle Ages. Calvin need only have contemplated the lot of Galileo in
order to gauge the seriousness of his course. But then, being a reformer,
it is certain that he was accustomed to being at odds with Rome. He said,
"Nor will that subtle argument of Aristotle avail, that usury is unnatural,
because money is barren and does not beget money; for ... a cheat ...might
make much profit by trading with another man's money, and the
purchaser of the farm might in the meantime reap and gather his
vintage. "8 Calvin imagines numerous cases where one man somehow
makes a large profit "by trading with another man's money". He concedes
it as obvious that money stored away in a box will never beget more
money, and quickly adds that such is not the purpose or function of
money. This was not a point that had escaped Aristotle, though he did not
admit the same conclusion. In the course of his brief remarks, Aristotle
7. J.T. Noonan, Jr., The Scholastic Analysis of Usury (Cambridge: Harvard Univ.
Press, 1957) Noonan points out that scholastic theory of usury got its start
independent of Aristotle, but the later-incorporated Aristotle gained authority.
8. Calvin, Commentaries on the Four Last Books of Moses, Vol.Ill, p.l3l
says, "For money was intended to be used in exchange, but not to increase
at interest. "9 He centers on the Greek (for him the vernacular)
terminology, viz.Tokos, here translated "interest", as in many versions of
the New Testament. He explains, "And this term interest, which means
the birth of money from money, is applied to the breeding of money
because the offspring resembles the parent. Wherefore of all modes of
getting wealth this is the most unnatural."lQ However, it seems obvious to
Calvin that money put to its right purpose certainly yields gain. Calvin
concentrates on the effects of trading with money. Calvin certainly is
correct in this regard, yet he seems oblivious to the differing legal status
of "lender" and "partner". A partner certainly is entitled, according to
the terms of the partnership, to some share of the venture profits (or
losses), but a lender is entitled only to repayment of the loan.
It is interesting that Calvin should multiply examples and illustrations
utilizing the farm and vineyards, for it is in these cases that Aristotle's
principle falls apart. Money indeed is barren; but a cow is not barren, nor
a seed. If the barrenness of the thing lent is the only reason why usury on
the loan is to be prohibited, then not even Aristotle could argue against
usury on a loan of seed or livestock. Aristotle's problem was that he
approached the problem through science instead of law. The law says that
usury is prohibited not only on money, but also on "food, or anything that
may be loaned at interest" (Deuteronomy 23:19b). The reason that usury
is prohibited is not because it is unnatural, but "so that the Lord yourOod
may bless you in all that you undertake in the land which you are about to
enter to possess." (23:20b). Calvin sought to refute Aristotle in order to
remove all theoretical barriers to usury. The present writer refutes
. Aristotle because his arguments against usury are spurious and
inadequate.
It is apparent that in his pursuit of the conditions under which usury
may be exacted lawfully, Calvin executed a transition in his thinking. In
one passage he flatly stated the unlawfulness of usury in case of loans to
one's brother, and the lawfulness of it only in case of loans to the stranger.
However, the more he wrote about usury, and the more he tried to refute
But if a man is rich, and has moneyof his own,as the sayingis, and has a
very good estate and a large patrimony, and should borrow money of his
neighbor,will that neighborcommit sin by receivinga profitfrom the loan of
his money? Anotherborroweris the richerof the two, and mightdo withoutit
and suffer no loss : but he wishes to buy a farm and enjoy its fruits : why
shouldthe creditorbe deprivedof his rightswhenhis moneybringsa profitto a
neighborricherthanhimself?12
5. Henick, History of Commerce and Industry (New York: The MacmilJan Co.•
1920), p.144
6. NASB Exhaustive Concordance, Hebrew-Aramaic Dictionary (Nashville: Holman
Bible Publishers, 1981)
agreement be made by the partners concerning their share of profit and
loss; the loss and the profit must be equally divided. But if an express
agreement be made, it must be observed ..."7 More numerous and more
complicated regulations sprang up to address the conditions under which
partners in a venture may share the profits and losses unequally.
Important to the issue of usury was the question of whether a man
who contributes money to a commercial venture was to be regarded as a
lender or a partner. This was important because throughout the middle
ages ecclesiastical law (and much civil law) prohibited usury on any loans.
A lender would not be entitled to any profits from the venture; he would
be entitled only to repayment of the loan. A partner, however, would be
entitled to a share of the profits. The basis of this distinction was the legal
precedence that a lender actually transferred ownership of what was
loaned to the borrower, while he who committed money or goods to a
partnership venture retained ownership of them. On the strength of this
idea Thomas Aquinas wrote, "He who commits his money to a merchant
or manufacturer in partnership does not transfer ownership of the money,
so that the merchant or manufacturer works with it at the other's risk,
hence that other may lawfully seek a share in the profit as it arises from
his own property."8 Cleary points out that in this passage Thomas brings
two elements together; ownership and risk. He observes, "Here
ownership of the property is the ostensible reason assigned for a right to a
share in the profit, yet one cannot help thinking that St. Thomas attached
some special importance to the fact that the risk is retained by the
capitalist. "9 That there was an importance attached to the bearing of risk
seems undeniable, however, it also seems that the importance of risk was
other than the importance of ownership, viz. risk was taken as evidence of
partnership, and ownership was the basis of claim on profits. Cleary
observes this fact: "Liability to risk had been made the test of true
partnership by the early cannonists. This was the result of their teaching
7. cited in Cave & Coulson, eds., A Source Bookfor Medieval Economic History
(New York: Biblo and Tannen, 1965), p.184
8. cited in Cleary, The Church and Usury (1914; Hawthorn: The Christian Book Club
of America, 1972), p.87
9.ffiID
on the inseparability of risk and ownership ... " 10 It is clear that risk and
ownership are inseparable in commercial enterprise, since the loss of
property is a hazard that is bourne by the owner. A medieval application
of this principle was a London ordinance of 1391, which declared, "if any
person shall lend or put into the hands of any person, gold or silver, to
receive gain thereby, or a promise for certain without risk, such person
shall have the punishment for usurers ... "11 Risk was a valid test for
partnership simply because the lender originally bore no risk. The debt
of principal and usury to him was dependent on no contingency. It
mattered not whether the borrower prospered or failed.
As was noted in a previous chapter, during the Middle Ages usury
was outlawed throughout much of Europe. This did not stop usury, but
incited an evil sort of creativity in men to arrange their business deals to
accomplish the same thing as usury, while escaping the condemnation of
the statute. Some of these special arrangements, called "extrinsic titles"
dealt with seemingly legitimate claims for the repayment of more than
was loaned, and were readily accepted by the church. One that was not so
easily accepted, however, was the title that was named "Periculum Sortis",
which basically was a claim to compensation because of risk; virtually the
same claim that presently is under examination. The church leadership
stood against such a claim. An example is a decree by Pope Gregory IX:
"He is to be accounted a usurer, who lends a certain sum to one who is
about to make a voyage, or attend a market, on the condition of receiving
more than he lent merely because he undertakes the risks."12 Risk was
recognized as a handy test of ownership, to weed out those business deals
that were so constituted as to get around usury laws, but a considerable
effort was required by usurers to get "Periculum Sortis" recognized as
itself a legitimate claim to compensation over and above the principal.
Finally, at the outset of the Reformation, Periculum Sortis was
recognized. This title was formulated in the same form in which it still
exists today. There is no difference between Periculum Sortis and the
idea that a lender ought to be compensated for taking a risk. The problem
Come now, you who say, "Today or tomorrow, we shall go to such and
such a city, and spend a year there and engage in business and make a profit."
Yet you do not know what your life will be like tomorrow . You are just a
vapor that appears for a little while and then vanishes away. Instead, you ought
to say, "If the Lord wills, we shall live and also do this or that." But as it is,
you boast in your arrogance; all such boasting is evil. Therefore, to the one
who knows the right thing to do, and does not do it, to him it is evil.
That there is undoubtedly an analogy between interest and the profit from
land rent, was very likely to lead logically to a conclusion involving land rent in
the same condemnation as interest. To this Locke's theory would have
presented sufficient support, since he expressedly declares rent also to be the
fruit of another man's industry. But with Locke the legitimacy of rent appears
to have been beyond question.2
The ancient Israelite was free to lend his work animals for pay (Exodus
22:15). He was free to "lend" himself as a laborer for hire (Deuteronomy
24: 15). He was even free to rent out his land (though not to sell it) for a return
based on the number of harvests during the lease (Leviticus 25:15-16). The
1. cited in E. v.Bohm-Bawerk, Capital & Interest (New York: Kelly & Millman, Inc.,
1957), YoU, p.4S
2. IBID, p.46
principle is clear: It was right and proper to expect payment for the usage of
such assets as land, animals. or even one's own person.
But if he could receive payment for the use of his land, by what principle
of equity should he have been forbidden to collect "rent" on the use of his
money?
The answer, of course, is that in fact it is not lawful for one to sell the
use of his property (rent). But that is the point in question, so let us
examine the three scripture references that are given in the remarks cited
above. The most easily dismissed is the idea that wages may be viewed as
"rent" of one's labor. Labor is the most basic manner in which one may
provide a service to others. Goods and services are the property that men
offer in trade with one another. The "hire" of a laborer is what he
receives in exchange for providing the service of his labor. It cannot be
confused with "rent", as Mr. Mitchell himself appears to acknowledge
when he uses "lend" in quotes when applying this term to labor. Also, the
Hebrew word for "hire", sakar, is most often translated "wages" in the
NASB, and in no way can be given the sense of "rent".
Secondly, Mr. Mitchell suggests that the Bible sanctions the renting
of work animals. In support of this he cites Exodus 22:15. The passage in
which this verse is found deals with laws concerning the loss of property
under various circumstances. Starting with v.14, it says, "And if a man
borrows anything from his neighbor, and it is injured or dies while its
owner is not with it, he shall make full restitution. If its owner is with it,
he shall not make restitution; if it is hired, it came for its hire." In the first
case, an animal is borrowed. Under typical terms of a loan, the borrower
owes the lender that which is loaned. The death or injury of the animal
loaned does not alter the fact of this debt. The borrower owes the lender
an animal, even if he cannot give him the very animal which was loaned.
In the next case "its owner is with it", i.e. it is not a loan agreement. Mr.
Mitchell contends that this is a case of rent. However, the text says that
this is another case of "hire" - sakar. If the payer has rented the animal,
then why was the owner with it? If he has not rented it, but hired the
animal, then how did he make a wage agreement with an animal? The
only way in which to understand the text is that this is a case of one hiring
a man with an animal to bring his animal and perform some service with
it. That is why no restitution is required in this case, should the animal die
or suffer injury. The agreement of the payer is to pay the hire for the
services provided by the owner of the animal. It is no economical concern
of his should the owner's animal die or be injured in the performance of
this service.
A modem example will illustrate this point. The animal in this case
may be thought of as a tool. Though animate, it is a device which a man
uses to enhance the effectiveness of his labor. When one hires a plumber
to come to his house and repair a leak, the plumber brings his own tools to
perform the appropriate task. The fee for the plumber's services may be
estimated even before he begins his work, and may vary according to the
cost of the materials he uses and/or the time required for the work.
However, if the plumber should break one of his tools while performing
the work, it would not be lawful for him to hold his customer to be
responsible for this loss. Suppose instead that one should borrow some
tools and attempt to do the work himself. If he breaks a tool, then he is
responsible for it. He must replace it for the one from whom he
borrowed it. If he borrowed a tool, and it "dies", he shall make full
restitution. If the plumber is with it, he shall not make restitution, for "it
came for hire."
This text cannot be made to speak of payment "for the use of
another's property", and there is no linguistic element in the text which
supports the concept of "rent". The rendering of the key phrase in the
New International Version is confusing - "If the animal was hired, the
money paid for the hire covers the loss". This really is a paraphrase, that
is, it is not supported by the original text, but is interpretative. That
would not automatically be a problem, except for the fact that the
interpretation is faulty. The "hire" does not "cover the loss". The "hire"
covers the services rendered. The animal came to provide services, or "it
came for its hire", as the correct rendering says. Loss incurred by the
owner of the animal is the owner's problem. There is no responsibility
laid upon the "customer". There is no sense in which this can be
considered "rent".
Thirdly, Mr. Mitchell cites the Jubilee observance, and the attendant
reversion of lands, as an example of rent. Lev.25:13-16,
On this year of jubilee each of you shall return to his own property. If
you make a sale, moreover, to your friend, or buy from your friend's hand,
you shall not wrong one another. Corresponding to the number of years after
the jubilee, you shall buy from your friend; he is to sell to you according to the
number of years of crops. In proportion to the extent of the years you shall
increase its price, and in proportion to the fewness of the years, you shall
diminish its price; for it is a number of crops he is selling to you.
5. e.g. Cunningham states that the income that feudal tenants provided their lords
was "a very different thing from modem rent." (The Growth of English
Industry and Commerce, VoLl, p.5)
living. God does not speak to us in His Word of rent as we know it. What
He has declared to be unlawful - usury - cannot be legitimized by our
comparing it to a modern invention - rent. It is a curious procedure to
attempt to justify usury by means of positing an identity between usury
and rent. The law of God clearly prohibits the one, and on the strength of
the identity that already is admitted to obtain between them, one ought
easily to arrive at the unlawfulness of the other. Indeed, medieval and
early modem theorists maintained a strict opposition to usury while
seeking to legitimize the rental of tangible property by attempting to show
that the two are very different things. In modern discussions, it seems that
the dissimilarity of rent and usury is stressed whenever it is desired to
legitimize rent, and their essential similarity is stressed whenever it is
desired to legitimize usury. In order to pare away the uncritical
acceptance of rents that stands in the way of many receiving godly
instruction in area of economics, it will be helpful to look a rent in the
context of its historical development.
The origin of rent charges goes back to ancient taxation. Property
rights in Babylonian and Medo-Persian civilization were based on might.
The man with the biggest, or most effectively wielded sword, could claim
the most property. The rest of humanity was left in the position of doing
basically whatever the man with the sword said to do. The powerful
organized a virtual serfdom around themselves, and extracted a variety of
taxes and duties. Greek civilization was more sophisticated, but the idea
of absolute ownership of property still was foreign. In later stages,
Greece had a class of free landowners, though most men either were
urban laborers or rural sharecroppers. Taxation typically was a tribute
that was exacted from conquered peoples. Of Greek dominance over
Egypt, Durant says, "Everywhere the government took rentals, taxes,
customs, and tolls, sometimes labor and life itself. The peasant paid a fee
to the state for the right to keep cattle, for the fodder that he fed them, and
for the privilege of grazing them on the common pasture land."6 This
account shows the similarity in nature of rents and tributes.
6. Durant, The Story of Civilization (New York: Simon & Schuster, 1954), Vol.lI,
p.591
Rome had established a rigorous idea of property ownership based on
land. Property eventually reverted into the hands of the mighty anyway,
through outright conquest or through the distressed sale of war-ravaged
land. Also, farmers-turned-warriors often failed to return to their land
either because of death or because their military travels had introduced
them to the lure of urban life. Thus, a wealthy aristocracy accumulated
much of the real property, and rented it out to the peasantry. As Durant
explains,
The owners rode in now and then to look at their property; they no longer
put their hands to the work, but lived as absentee landlords in their suburban
villas or in Rome. This process, already under way in the fourth century B.C.,
had by the end of the third produced a debt-ridden tenant class in the
countryside, and in the capital a propertyless, rootless proletariat whose sullen
discontent would destroy the Republic that peasant toil had made.7
While the Roman Empire expanded, they also exacted tribute from
conquered peoples. The earliest occurrence of this sort of tribute that ties
linguistically with the modern idea of rent is the Roman census. The
meaning of the Latin term was very much the same as our word; an
enumeration of the population, particularly for the purpose of a head tax.
This term eventually gave rise to the medieval German Zinzen, which
meant "rent, tax, duty, and interest". This is the word that Martin Luther
gave in translation of the Hebrew Neshek (biting) and the Greek Takas
(birthing). The word is still in use to this day, however, its meaning is
limited to "usury".
Our English term "rent" finds its initial use in medieval feudalism.
The feudal system was essentially the same arrangement as ancient
slavery: the powerful assume control of the land and exact tribute from
the peasantry. In this case the "lord" (landlord) allots parcels of land to
his "serfs" (tenants), which they work, and pay to the lord some service or
quantity of produce (rent). One major difference between medieval
feudalism and ancient slavery was the enhanced dignity and status of the
serf. He entered into this arrangement voluntarily (although typically it
was virtually necessary to do so in order to survive), he was free to
conduct business with whatever surplus he had once his obligation to the
lord was satisfied, and most of the time he could pass on his allotted land
to heirs.
The term "rent" derives from the Latin "rendere", which has the
meaning of "payment", and was used not only in the sense of an economic
exchange, but also in the sense of surrendering a city or an army to
captors.8 This is the derivation of both the modem economic meaning of
"rent" and the violent meaning of "rend", i.e. to destroy (sur rend er).
Rent, in its ancient and medieval forms, was in the same class as usury.
Both were a means of one man dominating and enslaving another. Both
came under the condemnation of the church. In the early centuries of the
church, the bishops exhorted Christian lords not to enslave their brethren
as serfs. In short, for the first several millenia of recorded civilization,
rent and usury were treated as simply two types of economic oppression.
The similarity of one to the other served, as Bohm-Bawerk put it, to lead
to a conclusion involving land rent in the same condemnation as interest.
From the later Middle Ages to the present, rental of property was held to
be of a different class than usury on a loan of money. It was the newly
emerging science of economics that provided the theoretical categories in
terms of which such a distinction could be made. Beginning with Thomas
Aquinas, and continuing through the English Puritans, all the condem-
nation of usury in the Bible and the ancient church was directed to the
increase (usury) received on a loan of money, and diverted from the
increase (rent) received on a loan of other property.
The main idea that provided for the theoretical separation of rent and
usury was the distinction that was drawn between "durable" and
"perishable" goods. It was this sort of distinction that allowed Roman law
to specify two different types of loans, the commodatum and the mutuum,
an introduction to which the reader will recall from an earlier discussion.
The commodatum was a contract which provided that the borrower was
granted the use of a particular "durable" good for a specified period of
time, during which time it continued to be considered the property of the
lender, and upon the expiration of which time the very good was to be
restored to the possession of the lender. The contract of mutuum
provided that the borrower was to be granted title and use of certain
"perishable" goods, and the lender held an obligation from the borrower
that the borrower restore to him, by a specified time, goods which are like
the ones loaned in kind, quality, and number. One of the key differences
between commodatum and mutuum is that in the latter contract property
in the good transfers to the borrower, while in the former the property
always remains with the lender. Roger Fenton, an ardent foe of usury in
early 17th century England, defined "usury" only in terms of mutuum.,
and consequently in condemning usury, he meant only the increase
received by the lender of "perishable" goods. His comments in this regard
are typical of the views commonly held in his day:
He who takes usury for a loan of money acts unjustly for he sells what
does not exist, and such an action evidently constitutes an inequality and
consequently an injustice. To understand this we should note that there are
certain things whose use consists in their consumption, as in using wine we
consume it, or as we consume wheat in using it for food. In such cases then,
the use of a thing is inseparable from the thing itself, hence he, to whom the use
is granted, has the thing itself granted to him. Hence in loans of articles of this
description, ownership itself is handed over. If therefore a man wanted to make
two distinct sales, one of wine, the other of the use of the wine, he would be
either selling the same thing twice, or selling what does not exist - wherefore
manifestly he would commit a sin against justice. Similarly, he commits
injustice who lends wine or wheat, seeking a double recompense; the one, the
return of a quantity equal to the loan; the other, which we call usury, a payment
for its use.lO
But there are some things, which to use is not to consume (that is, which
are not consumed in use) : thus one uses a house by dwelling in it, not by
destroying it, and in such a case, a man may transfer the ownership of the
house to another, keeping for himself the right to dwell in it for some time, or
conversely, one may grant the use of the house to another whilst reserving its
ownership. Such a man might lawfully receive a price for the use of the house,
whilst in addition he may demand back the house which he has lent - the course
of action adopted in letting and hiring of houses. I I
10· Thomas Aquinas, Summa The%gica, cited in Cleary, The Church and Usury ,
p.79
II. IBID
distinction of "durable goods" and "perishable goods" is only utilitarian,
that is, it is useful on some occasions to make such distinctions. However,
in reality no good is absolutely durable; all goods are "consumable" or
perishable. The case of goods which are consumed in their first use
merely serves to illustrate this fact more dramatically than the other. To
speak of "durable goods" as opposed to "consumable goods" is only a way
of emphasizing the large difference in degree or rate of perishability of
different goods. To "use" bread is to consume it. This is obvious. But
what is not so obvious is that the same principle holds in the case of a
house or a field. One cannot live in a house without consuming the house.
Anyone who has lived in the same house for any appreciable length of
time is well aware of this fact. It may take much longer to consume a
house than to consume a loaf of bread, nevertheless living in a house and
never doing any maintenance on it will eventually consume it. Its
consumption is not as rapid as the consumption of bread, nor is the
entirety of it directly caused by human activity. Therefore, the tendency
is to view the consumption of a house as fundamentally different that the
consumption of bread. However, in principle it is the same thing. It must
be emphasized that it is only a difference of degree. The distinction of
perishable and imperishable goods is unwarranted since all goods perish
through use. The two imagined categories cannot explain all cases.
Repeated use of a shirt will cause it to perish, yet if one were to loan a
shirt he would expect to receive back the same shirt. So, is the shirt a
"perishable" good, or a "durable" good? If a fee is charged for the use of
the shirt, is this usury? Indeed it is usury.
Perhaps if the economies of the Byzantine era had produced a wider
array of goods, then the gap between consumables and durables might not
have been so firmly fixed in the medieval mind. Presently, we have a lot
of goods which are neither "perishable", in the extreme of something like
food, nor "durable" in the sense of indestructibility. All sorts of
machinery, for instance, occupies this class. In this case, one can morutor
the various stages of consumption of the good. The partially consumed
good may be thought of as "damaged". In this case the damage that is done
to such goods is called "wear and tear". Usually, such wear is not
sufficient to prohibit the return of the identical good that was loaned. In
many cases (such as the wear on internal combustion engines) the wear is
imperceptible following an average use. If the wear is quantifiable, a
money charge covering such wear is appropriate since the article now is
less than it was when it was loaned; returning it in its now worn condition
does not fulfill the obligation of repayment. This payment of money,
however, is not rent. It is a recompense for damages. Consequently, any
"rent" charged on the use of property that goes beyond recompense for
damages done to the property by the user, is the selling of use, or usury.
Linguistically, and in its functional characteristics, rent virtually is
indistinguishable from usury. Both are a violent means of enslavement.
It is a struggle for liberation to become free from both usury and rents.
Both of these are quite effective as a tax and tribute that the dependent
must pay to the "lord". The problem in modern times is that rent
automatically is assumed to be a legitimate economic relationship.
Therefore the undeniable similarity it bears to usury is used to give usury
an air of legitimacy. What must be emphasized is that later medieval
theorists argued for the legitimacy of rent by means of trying to show its
dissimilarity to usury. Until recently, any similarity that was seen
between rent and usury served only to result in the condemnation of rent.
H is a peculiar tactic of modern excusers to attempt to justify usury by
insisting on its similarity to rent. Historically, and theoretically, any
degree of success in trying to legitimize rent has rested upon arguing its
dissimilarity to usury. The modem mind is oblivious to the origin of the
pretended legitimacy of rent, and now glibly supposes that usury is
justified because usury and rent are the same!
This problem would not have arisen if medieval theorists had
succeeded in arriving at truly fundamental economical categories.
"Perishable" and "durable" are not economical categories. They merely
are ways of expressing a high degree of difference in the rate of
perishability of all created things. Strictly, all loans must be treated as
contracts of mutuum. Property and use may not be separated in the case
of any good. Only the thief uses goods that belong to someone else.
Property in a loaned good transfers to the borrower. However, the
borrower may not enrich himself by means of borrowing a lot of goods,
for "the borrower becomes the lender's slave" (Proverbs 22:7b). The
borrower is not free. He is bound by the contract of loan to a specific
performance, viz., to restore to the lender goods oflike kind, quality, and
number as he borrowed. This is true regardless of whether the goods
loaned are money, food, machinery, or houses. It is evident that the
ancient impulse to classify rent and usury together was correct, and that
the medieval idea of separating them was in error. Rent and usury do not
stand apart; they fall together.
The immediate objection to this analysis is that given its truth, much
commerce and industry as we know it is condemned. Acre upon acre of
farm land is not "owned" by the farmer, but rented. All kinds of capital
equipment is not "owned" by the entrepreneur, but by a "leasing
company" and rented to its use. Warehouse and apartment rentals
abound. Is this monolith in fact too great and awesome to condemn? The
ubiquity of usury on "money" has salved men's consciences so now the
rental of almost everything has reached an extent that not even Aquinas
would have tolerated. Horrible scenarios abound: "Without rent, no one
would build apartment buildings." That is the nature of the paralyzing
fear. However, is it unthinkable that apartment buildings ought not to be
built? If one of great means decided to build one and loan its units to poor
people who need a place to live, there is no principle of equity to prohibit
that. In fact, equitably, he may charge them a money fee as compensation
for damages, assuming such damages can suitably be quantified. But there
is no principle of equity that would permit the exaction of rent from such
tenants. This merely is usury and serfdom in disguise.
The abolition of rent along with usury would have no necessary
inhibiting effect on commerce and industry. Most of the commercial
rental agreements can be replaced directly with partnership. The
principle here is precisely the same as in the case of money loans. The
rent on industrial equipment is a gain that is guaranteed to the lender
regardless of the performance of the enterprise. As such it represents a
share of the enterprise's receipts that is claimed by him who has no share
in ownership, and no intention to share in its losses. The principle here is
the same as that stated in a previous segment on the matter of "risk". The
reader is referred there for a more complete treatment. A passage by
Calvin Elliot well sums up the present point,
12. Calvin Elliot, Usury a Scriptural, Ethical and Economic View (Millersburg: The
Anti-Usury League, 1902), p.246-7
of the masses. Jesus said, "You know that the rulers of the Gentiles lord it
over them, and their great men exercise authority over them. It is not so
among you, but whoever wishes to become great among you shall be your
servant." (Matthew 20:25,26) Service is the basis of a righteous economy.
Let not he who sells the use of his property think that he is providing any
kind of a service. Service is a gift, or it is one side of an exchange. As a
component of an exchange, it consists of the perfonnance of some labor,
whether of body or of mind, or the offering of some good. If one does
not produce something that may be given as a gift, or given in exchange,
then he cannot claim to be doing a service. What the seller of uses actually
is doing is playing the lord, and exacting tribute. In the City of God all
tribute is owed directly to our one and only Lord. Far be it from us to
enter into competition for even a portion of what rightly is ascribed only
to God. We must repent, and return to true brotherhood, and serve one
another truly, from the heart, to the glory of God.
Yet another popular excuse for usury is the factor of inflation. The
reader will recall from the previous historical discussion that
governments from antiquity have inflated or "debased" their money. In
modem times, the proliferation of paper "money" is parallel to the
ancient practice of diluting the precious metal content of coins. The end
result is the same: that which is serving the purpose of money becomes
less valuable. The "value" of money is, like other values, subjective. The
only way to think of it and express it is in terms of something else. In the
case of money, changes in value are evident in the rising and falling of
prices. In our day, inflation is tracked and reported based on the rate of
change of the Consumer Price Index. However, the rising of prices is
only symptomatic of the fact that "money" is becoming less valuable.
Suppose that in 1974 $20,000 is loaned for a home mortgage. The entire
amount will not be repaid for thirty years. Before the loan is even one
quarter paid, inflation has ruined the dollar's "purchasing power" by a
considerable margin, as reflected by the Consumer Price Index. Does this
not justify the repayment of a greater face amount than what was loaned,
since more of current dollars are needed in order to equal the value of the
dollars loaned? There are two ways of approaching this issue, both of
which reveal it to be merely an excuse for usury.
First, we must examine this excuse in light of the moral aspect of
inflation. As reported to us in the media, inflation is spoken of as though
it were a mysterious, autonomous, seemingly supernatural phenomenon.
The government's panel of experts is represented as searching diligently
for a solution to this elusive problem. Everything including the greed of
big business, the greed of organized labor, and the general public's lust
for material possessions is blamed for causing inflation. Everything
including cutting government spending, wage and price controls (let the
reader recall Diocletian), and general public "austerity" is proposed as a
solution. All that this sort of knit-brow pomposity accomplishes is to
distract the general public consciousness from the reality of the matter.
The real cause of inflation is the ever widening ratio of "money" to
products and services. Since nowadays "money" comes into being by a
simple stroke of a banker's pen, its increase is able by far to out pace the
increase of available goods that it is supposed to buy. The real solution to
inflation is to take away bankers' money-creation powers, and to repeal
legal tender laws.
In the mean time, the general population is left with the idea that
inflation is like a law of nature. It is, to them, simply another one of those
unpleasant facts of life; like death and taxes. Therefore, all of the energy
and resources that are directed to the problem of inflation have no motive
behind them to combat evil, but only to get around a morally neutral
investment problem. Of course, such a distorted concept of inflation
hardly will challenge anyone's involvement in usury. That is why the
present discussion is necessary.
The fact of the matter is that inflation is a conscious course that is
taken by men who know exactly what they are doing. What they are doing
is lawlessness (Lev.19:35,36; Deu.25:13-15; Pr.ll:l), and therefore evil.
The self-consciousness of this evil in those who would appeal to inflation
in order to excuse their usury is evident in their behavior during times of
deflation. If inflation really justified the practice of requiring in
repayment more than was loaned, then by the same principle deflation
would justify the practice of requiring in repayment less than was loaned.
In hypocrisy some would excuse their usury because of inflation, and yet
during deflation there is no rush to offer rebates to debtors. Gary North
theorizes, "A society could conceivably produce a negative money rate of
interest if the value of the purchasing power of money were rising at a
faster rate than the market's registered rate of time-preference plus the
risk premium."! However, in light of the rising value of money, North
does not envision borrowers repaying less, but an equivalent amount. "If
you could buy more with the money received in the future, you might
need to ask only for an equal amount of paper money or coins as a
retum."2 While North acknowledges the immoral nature of inflation, it
does not seem that this fact has much significance for his counsel to
inflation-ravaged "investors".
On the immorality of inflation Rushdoony has said:
Surely, it is a fair course for one to avoid the effects of other men's
evil deeds. However, neutrality in respect to evil is not permissible
(Ephesians 5: 11) nor possible (Matthew 12:30). Christians must be wise
in this world. We must be light to the world. Let us not be mezmerized
by the media, nor carried along by every wind of doctrine. Our energies
and resources in this area must be devoted to the exposure of the evil of
inflation. Those who have sufficient position and influence must work to
stop the practice of "money creation", In the mean time, our efforts to
protect ourselves from the effects of inflation must be limited to divesting
ourselves of Federal Reserve notes and bank balances, and acquiring
tangible assets. A very effective and popular way of doing this is the
purchase of gold and silver coins. In any case, we must not hedge
ourselves against inflation by plundering our brethren through usury.
Inflation surely is a form of theft, but it simply will not do for Christians
to protect themselves from this evil by means of committing the equally
3. R.I. Rushdoony, The Roots of Inflation (Vallecito: Ross House Books, 1982),
p.5
evil practice of usury upon their brethren. As it is said, "Two wrongs do
not make a right."
The above discussion involves the psychology of inflation, and its
moral nature. Secondly, we might consider usury vis-a-vis inflation on a
more theoretical plane. Initially it will be instructive to notice the role of
inflation according to economists. Some economists (e.g. Keynes)
advocate the use of inflation by governments as a controlling device.
Other economists (notably von Mises) condemn inflation as an
infringement on personal liberty. But no economist argues that inflation
is a necessary condition for the idea of usury. The attempt to justify usury
because of inflation gives inflation entirely too much significance. One
cannot justify usury by an appeal to that which does not even serve as a
necessary condition for the idea of usury. When a man attempts to justify
his actions, he appeals to that which makes his actions necessary. It has not
been demonstrated theoretically that inflation makes usury necessary. In
fact, some today even have advanced the theory that usury causes
inflation.4 Usury certainly aggravates inflation. As prices rise, "interest
rates" rise. This added cost of usury only aggravates the already rising
prices. The actions of modem financial institutions prove that inflation is
not a necessary condition for usury. "Interest rates" will fluctuate with
inflation as reported in the Consumer Price Index, but regardless of what
inflation does, interest never quite seems to make it to zero. According to
the most respected theorists, the necessary condition for usury is not
inflation, but the psychological phenomenon known as "the discount of
future goods as against present goods".5
If the invalidity of excusing usury by an appeal to inflation is as
obvious as the present thesis contends, then one would think that it should
not be too difficult to demonstrate the inadequacy of such an appeal.
However, a disadvantage faced by this writer is that error in this
discussion is more complicated than truth. The complication in this
discussion arises from the confusing nature of the current monetary
system. Under the current system, a loan of "money" is thought of, and
said to be, not a loan of some thing or substance, but a loan of an abstract
4. e.g. Thoren & Warner, The Truth in Money Book (Chagrin Falls: Truth in
Money, inc., 1984)
5. Please see the following discussion
idea known as "purchasing power". Actually, this "purchasing power" is
more than an idea, for it manifestly is a "power". By means of this
mystical power, men may acquire tangible goods and services. In order
to strip away some of the mysteriousness and abstractness which attends
this discussion, it will be helpful to consider the dynamics of fluctuating
values in terms of the ancient barter economy.
In the ancient form of loan, one might loan a bushel of wheat to a
brother with a hungry family. By the end of the next growing season,
when the borrower is able to repay, the exchange ratio of wheat to some
other goods may be much lower than when the loan was made (e.g. wheat
is more plentiful due to an unusually good season; certain other articles
that the lender wishes to acquire now are more scarce, etc.). The "price"
of rope in wheat may be much higher than when the loan was granted,
however, it may be that the "price" of pottery in wheat is much lower. If
the lender was counting on using the repayment of the loan of wheat to
trade for rope, he probably will feel disappointed. If his inclinations are
like modem excusers, he might even feel that the borrower ought to pay
him more wheat than was loaned, since now it is worth less in terms of
rope. But suppose the lender instead wishes to acquire pottery. He will
experience joy, and not disappointment, but will the modem excuser
counsel him to issue a rebate to the borrower since the "price" of pottery
in wheat has declined? In terms of the contract of loan, the borrower
owes the lender exactly what was loaned. The changing subjective
valuations of men during the term of the loan do not alter the borrower's
obligation, nor excuse the lender's covetousness. In the same way, the
fluctuation of prices due to inflation does not alter a borrower's
obligation to repay the exact quantity of dollars as he borrowed.
In summary, the first thing that must be noted concerning inflation is
its evil character. It is not a mysterious phenomenon, the effects of which
the hapless investor must plan carefully to escape. It is a sin of unjust
weights and balances, which evil men consciously enter into in an attempt
to control the economy to their own benefit. The response of the
Christian to this course of sin must be to expose it and combat it - not to
hide from it by plundering his brother. Secondly, in reply to the
theoretical concern it is noted that inflation cannot justify usury simply
because it has never been shown that inflation requires usury. The idea of
usury did not arise in the minds of men because of inflation, but because
of their covetousness. It is invalid to appeal to extraneous factors, like
inflation, to justify what was conceived in sin apart from any thought of
such factors. Inflation cannot require usury just because the changing
valuations of men subsequent to the loan contract cannot lawfully alter the
obligation of the borrower according to the contract.
One of the most sophisticated excuses for usury is what may be
termed "The discount of future goods as against present goods" 1, or "time
preference". The argument for time preference gets a little abstract. If
the reader perceives that this concept of interest has little, if anything, to
do with the medieval and biblical discussions that heretofore have been
entertained, it is because that is precisely the case. The reader who is not
acquainted with the notion of time-preference may elect to skip this
discussion. It may be interesting to learn about this theory, but it is futile
to do so only so one now is in a position to discard it.
With the birth of economics as a distinct theoretical discipline
(usually considered as coincident with the publication of Adam Smith's
The Wealth of Nations in 1776) there came also the secularization of
economic theory. The medieval theorists opposed usury fundamentally
because of the biblical prohibition. Their arguments basically were
appeals to law and authority. The modem economists discounted such
prOhibitions, and insisted on a rigorously secular idea of interest.
Throughout the 18th and 19th centuries, one theory after another was
advanced to explain the "necessity" of usury. These theories differed
from the "Extrinsic Titles" of the 13th and 14th centuries in that the
Extrinsic Titles did not mean to justify usury, but to justify some payment
over and above the principal that was not strictly to be considered usury
(extrinsic to the contract of loan). In fact, the term "interest" came into
vogue because it did not carry with it the negative connotation of "usury".
The "interest theories" of the modem economists mince no words in
declaring the necessity of usury (interest) in economic relations. At the
turn of the 20th century, modem interest theory crystallized around the
idea of "time preference".2
According to the idea of time-preference, one would value goods that
are available today more highly than the promise of the same goods
3. E. v. Bohm-Bawerk, Capital and Interest (1890; New York: Kelley & Millman,
Inc., 1957), Vol I, p.257-8
as Btihm-Bawerk put it, "The replacement of the capital + the interest
constitutes the full equivalent."4
It must be noted that this time-preference has nothing to do with
inflation. Currently, inflation causes 1986 "dollars" to have much less
purchasing power than had 1967 "dollars". So it may also be argued in
inflationary times that, since "dollars" repaid are worth less than "dollars"
previously loaned, then more of them are required in order to constitute
the repayment of a value equal to what was loaned. Although similar in
appearance, this actually is a different matter. The question of inflation
was treated at length in a previous discussion. The "time-preference" idea
is not concerned with and does not pretend to prophesy regarding
inflation. "Dollars" may have greater purchasing power in the future
than when they are loaned, but still, future goods are valued at a discount
just because they are future.
What is interesting in this development of the theory is that it is
represented as required that there be interest paid in order for the loan to
be considered as repaid in full. But, no one today who appeals to this
"time-preference" theory is happy merely to be repaid in full. They
actually want a profit. That is why they lend. They also are the ones who
cry, "Without interest, no one would lend!" To argue that usury is
necessary in order for the repayment to be the equivalent of the loan, and
then on that basis to ply usury as a means of gain, is nothing short of
hypocrisy. Once usury becomes justified as necessary in order to make a
full equivalence in repayment, then that very principle may safely be set
aside, and men may carry on profiting through usury on loans without the
social stigma that previously, and rightly, they suffered.
Modem Christian financial counselors, notably Gary North, have
been parroting this interest theory as a justification of usury. Dr. North
argues for "time-preference" as follows:
Every rational person discounts the value of future economic goods. Men
are mortal; they are subject to the burden of time. Each man places a premium
on the use of his wealth over time; he will not voluntarily forfeit that use
without compensation. His personal time-preferenc~ sets his discount rate for
the enjoyment of future goods and services that his money might buy
immediately. That rate of discount sets the rate of interest that he will demand
from someone who wants to borrow his money. Because money is more
highly valued now than the same amount of future money is valued now
(assuming a stable purchasing power for money), some men are willing to pay
to get access to money now.5
The fact that some men are willing to pay for the use of property
(usury) is incidental to the question of whether usury is lawful. The above
explanation of Dr. North does not justify usury, it merely describes how
men excuse their sin. If one man would rather use his money now than
later, then why does he not just go ahead and use it? The would-be
borrower in this case must be told that no money is available for loan,
because it is in use. If, however, he is not using it, then why would he feel
that he must demand compensation if someone wants to borrow it? In the
modem "fractional reserve" banking system, there is no such thing as
money that is not in use. All money is by definition in use at all times. No
bank has extra money that they would be willing to loan. When a bank
today extends a loan, the money that is loaned is created for that specific
purpose. In terms of the "time preference" idea, the borrower basically is
said to be hiring the bank to create some money for him. To call it hiring
is much too sterile; in reality usury is a bribe. Now, consider the
dynamics of lending in case the lender does not have this mystical power
to create money. Suppose one seeks a loan of "money" from a friend. In
this case the thing which is sought in loan already exists, and it either is in
use by the lender or it is not. Whether or not it is in use, the lender could
point out to the would-be borrower the interesting fact that the "money"
itself is worth more to him than the other's promise to pay the same
amount some time in the future. The reality of this preference is true, and
it is interesting to note, however it hardly follows from this that the lender
is justified in requiring more in repayment than what was loaned. Ought
the principle of law to revolve around subjective human preferences? If
one suggests that it is lawful for a lender to require a bribe from the
5. The appeal to Mr. Bahnsen's work on the question of God's law does not imply that
Mr. Bahnsen endorses the present thesis on usury.
What is sin? Sin is any want of conformity unto, or transgression of,
the law of God.
So says the Westminster Shorter Catechism (Question 14).
The Usurer shall crie unto his children [from hell], Cursed be you my
children, because you were the cause of these torments, for least you should be
poore, I was an Usurer, and robbed other, to leave riches unto you. To
whome, the children shall replie againe, nay, Cursed be you father, for you
were the cause of our torments; for if you had not left us other mens goodes,
we had not kept other mens goodes. Thus when they are cursed of God, they
shall curse one another, curse the Lord for condemning them, curse their sinnes
for accusing them, curse their parents for begetting them, and curse themselves,
because they cannot helpe themselves.2
Usury breaks the Sabbath. Since the modem mind is dull, it must be
pointed out that if there was any true sense in which "money" could work,
then to the above there would have been added, "or your money". It
already has been shown that "money" in fact does not work. But inasmuch
as the usurer perceives it as working, and does not give it a Sabbath rest,
Then the Lord spoke to Moses, saying, "When a person sins and acts
unfaithfully against the Lord, and deceives his companion in regard to a deposit
or a security entrusted to him, or through robbery, or ifhe has extorted from his
companion, or has found what was lost and lied about it and sworn falsely, so
that he sins in regard to anyone of the things a man may do; then it shall be,
when he sins and becomes guilty, that he shall restore what he took by robbery,
or what he got by extortion, or the deposit which was entrusted to him, or the
lost thing which he found, or anything about which he swore falsely; he shall
make restitution for it in full, and add to it one-fifth more. He shall give it to the
one to whom it belongs on the day he presents his guilt offering."
Jesus said that nothing of the law would pass away until all was
accomplished (Matthew 5:17-19). He did not diminish man's duty to God,
or to his brother, rather He enlarged upon it. He said, "A new
commandment I give to you, that you love one another." (John 13:34)
But this is not a new duty, rather it enlarges our understanding of the
requirement of the Decalogue. On the principle of love, Jesus said that we
must not only abstain from killing, but also abstain from hate; we must not
only abstain from adultery, but also from lust (Matthew 5:21-28). Paul
said, "love does no wrong to a neighbor; love therefore is the fulfillment
of the law" (Romans 13:10) Jesus coupled this principle of love for men
with the requirement of loving God, and said of this pair, "On these two
commandments depend the whole Law and the Prophets". (Matthew
22:40). We have exposed the evil of usury on several fronts, in
examination of several points of the law. That which is evil is supremely
condemned by that on which the law depends, for usury manifestly is
lacking in love. The usurer is in want of true love for God, for in
defiance of His law, the usurer excuses his sin in preference of temporal
pleasures. He also is in want of true love for his brother, for he would
feed off of him rather than labor to feed himself. As Henry Smith put it:
The Usurer loveth the borrower, as the Ivye loveth the Oke: The Ivye
loveth the Oke to grow up by it, so the Usurer loveth the borrower to grow rich
by him. The Ivye claspeth the Oke like a lover, but it claspeth out all the juice
and sap, that the Oke can not thrive after: So the Usurer lendeth like a friend but
hee covenanteth like an enemy, for he claspeth the borrower with such bands,
that ever after he diminisheth, as fast as the other encreaseth.3
For this you know with certainty, that no immoral or impure person or
covetous man, who is an idolater, has an inheritance in the kingdom of Christ
and God. Let no one deceive you with empty words, for because of these
things the wrath of God comes upon the sons of disobedience. Therefore do
not be partakers with them; for you were formerly darkness, but now you are
light in the Lord; walk as children of light (for the fruit of the light consists in all
goodness and righteousness and truth), trying to learn what is pleasing to the
Lord. And do not participate in the unfruitful deeds of darkness, but instead
even expose them; for it is disgraceful even to speak of the things which are
done by them in secret. But all things become visible when they are exposed by
the light, for everything that becomes visible is light. For this reason it says,
"Awake, sleeper,
And arise from the dead,
And Christ will shine on you."
Let us not suppose that the plague of usury oppresses us only by the
designs of "international bankers", or some other group. Men are not
sovereign in the world. We are not in reality compelled to live like
Babylonians. It is in unfaithfulness to our God and His Word that we have
so become entangled. But, the sins which so easily entangle us become a
scourge in the hand of God. Let us not regard lightly the discipline of the
Lord. He disciplines every son whom He receives. We cannot defy His
laws and expect that we shall escape the consequences. God is not mocked.
The calamities of our sin are to stimulate us to repentance. "He disciplines
us for our good, that we may share His holiness. All discipline for the
moment seems not to be joyful, but sorrowful; yet to those who have been
trained by it, afterwards it yields the peaceful fruit of righteousness."
(Hebrews 12:10-11). Some in American Christendom are experiencing
the sorrows of the Lord's discipline. They have had enough of debt.
They are ready to repent. Others still are intoxicated by the gains of
usury. They will not repent of usury, nor do they wish for their brothers
to stay out of debt, for there must be someone to pay their usury. If there
will not be repentance, we can be sure there will be more discipline. This
is certain. The question is, what how much discipline must we endure
before we turn?
If we do not repent in time, we will be caught up in the destruction
that perpetually attends Babylonian life. A temptation we face, in addition
to the false riches of usury, is to excuse our sin, and ease the convicting
sensation in our hearts, by blurring the distinction between law and
lawlessness. But this can only be a blurring of our own vision, for in
reality no aspect of the City of God can be confused with any aspect of
"the earthly city". Dr. Kuyper said, "Do not forget that the fundamental
contrast has always been, is still, and will be until the end: Christianity
and Paganism, the idols or the living God."4 Speaking of the political
troubles at the turn of this century, Dr. Kuyper responded in a manner
that speaks as well to the problem of usury, "Of course, this danger would
be far less menacing in case Christendom, in both the Old and the New
World, stood united around the Cross, shouting songs of praise to their
W.J. Ashley, English Economic History and Theory (1919; New York: A.M. Kelly,
1966)
Summerfield Baldwin, Business in the Middle Ages (New York: Holt & Co., 1937)
H.E. Barnes, An Economic History of the Western World (New York:Harcourt,
Brace & Co., 1942)
Cave & Coulson, eds., A Source Bookfor Medieval Economic History (New York:
Biblo and Tannen, 1965)
Commanger & Morris, eds. The Spirit of 'Seventy- Six (New York: Bonanza Books,
1983)
W. Cunningham, The Growth of English Industry and Commerce (1910; New York:
AM Kelly, 1968) 2 Vols.
Will Durant, The Story of Civilization ,(New York: Simon & Shuster, 1954), VoLI-
N
A.R. Epperson, The Unseen Hand (Tuscon: Publius Press, 1985)
Verna M. Hall, The Christian History of the American Revolution (San Francisco: The
Foundation for American Christian Education, 1976)
Edouard Heimann, History of Economic Doctrines (New York: Oxford University
Press, 1964)
C.A Herrick, History of Commerce and Industry (New York: Macmillan, 1920)
R.K. Hoskins,War Cycles - Peace Cycles (Lynchburg: The Virginia Publishing Co.,
1985)
W.A. Jurgens, The Faith of the Early Fathers (Collegeville: The Liturgical Press,
1970) 3 Vols
John Kent, 2000 Years of British Coins and Medals (British Museum Publications,
1978)
Herman E. Kroos, ed., Documentary History of Banking & Currency in the United
States (New York: Chelsea House, 1983) 4 Vols.
Jacob R. Marcus, The Jew in the Medieval World (New York: Atheneum, 1969)
James B. Pritchard, ed, Ancient Near Eastern Ta:ts (Princeton: Princeton University
Press, 1969)
Carroll Quigley, Tragedy and Hope (New York: Macmillan Co., 1966)
Philip Schaff, Creeds of Christendom (1877; Grand Rapids: Baker, 1977) 3 Vols.
Max Shapiro, The Penniless Billionaires (New York: Times Books, 1980)
Cleon Skousen, The Naked Capitalist (privately published, 1970)
AD. White, Fiat Money Inflation in France (1876; Caldwell: Caxton, 1974)
Greg L. Bahnsen, Theonomy in Christian Ethics (Phillipsburg: Presbyterian &
Reformed, 1977)
Frederick Bastiat, The Law (1850; Irving-on-Hudson: FEE, 1984)
Sir William Blackstone, W.C. Jones, ed., Commentaries on the Laws of England
(1915; Baton Rouge: Claitor's, 1976)
T. Robert Ingram, The World Under God's Law (Houston: St. Thomas Press, 1962)
Sir Henry S. Maine, Ancient Law (1861; Dorset Press, 1986)
G. Campbell Morgan, The Ten Commandments (Grand Rapids: Baker, 1977)
Rushdoony,The Institutes of Biblical Law (Nutley: Presbyterian & Reformed, 1973)
ECONOMICS
Eugen von BOhm-Bawerk, Capital and I merest (New York: Kelly & Millman, Inc.,
1957)
Ron Blue, Master Your Money (Nashville: Thomas Nelson, 1986)
Larry Burkett, Your Finances in Changing Times (Chicago: Moody Press, 1982)
Alejandro A. Chafuen, Christians for Freedom - Late-Scholastic Economics (San
Francisco: Ingatius. Press, 1986)
Gertrude M Coogan, Money Creators (1935; Hawthorne, CA: Omni Publications,
1982)
Rev. Denis Fahey, Money Manipulation and Social Order, (1944;Hawthorn, CA:
OmniPublications, 1986)
M. Fries & C.H. Taylor, The Prosperity Handbook (Oakland: Communications
Research, 1984)
Henry Hazlitt, Economics in One Lesson (New York: Arlington House, 1979)
Ludwig yon Mises, TheTheory of Money and Credit (1934; Indianapolis: Liberty
Classics, 1981)
HumanAction (1949; Chicago: Contemporary Books)
Gary North, An Introduction to Christian Economics (The Craig Press, 1973)
Honest Money (Ft. Worth: Dominion Press & Nashville: Thomas
Nelson, 1986)
Inherit the Earth, (Ft Worth: Dominion Press, 1987)
Condy Raguet, A Treatise on Currency & Banking (1840; New York: A.M. Kelly,
1967)
William F. Rickenbacker, Death of the Dollar (New York: Arlington House, 1968)
R. J. Rushdoony, The Roots oflriflation, (Vallecito: Ross House, 1982)
F. Tupper Saucey, The Miracle On Main Street, (Sewanee: Spencer Judd, 1980)
Hans Sennholz, Age of Inflation (Belmont: Western Islands, 1979)
Money and Freedom (Cedar Falls: Center for Futures Education,
Inc., 1985)
Roger Sherman, A Caveat Against Injustice (reprinted by Spencer Judd: Sewanee, TN
1982)
Mark Skousen, The 100 Percent Gold Standard (Lanham, Md: University Press,
1980)
Adam Smith, E. Cannan, ed., The Wealth of Nations (1776; New York: Random
House, 1937)
R.C. Sproul, Jr., Money Matters, (Wheaton: Tyndale House, 1985)
Thoren & Warner, The Truth in Money Book (Chagrin Falls: Truth in Money, 1984)
George Tucker, The Theory of Money and Banks Investigated (1839; New York:
Greenwood Press, 1968)
David Wells, Robinson Crusoe's Money (1896; New York: Greenwood Press, 1969)
G.K. Chesterton, Utopia of Usurers, and Other Essays (1917; Freeport: Books fot
Libraries Press, 1967)
Rev. P. Cleary, The Church and Usury (1914; Hawthorne: The Christian Book Club
of America, 1972)
Calvin Elliott, Usury, A Scriptural, Ethical, and Economic View (Millersburg: The
Anti-Usury League, 1902)
Roger Fenton, A Treatise of Usurie (1611; Norwood: WalterJ. Johnson, inc.,1975)
Benjamin Nelson, The Idea of Usury, From Tribal Brotherhood, to Universal
Otherhood (Princeton: Princeton Univ. Press, 1949)
J. T. Noonan, The Scholastic Analysis of Usury (Cambridge: Harvard University
Press, 1957)
F.W. Ryan, Usury and Usury Laws, (New York: Houghton Mifflin, Co, 1924)
Nicolas Sander, A Briefe Treatise of Usurie (London, 1568)
Henry Smith, An Examination of Usury in Two Sermons (1591; Norwood: Walter
Johnson, 1975)
Thomas Wilson, A Discourse Uppon Usurye (London, 1572)
Romans
Jeremiah 1:30 33
8: 17 95 3:21. 213
15: 10 105 4: 17......................... 220
30:21 167 6: 12......................... 216
7:7,12,14 213
Ezekiel 8:1-4 146,213
14:7 147 13: 10 231
18:1-17 106f
18:5-9 24,147 I Corinthians
18:12-13 24,156 3:6........................... 223
22: 1-2...................... 108f
22:29........................ 147 n Corinthians
10:5 60.163
4:3........................... 230
10:35 179 4:13-17 171,204
11 :5-6 13 7
19: 12-24 15, 11Of I John
20:9-16 176f 3:4 215
3: 10 146
6:27 220 Revelation
13:34........................ 231 18: 1-20 236f
20:27........................ 215 21 :6 222
21 :23........................ 222
American Colonies 67 basis of economy.............. 81
American National Bank 68f bondage of debtor 22,31,32
Anderson, E.L. 85 69,84f
Aquinas,Thomas .43f, 168, 184 of government 61,71,85,140
Aristotle 6,33f,43, 157f, 167 remission of 25,130f
third world crisis 86
Babylon 19,26,56 "Dollar" defined 68
Bahnsen, Greg 213f
Bank of England 63 Elliot, Calvin 113,188
Bank of France 66 Executive Orders 78,86
Bankruptcy Laws 83 Extrinsic Titles 47f, 169,197
Barbarians 39
Barter.................. 20f Fahey, Rev. Denis 75,76
Bastiat, Frederic 75 Farm Crisis 85
Bentham, Jeremy 52 Federal Reserve System 73f
Bills of Exchange 58f Federal Reserve Notes 78
Blackstone, William 5,8,9 illustrated 79
Bohm-Bawerk, E.v 172,198,20lf Fenton, Roger. ..7,9,49,50,118,129,
Burkett, Larry 15 151,183
Byzantinum 39
Gresham's Law 63
Calvin, John ...50,96,113,123,144f, Greece 28,30
154f
Calvinism 154 Hamilton, Alexander 68
Charlemagne 40f Hammurabi, Code of 3,20,28
Chesterton, G.K. 8 Heidleberg Catechism 50
"Church Fathers" 34 Hoskins, R.K 56
Coogan, Gertrude M 74,76 Howard, Rev. E.!. 134,135
Continental Currencies 67
Council of Elvira 35 Inflation 191 f
Council of Nicea 35 Interest, origin of term .4,48,94
Crusades .42 Islam 40,42
Would you like more information, or help with the practical implications of
our position? Send in your questions or objections, or simply give your name
to be put on the mailing list. An on-going discussion of our position will be
aired in a periodical news-letter, "The Theopolitan," which will be sent free of
charge to all who reply.