High Speed Rail Report
High Speed Rail Report
High Speed Rail Report
Rail Study
Phase 2 Report
1 The inter-city market is defined as journeys over 600 kilometres between the six main towns and cities in the corridor based on
population – Brisbane, Gold Coast, Newcastle, Sydney, Canberra and Melbourne.
2 The regional market has been broken into long regional trips greater than 250 kilometres, which includes Sydney-Canberra, and
short regional trips less than 250 kilometres, which includes Brisbane-Gold Coast and Newcastle-Sydney.
Key Findings
Sydney-Melbourne line
Sydney-Canberra 2027 2035
Canberra-Melbourne 2032 2040
Brisbane-Sydney line
Newcastle-Sydney 2037 2045
Brisbane-Gold Coast 2043 2051
Gold Coast-Newcastle 2048 2058
Sydney-Melbourne line
Sydney-Canberra 2022 (earliest possible start) 2030
Canberra-Melbourne 2027 2035
Brisbane-Sydney line
Newcastle-Sydney 2032 2040
Brisbane-Gold Coast 2038 2046
Gold Coast-Newcastle 2043 2053
High Speed Rail Phase 2 / ix
Financial assessment
The HSR program and the majority of If HSR passenger projections were met
its individual stages are expected to at the fare levels proposed, the HSR
produce only a small positive financial system, once operational, could generate
return on investment. sufficient fare revenue and other revenue
to meet operating costs without ongoing
• The distribution of the economic benefits of public subsidy.
HSR between users of the system and the
operator(s) would depend on the prices charged. • Post construction, the HSR program as a whole,
and each of its sectors (with the exception of
• Based on charging competitive fares, the HSR Sydney-Canberra as a stand-alone sector) are
operations and ancillary services (such as car expected to generate sufficient operating income
parking and lease revenues from related property to cover their ongoing operational and asset
development) would not deliver sufficient renewal costs.
revenue to fund or recover the expected capital
costs of the HSR program. HSR fares adopted for the study have been
assumed to be comparable to air fares on the
Governments would be required to fund the inter-capital routes, and it would appear HSR
majority of the upfront capital costs. could sustain higher fares.
• The potential to attract private finance is limited. • Increasing the cost of fares would increase the
An expected return of at least 15 per cent would financial returns and reduce the funding gap,
be required at this stage of project development although doing so would reduce the number of
to be attractive to commercial providers of debt people using the system. Even so, the economic
and equity to major infrastructure projects. HSR benefits of the program would remain positive.
would fall well short of this. • Given that airfares in Australia are already
• The estimated real financial internal rate of highly competitive on major routes, it is not
return (FIRR) is 1.0 per cent for Sydney- expected that airlines would respond to HSR
Melbourne and 0.8 per cent for the competition by reducing fares on a sustained
whole network. basis. It has been assumed, in line with
international experience, that airlines would
• If potential commercial funding were maximised,
quickly reduce capacity, either by reducing
a funding gap in the order of $98 billion, or
frequencies or aircraft sizes, to locations within
86 per cent of the up-front capital cost of the HSR
the HSR corridor where there is significant
program, would remain.
passenger diversion to HSR. It is likely that any
reduction in capacity would be redeployed to
routes outside the HSR corridor.
• Nevertheless, to the extent that airlines are
able to innovate in ways that have not been
anticipated in this study, there would be an
impact on HSR patronage and capacity to
meet operating costs. The sensitivity tests
included one scenario in which airfares were
reduced by 50 per cent for two years.
Key Findings
Economic assessment
Investment in a future HSR program could calculated using a discount rate of four per cent
deliver positive net economic benefits. a year until the start of construction in 2027
(financial year 2028), and expressed in $2012.
• The Sydney-Melbourne line would deliver a
slightly higher economic internal rate of return • The economic results remain positive under a
(EIRR) on investment than the whole network range of changed assumptions. When calculated
would. The EIRR of Sydney-Melbourne is using a seven per cent discount rate, which
estimated at 7.8 per cent, compared to 7.6 per represents a higher hurdle rate for judging
cent for an investment in the staged HSR economic performance, the EBCR would be 1.1
program as a whole. and the ENPV would be $5 billion.
• The economic benefit cost ratio (EBCR) • Most of the economic benefits (90 per cent)
calculates the ratio of the present value of would accrue to the users of the HSR system.
benefits to the present value of costs. When About two-thirds of the user benefits are
calculated using a discount rate of four per cent, attributable to business users travelling long
the ECBR is 2.5 for Sydney-Melbourne and 2.3 distances, which reflects in part the relatively
for the whole network. higher value of time attributed to business
travellers compared to leisure travellers.
• The economic net present value (ENPV) of
costs and benefits associated with a program • Externalities would be relatively minor,
of investment in the preferred HSR system accounting for only about three per cent of
would be $70 billion for Sydney-Melbourne the benefits.
and $101 billion for the network as a whole,
The expected growth in Without HSR, aviation would remain the primary
means of transport for long distance interstate
travel demand
(and some inter-regional) trips and road-based
Population and employment growth will continue travel by private vehicle would remain the primary
to challenge the capacity of existing transport mode for connections with, and between, regional
networks and public infrastructure along the centres. Together these would carry over 90 per
east coast of Australia1. Travel on the east coast cent of the trips on the east coast, subject to
of Australia is forecast to grow at around 1.8 per capacity being available.
cent per year over the next 20 years, increasing by
approximately 60 per cent by 2035. By 2065, travel This strategic study investigates how HSR can play
on the east coast will have more than doubled, an effective role in meeting future travel demand
from 152 million trips in 2009 to 355 million trips by providing an alternative mode of transport that
per year2 . would be attractive for people to use.
1 Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS) mid-range population projections estimate that between 2011 and 2050, the population will
grow by 37 per cent in NSW, 49 per cent in Victoria and 80 per cent in Queensland. ABS, Population Projections Australia 2006 to
2101, catalogue no. 3222.0.
2 See Chapter 2 for detail of how these forecasts were determined.
3 Japan, Italy, France, Germany, Spain, Switzerland, Belgium, Netherlands, Luxembourg, China, United Kingdom, Korea, Taiwan
and Turkey.
4 Derived from The World Bank, High speed rail: the fast track to economic development?, 2010 (updated).
5 Zhang Jianping, Planning and Development of High Speed Rail Network in China, UIC 8th World Congress on High Speed
Rail, 2012.
6 For example, both France and Spain operate services with speeds of over 300 kilometres per hour in commercial service.
7 Particularly in France and Germany and, to a limited extent, in Japan and China.
High Speed Rail Phase 2 / 5
Regional stations were selected on the basis of avoid disruption to built-up areas, these stations
potential patronage and have been proposed at would be located outside the current urban areas,
the Gold Coast, Casino, Grafton, Coffs Harbour, although they would typically be within ten to
Port Macquarie, Taree, Newcastle, Central Coast, 20 kilometres of the town centre and would
Southern Highlands, Wagga Wagga, Albury- have both car parking facilities and facilities to
Wodonga and Shepparton. To minimise cost and interchange with local public transport services.
Figure ES-1 Preferred HSR alignment and stations for the east coast of Australia
BRISBANE
Gold
QLD Coast
Casino
NSW Grafton
Coffs
Harbour
LINE 2
Port
Macquarie
Taree
Newcastle
Central Coast
SYDNEY
Wagga Wagga
CANBERRA
ACT
Albury-
Wodonga
Shepparton
VIC
MELBOURNE
BRISBANE
QLD Gold
Coast
2 hrs 37 mins
NEWCASTLE TO SYDNEY
Newcastle
39 mins
SYDNEY
SYDNEY TO MELBOURNE
SYDNEY TO CANBERRA
2 hrs 44 mins
64 mins
ACT
CANBERRA
VIC
MELBOURNE
Inter-capital express
Executive Summary
Table ES-1 Typical HSR travel times and distances between selected stations on Brisbane-Sydney line
Destination
Coffs Central
Newcastle Sydney
Harbour Coast
Table ES-2 Typical HSR travel times and distances between selected stations on Sydney-Melbourne line
Destination
Southern Albury-
Canberra Melbourne
Highlands Wodonga
0hr 29min 1hr 04min 1h 11min 1hr 55min 2hr 44min 3hr 03min
Sydney
(98km) (280km) (280km) (540km) (824km) (824km)
Southern 0hr 39min 1h 31min* 2hr 29min
- -
Highlands (183km) (442km) (727km)
Origin
Services would typically operate 18 hours per day Ultimately, train frequencies would be influenced
for 365 days per year. Service frequencies would by future market needs and the preferred train
typically be at least hourly, increasing as demand operating strategy (operating speeds and stopping
grew to reach peak period service frequencies in patterns) but the indicative frequencies established
2065, as shown in Table ES-3. for this study are compatible with the forecast
demand and efficient train utilisation.
Table ES-3 Peak service frequencies in 2065 (per hour in each direction)
Brisbane-Sydney 3-4 2
Gold Coast-Sydney - 4
Sydney-Canberra 1 2
Sydney-Melbourne 5 2
Canberra-Melbourne 1 1
8 For example, the average HSR single fares assumed in the reference case between Sydney and Melbourne were $141 for the average
business passenger and $86 for the average leisure passenger but sensitivity tests also considered fares up to 30 per cent and 50 per
cent greater. The corresponding average fares paid by air passengers were estimated as $137 and $69 respectively.
9 The reference case is part of the central case established for evaluation.
Executive Summary
Figure ES-3 HSR travel demand in 2065 between major cities – passenger trips
BRISBANE
QLD Gold
Coast
10.86 million
SYDNEY
SYDNEY TO MELBOURNE
SYDNEY TO CANBERRA
18.76 million
5.19 million
ACT
CANBERRA
VIC
MELBOURNE
*Includes new demand induced by the construction of HSR. Assumes the full system is operational.
10 Inter-city trips are defined as journeys over 600 kilometres between the six main towns and cities in the corridor based on population
(Brisbane, Gold Coast, Newcastle, Sydney, Canberra and Melbourne). Regional trips have been broken into long regional trips of
greater than 250 kilometres, which includes Sydney-Canberra, and short regional trips of less than 250 kilometres, which includes
Brisbane-Gold Coast and Newcastle-Sydney.
Executive Summary
Figure ES-4 HSR travel demand in 2065 by journey type (assuming the full HSR network was operational) – passenger trips
1%
13%
24%
9%
25%
27%
Figure ES-5 HSR travel demand in 2065 by journey type (assuming the full HSR network was operational) – passenger kilometres
Figure ES-4
Passenger Trips
2%
<1%
9%
29%
26%
33%
Table ES-5 shows the forecast travel matrix areas, other than that to and from Wollongong. A
for the reference case in 2065 when the full small proportion of the omitted longer trips could
network would be operational. Intermediate use HSR, and to this extent, the HSR forecasts
stations between capital centres are aggregated are conservative. Trips to and from places external
for presentation purposes. Excluding commuter to the study area were also excluded. The excluded
markets, Sydney-Melbourne is the largest market trips referred to above are shown by an X in
segment for HSR with about 19 million passenger the table.
trips, considerably more than the next largest,
Brisbane-Sydney, with nearly 11 million passenger About half of the HSR demand would be
trips and almost four times Sydney-Canberra, with diverted from forecast air travel as shown in
about five million passenger trips. Figure ES-6. About 19 per cent of total
trips would be new demand generated by the
Some travel was omitted from the matrix because introduction of an HSR service (shown as
it covered only a short distance, or would be best induced demand).
served by car, implying that few such journeys
would be likely to transfer to HSR. This included
all travel wholly within each of the intermediate
Table ES-5 HSR travel market matrix for 2065 (‘000 trips in both directions per year)
Intermediate
Intermediate
Intermediate
Intermediate
Gold Coast
Melbourne
Newcastle
Canberra
Brisbane
Sectors
Sydney
Brisbane X 2,210 1,650 750 600 10,860 1,240 1,130 730 2,490 Total
Gold Coast X 900 520 580 3,830 610 190 440 340
Intermediate X 810 X 5,500 190 330 X 850
Newcastle X 170 1,760 220 250 150 330
Intermediate X 2,990 20 300 X 730
Sydney X 2,690 5,190 2,290 18,760
Intermediate 80 480 100 2,320
Canberra X 640 2,720
Intermediate X 4,660
Melbourne X
Total 83,600*
*Cells may not exactly sum to the total due to rounding.
Executive Summary
Figure ES-6 Source of HSR travel demand in 2065 by journey type (passenger trips)
All
19%
2%
55%
23%
1%
Business
24%
<1%
9% 66%
<1%
Non-business
17%
2%
49%
30%
2%
Figure ES-6
High Speed Rail Phase 2 / 15
How the total HSR and air market would be Melbourne and Sydney-Brisbane), observed HSR
shared between the two modes of transport is a market shares range from around 55 per cent up to
key issue in the demand assessment. Considerable around 70 per cent.
evidence has been assembled in the international
literature on the impacts of HSR on inter-capital This study’s reference case inter-capital forecasts
air travel in Europe and East Asia. In Figure for 2035 have been included in the figure for
ES-7, the international markets are represented by comparison and show a high degree of consistency
the blue dots, which show the proportion of the with the international experience. Sydney-
combined air and HSR travel market captured by Canberra is lower than the expected range for
HSR on selected routes. For HSR journey times journeys less than two hours, but this is largely
of less than two hours, this is typically over 80 per explained by the relatively high proportion of
cent, whereas if HSR journey times exceed four passengers transferring to connecting flights,
and a half hours, the HSR share falls below 30 per which are assumed in the forecasts not to divert
cent. For trips of up to three hours (as for Sydney- to HSR.
Figure ES-7 HSR share of combined HSR/air travel market, comparing the final model forecast for 2035 with international evidence
100%
90%
80%
Sydney–Canberra
70%
Sydney–Melbourne
HSR mode share (%)
Canberra–Melbourne
60%
Brisbane–Sydney
50%
40%
30%
Brisbane–Melbourne
20%
10%
0%
0 50 100 150 200 250 300 350 400 450
HSR in-vehicle time (mins)
Figure ES-7
Executive Summary
The capital costs have been risk-adjusted to reflect In total, the risk adjustment process increased
uncertainty, principally around the scope of the capital costs by about 10.8 per cent11.
major construction, engineering and operational
elements of a future HSR program. Expected The estimated capital cost for the full HSR system,
construction costs are expressed throughout this excluding the cost of train sets12 , is $114.0 billion
chapter in terms of risk-adjusted value, in $2012. in $2012, as shown in Table ES-6.
Gold
Canberra Brisbane- Total
Sydney- Newcastle- Coast
Junction- Gold HSR
Canberra Sydney Junction-
Melbourne Coast system
Newcastle
Project
2.2 2.5 1.7 1.0 3.1 10.4
development
Construction 20.8 24.4 17.2 10.0 31.2 103.6
Total capital costs 23.0 26.9 18.9 11.0 34.3 114.0
Notes: Total does not add up exactly due to rounding.
The references to ‘Canberra Junction’ and ‘Gold Coast Junction’ describe the points at which the Gold Coast and Canberra
spurs leave the main alignment.
11 This is the expected risk-adjusted cost and is within one per cent of the median risk-adjusted cost, commonly known as the P50; the
difference between them is due to the risk adjustment applied to the individual cost components being non-symmetrical. Taking into
account the allowances included in developing the non-risk-adjusted costs, the risk allowance is comparable with what would be
allowed as a physical contingency for a project at a similar early stage of development.
12 Train sets are assumed to be leased in the financial assessment.
13 The frequency represents the likelihood of the total construction costs being within a $1 billion band centred on the corresponding
point on the curve. Thus there is a two per cent chance that the cost will lie between $100.5 billion and $101.5 billion and a four per
cent chance they lie between $107 billion and $108 billion.
Executive Summary
Figure ES-8 Total construction costs (including development costs) ($2012, $billion)
0.06
0.05
0.04
Frequency
0.03
0.02
0.01
–
90 95 100 105 110 115 120 125 130 135 140
($2012, $billion)
Figure ES-9 HSR program average construction costs per route-kilometre in staging order ($2012, $million)
185
185
180
160
140 137
($2012 $million per km)
120
100 87
80
56 54 55 57 57
50
60 43
41 40 38
32
40 25
20
–
Central Coast to Sydney
Albury-Wodonga to Shepparton
Shepparton to Melbourne
Casino to Grafton
Taree to Newcastle
Staging the development of HSR Melbourne, and that establishing this link would
Figure ES-9 be the first priority for any HSR network on the
The size and complexity of an HSR system on the
east coast of Australia. At a construction cost of
east coast of Australia would be such that it could
about $50 billion in $2012 (risk-adjusted), the
not be delivered as a single project; instead, it
Sydney-Melbourne line would represent a major
would be delivered in stages linking the principal
undertaking and would itself need to be staged.
centres. Even these stages would be large projects
Canberra, which would be connected by a spur
by Australian standards. Staging would not only
line to the Sydney-Melbourne line, is the next
allow the upfront funding to be reduced and
most important city on this line from a demand
smooth future funding requirements, but would
viewpoint and would be an appropriate terminal
also better match system development to market
for the first stage to ensure revenue would be
growth and would allow revenue to be generated
generated as early as possible.
on sections of the system as they are completed.
LINE 2
2051
Gold Coast to Brisbane
BRISBANE
$11.0 BN
QLD Gold
Coast
NSW LINE 2
2058
Newcastle to Gold Coast
$34.3 BN
LINE 2
2045
Sydney to Newcastle
$18.9 BN Newcastle
LINE 1
2040 SYDNEY
Canberra to Melbourne
$26.9 BN LINE 1
2035
ACT Sydney to Canberra
CANBERRA
$23.0 BN
VIC
MELBOURNE
Figure ES-11 Staging of the preferred HSR system – cumulative capital costs ($2012, $billion)
A B C D E
120
100
80
($2012, $billion)
60
40
20
–
2015 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2055 2060
Figure ES-11 shows the profile of cumulative Following enabling legislation, a period of more
capital costs over the HSR program. than two years would be required for concept
design, environmental impact assessment and
Line 1 between Sydney and Melbourne would public consultation, before a decision to proceed
be a major undertaking in terms of planning, to implementation would be made in 2021.
construction, testing and commissioning and, There would then be a procurement period of
based on current industry experience, would two to three years to let contracts and to acquire
need to be done in discrete stages. For evaluation land. Enabling works would then be undertaken
purposes, a start date of 2035 was assumed. (critically at Sydney’s Central station). These works
Working back from that date, enabling legislation are anticipated to take four years to divert the
would need to be passed by 2019. Prior to 2019, the current services within the existing operational
final preferred route and station locations would station before the main implementation contracts
be determined, further technical investigations could commence in 2027 (i.e. financial year 2028).
completed and all necessary government approvals
obtained. Steps would also be taken to preserve the
preferred HSR corridor prior to any commitment
to proceed.
High Speed Rail Phase 2 / 23
Assumptions about the timing of the various stages operating costs and the costs of renewing assets
are also shown in Table ES-8. when they wear out. Therefore, provided traffic
forecasts and costs estimates are met, no ongoing
Table ES-9 sets out the summary of risk-adjusted government subsidy would be required to sustain
capital costs, revenues, operating costs and asset HSR operations once the system is constructed
renewals over the evaluation period to 2085. and operational. As traffic builds up, the ability of
The HSR program as a whole delivers a positive transport operations to return some of the capital
net operating surplus. That is, for the preferred costs would increase.
HSR system, revenues would cover ongoing
Table ES-8 Summary of FNPV and FIRR results (present value discounted to 2028, $2012, $billion, 4% discount rate)
Year operations
2035 2040 2045 2051 2058
commence
17 Network complete represents the entire HSR network between Brisbane and Melbourne.
High Speed Rail Phase 2 / 25
Table ES-9 Summary risk-adjusted capital costs, revenues, operating costs and asset renewals over the total evaluation period to 2085
(present value discounted to 2028, $2012, $billion, 4% discount rate)
Year operations
2035 2040 2045 2051 2058
commence
Figure ES-12 HSR program risk-adjusted project cashflows per year ($2012, $billion)
A B C D E
15
10
5
($2012, $billion)
-5
-10
-15
2015 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2055 2060 2065 2070 2075 2080
With the exception of the costs associated with (passenger numbers at that point increase by a
accessing Sydney (as shown in Figure ES-9), factor of five). Operating cashflows and returns
capital costs increase broadly in proportion to then also improve, reflecting the growth in
the length of the HSR line being constructed. patronage without a correspondingly material
As indicated in Figure ES-12, extensions to the increase in capital costs. The same benefit would
network lead to step changes in patronage and be observed when the Gold Coast is connected to
therefore are critical to the operating cashflows. Newcastle and the full HSR system is in operation,
For instance, completing Sydney-Canberra or resulting in a considerable uplift in demand
Canberra-Melbourne as stand-alone segments between Brisbane, Sydney and Melbourne. The
would produce only moderate passenger demand financial performance (annual cashflow) of each
and financial returns. When the whole line stage is summarised in Figure ES-13.
connecting Sydney-Melbourne is completed,
significant additional demand would be generated
High Speed Rail Phase 2 / 27
Figure ES-13 HSR program risk-adjusted cashflows per year by stage ($2012, $billion)
A B C D E
4
–
($2012 $billion)
-2
-4
-6
-8
2015 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2055 2060 2065 2070 2075 2080
Due to the future HSR program’s expected low Based on the detailed analysis of program
financial
Figurereturns,
2 significant private sector funding cashflows, the commercial financing gap for the
(debt/equity) would not be available or appropriate entire HSR program would be about $98 billion (or
to finance the program. As such, a considerable 86 per cent of the total risk-adjusted capital cost) as
commercial financing gap would exist between shown in Table ES-10. For the Sydney-Melbourne
the total capital cost of the HSR program and the line, the commercial financing gap would be about
amount of financing that could be raised from the $45 billion, or 92 per cent of the total capital cost.
financial markets on commercial terms, based on
the future HSR program operating cashflows.
Executive Summary
Table ES-10 Summary of the commercial financing gap – reference case ($2012, $billion)
Value capture has the potential to partially close have on closing the commercial financing gap is
the commercial financing gap through measures therefore difficult to determine at this stage.
such as government land sales and capturing the
incremental impact that the HSR program would Ultimately governments would be required to
have on stamp duty, developments and rates in fund the majority of the future HSR program’s
the HSR affected zones. However, this would be upfront capital costs. A summary of the cashflow
a small contribution at best. It is highly unlikely implications for government for the whole network
that all of these measures would be implemented is presented in Figure ES-14.
and the ultimate benefit that value capture might
A B C D E
—
($2012, $billion)
-2
-4
-6
-8
2015 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2055 2060 2065 2070 2075 2080
Figure ES-15 Present value of costs and benefits for the HSR program (present value discounted to 2028, $2012, $billion,
4% discount rate)
($bn)
120
100
14 1 25 101
80
60
141
40
20
-20
-40
-60
79
-80
-100
Capital User Operator Externalities Residual ENPV
expenditure benefits benefits value
The HSR user benefits dominate the economic Business travellers would gain the majority of user
results and account for 90 per cent of the estimated benefits due to their higher value of time, even
benefits (excluding the residual value). A key though they only represent about 35 per cent of the
component is the assessment of time savings for total HSR travel market, as shown in Table ES-11.
travellers across their full journey including travel
time, waiting time, check-in time and access
time, with adjustments for the inconvenience of
having to change modes. Travel time savings are
measured using values of time based on market
research conducted for this study and tested for
reasonableness against conventional values used in
road projects, which vary by trip purpose
(e.g. business versus leisure)20 .
Table ES-11 User benefit estimates by market segment (present value discounted to 2028, $2012, $billion)
The summary results for the reference case predict discount rate21. A seven per cent discount rate has
that an investment in the preferred HSR program also been tested and would reduce the ENPV to
would generate an economic internal rate of return $5 billion and the EBCR to 1.1, as shown in
(EIRR) of 7.6 per cent and an economic cost- Table ES-12; although marginal, the estimated
benefit ratio (EBCR) of 2.3 using a four per cent economic benefits remain positive.
Table ES-12 Summary economic indicators for the HSR program (present value discounted to 2028, $2012, $billion)
Sydney-Melbourne is the strongest performing line, with an estimated EIRR of 7.8 per cent, as shown in
Table ES-13. It has an estimated positive ENPV of $69 billion and an EBCR of 2.5 when measured on a
stand-alone basis.
Table ES-13 Summary economic indicators for Sydney-Melbourne (present value discounted to 2028, $2012, $billion)
21 The EIRR represents the discount rate that makes the net present value of all economic cashflows equal to zero. The higher the EIRR
the greater the net economic returns achieved by a project relative to its capital resource costs and if EIRR is greater than the
discount rate, then the project would deliver a positive net economic benefit.
Executive Summary
The incremental economic results for each from Newcastle-Melbourne and Brisbane-Gold
additional stage of the preferred HSR program Coast add little incremental economic value on a
are set out in Table ES-14. The results support stand-alone basis (i.e. ENPV does not materially
the preferred staging of the HSR program, with change) and the results suggest they would not be
Sydney-Melbourne delivering an estimated EIRR undertaken unless the intention were to complete
of 7.8 per cent. The subsequent northern stages the line connecting Brisbane and Sydney.
Table ES-14 Incremental economic impacts for each additional stage of the HSR program (present value discounted to 2028, $2012,
$billion)
Year operations
2035 2040 2045 2051 2058
commence
Overall, the results of the analysis present a • No significant increase in aviation capacity
positive economic case for the introduction of in the Sydney basin. This results in increased
HSR. Forecasts were prepared for the reference delays and the inability of passengers to travel
case (i.e. with HSR) which was part of the central at preferred times, consistent with assumptions
case for evaluation purposes. The reference case in the Joint Study on Aviation Capacity for the
reflects a range of long-term assumptions and Sydney Region 22 . Assumed additional aviation
expectations, including: capacity in Sydney has the effect of reducing
• Strong growth in the base travel market over the estimated EIRR for the HSR program as
the 52 years to 2065 (travel on the east coast a whole from 7.6 per cent to 7.1 per cent and
will more than double from 153 million trips to reducing the ECBR from 2.3 to 2.1. Additional
355 million trips). aviation capacity also reduces the financial
return from 0.8 per cent to 0.3 per cent.
22 Australian Government and NSW Government, Joint Study on Aviation Capacity for the Sydney Region, Canberra, 2012.
High Speed Rail Phase 2 / 33
Airline services are mobile in the sense that there are few significant sunk capital costs in servicing
particular routes and assets can be quickly redeployed to other routes. Airlines operating along key
regional and inter-capital routes across the east coast of Australia already compete strongly against each
other, and fare levels of many fare classes have declined over time, which suggests that airfare levels are
already highly competitive on major routes.
It is not expected that airlines would respond to HSR competition by reducing their fares on a sustained
basis. Rather, it has been assumed that airlines would quickly reduce capacity, either by reducing
frequencies or aircraft sizes, to locations within the HSR corridor where there is significant passenger
diversion to HSR. This assumption is consistent with overseas experience where, following the
introduction of HSR, the airline response has generally been to reduce services on the
competitive route.
Airlines do not control all of the components of an end to end journey by air that influence the relative
competitiveness of air travel and HSR travel. Most important of these are the cost of accessing the
airport, its location relative to HSR stations and airport capacity. Nevertheless, to the extent that
airlines are able to innovate in ways that have not been anticipated in this study, it could have an impact
on actual HSR patronage.
Executive Summary
A low demand/high cost sensitivity was • The high growth scenario assumes that the
developed that included a range of alternative Australian economy experiences strong growth
assumptions which in combination result in a set into the future (high GDP growth), with high
of circumstances unfavourable to HSR. The low population growth. This scenario results in
demand/high cost scenario includes: higher overall demand for transport and thus
• No aviation capacity constraints in Sydney. higher demand for HSR. Per capita GDP
growth rates are assumed to be 0.3 per cent
• A 30 per cent increase in pre-risk capital costs.
per year higher than in the reference case, and
• Low population growth and low population growth is assumed to be 103 per
economic growth. cent between 2010 and 2065, compared to
• A 50 per cent increase in HSR fares. 72 per cent in the reference case.
While the combination of these assumptions may • Higher (+30 per cent and +50 per cent)
be unlikely, the results of the analysis provide a HSR fares.
useful basis for comparison and an understanding • An aggressive competitive aviation response
of the economic performance of the HSR program. which results in a 50 per cent reduction in fares
The combination of assumptions significantly for two years.
reduces the economic return generated by the • Additional aviation capacity within the Sydney
future HSR program from 7.6 per cent to region, which removes the negative effects of
3.8 per cent. The impact on the financial return is, travel time on flights to/from Sydney from the
however, modest with the higher costs offset by the reference case, and assumes there is no
large fare increase. unmet demand.
The economic and financial results were tested • Additional aviation capacity within the Sydney
against a range of sensitivity tests, with the results region, combined with 30 per cent increase in
summarised in Figure ES-16 and Figure ES-17: HSR fares.
• The low growth scenario assumes lower • Low demand and high costs (described above).
economic and population growth (relative to • Mode choice model sensitivities (including
the reference case) resulting in lower overall alternative specific constants (ASCs), access/
demand for transport and thus lower demand egress weighting and values of time).
for HSR. It assumes per capita GDP growth • Higher (+30 per cent) capital and
rates are assumed to be 0.3 per cent per year operating costs.
lower than the reference case, and population • Lower (−10 per cent) capital and
growth is assumed to be 51 per cent between operating costs.
2010 and 2065, compared to 72 per cent in the
reference case.
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
0
1
2
3
4
-9
-8
-7
-6
-5
-4
-3
-2
-1
10
-10
EIRR (%)
FIRR (%)
Low case
Low case
5.9%
-0.8%
High case High case
9.4%
1.9%
HSR fares HSR fares +30%
7.4%
2.3%
+30%
7.2%
3.0%
+50%
Competitive Competitive
7.6%
0.8%
aviation response aviation response
0.3%
capacity aviation capacity
2.0%
fares +30% fares +30%
0.6%
Figure ES-16 Impact of alternative assumptions on the economic results (EIRR)
Access/egress Access/egress
7.4%
0.6%
set to 1.0 set to 1.0
Figure ES-17 Impact of alternative assumptions on the financial results (real FIRR post tax)
Fixed value of time Fixed value of time
6.1%
0.6%
Low demand / Low demand /
3.8%
0.5%
high costs high costs
1.8%
=0.8%
=7.6%
-9.8%
Reference case
Reference case
High Speed Rail Phase 2 / 35
Executive Summary
the required HSR capital stock, some of Australia’s The expansion in NSW/ACT’s GSP would
pool of investment would be channelled into HSR come at a cost to the other states, which would
instead of elsewhere. This investment substitution share the burden of reduced investment in other
effect produces a negative impact on the economy, sectors. Productivity gains are also expected to be
since it assumes that investment would be diverted concentrated in NSW/ACT, although there would
away from sectors with a higher financial return still be sufficient gains in Victoria and Queensland
than would be achievable for HSR (which is to yield a positive GSP impact.
projected to achieve only a 0.8 per cent financial
rate of return on capital invested), lowering The construction of HSR draws labour into NSW/
Australia’s average return on investment. Other ACT and away from other states. The assumed
things being equal, and in the absence of higher constraint on labour supply means that the bulk
productivity benefits generated by HSR, this of the expansion in construction sector labour
would lower consumption and GDP. However, requirements in NSW/ACT would have to be
business travel time savings generated by HSR are offset by contractions in other sectors, leading to
estimated to increase labour productivity, which varying impacts on employment by state similar to
over the long term drives gains in GDP, offsetting impacts on GSP by state, but with less intensity.
the negative investment impacts. While beyond the scope of the modelling,
The investment impacts of HSR would be different alternative funding arrangements involving a
if it were assumed to be financed by borrowing different sharing of the financing of HSR would
from foreign sources. There would be less crowding clearly alter the pattern of gains and losses in
out of higher return capital, but costs involved with different regions.
servicing the foreign debt would be incurred.
Implementing a future
Real consumption is estimated to decrease during
the construction of HSR (until around 2056).
HSR program
Post 2056, real consumption begins to increase Roles of the public and private sectors
relative to the baseline as benefits start to flow The Australian Government, ACT Government
from the operation of HSR. As investment in and relevant state governments would need to
HSR tails off and productivity gains flow from the have a central role in the development of HSR.
operational phase, resources can be redirected to This would be due both to its strategic nature and
other investment uses and to consumption, and to the fact that the Australian public would have
national income (moving closely with GDP due to to fund most of the infrastructure. Governments
the assumption of domestic financing) begins to would own the infrastructure and would have
increase and move above the baseline. an obligation to ensure that it was efficiently and
effectively provided and used.
Similarly, the investment substitution effect
means that HSR would impact each of the With an initial capital cost in excess of
Australian states in different ways. All else being $100 billion, a future HSR program would be
equal, an increase in investment in one state, for one of the largest infrastructure programs ever
example, would result in a reduction in the level undertaken in Australia. Its size would challenge
of investment across the remaining states. In the the resources of the supplier industry, both
case of HSR, the impact on each state reflects the domestically and globally, with only a limited
strength of investment in and operation of HSR, number of organisations having the financial
and the concentration of industries that compete capacity and depth of skills and resources available
for HSR inputs within each state. to compete for the likely size of works packages. To
achieve value for money, governments would need
Based on these assumptions, NSW/ACT is to carefully package and stage the procurement
expected to be the primary beneficiary state from to ensure competitive bids were achieved for
HSR due to the substantial investment it receives.
High Speed Rail Phase 2 / 39
each package. Government would need to retain Under the preferred model, HSR train services
some of the risks around the integration of would be contracted to a private sector operator
the component parts, but these risks could be through one or more concession arrangements.
mitigated through rigorous technical oversight. There would be separate concessions for
Line 1 and Line 2, each being a combined
Governments would retain an ongoing role in the exclusive concession for inter-capital express and
stewardship of the HSR sector after construction, regional services on that route, although a single
to ensure the objectives and economic benefits operator would not necessarily be precluded
of the HSR program were achieved. This role from operating both concessions. The concession
would involve providing oversight of the delivery holder(s) would operate the train services, control
of HSR services against agreed price and service the movement of trains through the network and
quality metrics, while being careful to avoid maintain the HSR network.
constraining the market agility and innovation
of those managing the transport services. The preferred model for Australia has common
Governments would also be responsible for safety elements with many of the world’s HSR lines,
and environmental compliance. although overall it is perhaps closest to the
Japanese model for new HSR lines. In Japan, a
The private sector should be closely involved in a single state-owned entity (JRTT) is responsible
broad range of roles: for the development and strategic management of
• Design and construction of components of the the HSR network, but operation of train services,
HSR infrastructure network under contract control of the movement of trains and maintenance
to governments. of lines is carried out by (mainly) private sector
• Development of station precincts in partnership train operating companies serving particular high
with the relevant government. speed routes on an exclusive basis, for which they
• Supply of rolling stock (train sets) and the pay JRTT a fee for use of the line.
signalling and communications systems. Delivering the public sector components
• Control and operation of HSR trains to deliver of a future HSR program
high standard transport services to the public. If adopted, a future HSR program would be
• Maintenance of the HSR system. developed in discrete phases, starting with initial
feasibility studies and investigations, leading
Development of HSR stations, and associated
on to construction and operation of the HSR
commercial opportunities, would offer an
system. Four separate phases can be identified, as
opportunity for private finance. A public-private
illustrated in Figure ES-18.
partnership model is envisaged for greenfield
station developments, with the private sector
partnering with the relevant state or territory
government for CBD station developments.
Executive Summary
1 2 3 4
Preparation & Detailed planning Construction Operation
corridor protection & procurement
The first phase in a future HSR program would Once there is a mandate to implement a preferred
be a preparation and corridor protection phase, HSR system, a publicly-owned HSR development
which would precede a formal commitment authority (HSRDA) would be created to develop,
to build the HSR system. This phase would procure and integrate the HSR system, including
provide the necessary policy foundation for the procuring and owning the required land. A
procurement, construction and operation of a single coordinating authority, with appropriate
future HSR program. It would require alignment professional management expertise, would be
between the participating governments on the required to effectively and efficiently progress the
program objectives, mechanisms and timeframes detailed planning required to develop and procure
for resolving issues, and the delivery of enabling an HSR system (the HSRDA would later evolve
regulation or legislation. into an HSR development and management
authority in the operational phase, and would
The proposed model for pursuing multi- prepare and manage train operations concessions).
jurisdictional agreements of the type needed to The HSRDA could be owned jointly by the
support the HSR program is to adopt a ‘gated Australian Government, ACT Government and
approach’ using a series of formal agreements. relevant state governments.
Each formal agreement in the process would need
to be in place prior to progressing to the next stage,
ensuring alignment of governments at critical
milestones. The first gate would be a Memorandum
of Understanding (MoU) between the Australian,
ACT and state governments to formalise the
engagement on the HSR program and to set out
the responsibilities of the parties, the process
to be followed and the timelines for resolving
issues. Subsequent gates would involve formal
inter-governmental agreements (IGAs), first to
protect an HSR corridor and later to develop and
implement a stage or stages of HSR.
High Speed Rail Phase 2 / 41
Next steps
If it were decided that the case for HSR on the east
coast of Australia has sufficient merit for further
government action to be taken, there are a number
of immediate next steps in the process that could
lead to a decision to protect the HSR corridor and
possibly to a decision to implement HSR.